View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March I, 1997

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Maintaining a Low Inflation Environment
by John B. Carlson
The slight firming of monetary conditions is viewed as a prudent step that
affords greater assurance ofprolonging
the current economic expansion by sustaining the existing low inflation environment through the rest of this year and
next. The experience of the last several
years has reiriforced the conviction that
low inflation is essential to realizing the
economy sfa/lest growth potential.
- FOMC, March 25, 1997

Immediately after its March 25 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) announced that it had "decided
to tighten money market conditions
slightly, expecting the fed funds rate to
rise Y. percentage point to around 5Yi
percent." 1 This was the Committee's
first action in almost 14 months and the
first increase since January 1995.
The FOMC's policy actions receive a
great deal of attention in the financial
press, and the recent rate hike was no
exception. Reports typically focus on the
possible near-term consequences of interest rate changes, including the potential impact on other interest rates and on
asset prices. If investors believe that an
increase in the federal funds rate is likely
to be persistent or to be followed by additional rate hikes, other interest rates typically rise as well (although less than
proportionally). Financial market commentary sometimes speculates that
higher interest rates will lead to an economic downturn.

ISSN 0428- 1276

Experience in the 1970s revealed a
strong negative correlation between significant moves in interest rates and subsequent economic activity. Yet, interest
rates can rise markedly without causing a
downturn in the economy. Between January 1982 and August 1984, for example,
FOMC actions drove the federal funds
rate up 300 basis points (b.p.), to 11.6
percent. Although the economy's rate of
expansion slowed, it still grew at a 3.3
percent pace over the following two
years. In 1994, the funds rate again increased 300 b.p., yet the economy expanded nearly 3 percent over the last
two years and 4.0 percent over the last
four quarters.
What makes these experiences different
from that of the 1970s? The answer, I
believe, is that the FOMC's actions since
1982 have demonstrated the Federal Reserve's determination to achieve and
maintain price stability. This policy
stance has fostered conditions that allow
the economy to attain its fullest growth
potential. If the Committee had failed to
act in a manner consistent with maintaining stable prices, it would have risked allowing inflationary imbalances to develop. These imbalances could then have
been eliminated only with even greater
and more persistent rate increases, such
as those required in the 1970s. It is this
persistence that is more likely to induce
economic contractions.

-

M onetary policy since 1982 demonstrates that the federal funds rate can
vary substantially with few or no
adverse economic consequences. In
fact, funds rate increases in response
to inflationary pressures have been
associated with robust growth in
recent years. The economy's favorable performance over the past
decade and a half highlights the
importance of maintaining the existing low inflation environment.

Fed's primary problem is the acquisition
and maintenance of credibility in its
commitment to low inflation.3 Key to
this analysis is Goodfriend's formulation
of the inflation scare problem.

The Inflation Scare Problem

An inflation scare is defined as a significant rise in long-term interest rates in
the absence of an aggressive policy response. Fluctuations in long-term rates
are driven by two components: one connected with the current funds rate target
that anchors short maturity rates, and
one driven by inflation expectations. An
inflation scare occurs when the FOMC
does not raise the funds rate enough to
prevent investors from questioning the
credibility of its commitment to maintaining stable prices. Failure to respond
promptly and adequately to such a scare
risks a crisis in confidence that encourages higher inflation.

Evidence for this thesis can be found by
reviewing monetary policy since 1982 in
the context of a framework proposed by
Federal Reserve economist Marvin
Goodfriend. 2 He postulates that the

To avoid inflation scares, the FOMC
must take pre-emptive action if incoming data indicate a greater risk of future
inflation. In principle, this requires the

•

FOMC to adjust its funds rate target over
the business cycle to prevent excessive
money growth. In the early 1990s, however, the reliability of money measures
as indicators of inflation was called into
question. In fact, evidence showed that
the relationship between money and
economic activity bad become permanently disturbed. Since 1993, the FOMC
has been operating without a widely accepted guideline for money growth, a
process that has complicated the group's
efforts to anticipate and respond to incipient signs of inflationary pressure. 4
Pressure on the price level can arise ifthe
FOMC does not adjust the funds rate in
the face of changing credit demands driven by cyclical fluctuations in economic
activity.5 For instance, credit demand is
typically strong near the peak of a business cycle. This tends to put upward
pressure on market interest rates. If the
FOMC does not respond by sufficiently
raising the funds rate, at some point inflation will rise and will have to be counteracted by corrective actions more likely to
depress economic activity. The go/stop
policies of the 1970s provide a clear example that waiting until the public recognizes that inflation is a problem means
waiting too long. 6

•

The Post-1982 Experience

By contrast, the policy experience since
1982 provides examples of the FOMC's
efforts to pre-empt inflation. During this
time, the funds rate was increased over
sustained periods on three occasions:
August 1983 to August 1984, April 1988
to March 1989, and February 1994 to
February 1995 (see figure 1). Below, I
discuss each of these episodes in turn.

