View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 1, 2000

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Evolution in Banking Supervision
by Ed Stevens

I

t’s no secret that the banking business
has been changing rapidly. Computer,
telecommunications, and satellite technologies have opened avenues for intermediation and risk management that
were inconceivable as recently as 25
years ago. Moreover, whether independently or because of pressures created by
technical change, a worldwide movement toward less restrictive financial regulation has been at work.1 Global banking and financial markets have flourished
as barriers to the free flow of capital and
goods and services have fallen around
the world. In the United States, mergers
of large into ever-larger banking organizations have accompanied the elimination of legal barriers to nationwide
branching. Combinations of banking,
securities, and insurance businesses were
emerging even before recent financial
modernization legislation clarified the
relaxation of regulatory restraints.
Banking supervision has been adapting to
these vast structural changes both in the
United States and abroad. Traditionally,
supervision of safety and soundness
relied on bank examiners to test the quality of a bank’s assets and, indirectly, its
asset selection process. Examiners’
reports formed the basis for a supervisory
judgment about the adequacy of a bank’s
capital for absorbing potential unexpected losses. Like banking, however,
supervisory techniques are changing
around the world. Last year, the worldwide Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision, operating under the auspices
of the Bank for International Settlements,
published proposals for a new supervisory capital-adequacy framework that
would supercede its widely adopted 1988
capital accord. This Economic Commentary describes the major innovations in
the new Basel Committee proposals,
ISSN 0428-1276

placing them in the context of changing
banking and supervisory technology.
Before doing that, it will be helpful first
to consider why supervision is necessary
at all and then why the 1988 Basel capital
accord is said to be “in tatters.”

■ Why Regulate and Supervise
Banks?
No one should have a more intense
concern for both the profits and safety
of a bank than its own shareholders.
That being the case, how can nonmarket
governmental supervisors be any better
at evaluating a complex banking organization’s risk exposures and need for
capital than the managers of that organization itself?
One reason why banking regulation and
supervision are necessary is to redress
“moral hazard.” In most countries, banks
are protected by government safety nets,
typically including a lender-of-last-resort
facility and/or deposit insurance. Safety
nets can produce suboptimal market
results by inflating banks’ incentives to
take risk. Banking regulation and supervision must replace the market discipline
removed by the safety net.
A second rationale—at least in the case
of Federal Reserve banking supervision—is that a Reserve bank carries on
a banking business, requiring careful
attention to its own counterparty risk
exposures. Each business day banks in
this country make about $1 trillion in
payments to one another. A substantial
share of these involve near-instantaneous,
irrevocable wire transfers of funds by
the Reserve banks for their banking customers. In order to fund the wire transfers, the Reserve banks extend something like $100 billion of daylight credit.
They must manage their resulting risk

Banking supervision must keep pace
with technical innovations in the
banking industry. The international
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision currently is reviewing public
comments on its proposed new
method for judging whether a bank
maintains enough capital to absorb
unexpected losses. This Economic
Commentary explains how existing
standards became obsolete and
describes the new plan.
exposure to protect themselves from any
loss that would result if a customer bank
were to fail without having repaid its
daylight borrowing. Managing this
exposure involves monitoring the credit
quality of their customer banks and
supervising their adherence to capitaladequacy requirements.

How to Supervise
The moral hazard of a safety net as well
as prudent scrutiny of the central bank’s
customers provide a rationale for regulating and supervising banking organizations—to curtail risk taking. They do
not, however, explain how to do this or
to what degree. Traditional ex post tests
of a bank’s capital adequacy suffer from
several drawbacks, especially in supervising large, complex banking organizations. One is that the legal entity of a
bank is becoming increasingly irrelevant
in managing risk. A banking organization—a holding company or a bank with
bank and nonbank subsidiaries—typically manages lines of business that cut
across corporate legal boundaries. Supervisors not only must be aware of the role
a particular bank plays in each line of
business, but must understand the riskmanagement strategy of the whole banking organization in order to evaluate the

risk exposures of a particular bank.
Another is that risk management relies on
a variety of financial instruments whose
values vary day by day in response to
developments in securities markets.
Supervisors have responded to these two
difficulties by developing risk-focused
examinations. According to the General
Accounting Office, this approach “emphasizes a supervisory plan … tailored to
the institution’s risk profile and organizational structure.”2 Risk-focused examinations deal with how to curtail risk, but
don’t provide criteria for how much risk
to curtail. The Basel risk-adjusted capital
guidelines represent a concerted global
effort to establish those criteria.

