View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Conclusion
Most analysts believe that growing
U.S. trade deficits cannot continue. As
our international indebtedness grows,
foreigners will become increasingly
reluctant to acquire additional dollardenominated assets. This will initiate
adjustments in many economic variables, including exchange rates and
interest rates, to bring the international economy back into balance. How
and how quickly these adjustments
take place depends in large part on how
rapidly the market decides to adjust its
holdings of dollar-denominated assets."
Depreciation of the dollar can contribute to the adjustment process by
increasing the competitiveness of U.S.
goods and services in world markets.
Nevertheless, economists have long
realized that the ability of an economy
to meet increased demands for its goods

and services limits the contribution of a
currency depreciation to improving its
trade balance. If the economy is operating at full capacity, the depreciation
will not generate much improvement in
the trade balance. Ultimately a reduction in the trade deficit requires that
the United States reduce its budget
deficit, that it promotes savings, and
that it encourages production of tradable goods and services.
Exchange-market participants understand these relationships and look for
compatible developments in U.S. economic policies. If they believe that the United
States is attempting to force a dollar
depreciation through an inflationary
increase in money growth or that the
United States is not taking credible
steps to reduce its budget deficit, international investors, who have played an
important role in helping finance U.S.
credit demands, could shift rapidly out
of dollars into assets denominated in

other currencies. Under such circumstances, no amount of exchange-market
intervention could supplant appropriate
monetary or fiscal policies.
If, on the other hand, monetary and
fiscal policy are consistent with a reduction in the trade deficit and an
orderly depreciation of the dollar, then
intervention can playa useful role in
reinforcing the intention of policy should
market uncertainty arise. Policymakers
should clearly state the objectives of
such policies. Under these circumstances, monetary and fiscal policies
will help minimize market uncertainty
and, hence, the need for intervention.

12. See Humpage, Owen F. "Should We Be Concerned About the Speed of the Depreciation?"
Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, March 15, 1986.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested:
Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

February 1, 1987

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

ISSN 0428·1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
The Group of Five countries (France,
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom
and the United States), plus Canada,
met in Paris on February 21 and 22,
seeking ways to eliminate huge trade
imbalances in the United States, Japan
and Germany, to encourage greater
exchange-market stability, and to
thwart growing protectionism.'
The recent rapid depreciation of the
dollar, which poses major problems both
for the United States and for our major
trading partners, prompted the Paris
meeting. As the dollar depreciates relative to other currencies, foreign exporters find it difficult to compete against
U.S. goods in world markets. The dollar
depreciation already has contributed to
a sharp slowdown in Japan's economic
growth. For the United States, fear of
continued rapid dollar depreciation increases the risk that international
investors will shift funds out of dollardenominated assets and, thereby, force
up U.S. interest rates. Federal Reserve
Chairman Paul A. Volcker repeatedly
has cautioned about this possible effect.
The depreciation also will contribute to
higher prices in the United States.
Although vague on the issue, the Paris
meeting increased speculation that the
participating countries would intervene
more forcefully in an attempt to limit
movements in key exchange rates. As
newspapers recently have reported, Japan, and to a lesser extent, Germany
have committed large sums to exchangemarket intervention. In contrast, however, the United States has been reluctant to intervene in the exchange

market, believing that when nations
conduct intervention independent of
their monetary policies it has, at best, a
limited influence on exchange rates.
This Economic Commentary discusses
the U.S. reluctance to intervene in exchange markets. We present three
theoretical channels through which
exchange-market intervention could influence exchange rates: the monetary
channel, the portfolio-adjustment channel, and the expectations channel.2

Owen F. Humpage is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

1. This article was revised and published after
the February Group of Five meeting and has been
backdated in order to maintain the continuity of
the Economic Commentary series- editor.

