View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 15, 1989

• Conclusion
The current thrift-industry debacle will

•

1. See James Barth and Michael Bradley,

ward Kane, The Gathering Crisis in Federal

be expensive to resolve. Of the estimated $124 billion needed to resolve the
crisis, at least $40 billion to $60 billion
will come directly from the taxpayer.

"Thrift Deregulation and Federal Deposit In-

Deposit Insurance, Cambridge, MA: MIT

With this commitment of taxpayer
money should come a reexamination of
the objective of the deposit-insurance
system and far-reach ing reforms in its
design so that a crisis of the current
magnitude is not repeated.
Any changes to the deposit-insurance
mechanism should be made with a
clear understanding of the associated
costs and benefits. Society needs to be
more aware of the size and value of
govemment guarantees, like deposit
insurance, and the public should make
strenuous efforts to ensure that the
costs of providing these guarantees do
not exceed the benefits.

Footnotes

surance," Journal of Financial Services Re-

Press, 1985, chapter 3.

search, vol. 2 (1989-forthcoming).

7. The failure-resolution

JUL

policies of the

2. The $124 billion includes $50 billion for

FDIC and FSLIC are the process through

prior case resolutions and $74 billion for

which implicit guarantees are issued to un-

restructuring insolvent thrifts. The $ I24 bil-

insured depositors, general creditors, subor-

lion estimate does not include financing costs

dinated creditors, and even stockholders. For

of $8 I billion ($150 billion) if the spending

a discussion of FDIC failure-resolution

is financed over 10 (30) years at current

policies, see Daria Caliguire and James

market interest rates. See Barbara Pauley,
'The Thrift Reform Program: Summary and

Thomson, "FDIC Policies for Dealing with

Implications," New York: Salomon Brothers,

Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of

April 1989.

Cleveland, October I, 1987.

3. See Edward Kane, The Gathering Crisis

8. See Arthur Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff, Washington, D.C.: The

in Federal Deposit Insurance, Cambridge,

eCONOMIC
t.tBeO~MeNTaRY

6. For a discussion of this point, see Ed-

\

MA: MIT Press, 1985, chapters 5 and 6; and

Brookings Institution, 1975.
9. One feature of the original Bush administration proposal is uniform capital re-

Urban Institute, 1989.

quirements for banks and thrifts by June

4. Some economists question whether

1991. The Bush administration has indicated

federal deposit insurance is needed at all.

to the Congress that it will veto any legisla-

After all, the liabilities of other financial

tion for resolving the thrift-industry crisis

intermediaries are neither explicitly nor

that waters down this provision.

by James B. Thomson

T

he dramatic rise in interest rates
during the late 1970s and early 1980s
wreaked havoc on the balance sheets of
savings and loan (thrift) institutions. As
their cost of funds rose above what they
could earn on their asset portfolios,

implicitly guaranteed by the federal govern-

Policymakers should consider depositinsurance reforms in the context of the
overall evolution of the financial services industry and also in the context of
other regulatory reforms. The result
should be a deposit-insurance system
with modest, well-specified objectives
that are easy to understand and administer. With this in mind, federal deposit
insurance should be structured in a
fashion that accomplishes its goals with
minimal disruption of market forces.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,

Address

0"

ment. Many of these institutions compete
head-on with banks and thrifts for funds and
provide many of the same services as insured

James B. Thomson is an assistant vice presi-

depository institutions.

dent and economist at the Federal Reserve

S. This role for deposit insurance is the
motivation for the safe-bank proposals of
Litan and others. See Robert Litan, What
Should Banks Do? Washington, D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1987.

thrift institutions began to lose billions
of dollars. By the end of 1982, 237
thrifts (with $67.8 billion in assets) in-

Bank of Cleveland. The author would like to

sured by the Federal Savings and Loan
Insurance Corporation (FSLlC) were insolvent by generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP). I

thank William Osterberg, Mark Sniderman,
and EJ. Stevens for helpful comments and
suggestions.
The views stated herein are those of the

is estimated at more than $124 billion? Furthermore, approximately 500
additional thrifts are above normal risks
for failure. The expected future cost associated with these failures is not included in the FSLlC loss estimates.
In contrast, the fund of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
remains solvent, despite having eroded
in this decade under the pressure of
record bank failures and an increase in
failure-resolution costs. In 1988, the
FDIC experienced its first loss in the

author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid

The initial response of Congress and
the Federal Home Loan Bank Board to

post-Depression era, as the book value
of its fund balance shrank from $18.3

the thrift crisis was a policy of capital
forbearance. Capital requirements were

billion to $14.1 billion. Academic
economists and private banking

relaxed for the industry as a whole, and
insolvent and capital-deficient thrifts
were allowed to operate because if in-

analysts estimate the real value of the
fund as being significantly less. In fact,

terest rates declined, the institutions
stood a chance of recovering.

