View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

February 1, 2002*

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Legal Systems and Bank Development
by O. Emre Ergungor

W

hat promotes economic development? The question has puzzled economists for years. Recent research suggests
that a country’s financial system plays a
key role in its growth (see King and
Levine 1998 and Levine 1999). In some
countries—France and Germany, for
example—most firms borrow the money
they need from banks. In others—like the
United States and the United Kingdom—
firms most often turn to credit markets to
raise capital. Some anecdotal evidence
suggests that in the latter half of the
1990s, economies with market-based
financial systems grew more rapidly than
bank-based systems. But research shows
that over long periods, countries with
large banking industries do as well as
those with large financial markets. The
important factor is how well developed a
financial system is, not its type (see
Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic 1998
and Levine and Zervos 1998).
If that is so, why do some countries have
market-oriented financial systems while
others are oriented toward banks? One
strand of research suggests that a country’s financial system is influenced by
the path its industries took during the
industrial revolution. Another strand
traces countries’ differences in financial
structure to differences in their regulatory environments. But neither approach
satisfactorily explains why banks predominate in some countries and markets
predominate in others. The missing
piece of the puzzle seems to be a country’s legal traditions, which determine
the structure of its financial system.
Countries that follow common law
(based on the law of England) are
market-oriented, while those that follow

ISSN 0428-1276
*Printed March 2002

civil law (based on the law of France)
have a marked preference for banks.
This Commentary examines the role of
legal systems in determining the type of
financial system a country develops. It
describes the differences in how judges
interpret and enforce contracts under
civil law versus common law and how
those differences affect a country’s
financial system. Where civil law prevails, the courts’ literal interpretation of
contract language makes writing onetime, bilateral contracts problematic and
requires involving a financial intermediary such a bank in the contracting
process. The wider discretion enjoyed by
common law judges in interpreting contract language reduces the cost of writing contracts and favors market-oriented
financial systems. On the whole, differences in how countries make and apply
laws (that is, their legal traditions) may
be the most important factor shaping
their financial systems.

■ Civil Law versus
Common Law
Judges’ power to issue opinions that go
beyond the literal interpretation of
statutes is an important difference
between civil and common law. Civil
law’s tradition of strict interpretation of
statutes and contracts dates to the French
Revolution. Accusations that corrupt
judges were betraying the people by systematically ruling in favor of the aristocracy led to the enactment of Article 5 of
the French Civil Code of 1804, which
forbade judges to lay down general rules
in deciding cases. Continued mistrust of
judges strongly influenced the organization of the courts, which were eager to

In some countries, banks are firms’
key source of financing. In others,
firms look mainly to credit markets to
meet their financial needs. Why
should this be so? New research suggests that a country’s legal tradition
strongly influences which financial
system becomes dominant there.

show their submissiveness to the new
order. The result—complete obedience
to the word of the law—became an integral part of the civil law tradition.
Under civil law, the judge’s duty is strict
application of the law as laid down in
codes and enactments. But no legislation
can be applied in a purely mechanical
way, so civil codes contain explicit
directions for interpreting texts. The
most famous of these interpretive directives is Article 1 of the Swiss Civil Code
of 1907, which instructs the judge that if
he can find no rule in enacted law, he
must decide in accordance with customary law and, failing that, in accordance
with the rule that he as a legislator would
adopt, consistent with approved legal
doctrine and judicial tradition. But during the years the Swiss Civil Code has
been in force, Article 1 has rarely been
invoked. Swiss judges almost always
prefer to follow more traditional methods of interpretation, which involve logical and grammatical torture of the code
in search of a section that applies to the
issue at hand.

In the common law tradition, however,
judges sometimes are required not only
to apply the law but also to interpret and,
to a degree, even create it. This creation
process has been described as “the discovery of the old unwritten custom of
the land” (in the declaratory theory of
common law). Some legal scholars compare common law to Newton’s laws of
nature, which had always existed; Newton, they say, did no more than discover
and label them (see Greenberg 1986).
Judges’ rulings often rely on precedents
that were established by past decisions;
that is, judges can base their decision on
more than the specific terms of existing
laws, they can apply other judges’ arguments and interpretations, and they can
extend the general principles underlying
previous decisions to situations they
view as similar. In Law and Society,
Steven Vago claims the practice has several strengths. Vago says it is often much
easier and less time-consuming to follow
precedents than to search all over again
for solutions that have already been
found by applying pre-existing laws.
Precedents also enable the judge to draw
on wisdom accumulated by earlier generations outside of legal statutes. Applying precedents is argued to minimize
arbitrariness and make it easier for less
experienced judges to issue fair decisions. More important, it enables individuals to plan their conduct, secure in
the expectation that past decisions will
be honored in the future.
All this could lead us to suppose that
common law courts are more effective
in resolving conflicts than civil law
courts because they are freer to create
and interpret the law when the statues
are incomplete and do not address a
particular situation. However, this
argument may seem too strong because
Western European and North American
countries are known to have very efficient judicial systems. But the most
commonly used measures of judicial
efficiency include factors like the speediness with which a case is resolved in
court or judges’ susceptibility to bribes.
In our context, “efficiency” is not
measured by the number of cases
heard or the amount of time and money
expended per case. Nor does it concern
judges’ integrity. It refers to the interpretive power of judges to go beyond the
letter of the law and the fact that codes
in civil law countries constrain judges
far more powerfully than those in common law countries (see Glaeser and
Shleifer 2001).