A Definition
Exchange-market intervention refers to
official purchases and sales of foreign
exchange, which nations undertake
through their central banks to influence
the exchange val ue of their currencies.
Although nations have many ways to influence their exchange rate-such as
using monetary and fiscal policy, capital controls and trade barriersexchange-market intervention seems the
most direct and most flexible method.
Many nations, therefore, frequently
resort to intervention. Members of the
European Monetary System, for example, routinely intervene to keep their
exchange rates within narrow margins.'
Much of the recent interest in intervention stems from the belief that
intervention enables nations to influence their exchange rates without
altering monetary and fiscal policies.
To understand this, we first must distinguish between sterilized and nonsterilized intervention. When a country
undertakes sterilized intervention, it
engages in other transactions to prevent either the purchase or sale of for-

2. The author presents a more detailed analysis
of intervention and a survey of the literature in:
"Exchange- Market Intervention: The Channels
of Influence," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Quarter 3, 1986, pp.2·14.

Should We
Intervene in
Exchange
Markets?
by Owen F. Humpage

eign currency from influencing its
money-supply growth. In contrast,
nonsterilized intervention can alter a
country's money supply.
An example can help clarify the
important distinction between sterilized and nonsterilized intervention.
Suppose the United States wants to
slow a depreciation of the dollar relative to the German mark. At the direction of the Treasury Department, the
Federal Reserve System would buy dollars with German marks through its
foreign-exchange desk in New York.
Because this transaction reduces the
supply of dollars in the foreignexchange market, the dollar should
then appreciate relative to the German
mark. The foreign-exchange desk's
purchase of dollars, however, also contracts the money supply in the United
States. At this point, the intervention
transaction is nonsterilized.
The reduction in the money supply
resulting from intervention might be
inconsistent with the domestic objectives of monetary policy. Consequently,
the Federal Reserve then might wish to
offset the impact of the intervention
purchases of dollars by purchasing
Treasury bills through the System's
open-market desk at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. The purchase of Treasury bills supplies
reserves to the banking system and
increases the money supply. Thus, by
coordinating the activities of the
foreign-exchange and open-market
desks, the Federal Reserve can offset,
or sterilize, the monetary impact of its
exchange-market activities.

3. The United States intervened quite frequently
during much of the 1970s, but has intervened
relatively infrequently in the 1980s.

While sterilized intervention has no
effect on the money stock, it does
change the public's relative holdings of
U.S. Treasury securities and foreign
securities. In our example, sterilized
intervention reduces the supply of
dollar-denominated Treasury securities
in the market.'
The Impact of Nonsterilized
Exchange- Market Intervention
Nonsterilized intervention alters nations' money supplies, whereas sterilized
intervention alters relative supplies of
government securities." Consequently,
we initially discuss the influence of a
change in monetary policy on the
exchange rate and then describe the
unique influence of sterilized intervention. Both types of intervention can
influence expectations, which we also
will discuss.
Economists have long recognized a
relationship between changes in countries' monetary growth rates and
changes in exchange rates (or in the
balance of payments under fixed
exchange rates). Although economists
might disagree about the timing, about
the precise chain of causation, and
about the relative importance of money
for determining exchange rates, few
would object on theoretical grounds to
the inclusion of money among the key
determinants of exchange rates.
A common description of the chain of
events connecting a reduction in money
growth to a currency appreciation
would be as follows: If the United
States were to slow its money growth,
say from 10 percent per year to 8 percent, with other factors unchanged, it
would experience an increase in its
interest rates, at least initially. If foreign countries maintain their interest
rates, international investors will
transfer funds from assets denominated in foreign currencies, say German marks, to assets denominated in
dollars. To obtain dollars, these investors will trade German marks for dollars in the exchange market. The
increased supply of German marks and
increased demand for dollars will tend
to cause the dollar to appreciate relative to the mark.