Cleveland.Dfl
Permit No. 385

This policy of capital forbearance entailed a high degree of risk. By buying

44101

Correction

,

Economic Principles and
Deposit- Insurance Reform

Failed and Troubled Institutions," Economic

Edward Kane, The S&L Insurance Mess:
How Did It Happen? Washington, D.C.: The

i I 3 2 ~e~~\al\las~;ve Bank of Cleveland

Requested:

Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.

the private group known as the Shadow
Financial Regulatory Committee estimates that the true reserve balance of
the FDIC fund, net of estimated unbooked losses, is only $400 million.

time to deal with the insolvency prob-

On February 6, 1989, the Bush ad-

lem, the ultimate cost of resolving the
problem could have become smaller.
Unfortunately, the outcome was disappointing, as both the number of insol-

ministration announced a plan for
resolving the thrift crisis that includes
provisions to recapitalize the insolvent
FSLlC and to close nearly 500 savings

vent institutions and the cost of resolving these insolvencies rose through the
end of 1987 (see table 1).

and loan institutions that are currently
insolvent or in danger of failing. The
Bush plan also contains provisions for
strengthening the FDIC's fund.

By late 1988, nearly 500 thrifts were
either GAAP-insolvent
Material may be reprinted provided that

or in danger of

failing. The cost of closing, reorganizing, or recapitalizing these institutions

the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.
ISSN 0428-1276

Conspicuously absent from this
proposal are fundamental reforms to

The current

system of federal deposit

insurance subsidizes risk-taking by
depository institutions, resulting in
increased failure-resolution
costs and
decreased efficiency for the entire
financial system.

Reforms to the

deposit-insurance
system should consider both the policy objectives and
the attendant economic consequences
and costs of deposit guarantees.

the federal deposit-insurance

system

runs. Some economists believe that an

tions achieves the same result with

that would help prevent another such
crisis~ Numerous proposals for
deposit-insurance reform have been advanced. The purpose of this Economic

individual bank run can become contagious and result in a run on the entire
banking system. If so, deposit insurance could remove or reduce the in-

greater efficiency. Furthermore, as in
the case with systemic bank runs, a
properly functioning lender of last
resort could immunize other banks

Commentary is to examine the fundamental economic principles that
should be used in evaluating these
reform proposals.

centives for bank runs and thus stabilize the banking system.

fects of a single bank failure.

A rational bank run is one that occurs
because depositors have good informa-

Clearly, the type of deposit-insurance
system we should adopt depends criti-

tion that their depository institution has
(or may) become insolvent. This type of

cally on our goals. For example, if the
purpose of deposit insurance is to protect the savings and transactions balances of informationally disadvantaged

•

The Purpose of Deposit Insurance

What are the policy objectives of
deposit insurance? Are depository institutions special in some way that requires that they have access to federal
deposit guarantees, or are they simply
special because they have access to
these guarantees? While often ignored,
these fundamental questions are important because different objectives for
deposit insurance could correspond to
different methods of implementing a
deposit-insurance system."
One widely cited justification for
federal deposit guarantees is the need to
protect the savings and transactions balances of small savers. If small depositors lack the sophistication and resources to monitor the condition of their
banks effectively (and the resources to
absorb unpredictable losses), then perhaps their accounts should be safeguarded -,Deposit insurance is but one
of many ways to achieve this.
It has also been argued that federal
deposit insurance is needed to improve
the informational efficiency of the
financial sector. If it is relatively costly
for some depositors to evaluate the condition of their depository institution,
then it might be more efficient to have

run should not be contagious, and in
fact should act as a form of market discipline on bank management. An irrational bank run is one that occurs because poorly informed depositors
mistakenly believe that their depository
institution has (or may) become insolvent. If the primary purpose of a
deposit-insurance system is to prevent
irrational bank runs, then the system

bined efforts of a mass of small
depositors. However, federal deposit insurance is not needed to lower information costs. These costs could be
reduced simply by having an agency
collect and disseminate information

protect the payments system, then the
type of account insured is more important than the amount of explicit
coverage. For example, consumer and

tificates of deposit would receive no, or
only nominal, coverage.