August 1983- August 1984
After enduring the worst recession since
the Great Depression, the economy
rebounded sharply in 1983 and continued to grow at nearly a 6 percent pace
throughout 1984. The 1985 Economic
Report ofthe President attributed the
robust economic expansion and high real
interest rates to tax policies that raised
the real after-tax rate ofreturn on new
business investment. With such a favorable return on new investment, it became worthwhile for firms with good
investment opportunities to borrow at
the higher rates.

Investment booms, however, are by nature transitory. It is thus hard to reconcile
such an event with the substantial rise in
long-term interest rates that occurred in
the year ending June 1984. The yield on
the 10-year Treasury bond, for example,
increased 200 b.p. over that period.
Hence, the rise in long rates partly reflected growing inflation expectations
(see figure 2), while the run-up in the
federal funds rate, which lagged, largely
reflected an effort by the FOMC to contain an inflation scare.
Real interest rates also rose, but by less
than nominal rates (see figure 3). Although inflation expectations picked up
between the fall of 1983 and the summer
of 1984, an acceleration in core inflation
failed to materialize, and inflation expectations fell sharply over the following
two years. In 1985, financial markets
became more confident that inflation was
contained, and long-term nominal interest rates generally fell, reaching cyclical
lows in the fall of 1986. As evidence
accumulated that the trend inflation rate
was settling down to around 4 percent,
the FOMC lowered the funds rate to the
mid-6 percent range.7

-

FIGURE 1 FED FUNDS RATE
AND THE 10-YEAR
TREASURY YIELD

o.___.__.__.___._.__.._.....__.___..__..._.._.....__.___..__.

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

-

FIGURE 2 INFLATION
EXPECTATIONS a

6Percent
.0.--------------------.
5.5

5.0

4.5
4.0
3.5

April 1988-March 1989
An acceleration in economic activity in
1987 was accompanied by a 200-b.p.
increase in long-term rates between
March and October. Between April and
October, the FOMC raised the intended
federal funds rate from 6 to 7 3/s percent.
This course was reversed sharply in
October in the face of dramatically
declining stock prices, with the funds
rate being pushed down more than 60
b.p. over the following five months.
Then, a series of funds rate increases
was resumed in April 1988, but not in
time to head off an abrupt jump in the
trend of core inflation. Hence, policy
actions over the course of the following
year were largely directed at reversing
an acceleration in the price level.
From April 1988 to March 1989, the
funds rate increased more than 300 b.p.,
while the 10-year Treasury rose only-I 00
b.p. Breakpoint analysis suggests that
the sudden increase in the core inflation
trend was contained and that the index
began drifting down somewhat later, in

3.0

2.5
2.0 .__..__.__.__.___.__,_.__...___._......__._........__.--''--'
1983 1985 1987 1989 1991
1993 1995 1997

a. Data reflect year-ahead expectations.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia's Survey of
Professional Forecasters.

August 1990 (see figure 4). Moreover,
this episode was followed by a recession
beginning in 1990, implying that the
necessary corrective policy actions may
have exacerbated a weakening economy.
It should be pointed out that this period
included an oil price shock induced by
Iraq's invasion of Kuwait, which could
account for a downturn in economic
activity. Nevertheless, had the FOMC
been able to follow through on the policy tightening initiated in 1987, the need
for a corrective response would have
been mitigated. Hence, the economy
would have been less vulnerable to the
oil supply shock.

-

FIGURE 3 NOMINAL AND REAL
INTEREST RATES
Percent
13

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System; and the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia's
Survey of Professional Forecasters.

-

FIGURE 4 CORE INFLATION
SINCE 1982 3
Percent change, annual rate

three 25-b.p. increments until it reached
SY. percent by mid-winter 1996. The rate
remained around this level until the
March policy action, a period of almost
14 months. Long-term interest rates bottomed out around the beginning of 1996
and increased slightly in the early months
of the year. The 10-year Treasury, for example, rose to nearly 7 percent in June
1996 and has been varying just under
that level ever since.
Long-term rates, however, remain well
below their 1994 peak levels, suggesting
that the inflation scare of 1994 has been
arrested. Moreover, although the funds
rate has retraced less than a third of its
advance over this period, the economy
has showed great resilience, and inflation has not accelerated. Indeed, it has
been decades since there has been such a
favorable constellation oflow inflation,
low unemployment, and high output
growth. To a large extent, this outcome
is a consequence of the FOMC's timely
responses to inflationary pressures.

•

o .__..__.__.___..~.__..__.__.___..___..__.._....__.___..__.

