View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 1, 1998

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Gold Prices
by Joseph G. Haubrich

T

his January marked the 150th
anniversary of a major event in American history: the discovery of gold at
Sutter’s Mill, California. Fittingly, gold
made news again this year by dropping
past $300 an ounce to hit its lowest price
in nearly two decades. While some of
the subject’s interest undoubtedly
springs from an almost voyeuristic fascination with the precious metal itself,
gold prices are nonetheless legitimate
news, since they are considered harbingers of stability or future inflation. Careful observers’ acquaintance with the
gold market’s particular twists, turns,
and idiosyncrasies gives them a more
reasoned understanding of its uses as an
economic indicator. This Economic
Commentary takes the confluence of historical and current events as an excuse to
refine our understanding of gold, gold
prices, and inflation.

■ Supply and Demand
Like any other good, gold’s price depends on supply and demand. But unlike
wheat, say, where most of the current
supply comes from this year’s crop, gold
is storable and most of the supply comes
from past production accumulated over
centuries. In economists’ jargon, the current stock far exceeds this year’s flow.
Of the total world supply of 125,000
metric tons of gold, annual production
ranges around 2,400 tons. This means
that in contrast to soybeans, corn, or
pork bellies, this year’s gold production
has little influence on prices.

ISSN 0428-1276

In this sense, gold behaves less like a
commodity than like long-lived assets
such as stocks or bonds. That characteristic makes expectations particularly
important because, like the stock market,
gold prices are forward-looking, and
today’s price depends heavily on future
demand and supply.
Among other things, these expectations
must take account of uncertainties in
gold production, the most obvious being
discoveries of new deposits. Production
increased dramatically after discovery of
the New World (which provided some
exceptionally low-cost mines, such as
Inca temples and palaces), and again in
the 1850s when California and Australia
became important producers. Equally
essential, though less romanticized by
Hollywood, have been technological
changes. Development of the cyanide
extraction process in 1890, for example,
made it possible to recover gold from an
inferior grade of ore. Further developments in chemistry and engineering continue to lower the price of extraction.
Still, unlike stocks, bonds, or Rembrandts, gold production does depend on
prices. If the price of gold is very high,
more mines will open up and existing
ones will take out lower-grade ore. If the
price is very low, some mines will shut
down and others will curtail production,
leaving low-grade ore in the ground. This
adds a degree of “mean reversion” to the
price of gold, which tends slowly to return to the cost of producing more gold.

Long after disappearing from our
coinage, gold continues to command
attention as a substance whose price
foretells stability or inflation—and
to retain a singular position on the
balance sheets of central banks.

In the very short term, however, there
may be no such mean reversion. A price
increase today could signal an even bigger rise in the near future, enticing mine
operators to reduce output until prices
move up. Alternatively, high prices may
reduce output temporarily by encouraging some mine operators to move to
low-grade ore, which is only profitable
when prices are high. Since production
capacity can be somewhat fixed, the
shift to lower-grade ore could mean a
lower supply—and thus a higher
price—of gold.1
Gold demand puts its own spin on matters. Unlike oil, for example, which literally goes up in smoke, gold is rarely
destroyed while being used.2 The largest
demand is for jewelry and investments
(which are often lumped together
because it’s hard to categorize Krugerrand cuff links or ingot necklaces). Combined jewelry and investment demand
runs about 2,800 tons a year. Dental and
industrial demand is smaller, at 120 tons
annually. Gold, of all known metals the

FIGURE 1 CPI AND GOLD PRICES

SOURCE: DRI/McGraw–Hill.

