View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

January 1, 2000

Economic Commentary
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

The Evolving Global Monetary Order
by Jerry L. Jordan

This final decade of the millennium
has seen considerable financial market
turbulence. The old order is evolving.
How should we respond to what seems
to be emerging in monetary matters?
Certainly, it would be a “fatal conceit” 1
to think that a group of economic architects could dream up a monetary structure to house the global financial system for the new millennium. I hasten to
add that I do not suggest that we do
nothing. Rather, I believe that we
should be guided by Karl Brunner’s
prescription: the state should be “an
umpire in a positive sum game, not the
operator of a negative sum game.” 2 I
contend that the same should be true of
any international organizations created
by nation-states.
International monetary developments in
recent years can be explained in the
context of powerful economic forces
challenging ossified domestic institutions. By “institutions” I mean both organizations and sets of rules (such as
contract enforcement, labor laws, laws
of incorporation, and the judicial system, or various types of economic controls, such as wage, interest-rate, exchange, and capital controls). Some
institutions are intended to alter the
working of markets because the benefits of intrusion are perceived to be
greater than the costs. That is the case
when political or social objectives seem
to be more important than economic efficiency. Objectives such as income redistribution—a political decision to
give priority to sharing wealth, rather
than creating wealth—result in institutional arrangements that reduce the efficiency of markets.

ISSN 0428-1276

The study of institutional arrangements and their consequences in the
second half of the twentieth century has
become a matter of learning what will
not serve in the future, rather than what
will best replace it. We have become
informed about the unintended consequences of well-intended efforts by international organizations and various
foreign-aid programs.
For example, the Bretton Woods System, established in the final days of
World War II, had built into it rules for
exchange-rate adjustment. Nevertheless, because of the asymmetry in the
way the rules worked, there proved to
be a rigidity that caused the system to
break, rather than bend, in the face of
specific economic forces—namely, the
debasement of what was intended to be
the anchor currency, the U.S. dollar.
The ultimate implication of a conflict
between powerful economic forces and
rigid political institutions is that institutions must change, or they will fail.
There must be an effective political and
economic regeneration in which various institutional arrangements, especially organizations, are adaptable to a
changing environment.

■ The Evolving Nature of
Institutions
Propelled by technological change and
chance economic events, the institutions that define our global economy
undergo a continual process of change.
Qualities that enhance economic wellbeing tend to survive, and those that do
not eventually disappear.

In a speech at the Cato Institute,
Jerry L. Jordan, President and CEO
of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, discussed the forces shaping the
emerging global monetary order and
offered guidelines for the design of any
international organization promoting
efficient international financial markets. This Economic Commentary is
adapted from his remarks at the Institute’s Seventeenth Annual Monetary
Conference on October 21, 1999.

The idea that tangible manufactured
goods must compete not only in local
shops but also increasingly in the global town square is obvious to everyone.
Yet the thought that institutional arrangements are also tested against others in the international arena is not so
well understood. Ideas must face competition no less than goods and services.
Politicians have long known that they
must compete, but their focus was on
rivals in their own party or other political parties in their country. What has
changed is the competition they face
from policies and institutional arrangements in other countries. The voters are
not only the citizens at the local ballot
box, but also the financial-asset managers in global capital markets.
Domestic ballot-box voters respond
well to politicians who satisfy their
craving for wealth-sharing programs.

Capital-market voters survey the world
for those who pursue the best wealthcreation policies. Gaining the support
of one is almost sure to diminish support from the other.
Courts that will not enforce the contracts and protect the property of their
own citizens will not be used by foreign trading partners. Banks that engage in unsound local lending practices
cannot sustain the risk-adjusted rate of
return sought by foreign investors—
unless government guarantees transfer
risk exposure from banks and investors
to the general taxpayer. Governments
with unsustainable fiscal policies, such
as promising overly generous pensions
to citizens, will find it increasingly
difficult—or impossible—to raise sufficient taxes or issue new debt to meet
their commitments.
In the end, just as trade barriers cannot
permanently withstand the competition
of better goods produced elsewhere, so
too exchange and capital controls cannot serve as permanent obstacles to
pressure from capital-market voters
who constantly search for the best
wealth-creating environment.