The reduced rate of U.S. money
growth also might slow the pace of
economic activity and reduce the rate
of inflation in the United States. But,
prices typically adjust more slowly
than the exchange rate, so the initial
slowing in the money growth rate will
cause the dollar to appreciate both on a
nominal basis and on an inflationadjusted, or real, basis." The real
appreciation of the dollar will make
U.S. goods less competitive in world
markets, until the U.S. inflation rate
adjusts to the slower pace of money
growth in the United States.
In summary, nonsterilized intervention is identical to central bank openmarket operations, except that the bank
would slow the money supply growth
through sales of foreign exchange
instead of securities. A slower rate of
money growth resulting from nonsterilized intervention can result in a persistent nominal appreciation of the dollar and a temporary real appreciation of
the dollar. Nonsterilized intervention
thus will not have a long-term impact
on a nation's competitive position.'
Sterilized Intervention
and Portfolio Adjustments
While little disagreement exists about
the ability of nonsterilized intervention
to alter exchange rates through
changes in money growth, disagreement about the potency of sterilized
intervention abounds. Economists have
suggested two theoretical channels
through which sterilized intervention
might influence exchange rates. These
are the portfolio-adjustment channel
and the expectations channel.
According to the portfolio-adjustment
channel, sterilized intervention, which
alters the amounts of U.S. Treasury
securities relative to foreign government securities in private hands, can
cause investors to reorganize their
portfolios. This re-diversification can
affect exchange rates.
To understand how the portfolioadjustment effect operates, consider a
world in which risk-averse investors,
facing uncertain rates of return on an

4. The purchase of dollars with marks also will
increase the German money supply. We assume
throughout our example that the Germans sterilize the influence on their money supply by selling
government securities to the market.

6. The nominal exchange rate is the rate that
traders and newspapers typically quote. The real
exchange rate is equal to the nominal exchange
rate adjusted for inflation-rate differentials
between the countries in question.

5. See: "The Channels of Influence," op. cit.,
pp.4·5.

7. This description ignores the important contribution of expectations. Expectation, however,

array of assets, diversify their portfolios
instead of holding only the single asset
currently yielding the highest rate of
return. When we acknowledge that assets denominated in different currencies
can carry varying degrees of exchange
risk and political risk, a strong incentive then exists for investors worldwide
to diversify their portfolios across currencies." In the case of major developing countries, most analysts attach the
greatest importance to exchange risk.
Economists believe that the exchange
risk associated with bonds denominated
in a particular currency increases with
the proportion of similarly denominated
bonds held by investors.
Since sterilized intervention alters
the relative amounts of bonds in the
hands of the public, it has the potential
to affect risk-based premiums. Consider
our original example. If the Federal
Reserve undertakes open-market operations to sterilize the impact of the dollar purchases on the U.S. money supply,
it will reduce the amount of dollardenominated securities in the hands of
the public. The change in the relative
supply of dollar- and mark-denominated
assets then could lower the relative
risk premium associated with dollar
assets. Moreover, if the German Bundesbank also sterilized the impact of
our sales of German marks through its
own open-market operation, it would
further affect the relative supplies of
securities and the risk premium. The
lower risk premium could entice international investors to diversify into dollar assets, thereby causing the dollar to
appreciate relative to the mark.
For the portfolio balance approach to
operate, investors must view dollar-and
foreign-currency denominated bonds as
imperfect substitutes because of differences in the risk premium associated
with each. If, in our example, investors
viewed U.S. and German bonds as perfect substitutes with equal risks, they
would willingly substitute German securities for dollar securities in their portfolios. They would see no need to diversify
their portfolios and, consequently, no
exchange-rate movements would result.
Empirical research does not strongly
support the portfolio-adjustment channel. Although the issue remains unresolved, the evidence on the existence of

will not alter the outcome of a decrease in the
rate of money growth, but can alter the speed and
contours with which events take place.
8. Exchange risk is the uncertainty associated
with unanticipated exchange-rate movements;
political risk refers to the probability that
governments will impose capital controls.

a risk premium between similar assets
denominated in currencies of different
major developed countries is mixed.
But, even if the relevant bonds are
imperfect substitutes, it appears that
the response to small changes in the
risk premium is quite low.
Michael Hutchison, for example,
noted that the change in the total outstanding publicly held government debt
was the relevant variable for portfolio
decisions." Total government debt
responds to intervention, to changes in
the budget deficit, and to monetary policy. The volume of exchange-market
intervention is usually too small, compared to the total volume of outstanding debt, to have a significant impact
on portfolio choices. With the publicly
held federal debt in excess of $1.7 trillion, the Federal Reserve and foreign
central banks probably would need to
undertake a massive volume of intervention before it had a significant
impact on investors' portfolio decisions.
Expectations
Even in the absence of a significant
portfolio-adjustment effect, sterilized
intervention could affect exchange
rates by altering market expectations.
Exchange markets are highly efficient
processors of information. Traders
make full use of all currently available
information, including information
about predictable future events and policy decisions. Exchange rates on any
given day embody all of this information. Changes in exchange rates reflect
new information that has altered traders' expectations. Intervention thus
could alter exchange rates if it provided
new information to the market.
The scope for altering expectations
through official purchases or sales of
foreign exchange seems rather narrow.
First, the Federal Reserve and the U.S.
Treasury probably do not have better
information than the market concerning day-to-day developments. Nevertheless, officials do, from time to time,
possess better information in the