sacrificed to remove the potentially destabilizing effects of irrational bank
runs. Once again, however, deposit insurance is not the only solution. A
properly functioning lender of last
resort can prevent irrational bank runs
from becoming systemic bank runs by
providing liquidity to solvent institutions experiencing runs, thus removing
the destabilizing effects of irrational
bank runs without precluding rational
bank runs on insolvent institutions.

savings and investment vehicles such as
money market deposit accounts and cer-

• Economic Consequences and
Costs of the Current DepositInsurance System
The estimated $124 billion needed to
resolve the thrift crisis is just the direct
monetary cost of our current system of
federal deposit guarantees. Other economic consequences and costs include
an overinvestment in risky assets and
the subsidization of depository institutions on the basis of risk and size. In
fact, perverse incentives built into these
subsidies contributed significantly to
the current thrift crisis. Without meaningful reforms to the deposit-insurance

The need to protect the nation's payments system is the fourth reason
often cited to justify federal deposit
guarantees.I According to this view, a

mechanism, there are strong incentives
for this situation to be repeated.

default on the payments system could

As presently priced and administered,
federal deposit insurance subsidizes

be triggered by the failure of a large
bank, leading other banks to become insolvent. By guaranteeing the payments-

risk-taking by depository institutions in
two ways. First, the FDIC and FSLIC
provide a risk-related subsidy to all in-

related liabilities of banks, deposit in-

sured depository institutions. Second,

A third motive for federal deposit in-

surance immunizes the payments
system from bank failures. An objection to this view is that providing direct

insured institutions that are safe and
well-managed subsidize the risk-taking
behavior of the "high-fliers" of the in-

surance is t9 prevent destabilizing bank

guarantees of payments-system

dustry." In both cases, the amount of

without guaranteeing deposits.

transac-

Year

Number of GAAPInsolvent Thrifts

FSLlC Loss
Exposure
(in billions $)

Assets
(in billions $)

1982

237

$ 67.8

$ 3.08

1983

293

83.9

4.98

1984

445

115.5

16.89

1985

470

138.0

22.14

1986

471

137.2

33.76

1987

520

200.1

SOURCE: Edward Kane, The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did II Happen'
stitute, 1989, table 3·6.

69.51
Washington.

D.C.: The Urban In-

the risk-related subsidies increases with
the degree of risk assumed by the institution and leads to an overinvestment in risky assets in the economy.
Currently, the failure-resolution

policies

of the FDIC and FSLIC have resulted in
a system of federal deposit insurance
that is biased in favor of large institutions.7 For example, the FDIC has
never liquidated a bank with more than
$600 million in assets, thereby providing de facto 100-percent insurance for
all depositors in such institutions, On
the other hand, small banks have been

Some have argued for government interference into markets on equity
grounds.f Equity can be used to justify
federal deposit insurance if it corrects
biases or favoritism existing in the absence of deposit insurance. Because
equity is a relative concept, we typically judge the equity of a proposal relative to the market outcome.
For a deposit-insurance system to be
equitable, it must treat all financial institutions alike. As discussed earlier,
the current system of federal deposit insurance is not equitable because the

liquidated routinely, and some uninsured depositors in these institutions
have suffered losses. This perceived as-

failure-resolution policies of the FDIC
and FSLIC are biased in favor of large
depository institutions. A second ex-

surance against liquidation has given
large depository institutions a competitive advantage over small ones in issuing large, uninsured deposits.

ample of the inequity of the current system is in the area of capital regulation.
If capital is costly to obtain, then the
equity criterion implies that all insured

• Using Economic Principles to
Evaluate Reform Proposals

institutions should be subject to the
same set of regulations as a condition
for receiving federal deposit guaran-

Equity and efficiency are the two basic
principles economists apply when
evaluating programs such as federal
deposit insurance, The concepts of
equity and efficiency must be considered in the context of both depositinsurance objectives and the regulatory
and market structure of the insured industry. Because a trade-off can exist between equity and efficiency, the "best"
deposit-insurance

system may not rank

as the top proposal in terms of either
criterion alone,

tees. For instance, if a minimum capital
ratio is specified as a condition for
receiving deposit guarantees, then all
insured institutions should be subject
to the same capital requirements.