most malleable (easily shaped) and ductile (easily hammered flat or pulled into
a wire),3 has many industrial applications. Fine wires are used in electronics;
thin coatings are used to insulate glass.
Since most gold survives its use, the
total world stock continues to grow, and
this characteristic too makes its prices
resemble those of a long-lived asset. As
a result, they show much less mean
reversion than do prices of other storable
commodities, such as oil or copper.4
Gold’s extra, unique source of demand
and supply, which is receiving intense
scrutiny in 1998, relates to its role in the
world monetary system, namely, the
gold stocks of central banks. Of the total
supply of 125,000 tons, between 28,000
and 35,000 are held by central banks
around the world. The International
Monetary Fund’s current official figure
is 35,623 tons, though this may be an
underestimate because not all countries
report their holdings.
Central bank sales were often blamed for
pushing gold prices down in 1997. Early
that year, Argentina sold 125 tons, an
amount exceeding the average annual
industrial demand; in July, Australia sold
167 tons. The Argentine sale illustrates
how financial markets affect gold prices.
Argentina’s central bank did not sell

gold directly on the open market;
instead, it exercised put options, financial contracts that entitled it to sell at a
previously specified price. In November,
Switzerland’s central bank merely proposed selling 1,400 tons by the year
2000, and prices fell. This illustrates the
already-mentioned “asset” side of gold,
where expectations about future demand
and supply matter a great deal.
A related controversy brought the point
home even more powerfully. The European Union must decide how much gold
the European Central Bank will hold.
Fears were that it would hold a lower
proportion of gold than do existing
European central banks, and that this
could entail selling some of the 2,900
tons currently held by the European
Monetary Institute.

■ Gold Prices and Inflation
Treating gold simply as a commodity
misses the point, fascinating as the particular details of its market may be. From
earliest times, gold has served as money,
and this association persists in many
people’s minds, despite the metal’s disappearance from our coinage, the abandonment of the gold standard, and Mr.
Keynes’ wry comments about digging up
gold only to bury it in bank vaults.5
Much of the discussion about gold prices

centers on whether the dollar remains “as
good as gold”6 and what changes in the
price of gold mean for prices and inflation in the rest of the economy.
Gold’s most natural relationship to the
general price level is what one might
expect for any good or asset: A higher
general price level should be associated
with higher gold prices.7 To put it differently, cars cost more in 1998 than they
did in 1958; so do haircuts and movie
tickets. If it takes more dollars to buy
cars, haircuts, and movie tickets, it seems
likely that more dollars would also be
needed to buy an ounce of gold. Over the
long term, this generally holds true: An
ounce sells for more now than it did in
1970 ($285 versus $35). On shorter time
horizons, however, the Consumer Price
Index (CPI) and the price of gold often
go their separate ways. In recent U.S.
experience, the relationship between the
two is tenuous at best (see figure 1). Gold
prices today are less than half what they
were in January 1980, while the CPI has
more than doubled. This is not due solely
to the gold price spike of the early 1980s;
gold prices now are lower than they were
in 1985, even though the CPI has risen
more than 50 percent since then. Such a
relative price change is not unique. Consider the price of computing power,
which has dropped so precipitously that a
1998 laptop is more powerful than a
1960s commercial mainframe.
A closer relationship exists between gold
prices and inflation, that is, the rate of
change in the general price level.8 Figure
2 plots both these series, lagging gold by
a year. Figure 3 further clarifies the relationship by plotting the CPI inflation rate
in each period against the gold price in
the previous period. Two periods particularly stand out: The high inflation of the
early 1980s is matched by high gold
prices, which definitely appear to “lead”
the CPI inflation rate by about a year, a
relationship that doesn’t break down until
1988. The most recent decrease in the
inflation rate also corresponds to a drop
in gold prices, though that relationship is
much more synchronous, without a clear
lead or lag time.

FIGURE 2 CPI AND LAGGED GOLD PRICES

player who sinks a few shots as the next
Michael Jordan. In both cases, though, it
pays to keep watching.
Another feature that weakens the relationship between gold and inflation is
that it may change over time. This is
especially likely if some third factor,
such as monetary policy, is causing the
relationship. Conceivably, a monetary
policy designed to bring down inflation,
as in the early 1980s, might have a different impact than one promoting a stable, low-inflation environment, like that
of the 1990s.9
The other factor to notice is the quantitative side of the relationship. Does the
rebound in gold prices since January
indicate a resurgence of inflation? Apart
from the statistical caveats already given,
it is wise to look at the actual relationship
in figure 3. The rebound, lifting prices
from $280 to $300 an ounce, predicts
that inflation will increase 0.48 percent.
Similarly, the newsmaking drop in the
price of gold from its local high in February 1996 (when it topped $400) to its
nadir in January 1998 (just below $280)
suggests an inflation rate decrease of
2.9 percent, a more significant shift.