9. See Hutchison, Michael M. "Intervention, Deficit Finance and Real Exchange Rates: The Case
of Japan," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, Winter 1984, pp. 27·44.

important sense that market participants might be confused or unsure of
the future course of monetary or fiscal
policy. If intervention can clarify policy
intentions, it thus could alter expectations and exchange rates.
The decision of the Group of Five
countries to intervene in late September
1985 (the Plaza decision) seems to
represent a recent example of successful intervention that altered expectations in the foreign-exchange market.
Prior to the meeting, the dollar was
depreciating, but the market seemed uncertain about the future course of U.S.
monetary and fiscal policies. The narrowly defined money stock was growing in
excess of its target range, suggesting to
many observers that the Federal
Reserve might reduce money growth.
On the other hand, economic activity
seemed weak at the time; many complained that the dollar was overvalued,
and banks continued to experience difficulties with agricultural and internationalloans. These events suggested to
many observers that the Federal Reserve might take no action to slow
money growth. The United States intervened forcefully immediately following
the G-5 meeting, but did not continue to
intervene beyond the fourth quarter.
Foreign-exchange market participants
seemed to view the decision to intervene
as a signal that U.S. monetary policy
would not move in a direction that might
strengthen the dollar. Money continued
to grow above the target range and the
dollar continued to depreciate.
Designing and implementing
exchange-market intervention to influence expectations presents many difficulties. As already noted, the authorities must provide new information to
market participants, but the possibilities of doing so seem limited. Experienced market participants will anticipate and adjust for policy decisions.
Consequently, intervention will alter
expectations only when it is not routine, and when a credible change in
monetary policy accompanies it.
If the market believes domestic economic or political consideration prohibit
a tightening of monetary policy, it will
not respond favorably to intervention

that is designed to slow a dollar depreciation. Such was the case in the late
1970s. Heavy U.S. intervention in 1978
and 1979 to stem the dollar's decline appeared to have little effect, because the
market believed that the United States
lacked the resolve to end inflation. Only
after the Federal Reserve re-established
credibility with a new chairman and
with a new operating procedure did the
dollar begin to appreciate.
If we accept the argument that the
authorities have the ability to influence
foreign-exchange-market expectations by
providing new information about policy,
is intervention then the most effective
vehicle for introducing this information? Could the central bank not provide the same information more effectively through the announcement of
monetary-policy intentions or by altering an instrument of monetary policy?
One reason for thinking that actual
currency purchases or sales might be
more effective in convincing the market
about central-bank intentions is that
they represent a bet by the central
bank on its own information. Profitable
central-bank intervention-buying
foreign currency when it is cheap relative
to the dollar and selling it when it is
expensive relative to the dollar-tends
to smooth fluctuations in the exchange
rate. As Dale Henderson has noted,
when the prospects are such that the
central bank will incur a loss on its
intervention activity if it does not follow through with the correct change in
monetary policy, the market has greater reason to trust that the central bank,
in fact, will initiate the appropriate
monetary adjustment. 10
One also might wonder about the
extent to which intervention, which
alters expectations about future monetary policy, is truly sterilized. Many
observers believe that such intervention, when accompanied by a future
change in monetary policy, has a significantly larger impact on the market
than an unaccompanied change in
monetary policy." Nevertheless, ability
to alter expectations clearly depends on
fulfillment of the expectations.

10. See Henderson, Dale W. "Exchange Market Intervention Operations: Their Role in Financial
Policy and Their Effects," in John F. O. Bilson
and Richard C. Marston, eds. Exchange Rate Theory and Practice, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1984.

1l. See Jurgensen, Phillippe (Chairman). Report 0/
the Working Group on Exchange Market Interuention, processed, March 1983.