■ The Lessons of Financial Crises
There is little doubt that recent crises
reflect financial discipline imposed on
countries’ policies and institutions by
the increased scrutiny of foreign investors and lenders.
International capital flows have proven
to be a mixed blessing for many economies in the post–World War II era. But
erecting obstructions to the free flow of
savings is not desirable, even if it were
possible. Instead, the challenge is to ensure that access to foreign capital is
more often a blessing than a curse.
Capital mobility does not in itself result
in monetary or exchange-rate crises. At
its roots, Mexico in 1994–95 did not
have a monetary crisis or an exchangerate crisis. Likewise, what ended up as
an Asian monetary or foreign-exchange
crisis did not start out as such.
Common to all of these and other episodes were government guarantees or
promises that ultimately were revealed
to be unreliable. The prior presence of
government guarantees (or implicit
promises) had induced behavior—relying on the guarantees or promises—that

altered incentives to the point where
risk/reward relationships were distorted. Sometimes the guarantees took the
form of financial instruments—such as
Tesobonos in Mexico—exchange-rate
pegs, guaranteed loans to domestic
banks, or government-agency or nationalized-industry borrowing. The failures
of such arrangements in the crisis countries often became a monetary crisis or
an exchange-rate crisis. Such marketcorroding practices were already undermining sustainable prosperity even before access to foreign capital magnified
the distortions.
Merely allowing the value of a currency
to float does not eliminate the problems
revealed in fixed-exchange-rate regimes
confronted by financial crisis. Only a few
currencies in the world enjoy a reputation that permits either the issuing government or private borrowers the privilege of selling obligations to foreigners
without incurring exchange-rate risk.
Under a fixed-exchange-rate regime,
the government stands ready to supply
foreign currency in exchange for the
domestic currency. Under a freely floating exchange-rate regime, the government makes no such promise. The risk
of exchange-rate depreciation from
overly expansionary monetary policy
means that interest rates paid by domestic borrowers will be higher than
global market rates.
As we have often seen, however, governments have sought to minimize the
interest differential by guaranteeing the
obligations that domestic banks and
other borrowers have incurred to foreign investors. This creates an unavoidable moral hazard. Furthermore, because
such guarantees involve a subsidy to
borrowers, the demand for them will always exceed the amount the government can possibly honor. The nonprice
rationing of guarantees introduces political considerations into the allocation
of capital flows, further undermining the
discipline of market forces.
Institutional investors in global capital
markets conduct a continuous plebiscite on the political and economic policies developing in the nation-states of
the world. Seemingly, no economy is
immune to these pressures. Advances in
communications and information technologies have been revolutionizing all
the financial markets. Adverse judg-

ments by participants in such markets
can quickly and dramatically change
the price and availability of funds to
any borrower, large or small. It is becoming apparent that governmental
promises—whether in the form of
pegged exchange rates or deposit, loan,
or investment guarantees—are on the
endangered-species list.