International Standards
A bank’s capital typically is said to
include the amounts paid in by shareholders and its retained earnings, as well
as certain liabilities that have lowest priority when paying off the creditors of a
failed bank. The larger a bank’s capital,
the larger the loss of asset value the bank
can sustain before depositors (and a
deposit insurance agency) suffer losses.
Minimum capital requirements are
among the earliest forms of government
regulation of banking.
Increasing globalization of trade and
finance over the post–World War II
period resulted in increasingly intense
competition among banks. This drew
attention to international differences in
capital requirements and their role in
determining competitive advantages and
disadvantages in the global banking market. Finally, after considerable negotiation, the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision of the Bank for International
Settlements worked out the 1988 international accord on capital regulation.3
The 1988 accord was an agreement
among the G-10 central banks to apply
common minimum regulatory capital
requirements to their respective banking
industries. The standards set the minimum level of capital a bank should
maintain at 8 percent of risk-adjusted
exposure.4 This exposure is determined
as a weighted average of the value of a
bank’s assets and equivalent off-balancesheet items. The framework, updated
several times over the intervening years,
still provides the foundation for minimum risk-adjusted capital standards in
the major national banking systems of
the world.

The idea behind the accord is simply that
a bank’s capital should be commensurate
with the riskiness of its business. The
framework has two main parts. The first
defines what to include in a measure of
capital, distinguishing between two
types—primary and secondary. The
bank’s common stock and noncumulative perpetual preferred stock issues,
plus certain reserves, are included in primary capital, while secondary capital
consists of other kinds of reserves and
other classes of stock, plus certain liabilities, including subordinated term debt.5
The other part of the framework lays out
a weighting system used to calculate a
minimum capital standard for each bank.
Weights are 0, 10, 20, 50, or 100 percent,
and they are applied to specific types of
assets and off-balance-sheet items, depending on the nature of the financial
instrument and borrower, although
national supervisors have some discretion over their own guidelines. Cash and
government securities of the bank’s own
country get a risk weight of zero, claims
on public-sector entities get 10 percent,
claims on banks incorporated in OECD
nations, 20 percent, fully secured mortgages on residential property, 50 percent,
while all other claims on private-sector
entities get a 100 percent risk weight.
Market-risk provisions were added in
1996. These address the risk that
changes in interest rates will change the
market value of a financial instrument.
They apply to interest-rate-related
instruments and equities in a bank’s trading account, and foreign-exchange and
commodities risks throughout the whole
bank.6 The sum of all risk-weighted
assets, when multiplied by 8 percent,
produces the minimum capital required
by the supervisory process.

■ Diminishing Effectiveness
of the 1988 Accord
Despite the shift to risk-focused examinations, risk-based capital guidelines have
become less and less effective as a basis
for supervisory judgments about the quality of a banking organization. This especially applies to the largest, most complex banking organizations, and to a
lesser extent to all banking organizations
as they move into new financial technologies. Capital arbitrage has seriously
eroded the effectiveness of the arbitrary
risk weights regulators use to determine a
bank’s minimum need for capital.