creditors, and equity-holders when
those banks fail. Each class of
claimants on the bank's assets should
receive the same treatment irrespective
of the size, location, or type of insured
institution. Otherwise, the presence of
deposit insurance changes the relative
cost of funds and equity capital across
institutions.
Efficiency is the second criterion by
which deposit-insurance reforms
should be judged. Economists are
usually concerned with allocative efficiency; that is, how close the resource
allocation under each proposal is to
some perceived optimal, yet usually unattainable, resource allocation.

limit of $100,000. On the other hand, if
the purpose of deposit insurance is to

Unfortunately, deposit-insurance

the monitoring performed by a centralized agency. In addition, a centralized
agency is likely to have lower information costs than the total cost of the com-

small savers, then the coverage necessary is less than the current explicit

corporate checking accounts would be
fully insured under this motive, while

tems cannot differentiate between rational and irrational bank runs. Consequently, the desirable market discipline
of occasional rational bank runs is

ESTIMATES OF FSLIC LOSS EXPOSURE
TO GAAP-INSOL VENT THRIFTS

(and the payments system) from the ef-

should insure only the deposits of customers who are likely to act on poor
information.
sys-

TABLE 1

How-

ever, most thrifts are currently required
to hold only half as much capital as
banksY
Equity also implies that all depositors
should be treated equally. That is, there
should not be differential treatment
across banks of uninsured depositors,

The allocative efficiency of each
reform proposal cannot be directly observed. However, judgments about the
relative efficiency of alternative
deposit-insurance systems can be based
on the incentives built into each one.
From an efficiency standpoint, the incentives built into deposit insurance,
through the pricing of the guarantees
and the failure-resolution policies of
the FmC and FSLIC, should not subsidize risk-taking either through crosssubsidies between depository institutions or through the Treasury (to the
extent that the Treasury stands behind
the FDIC and FSLIC),
The efficiency criterion requires that
when circumstances warrant, regulators must allow banks and thrifts
(regardless of size) to fail. Failure is
the mechanism through which the
market corrects persistent and substantial inefficiencies. Failure does not
imply that the institution always must
be liquidated or otherwise disappear;
rather, it means that the owners and
management are replaced. As we have
found in the thrift industry, the lack of
resolve to close institutions when they
are insolvent increases the ultimate
failure-resolution costs and decreases
the efficiency of the financial system.

the federal deposit-insurance

system

runs. Some economists believe that an

tions achieves the same result with

that would help prevent another such
crisis~ Numerous proposals for
deposit-insurance reform have been advanced. The purpose of this Economic

individual bank run can become contagious and result in a run on the entire
banking system. If so, deposit insurance could remove or reduce the in-

greater efficiency. Furthermore, as in
the case with systemic bank runs, a
properly functioning lender of last
resort could immunize other banks

Commentary is to examine the fundamental economic principles that
should be used in evaluating these
reform proposals.

centives for bank runs and thus stabilize the banking system.

fects of a single bank failure.

A rational bank run is one that occurs
because depositors have good informa-

Clearly, the type of deposit-insurance
system we should adopt depends criti-

tion that their depository institution has
(or may) become insolvent. This type of

cally on our goals. For example, if the
purpose of deposit insurance is to protect the savings and transactions balances of informationally disadvantaged

•

The Purpose of Deposit Insurance

What are the policy objectives of
deposit insurance? Are depository institutions special in some way that requires that they have access to federal
deposit guarantees, or are they simply
special because they have access to
these guarantees? While often ignored,
these fundamental questions are important because different objectives for
deposit insurance could correspond to
different methods of implementing a
deposit-insurance system."
One widely cited justification for
federal deposit guarantees is the need to
protect the savings and transactions balances of small savers. If small depositors lack the sophistication and resources to monitor the condition of their
banks effectively (and the resources to
absorb unpredictable losses), then perhaps their accounts should be safeguarded -,Deposit insurance is but one
of many ways to achieve this.
It has also been argued that federal
deposit insurance is needed to improve
the informational efficiency of the
financial sector. If it is relatively costly
for some depositors to evaluate the condition of their depository institution,
then it might be more efficient to have

run should not be contagious, and in
fact should act as a form of market discipline on bank management. An irrational bank run is one that occurs because poorly informed depositors
mistakenly believe that their depository
institution has (or may) become insolvent. If the primary purpose of a
deposit-insurance system is to prevent
irrational bank runs, then the system

bined efforts of a mass of small
depositors. However, federal deposit insurance is not needed to lower information costs. These costs could be
reduced simply by having an agency
collect and disseminate information

protect the payments system, then the
type of account insured is more important than the amount of explicit
coverage. For example, consumer and

tificates of deposit would receive no, or
only nominal, coverage.