■ Central Banks and
National Currencies
Other twentieth-century institutional arrangements coming under increasing
scrutiny are central banks and national
currencies. Certainly there are national
vested interests in maintaining local
governmental monopolies over the issuance of national media of exchange.
Beyond that, the idea persists that a
country has something called “monetary sovereignty” and can therefore pursue an “independent monetary policy.”
History demonstrates, however, that national currencies inevitably compete in
the international financial arena.
In globally oriented discussions, “monetary independence” refers to the asserted benefit of having a central bank
and a national currency that permit a
country to choose independently “the
appropriate rate of inflation.” It is increasingly difficult to understand what
such a statement means. If it means the
“politically acceptable” rate of inflation
from the standpoint of domestic constituencies, then the inherent economic
inefficiencies of policies that systematically debase the purchasing power of
money mean less-than-potential wealth
creation. There are unavoidable wealth
redistributions and deadweight wealth
losses that result from debasement of
the currency, whether intended or not.
Traditional rationalizations for deliberate inflation—such as claims of rigid
wages or implications for real exchange
rates—seem increasingly quaint.
To prosper, every economy needs
sound money. Changes in the money
prices of goods and assets convey information. If an economy’s monetary
unit is known to be a stable standard of
value,3 then changes in money prices
will accurately reflect changes in the
relative values of goods and assets.
That is, price fluctuations signal changes in the demand for, or supply of,
goods or assets. Resource utilization
then shifts toward more valued uses
and away from those less valued.

However, if the information in changes
in money prices is contaminated by inappropriate monetary policies, false
signals are sent to businesses and
households. Bad decisions are made,
and resources are misallocated. Saving
and investment decisions are affected,
and standards of living fail to rise at
their potential rate.
It is now generally accepted that accelerations and decelerations of inflation
do not enhance economic performance.
Unanticipated inflations and deflations
also induce redistribution of wealth—
especially between debtors and creditors—but they leave the average standard of living lower. The same is true
of devaluations or revaluations of the
external value of a currency. A government’s decision to alter the exchange
rate of a currency that had been fixed
involves the breaking of promises.
Losses are imposed on someone.
If the internal value of a currency is not
stable, then the external value must ultimately reflect this. Clearly, if the domestic purchasing power of a currency
falls, the external value must eventually
fall relative to stable currencies. The
notion that a country can maintain a
permanently fixed exchange rate while
tolerating domestic inflation has been
proven to be false numerous times.
If monetary sovereignty or independence is not worth much in today’s
global capital markets, and if seigniorage is quite small in a noninflationary
world, then the costs and risks associated
with a national central bank and a national currency become harder to justify.
Whatever the views of domestic politicians, the trend in the behavior of businesses and households around the
world is unmistakable. In the absence
of fixed exchange rates, Gresham’s
Law no longer applies. What we now
see—where not prohibited by effective
severe punishment—is the use of
“high-confidence monies” driving out
the everyday use of “low-confidence
monies.”4 Just as the brand name of
running shoes is more important to
consumers than the location of the assembly plant, so too the brand name of
currency used to denominate contracts
and trade assets is more important than
the local content or national origin of
the standard of value.

International brand identification of
goods evolved as governmental and
technological constraints diminished.
As we are now seeing, brand identification of standards of value is also becoming more pervasive as the falling
costs of information and communications technologies make it increasingly
easy to compare the quality dimension
of standards of value.
Under the true gold standard of an earlier era, most currencies were gold or
silver certificates—warehouse receipts
for the true standard of value. Then, in
the Bretton Woods period, a dollar,
firmly anchored to gold, served as a
standard of value, and other currencies
were defined in terms of the dollar. An
obvious twentieth-century trend was
the proliferation of national currencies,
especially as new nation-states emerged
from the breakup of the colonial empires and the Soviet Union. What is
less apparent, though, is that while
there are now a great many currencies,
there are still very few standards of value.
In time, the emergence of national fiat
monies during the twentieth century, together with securities markets that allowed the issuance of government
debts payable in fiat monies, will be
viewed as an experiment that made the
costs of monetary mischief increasingly
clear. Traditional justifications for monetary independence will sound hollow,
and constraints on fiscal-policy actions
will become more binding.