“Capital arbitrage” characterizes a variety of techniques banks use to reduce the
impact of binding capital requirements.
To see how, one must distinguish between the regulatory and the economic
perceptions of adequate capital. Regulatory capital corresponds to the risk-based
requirements associated with the Basel
accord. Economic capital is what a bank
would hold in the absence of regulation
to achieve a desired position on its
risk/return trade-off. In general, regulatory capital requirements can be expected to constrain the behavior of banks
as long as supervision is designed to
compensate for the failure of market discipline to price risk taking appropriately.
This means that banks must maintain
more capital than they have an economic
incentive to hold. Equivalently, banks
have an incentive to devise ways of
avoiding the requirement. In the last
decade of the twentieth century, banks
have been able to respond to these incentives with some ease. New financial
technologies have increased the substitutability of loans and securities, while
derivative instruments enable risks to be
deconstructed into marketable components. Two main features characterize
most of the ever-increasing variety of
capital arbitrage techniques: “cherry
picking” and securitization.7
Cherry picking refers to practices that
shift a bank’s portfolio toward the riskier
of two loans when supervisors would put
both loans in the same “risk bucket.”
Banks have an incentive to accommodate the credit needs of high-quality borrowers in ways that avoid straight loans
in order to achieve a lower risk weight.
Securitization is the act of packaging and
selling loans as marketable securities. It
is the usual method banks use to shed
their lower-risk loans. The problem with
this method, however, is that the market
frequently requires that such securities be
“enhanced” or “insured.” The most
straightforward enhancement is to sell
them with “recourse,” where the bank
selling the securitized loans retains liability in the case of default. Simply selling a
loan-backed security with recourse could
be worse than holding the loans themselves because recourse requires a 100
percent capital requirement.
Banks have found ways around this,
however, by exploiting a provision in the
accord which treats these financial guarantees more favorably for regulatory

TABLE 1 PROPOSED WEIGHTS FOR CALCULATING
CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS
Assessment (percent)
Claim

Governments
Banks
Option 1a
Option 2b
Corporates

AAA
to AA–

0
20
20
20

A+ to A–

BBB+
to BBB–

BB+
to B–

Below B–

Unrated

20c
50c
50c
100c

50c
100c
50c
100c

100c
100c
100c
100c

150
150
150
150

100c
100c
50c
100

a. Risk weighting based on risk weighting of sovereign in which the bank is incorporated.
b. Risk weighting based on the assessment of the individual bank.
c. Claims on banks of a short original maturity, for example less than six months, would receive a
weighting that is one category more favorable than the usual risk weight on the bank’s claims.
SOURCE: Adapted from “A New Capital Adequacy Framework” (see footnote 8), p. 31.

purposes if the enhanced assets are not
owned by the bank. The bank accomplishes this by “remote origination,” creating an organization that officially originates the loan (referred to as a “special
purpose vehicle” or SPV). A bank refers
customers who satisfy its underwriting
criteria to the SPV, which in turn funds
the loans. The SPV funds the loans by
issuing securities, such as commercial
paper, with a significant credit enhancement from the bank. Note that if this
enhancement is 100 percent, there is no
risk on the securites the SPV issues.
From the standpoint of the bank, the
method is identical to funding the loans
and selling them with recourse except
that the credit enhancement is treated as
a direct credit substitute for regulatory
purposes. This amount can be substantially less than the amount of credit
issued by the “vehicle.” Other more
complex arrangements involving indirect credit enhancements are also used,
tailored to the unique circumstances of
particular customers.
Notice that these techniques economize
on capital in two ways. First, securitized
or enhanced assets carry a lower risk
weight when calculating regulatory capital. Second, assets that remain in the
bank’s portfolio after cherry picking and
securitization carry no higher risk weight
despite the fact that these capital arbitrage techniques reduce the average
quality of assets in a given risk bucket.

of ways, but primary interest centers on
two new approaches for determining
minimum regulatory capital. One would
replace the arbitrary risk weights with
weights based on external credit ratings.
The other would tailor the determination
to the unique risk profile of each institution through reliance on that institution’s
own internal risk ratings.

External ratings
The first approach effectively would
reduce weights on the highest-quality
assets and increase weights on lowerquality assets. Banks’ claims on governments, other banks, securities firms, and
all other corporations would be rooted in
the professional judgments of rating
agencies such as Standard and Poors,
Moody’s, and Fitch IBCA. Table 1 is a
simplified illustrative example based on
Standard and Poor’s rating system.
Replacing arbitrary risk buckets with
weights based on external ratings could
reduce the present incentive to cherry
pick. Also, the proposed new framework
would replace the current arbitrary
weights for securitizations with weights
based on external ratings that should
more effectively reflect actual risks. Presumably, the recourse or insurance part
of the asset that is attached to many securitized loans would have a higher risk
weight—given its lower value—than
the underlying securities themselves.