While sterilized intervention has no
effect on the money stock, it does
change the public's relative holdings of
U.S. Treasury securities and foreign
securities. In our example, sterilized
intervention reduces the supply of
dollar-denominated Treasury securities
in the market.'
The Impact of Nonsterilized
Exchange- Market Intervention
Nonsterilized intervention alters nations' money supplies, whereas sterilized
intervention alters relative supplies of
government securities." Consequently,
we initially discuss the influence of a
change in monetary policy on the
exchange rate and then describe the
unique influence of sterilized intervention. Both types of intervention can
influence expectations, which we also
will discuss.
Economists have long recognized a
relationship between changes in countries' monetary growth rates and
changes in exchange rates (or in the
balance of payments under fixed
exchange rates). Although economists
might disagree about the timing, about
the precise chain of causation, and
about the relative importance of money
for determining exchange rates, few
would object on theoretical grounds to
the inclusion of money among the key
determinants of exchange rates.
A common description of the chain of
events connecting a reduction in money
growth to a currency appreciation
would be as follows: If the United
States were to slow its money growth,
say from 10 percent per year to 8 percent, with other factors unchanged, it
would experience an increase in its
interest rates, at least initially. If foreign countries maintain their interest
rates, international investors will
transfer funds from assets denominated in foreign currencies, say German marks, to assets denominated in
dollars. To obtain dollars, these investors will trade German marks for dollars in the exchange market. The
increased supply of German marks and
increased demand for dollars will tend
to cause the dollar to appreciate relative to the mark.

The reduced rate of U.S. money
growth also might slow the pace of
economic activity and reduce the rate
of inflation in the United States. But,
prices typically adjust more slowly
than the exchange rate, so the initial
slowing in the money growth rate will
cause the dollar to appreciate both on a
nominal basis and on an inflationadjusted, or real, basis." The real
appreciation of the dollar will make
U.S. goods less competitive in world
markets, until the U.S. inflation rate
adjusts to the slower pace of money
growth in the United States.
In summary, nonsterilized intervention is identical to central bank openmarket operations, except that the bank
would slow the money supply growth
through sales of foreign exchange
instead of securities. A slower rate of
money growth resulting from nonsterilized intervention can result in a persistent nominal appreciation of the dollar and a temporary real appreciation of
the dollar. Nonsterilized intervention
thus will not have a long-term impact
on a nation's competitive position.'
Sterilized Intervention
and Portfolio Adjustments
While little disagreement exists about
the ability of nonsterilized intervention
to alter exchange rates through
changes in money growth, disagreement about the potency of sterilized
intervention abounds. Economists have
suggested two theoretical channels
through which sterilized intervention
might influence exchange rates. These
are the portfolio-adjustment channel
and the expectations channel.
According to the portfolio-adjustment
channel, sterilized intervention, which
alters the amounts of U.S. Treasury
securities relative to foreign government securities in private hands, can
cause investors to reorganize their
portfolios. This re-diversification can
affect exchange rates.
To understand how the portfolioadjustment effect operates, consider a
world in which risk-averse investors,
facing uncertain rates of return on an

4. The purchase of dollars with marks also will
increase the German money supply. We assume
throughout our example that the Germans sterilize the influence on their money supply by selling
government securities to the market.

6. The nominal exchange rate is the rate that
traders and newspapers typically quote. The real
exchange rate is equal to the nominal exchange
rate adjusted for inflation-rate differentials
between the countries in question.