sacrificed to remove the potentially destabilizing effects of irrational bank
runs. Once again, however, deposit insurance is not the only solution. A
properly functioning lender of last
resort can prevent irrational bank runs
from becoming systemic bank runs by
providing liquidity to solvent institutions experiencing runs, thus removing
the destabilizing effects of irrational
bank runs without precluding rational
bank runs on insolvent institutions.

savings and investment vehicles such as
money market deposit accounts and cer-

• Economic Consequences and
Costs of the Current DepositInsurance System
The estimated $124 billion needed to
resolve the thrift crisis is just the direct
monetary cost of our current system of
federal deposit guarantees. Other economic consequences and costs include
an overinvestment in risky assets and
the subsidization of depository institutions on the basis of risk and size. In
fact, perverse incentives built into these
subsidies contributed significantly to
the current thrift crisis. Without meaningful reforms to the deposit-insurance

The need to protect the nation's payments system is the fourth reason
often cited to justify federal deposit
guarantees.I According to this view, a

mechanism, there are strong incentives
for this situation to be repeated.

default on the payments system could

As presently priced and administered,
federal deposit insurance subsidizes

be triggered by the failure of a large
bank, leading other banks to become insolvent. By guaranteeing the payments-

risk-taking by depository institutions in
two ways. First, the FDIC and FSLIC
provide a risk-related subsidy to all in-

related liabilities of banks, deposit in-

sured depository institutions. Second,

A third motive for federal deposit in-

surance immunizes the payments
system from bank failures. An objection to this view is that providing direct

insured institutions that are safe and
well-managed subsidize the risk-taking
behavior of the "high-fliers" of the in-

surance is t9 prevent destabilizing bank

guarantees of payments-system

dustry." In both cases, the amount of

without guaranteeing deposits.

transac-

Year

Number of GAAPInsolvent Thrifts

FSLlC Loss
Exposure
(in billions $)

Assets
(in billions $)

1982

237

$ 67.8

$ 3.08

1983

293

83.9

4.98

1984

445

115.5

16.89

1985

470

138.0

22.14

1986

471

137.2

33.76

1987

520

200.1

SOURCE: Edward Kane, The S&L Insurance Mess: How Did II Happen'
stitute, 1989, table 3·6.

69.51
Washington.

D.C.: The Urban In-

the risk-related subsidies increases with
the degree of risk assumed by the institution and leads to an overinvestment in risky assets in the economy.
Currently, the failure-resolution

policies

of the FDIC and FSLIC have resulted in
a system of federal deposit insurance
that is biased in favor of large institutions.7 For example, the FDIC has
never liquidated a bank with more than
$600 million in assets, thereby providing de facto 100-percent insurance for
all depositors in such institutions, On
the other hand, small banks have been

Some have argued for government interference into markets on equity
grounds.f Equity can be used to justify
federal deposit insurance if it corrects
biases or favoritism existing in the absence of deposit insurance. Because
equity is a relative concept, we typically judge the equity of a proposal relative to the market outcome.
For a deposit-insurance system to be
equitable, it must treat all financial institutions alike. As discussed earlier,
the current system of federal deposit insurance is not equitable because the

liquidated routinely, and some uninsured depositors in these institutions
have suffered losses. This perceived as-

failure-resolution policies of the FDIC
and FSLIC are biased in favor of large
depository institutions. A second ex-

surance against liquidation has given
large depository institutions a competitive advantage over small ones in issuing large, uninsured deposits.

ample of the inequity of the current system is in the area of capital regulation.
If capital is costly to obtain, then the
equity criterion implies that all insured

• Using Economic Principles to
Evaluate Reform Proposals

institutions should be subject to the
same set of regulations as a condition
for receiving federal deposit guaran-

Equity and efficiency are the two basic
principles economists apply when
evaluating programs such as federal
deposit insurance, The concepts of
equity and efficiency must be considered in the context of both depositinsurance objectives and the regulatory
and market structure of the insured industry. Because a trade-off can exist between equity and efficiency, the "best"
deposit-insurance

system may not rank

as the top proposal in terms of either
criterion alone,

tees. For instance, if a minimum capital
ratio is specified as a condition for
receiving deposit guarantees, then all
insured institutions should be subject
to the same capital requirements.