Internal ratings
■ A Proposed New CapitalAdequacy Framework
In June of last year the Basel Committee
requested public comments by March 31,
2000, on a proposal for a new capitaladequacy framework.8 The proposed
framework is intended to maintain at
least current levels of bank capital and to
“enhance competitive equality.” It differs
from the existing framework in a number

Risk management at internationally
active banking organizations is becoming a highly sophisticated scientific discipline involving models of market,
credit, and operational risks that are
intended for use in the analysis of compensation, customer profitability, pricing, portfolio allocation, and capital
needs. Models of market risk are better

developed than others because historical
data are readily available and all banks’
exposures derive from the common pool
of securities available in the market.
Credit-risk modeling is more difficult,
given the vast number of unique potential borrowers and very little in the way
of a common pool of historical information available to all banks.9 Risk ranking
of assets within a bank will be more reliable than across banks because true risk
can be very institution specific.
Nonetheless, “the Basel Committee …
believes that an internal ratings-based
approach could form the basis for setting
capital charges for some sophisticated
banks.” This supervisory approach must
overcome two hurdles to become practicable. One is the challenge to both banks
and supervisors of translating internal
relative credit ratings into absolute capital requirements. The other is the supervisory challenge of achieving consistency both among the sophisticated
banks for whom an internal ratingsbased methodology is feasible and
between those banks and others for
whom the standardized external ratingsbased methodology is appropriate.
So far, the internal ratings-based approach is a methodology in the making,
not yet an operational option. As an
indication of future practice, however,
it highlights the significant shift that is
taking place in banking supervision.
Periodic examination for compliance
with arbitrary regulatory requirements
is giving way to continuous monitoring
based on an understanding of each
bank’s own technically sophisticated
risk-management strategies.

■ Concluding Comment
The 1988 Basel accord has become outmoded. For many banking organizations,
the Committee’s new proposal to employ
external ratings in judging asset risk
could remove some of the existing incentive for capital arbitrage. At the same
time, for the largest, internationally active banking organizations, the possibility of focusing supervisory attention on
their emerging internal risk-management
methods could enhance the effectiveness
of the supervisory process by putting
both bank and supervisor “on the same
page.” In both cases, the new proposals
would reduce inconsistencies between
regulatory and economic estimates of the
risk of one asset relative to that of
another, thereby removing a major incentive for capital arbitrage. However, the

unique supervisory problem remains that
of judging how much capital is adequate
both for the risk profile of a bank as well
as for the moral hazard generated by the
banking safety net.

Footnotes
1. An impressive body of examples can be
found in Enhancing the Role of Competition
in the Regulation of Banks, Competition Policy Roundtable, Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development, Directorate
for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs,
Committee on Competition Law and Policy,
September 7, 1998.

papers mentioned are available at
<www.bis.org>.
5. In calculating the adequacy of its capital, a
bank cannot include any secondary capital in
excess of primary capital or any subordinated
debt in excess of half of primary capital.
6. “Amendment to the Capital Accord to
Incorporate Market Risks,” Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision, Bank for International Settlements, January 1996.

2. Risk-Focused Examinations—Regulators
of Large Banking Organizations Face Challenges, Report to Congressional Requesters,
Washington, D.C.: General Accounting
Office, January 2000.

7. See “Capital Requirements and Bank
Behaviour: The Impact of the Basel Accord,”
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
Working Paper no. 1, April 1999, p. 23, and
David Jones, “Emerging Problems with the
Basel Capital Accord: Regulatory Capital
Arbitrage and Related Issues,” Journal of
Banking and Finance, vol. 24, no. 1/2 (January 2000), pp. 33–58.

3. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision is a committee of banking supervisory
authorities established by the central bank
governors of the G-10 countries in 1975.

8. “A New Capital Adequacy Framework,”
Consultative paper issued by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Bank for
International Settlements, June 1999.

4. “International Convergence of Capital
Measurement and Capital Standards,” vol. 1,
chap. 1, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Bank for International Settlements,
April 1997. All of the Basel Committee

9. For details, see “Credit Risk Modelling:
Current Practices and Applications,” Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision, Bank
for International Settlements, April 1999.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

Ed Stevens is a senior consultant and
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.
The views stated here are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org, or fax it to
216-579-3050.
Economic Commentary is also available
at the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World Wide
Web: www.clev.frb.org/research, where glossaries of terms are also provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385