■ Guidelines for the New
Millennium
Following Hayek, I submit that approaches to international monetary
relations that foster competition among
alternative currency units are more likely to enhance world welfare than systems, like Bretton Woods, which mandate change directed by supranational
governmental bodies, which tend to
ossify over time.
Countries can take specific steps to allow and even encourage this competition. The first is to remove any capital
and exchange controls, including prohibitions on deposits denominated in foreign currencies. Argentina went a step
further and clearly signaled its intention
to maintain monetary stability by granting people the legal right to contract
under any and all circumstances—

including tax payments and other transactions with the government—in any
currency they might choose. Argentine
legislation requires courts to enforce
contracts in the currency specified
therein. This “specific performance”
law5 provides a level playing field for
competition between the domestic and
foreign currencies.
During the Asian crises of 1997, broad
macroeconomic policies—fiscal policies, monetary policies, and balance-ofpayments accounts—did not raise any
warning flags. Instead, the less obvious
underlying flaws in the domestic financial markets (especially the banking
companies) were revealed to be pervasive. Undercapitalization, connected
lending, inadequate supervision, duration mismatches, uncovered exchangerate exposure, and other flaws were
revealed in the postmortem of the socalled currency crises.
It is tempting to say that what is needed
is an international organization responsible for working toward global adoption of sound banking and other financial-market practices. However, the
idea of empowering a “conditionality
enforcer of first or only resort” is troublesome. Some combination of carrots
and sticks will always be present.
Whether carrots or sticks dominate will
change over time, depending on personalities and political environment. I
doubt anyone would defend the view
that what is needed is a global financial
policeman/prosecutor/judge/jury/executioner all rolled into one. To some people, the world’s capital markets may
seem, at times, like the wild, wild west,
but they would still stop short of a call
for a financial Judge Roy Bean.
Instead, following Mises,6 we might
think that a financial night watchman
would better serve as the role model for
the professional staff of any international organization that is empowered
to work on behalf of creditor nationstates. A common element of all financial crises in recent years was the existence of government guarantees that
were revealed to be unsustainable. The
sooner the revelation, the better countries were equipped to eliminate the
distortions without a crisis. To this end,
an international organization might
truly add value.

■ Footnotes
1. Friedrich A. Hayek, “The Fatal Conceit:
The Errors of Socialism,” in W.W. Bartley,
III, ed., The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek,
vol. 1, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1988.
2. Karl Brunner, “The Poverty of Nations,”
Business Economics, vol. 20, no. 1 (January
1985), pp. 5–11.
3. Monetary stability—a stable standard of
value—is not the same thing as a stable
“price level,” nor does it mean “zero inflation.” For a classic treatment of these terms,
see Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: A
Treatise on Economics. New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1949. For an excellent
contemporary discussion, see George A.
Selgin, “Less than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy,”
Hobart Papers: vol. 132, London: Institute
of Economic Affairs, 1997. An important
conclusion is that the wealth gains emanating from a favorable productivity surprise
should be reflected in the rising purchasing
power of money.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send
copies of reprinted materials to the
editor.

4. Benjamin Klein, “The Competitive Supply of Money,” in Lawrence H. White, ed.,
Free Banking: Modern Theory and Policy,
vol. 3. Elgar Reference Collection. International Library of Macroeconomic and Financial History, No. 11, Aldershot, UK: Elgar, 1993 (previously published 1974).
5. Specific performance legislation is not a
“legal-tender law.” Legal-tender laws require that residents of a country accept a
certain currency in settlement of a financial
obligation, even if they are owed a foreign
currency, gold, or bales of hay. Specific performance legislation means the courts must
require delivery of what was promised in the
contract, even if that is the currency of another country, gold, or bales of hay.
6. Ludwig von Mises, “Liberty and Property,” a lecture delivered at Princeton University, October 1958, at the Ninth Meeting of
the Mont Pelerin Society, reprinted by The
Heritage Foundation, 1998.

Jerry L. Jordan is President and Chief Executive Officer of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Economic Commentary is published by
the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
To receive copies or to be placed on the
mailing list, e-mail your request to
4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to
216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is
also available at the Cleveland Fed’s Website: www.clev.frb.org/research, where glossaries of terms are also provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No.385