creditors, and equity-holders when
those banks fail. Each class of
claimants on the bank's assets should
receive the same treatment irrespective
of the size, location, or type of insured
institution. Otherwise, the presence of
deposit insurance changes the relative
cost of funds and equity capital across
institutions.
Efficiency is the second criterion by
which deposit-insurance reforms
should be judged. Economists are
usually concerned with allocative efficiency; that is, how close the resource
allocation under each proposal is to
some perceived optimal, yet usually unattainable, resource allocation.

limit of $100,000. On the other hand, if
the purpose of deposit insurance is to

Unfortunately, deposit-insurance

the monitoring performed by a centralized agency. In addition, a centralized
agency is likely to have lower information costs than the total cost of the com-

small savers, then the coverage necessary is less than the current explicit

corporate checking accounts would be
fully insured under this motive, while

tems cannot differentiate between rational and irrational bank runs. Consequently, the desirable market discipline
of occasional rational bank runs is

ESTIMATES OF FSLIC LOSS EXPOSURE
TO GAAP-INSOL VENT THRIFTS

(and the payments system) from the ef-

should insure only the deposits of customers who are likely to act on poor
information.
sys-

TABLE 1

How-

ever, most thrifts are currently required
to hold only half as much capital as
banksY
Equity also implies that all depositors
should be treated equally. That is, there
should not be differential treatment
across banks of uninsured depositors,

The allocative efficiency of each
reform proposal cannot be directly observed. However, judgments about the
relative efficiency of alternative
deposit-insurance systems can be based
on the incentives built into each one.
From an efficiency standpoint, the incentives built into deposit insurance,
through the pricing of the guarantees
and the failure-resolution policies of
the FmC and FSLIC, should not subsidize risk-taking either through crosssubsidies between depository institutions or through the Treasury (to the
extent that the Treasury stands behind
the FDIC and FSLIC),
The efficiency criterion requires that
when circumstances warrant, regulators must allow banks and thrifts
(regardless of size) to fail. Failure is
the mechanism through which the
market corrects persistent and substantial inefficiencies. Failure does not
imply that the institution always must
be liquidated or otherwise disappear;
rather, it means that the owners and
management are replaced. As we have
found in the thrift industry, the lack of
resolve to close institutions when they
are insolvent increases the ultimate
failure-resolution costs and decreases
the efficiency of the financial system.

May 15, 1989

• Conclusion
The current thrift-industry debacle will

•

1. See James Barth and Michael Bradley,

ward Kane, The Gathering Crisis in Federal

be expensive to resolve. Of the estimated $124 billion needed to resolve the
crisis, at least $40 billion to $60 billion
will come directly from the taxpayer.

"Thrift Deregulation and Federal Deposit In-

Deposit Insurance, Cambridge, MA: MIT

With this commitment of taxpayer
money should come a reexamination of
the objective of the deposit-insurance
system and far-reach ing reforms in its
design so that a crisis of the current
magnitude is not repeated.
Any changes to the deposit-insurance
mechanism should be made with a
clear understanding of the associated
costs and benefits. Society needs to be
more aware of the size and value of
govemment guarantees, like deposit
insurance, and the public should make
strenuous efforts to ensure that the
costs of providing these guarantees do
not exceed the benefits.

Footnotes

surance," Journal of Financial Services Re-

Press, 1985, chapter 3.

search, vol. 2 (1989-forthcoming).

7. The failure-resolution

JUL

policies of the

2. The $124 billion includes $50 billion for

FDIC and FSLIC are the process through

prior case resolutions and $74 billion for

which implicit guarantees are issued to un-

restructuring insolvent thrifts. The $ I24 bil-

insured depositors, general creditors, subor-

lion estimate does not include financing costs

dinated creditors, and even stockholders. For

of $8 I billion ($150 billion) if the spending

a discussion of FDIC failure-resolution

is financed over 10 (30) years at current

policies, see Daria Caliguire and James

market interest rates. See Barbara Pauley,
'The Thrift Reform Program: Summary and

Thomson, "FDIC Policies for Dealing with

Implications," New York: Salomon Brothers,

Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of

April 1989.

Cleveland, October I, 1987.