■ Legal Systems and Financial
System Development
One way to characterize a country’s
financial system is to look at the ratio
between loans by deposit-taking banks
and market capitalization. As this ratio
goes up, so does the importance of
banks in the economy. By this standard,
figure 1 shows that in 1994, markets
were more important than banks in
economies like those of the United
States (with a ratio of 1.33), the United
Kingdom (1.22), Nigeria (0.85),
Zimbabwe (0.78), Malaysia (0.68), and
South Africa (0.43). Banks were the
key players in France (ratio of 6.57),
Austria (22.67), Egypt (5.50), the
Philippines (4.50), Indonesia (3.20),
and Argentina (4.14).
The crucial point in figure 1 is that
countries whose legal systems are based
on common law have market-oriented
economies (with a low bank/market
ratio), and countries with legal systems
based on civil law are bank-oriented
(with a high bank/market ratio). Why
is there a relationship between legal
systems and financial systems when neither factor in itself seems to affect a
country’s per capita GDP (horizontal
axis of figure 1)? The answer may lie
in differences in the way contracts are
written and enforced.
We know that it is practically impossible
for any contract to include a clause that
covers every contingency. Then how do
you settle disputes that arise when an
uncovered contingency becomes a reality? You can go to court. This is a viable
alternative in common law countries
because judges are not strictly bound by
the clauses of the contract but feel free to
interpret them (or the laws for that matter) to determine whether the parties
acted in accord with the spirit of the contract. One good example is contracts’
penalty clauses, which specify sanctions
for a party’s failure to abide by the terms
of the agreement. In the U.S. (common
law) legal system, penalty clauses are
generally inapplicable because the judge
determines whether a contractual
promise has been broken and, even if it
has, can alter the contractual penalty.
But in civil law countries, contracts,
including penalty clauses, are strictly
enforced. Another good example is the
code that governs the distance between
buildings and trees in a community. In
civil law countries, a slight violation,
although reasonable and harmless to a

neighbor, compels destruction of the
building or eradication of the offending
tree. In common law countries, a standard of reasonableness guides the
judge’s decision (the second example is
from Mattei 2000).
Recent research shows that, in the civil
law tradition, restraints on judges’ interpretive powers affect the way contracts
are written and enforced. When a country’s civil law courts are not effective in
settling disputes between credit market
participants, banks emerge as institutions
that can resolve conflicts and enforce
contracts without a court’s intervention
(see Ergungor 2001 for a full discussion).
To see how banks mitigate contractual
problems, imagine that a borrower has
devised a fraudulent way to transfer
assets or profits. The lender has been
damaged, but a civil law court cannot
remedy the situation because the borrower’s technique is not specifically covered in the statutes. In other words, the
borrower’s actions are immoral but not
necessarily illegal. Civil law courts do
not function this way because they are
negligent or incompetent but because,
unlike their common law counterparts,
they put more emphasis on the word of
the law than on fairness. This allows
insiders in civil law countries to structure unfair transactions that conform to
the letter of the law. Johnson et al.
(2000) confirm this behavior of civil law
courts in conflicts between minority and
controlling shareholders when controlling shareholders transfer the assets and
profits out of the firm.
The economic effect of civil courts’ limitations is that would-be borrowers cannot convince lenders that they will not
exploit them, so they cannot borrow
from capital markets. What advantage
does a bank have in these circumstances? It can make a credible commitment to provide borrowers with a service
in the future that individual investors
cannot offer. For example, a bank can
promise to lend a customer money in the
future at a predetermined rate (a contract
known as a loan commitment). For reasons similar to those that weaken
promises made by individual borrowers,
promises by individual lenders would
lack credibility: Individual lenders are
more inclined to opportunistic behavior
because even though they put their
reputation and future business opportunities at risk, they collect all the benefits
of their action. In contrast, shareholders

■ Recommended Reading

FIGURE 1 RATIO OF BANK LOANS TO STOCK MARKET
CAPITALIZATION VERSUS PER CAPITA GDP, 1994

Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale.
1999. “Diversity of Opinion and
Financing of New Technologies.”
Journal of Financial Intermediation.
8 (1–2), pp. 68–89.