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

a. Core inflation is measured as the trimmed mean of the
Consumer Price Index. Brown lines represent trend rates
determined by breakpoint tests.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

February 1994-February 1995
With evidence that inflation had been
contained, long-term rates began to head
down in the spring of 1989 and continued this trend until the fall of 1993. A
subsequent rise in long rates that began
in November of that year represented a
potential inflation scare. The FOMC responded vigorously, raising the intended
funds rate 300 b.p. between January
1994 and February 1995. Inflation remained steady and has continued to vary
around its mean rate since August 1992.
When inflationary pressures abated, market interest rates fell, and the FOMC
reduced the intended federal funds rate in

Concluding Thoughts

Since 1982, U.S. output growth has exceeded 3 percent per year. This compares with an average annual growth rate
of2.3 percent over the previous 15 years.
Moreover, economic expansion in the
later period has been interrupted by only
one recession, ending six years ago. Inflation, by contrast, is now substantially
below its 1980s' trend rate.
One of the fruits of achieving a low inflation environment is that inflation expectations have fallen substantially. This, in
turn, has allowed for a trend decline in
interest rates. The drop in inflation expectations largely reflects the enhanced
credibility of the FOMC's commitment
to price stability-a credibility that it acquired by demonstrating a willingness to
respond to inflationary pressures before
they could become permanently embedded in a higher inflation trend.
The post-1982 experience also demonstrates that the funds rate can vary substantially with few or no adverse economic consequences. The first and third
episodes of rate increases were followed
by relatively robust economic conditions
and stable inflation. They represent

examples of pre-emptive policies. The
middle episode, although followed by a
recession, came too late to head off an
increase in inflation.
It is not clear that any policy can reverse
an acceleration in the price level without
risking a decline in output. This suggests
that it is imperative for the FOMC to
anticipate inflationary imbalances and to
take action before inflation becomes
embedded in a higher trend rate. Such
policies could mean raising the funds
rate substantially and expediently. The
post-1982 experience suggests that such
timely actions may be necessary to
maintain the low inflation environment
required for the economy to realize its
fullest growth potential.
The FOMC's main tactical problem is
deciding when pre-emptive actions are
necessary and how aggressive they
should be. Some analysts fear that the
Committee's approach to this problem
since 1982, while successful, may not be
sufficient to deal with all situations. In
their view, the central bank's commitment to price stability could be strengthened by legislative mandate.8 A bill proposed by Senator Connie Mack (R-Fla.)
would make low inflation the primary
goal of monetary policy.
In addition, the FOMC's tactics might be
enhanced by a strategy that includes
intermediate targets for nominal GDP or
some money measure. For much of the
post-1982 period, the Committee set
annual targets for M2 as the primary
guide for policy. Although the relationship between M2 and economic activity
has broken down, evidence is accumulating that it may again become a reliable indicator. IfM2 velocity does stabilize around some new level, efforts to
keep the aggregate's growth trend low
would also keep inflation in check.

•

Footnotes

1. This article went to press on July 8, 1997.
2. See Marvin Goodfriend, "Interest Rate
Policy and the Lnflation Scare Problem:
1979- 1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly, vol. 79; no. I
(Winter 1993), pp. 1- 24.

5. In a world of perfect credibility, adjustments in the federal funds rate might not be
required. For a framework that illustrates
this point, see Charles T. Carlstrom and
Timothy S. Fuerst, "Interest Rate Rules for
Seasonal and Business Cycles," Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentmy, July 1996.

-

John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. For helpful
comments and suggestions, the author thanks

Jagadeesh Gokhale, Mark Sniderman, and
E.J Stevens.
The views stated herein are those of the

3. The notion of credibility is important
because it can contain movements in inflation
expectations reflected in long-term interest
rates. For example, to the extent tbat a policy
is directed at keeping inflation low (say,
below 2 percent), one might expect the I0year Treasury bond rate to range between 2
and 7 percent over a normal business cycle.
To the extent that such a policy is not credible
and the potential exists for inflation to accelerate to 1970 rates, one might expect the same
Treasury rate to be well above I 0 percent.

6. For a discussion oftbis point and a
description of policy over this period, see
Marvin Goodfriend, "Monetary Policy
Comes of Age: A 20th Century Odyssey,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly, vol. 83, no. I (Winter
1997), pp. 1-22.

7. The CPI fell to less than 2 percent in 1986
because of a sharp drop in energy prices.
Core inflation, on the other hand, remained
near its trend rate of just over 4 percent.

author and not necessarily those of the Fed. era/ Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Economic Commentary is available elec-

tronically through the Cleveland Fed's site on
the World Wide Web: http://www.clev.frb.org.
We also offer a free on-line subscription service to notifj; readers of additions to our Web
site. To subscribe, please send an email mes-

4. In July 1993, Federal Reserve Chairman
Alan Greenspan announced that "at least for
tbe time being, M2 has been downgraded as a
reliable indicator of financial conditions in the
economy, and no single variable bas yet been
identified to take its place." See 1993 Mone-

8. See, for example, Marvin Goodfriend,
"Monetary Policy Comes of Age: A 20th
Century Odyssey" (footnote 6).

sage to econpubs-on@clev.frb.org.

tmy Policy Objectives: Summary Report of the
Federal Reserve Board, July 20, 1993, p. 8.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.

Material may be reprinted provided tbat
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to tbe editor.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385