SOURCE: DRI/McGraw–Hill.

FIGURE 3 CPI VS. GOLD PRICES

■ Conclusion

SOURCE: DRI/McGraw–Hill.

The scatterplot diagram of figure 3 highlights the relationship more fully, though
it obscures the leads and lags on view in
figure 2. The slope of the line suggests
that a $100 rise in the price of gold is
associated, on average, with higher inflation in the following year of 2.4 percentage points. This pedantic terminology is
supposed to convey the idea that figures
2 and 3 do not say anything about causality. While gold prices do tell us something about the inflation rate, it need not
be either that inflation raises gold prices
or that higher gold prices cause inflation.
Some third factor, such as the money
supply, may influence both.

Pedantry aside, the statistical relationships does look fairly strong: Gold
prices can account for more than 70 percent of variation in the inflation rate.
Significantly, however, a lot of the relationship comes from high-inflation environments; without those data points, it is
decidedly weaker.
There are several possible reasons for
this. The relationship may only become
apparent when there are big swings in
the inflation rate; without them, the
noise may overwhelm the signal. If this
is so, we should be warned not to read
too much into the current numbers, just
as it’s unwise to anoint any basketball

In a memorable essay, Milton Friedman
wrote that “millions of people all over
the world regard gold as ‘money,’ if not
the only ‘true’ money.”10 As a consequence, the price of gold commands
attention, and rightly so, because it
serves to indicate general price stability
or inflation. But gold is also a commodity, used in jewelry and by industry. This
means that the details of its demand and
supply affect its pricing, and need to be
considered when gold is used to assay
monetary policy.

■ Footnotes
1. This is a simplification, as the full argument relies on other factors such as mines’
inventory policy. The evidence seems to support the idea that higher gold prices mean
lower output in the short run (see James Barney Marsh, “Keynes on the Supply of Gold:
A Statistical Test” Eastern Economic Journal, vol. 9, no. 1 [January– March, 1983],
pp. 7–12).
2. Of course, it is not always recycled after
its industrial uses, and in certain other cases
it is destroyed or irrecoverable. For example,
gold leaf of 20 carats and above is edible (see
Martha Stewart, Martha Stewart’s Christmas,
New York: C.N. Potter, 1989).
3. One ounce of gold, about the size of a
human teardrop, can be beaten into 187
square feet of gold leaf or drawn into a mile
of fine wire.
4. For a sophisticated discussion of these
results, see Eduardo S. Schwartz, “The Stochastic Behavior of Commodity Prices:
Implications for Valuation and Hedging,”
Journal of Finance, vol. 52, no. 3 (July 1997),
pp. 923–73.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

5. See The General Theory of Employment
Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt,
Brace and Company, 1936, sec. 6, chap. 10,
pp. 128–31.
6. The phrase, oddly enough, is from Charles
Dickens, A Christmas Carol (1848), stave III.
7. The meaning of “inflation” has changed
over the years and is not completely standard
even today (Michael F. Bryan, “On the Origin and Evolution of the Word Inflation,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary, October 15, 1997).
8. Two recent discussions that highlight this
relationship are Jude Wanninski, “The Optimum Price of Gold,” The Wall Street Journal, January 7, 1998, p. A22, and Wayne
Angell, “The Fed: On the Right Course,”
The Wall Street Journal, December 16, 1997,
p. A18.

Joseph G. Haubrich is a consultant and
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Economic Commentary is available electronically through the Cleveland Fed’s site on
the World Wide Web: http://www.clev.frb.org.
We also offer a free online subscription service to notify readers of additions to our Web
site. To subscribe, please send an e-mail message to econpubs-on@clev.frb.org.

9. Whether further reductions in the inflation
rate are desired is a separate, and often disputed, matter.
10. “A Commodity Reserve Currency” in
Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953, p. 239.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385