Bank / market ratio
25
Civil law legal tradition
Common law legal tradition
Austria

Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale.
2000a. “Comparing Financial
Systems.” In Comparing Financial
Systems, Cambridge: The MIT Press.

20

15

Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale.
2000b. “The Historical Development of
Financial Systems.” In Comparing
Financial Systems, Cambridge: The
MIT Press.

Germany

Portugal
10
Egypt
Philippines
Indonesia

Italy
Greece

Boot, W. A. Arnoud, Anjan V. Thakor,
and Gregory F. Udell. 1991. “Credible
Commitments, Contract Enforcement
Problems, and Banks: Intermediation as
Credibility Assurance.” Journal of Banking and Finance. 15 (3), pp. 605–32.

Spain
France

5
Turkey
Argentina
Thailand
Colombia
Brazil Korea
Mexico
Chile
South Africa
Peru
Malaysia
Zimbabwe

Pakistan
India
0

Finland

Norway
Belgium
Denmark
Netherlands
Sweden
Australia
New Zealand
United States
United Kingdom Hong KongSingapore
Israel

Switzerland
Japan

Canada

Nigeria

0

5

10

15
20
25
Per capita GDP (thousand of dollars)

30

35

SOURCES: Levine (1998); and La Porta et al. (1997).

of an institution would have to share
those benefits with all the other shareholders, while each individual shareholder has his entire reputation at risk
(see Boot, Thakor, and Udell 1991).
The ability to offer services that markets cannot offer gives banks superior
bargaining power. Banks can restrain
borrowers’ opportunistic behavior with
a credible threat to withhold unique,
valuable services. All market participants anticipate that a borrower who
has a relationship with a bank will
honor his obligations in order to preserve that relationship. Thus, banks
prevent credit market failure.

■ Conclusion
The orientation of a country’s financial
system seems to be influenced by that
country’s legal system: Firms in common law countries are more likely to
use credit markets, and firms in civil
law countries prefer banks. This Commentary examines the reasons for this
difference and argues that banks can
mitigate a legal system’s ill effects on
financing. Banks can use both carrot
and stick to restrain opportunistic borrowers from exploiting legal loopholes;
in doing so, banks allow credit markets
to function properly. This ability gives
banks a crucial role in the economy in
addition to their traditional role as liquidity providers.

40

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav
Maksimovic. 1998. “Law, Finance, and
Firm Growth.” Journal of Finance.
53 (6), pp. 2107–137.
Ergungor, O. Emre. 2001. “Market- vs.
Bank-Based Financial Systems: Do
Investor Rights Really Matter?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working
Paper, no. 01-01.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Andrei Shleifer.
2001. “Legal Origins,” Harvard Institute
of Economic Research, Discussion
Paper, no. 1920.
Greenberg, Donald W. 1986. “United
States.” In Alan N. Katz, ed., Legal Traditions and Systems: An International
Handbook. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, pp. 415–35.
Johnson, Simon, Rafael LaPorta,
Florencio Lopez de Silanes, and Andrei
Shleifer. 2000. “Tunneling,” Harvard
Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper, no. 1887.
King, Robert G., and Ross Levine.
1993. “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108 (3), pp. 717–37.

LaPorta, Rafael, Florencia Lopez de
Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert
Vishny. 1997. “Legal Determinants of
External Finance.” Journal of Finance.
52 (3), pp. 1131–50.
Levine, Ross. 1998. “The Legal
Environment, Banks, and Long-run
Economic Growth.” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking. 30 (3), pp. 596–620.
Levine, Ross. 1999. “Law, Finance, and
Economic Growth.” Journal of Financial Intermediation. 8 (1–2), pp. 8–35.
Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos. 1998.
“Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic
Growth.” American Economic Review.
88 (3), pp. 537–58.
Mattei, Ugo. 2000. Comparative Law
and Economics. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

O. Emre Ergungor is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
The views expressed here are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, or its staff.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your
request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or
fax it to 216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is also available at the Cleveland Fed’s
site on the World Wide Web:
www.clev.frb.org/research, where glossaries
of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

Vago, Steven. 2001. Law and Society.
Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice Hall.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385