5. See: "The Channels of Influence," op. cit.,
pp.4·5.

7. This description ignores the important contribution of expectations. Expectation, however,

array of assets, diversify their portfolios
instead of holding only the single asset
currently yielding the highest rate of
return. When we acknowledge that assets denominated in different currencies
can carry varying degrees of exchange
risk and political risk, a strong incentive then exists for investors worldwide
to diversify their portfolios across currencies." In the case of major developing countries, most analysts attach the
greatest importance to exchange risk.
Economists believe that the exchange
risk associated with bonds denominated
in a particular currency increases with
the proportion of similarly denominated
bonds held by investors.
Since sterilized intervention alters
the relative amounts of bonds in the
hands of the public, it has the potential
to affect risk-based premiums. Consider
our original example. If the Federal
Reserve undertakes open-market operations to sterilize the impact of the dollar purchases on the U.S. money supply,
it will reduce the amount of dollardenominated securities in the hands of
the public. The change in the relative
supply of dollar- and mark-denominated
assets then could lower the relative
risk premium associated with dollar
assets. Moreover, if the German Bundesbank also sterilized the impact of
our sales of German marks through its
own open-market operation, it would
further affect the relative supplies of
securities and the risk premium. The
lower risk premium could entice international investors to diversify into dollar assets, thereby causing the dollar to
appreciate relative to the mark.
For the portfolio balance approach to
operate, investors must view dollar-and
foreign-currency denominated bonds as
imperfect substitutes because of differences in the risk premium associated
with each. If, in our example, investors
viewed U.S. and German bonds as perfect substitutes with equal risks, they
would willingly substitute German securities for dollar securities in their portfolios. They would see no need to diversify
their portfolios and, consequently, no
exchange-rate movements would result.
Empirical research does not strongly
support the portfolio-adjustment channel. Although the issue remains unresolved, the evidence on the existence of

will not alter the outcome of a decrease in the
rate of money growth, but can alter the speed and
contours with which events take place.
8. Exchange risk is the uncertainty associated
with unanticipated exchange-rate movements;
political risk refers to the probability that
governments will impose capital controls.

a risk premium between similar assets
denominated in currencies of different
major developed countries is mixed.
But, even if the relevant bonds are
imperfect substitutes, it appears that
the response to small changes in the
risk premium is quite low.
Michael Hutchison, for example,
noted that the change in the total outstanding publicly held government debt
was the relevant variable for portfolio
decisions." Total government debt
responds to intervention, to changes in
the budget deficit, and to monetary policy. The volume of exchange-market
intervention is usually too small, compared to the total volume of outstanding debt, to have a significant impact
on portfolio choices. With the publicly
held federal debt in excess of $1.7 trillion, the Federal Reserve and foreign
central banks probably would need to
undertake a massive volume of intervention before it had a significant
impact on investors' portfolio decisions.
Expectations
Even in the absence of a significant
portfolio-adjustment effect, sterilized
intervention could affect exchange
rates by altering market expectations.
Exchange markets are highly efficient
processors of information. Traders
make full use of all currently available
information, including information
about predictable future events and policy decisions. Exchange rates on any
given day embody all of this information. Changes in exchange rates reflect
new information that has altered traders' expectations. Intervention thus
could alter exchange rates if it provided
new information to the market.
The scope for altering expectations
through official purchases or sales of
foreign exchange seems rather narrow.
First, the Federal Reserve and the U.S.
Treasury probably do not have better
information than the market concerning day-to-day developments. Nevertheless, officials do, from time to time,
possess better information in the

9. See Hutchison, Michael M. "Intervention, Deficit Finance and Real Exchange Rates: The Case
of Japan," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, Winter 1984, pp. 27·44.

important sense that market participants might be confused or unsure of
the future course of monetary or fiscal
policy. If intervention can clarify policy
intentions, it thus could alter expectations and exchange rates.
The decision of the Group of Five
countries to intervene in late September
1985 (the Plaza decision) seems to
represent a recent example of successful intervention that altered expectations in the foreign-exchange market.
Prior to the meeting, the dollar was
depreciating, but the market seemed uncertain about the future course of U.S.
monetary and fiscal policies. The narrowly defined money stock was growing in
excess of its target range, suggesting to
many observers that the Federal
Reserve might reduce money growth.
On the other hand, economic activity
seemed weak at the time; many complained that the dollar was overvalued,
and banks continued to experience difficulties with agricultural and internationalloans. These events suggested to
many observers that the Federal Reserve might take no action to slow
money growth. The United States intervened forcefully immediately following
the G-5 meeting, but did not continue to
intervene beyond the fourth quarter.
Foreign-exchange market participants
seemed to view the decision to intervene
as a signal that U.S. monetary policy
would not move in a direction that might
strengthen the dollar. Money continued
to grow above the target range and the
dollar continued to depreciate.
Designing and implementing
exchange-market intervention to influence expectations presents many difficulties. As already noted, the authorities must provide new information to
market participants, but the possibilities of doing so seem limited. Experienced market participants will anticipate and adjust for policy decisions.
Consequently, intervention will alter
expectations only when it is not routine, and when a credible change in
monetary policy accompanies it.
If the market believes domestic economic or political consideration prohibit
a tightening of monetary policy, it will
not respond favorably to intervention

that is designed to slow a dollar depreciation. Such was the case in the late
1970s. Heavy U.S. intervention in 1978
and 1979 to stem the dollar's decline appeared to have little effect, because the
market believed that the United States
lacked the resolve to end inflation. Only
after the Federal Reserve re-established
credibility with a new chairman and
with a new operating procedure did the
dollar begin to appreciate.
If we accept the argument that the
authorities have the ability to influence
foreign-exchange-market expectations by
providing new information about policy,
is intervention then the most effective
vehicle for introducing this information? Could the central bank not provide the same information more effectively through the announcement of
monetary-policy intentions or by altering an instrument of monetary policy?
One reason for thinking that actual
currency purchases or sales might be
more effective in convincing the market
about central-bank intentions is that
they represent a bet by the central
bank on its own information. Profitable
central-bank intervention-buying
foreign currency when it is cheap relative
to the dollar and selling it when it is
expensive relative to the dollar-tends
to smooth fluctuations in the exchange
rate. As Dale Henderson has noted,
when the prospects are such that the
central bank will incur a loss on its
intervention activity if it does not follow through with the correct change in
monetary policy, the market has greater reason to trust that the central bank,
in fact, will initiate the appropriate
monetary adjustment. 10
One also might wonder about the
extent to which intervention, which
alters expectations about future monetary policy, is truly sterilized. Many
observers believe that such intervention, when accompanied by a future
change in monetary policy, has a significantly larger impact on the market
than an unaccompanied change in
monetary policy." Nevertheless, ability
to alter expectations clearly depends on
fulfillment of the expectations.

10. See Henderson, Dale W. "Exchange Market Intervention Operations: Their Role in Financial
Policy and Their Effects," in John F. O. Bilson
and Richard C. Marston, eds. Exchange Rate Theory and Practice, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1984.

1l. See Jurgensen, Phillippe (Chairman). Report 0/
the Working Group on Exchange Market Interuention, processed, March 1983.

Conclusion
Most analysts believe that growing
U.S. trade deficits cannot continue. As
our international indebtedness grows,
foreigners will become increasingly
reluctant to acquire additional dollardenominated assets. This will initiate
adjustments in many economic variables, including exchange rates and
interest rates, to bring the international economy back into balance. How
and how quickly these adjustments
take place depends in large part on how
rapidly the market decides to adjust its
holdings of dollar-denominated assets."
Depreciation of the dollar can contribute to the adjustment process by
increasing the competitiveness of U.S.
goods and services in world markets.
Nevertheless, economists have long
realized that the ability of an economy
to meet increased demands for its goods

and services limits the contribution of a
currency depreciation to improving its
trade balance. If the economy is operating at full capacity, the depreciation
will not generate much improvement in
the trade balance. Ultimately a reduction in the trade deficit requires that
the United States reduce its budget
deficit, that it promotes savings, and
that it encourages production of tradable goods and services.
Exchange-market participants understand these relationships and look for
compatible developments in U.S. economic policies. If they believe that the United
States is attempting to force a dollar
depreciation through an inflationary
increase in money growth or that the
United States is not taking credible
steps to reduce its budget deficit, international investors, who have played an
important role in helping finance U.S.
credit demands, could shift rapidly out
of dollars into assets denominated in

other currencies. Under such circumstances, no amount of exchange-market
intervention could supplant appropriate
monetary or fiscal policies.
If, on the other hand, monetary and
fiscal policy are consistent with a reduction in the trade deficit and an
orderly depreciation of the dollar, then
intervention can playa useful role in
reinforcing the intention of policy should
market uncertainty arise. Policymakers
should clearly state the objectives of
such policies. Under these circumstances, monetary and fiscal policies
will help minimize market uncertainty
and, hence, the need for intervention.

12. See Humpage, Owen F. "Should We Be Concerned About the Speed of the Depreciation?"
Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, March 15, 1986.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested:
Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

February 1, 1987

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

ISSN 0428·1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
The Group of Five countries (France,
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom
and the United States), plus Canada,
met in Paris on February 21 and 22,
seeking ways to eliminate huge trade
imbalances in the United States, Japan
and Germany, to encourage greater
exchange-market stability, and to
thwart growing protectionism.'
The recent rapid depreciation of the
dollar, which poses major problems both
for the United States and for our major
trading partners, prompted the Paris
meeting. As the dollar depreciates relative to other currencies, foreign exporters find it difficult to compete against
U.S. goods in world markets. The dollar
depreciation already has contributed to
a sharp slowdown in Japan's economic
growth. For the United States, fear of
continued rapid dollar depreciation increases the risk that international
investors will shift funds out of dollardenominated assets and, thereby, force
up U.S. interest rates. Federal Reserve
Chairman Paul A. Volcker repeatedly
has cautioned about this possible effect.
The depreciation also will contribute to
higher prices in the United States.
Although vague on the issue, the Paris
meeting increased speculation that the
participating countries would intervene
more forcefully in an attempt to limit
movements in key exchange rates. As
newspapers recently have reported, Japan, and to a lesser extent, Germany
have committed large sums to exchangemarket intervention. In contrast, however, the United States has been reluctant to intervene in the exchange

market, believing that when nations
conduct intervention independent of
their monetary policies it has, at best, a
limited influence on exchange rates.
This Economic Commentary discusses
the U.S. reluctance to intervene in exchange markets. We present three
theoretical channels through which
exchange-market intervention could influence exchange rates: the monetary
channel, the portfolio-adjustment channel, and the expectations channel.2

Owen F. Humpage is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

1. This article was revised and published after
the February Group of Five meeting and has been
backdated in order to maintain the continuity of
the Economic Commentary series- editor.

A Definition
Exchange-market intervention refers to
official purchases and sales of foreign
exchange, which nations undertake
through their central banks to influence
the exchange val ue of their currencies.
Although nations have many ways to influence their exchange rate-such as
using monetary and fiscal policy, capital controls and trade barriersexchange-market intervention seems the
most direct and most flexible method.
Many nations, therefore, frequently
resort to intervention. Members of the
European Monetary System, for example, routinely intervene to keep their
exchange rates within narrow margins.'
Much of the recent interest in intervention stems from the belief that
intervention enables nations to influence their exchange rates without
altering monetary and fiscal policies.
To understand this, we first must distinguish between sterilized and nonsterilized intervention. When a country
undertakes sterilized intervention, it
engages in other transactions to prevent either the purchase or sale of for-

2. The author presents a more detailed analysis
of intervention and a survey of the literature in:
"Exchange- Market Intervention: The Channels
of Influence," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Quarter 3, 1986, pp.2·14.

Should We
Intervene in
Exchange
Markets?
by Owen F. Humpage

eign currency from influencing its
money-supply growth. In contrast,
nonsterilized intervention can alter a
country's money supply.
An example can help clarify the
important distinction between sterilized and nonsterilized intervention.
Suppose the United States wants to
slow a depreciation of the dollar relative to the German mark. At the direction of the Treasury Department, the
Federal Reserve System would buy dollars with German marks through its
foreign-exchange desk in New York.
Because this transaction reduces the
supply of dollars in the foreignexchange market, the dollar should
then appreciate relative to the German
mark. The foreign-exchange desk's
purchase of dollars, however, also contracts the money supply in the United
States. At this point, the intervention
transaction is nonsterilized.
The reduction in the money supply
resulting from intervention might be
inconsistent with the domestic objectives of monetary policy. Consequently,
the Federal Reserve then might wish to
offset the impact of the intervention
purchases of dollars by purchasing
Treasury bills through the System's
open-market desk at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. The purchase of Treasury bills supplies
reserves to the banking system and
increases the money supply. Thus, by
coordinating the activities of the
foreign-exchange and open-market
desks, the Federal Reserve can offset,
or sterilize, the monetary impact of its
exchange-market activities.

3. The United States intervened quite frequently
during much of the 1970s, but has intervened
relatively infrequently in the 1980s.