3. See Edward Kane, The Gathering Crisis

8. See Arthur Okun, Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff, Washington, D.C.: The

in Federal Deposit Insurance, Cambridge,

eCONOMIC
t.tBeO~MeNTaRY

6. For a discussion of this point, see Ed-

\

MA: MIT Press, 1985, chapters 5 and 6; and

Brookings Institution, 1975.
9. One feature of the original Bush administration proposal is uniform capital re-

Urban Institute, 1989.

quirements for banks and thrifts by June

4. Some economists question whether

1991. The Bush administration has indicated

federal deposit insurance is needed at all.

to the Congress that it will veto any legisla-

After all, the liabilities of other financial

tion for resolving the thrift-industry crisis

intermediaries are neither explicitly nor

that waters down this provision.

by James B. Thomson

T

he dramatic rise in interest rates
during the late 1970s and early 1980s
wreaked havoc on the balance sheets of
savings and loan (thrift) institutions. As
their cost of funds rose above what they
could earn on their asset portfolios,

implicitly guaranteed by the federal govern-

Policymakers should consider depositinsurance reforms in the context of the
overall evolution of the financial services industry and also in the context of
other regulatory reforms. The result
should be a deposit-insurance system
with modest, well-specified objectives
that are easy to understand and administer. With this in mind, federal deposit
insurance should be structured in a
fashion that accomplishes its goals with
minimal disruption of market forces.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,

Address

0"

ment. Many of these institutions compete
head-on with banks and thrifts for funds and
provide many of the same services as insured

James B. Thomson is an assistant vice presi-

depository institutions.

dent and economist at the Federal Reserve

S. This role for deposit insurance is the
motivation for the safe-bank proposals of
Litan and others. See Robert Litan, What
Should Banks Do? Washington, D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1987.

thrift institutions began to lose billions
of dollars. By the end of 1982, 237
thrifts (with $67.8 billion in assets) in-

Bank of Cleveland. The author would like to

sured by the Federal Savings and Loan
Insurance Corporation (FSLlC) were insolvent by generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP). I

thank William Osterberg, Mark Sniderman,
and EJ. Stevens for helpful comments and
suggestions.
The views stated herein are those of the

is estimated at more than $124 billion? Furthermore, approximately 500
additional thrifts are above normal risks
for failure. The expected future cost associated with these failures is not included in the FSLlC loss estimates.
In contrast, the fund of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
remains solvent, despite having eroded
in this decade under the pressure of
record bank failures and an increase in
failure-resolution costs. In 1988, the
FDIC experienced its first loss in the

author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid

The initial response of Congress and
the Federal Home Loan Bank Board to

post-Depression era, as the book value
of its fund balance shrank from $18.3

the thrift crisis was a policy of capital
forbearance. Capital requirements were

billion to $14.1 billion. Academic
economists and private banking

relaxed for the industry as a whole, and
insolvent and capital-deficient thrifts
were allowed to operate because if in-

analysts estimate the real value of the
fund as being significantly less. In fact,

terest rates declined, the institutions
stood a chance of recovering.

Cleveland.Dfl
Permit No. 385

This policy of capital forbearance entailed a high degree of risk. By buying

44101

Correction

,

Economic Principles and
Deposit- Insurance Reform

Failed and Troubled Institutions," Economic

Edward Kane, The S&L Insurance Mess:
How Did It Happen? Washington, D.C.: The

i I 3 2 ~e~~\al\las~;ve Bank of Cleveland

Requested:

Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.

the private group known as the Shadow
Financial Regulatory Committee estimates that the true reserve balance of
the FDIC fund, net of estimated unbooked losses, is only $400 million.

time to deal with the insolvency prob-

On February 6, 1989, the Bush ad-

lem, the ultimate cost of resolving the
problem could have become smaller.
Unfortunately, the outcome was disappointing, as both the number of insol-

ministration announced a plan for
resolving the thrift crisis that includes
provisions to recapitalize the insolvent
FSLlC and to close nearly 500 savings

vent institutions and the cost of resolving these insolvencies rose through the
end of 1987 (see table 1).

and loan institutions that are currently
insolvent or in danger of failing. The
Bush plan also contains provisions for
strengthening the FDIC's fund.

By late 1988, nearly 500 thrifts were
either GAAP-insolvent
Material may be reprinted provided that

or in danger of

failing. The cost of closing, reorganizing, or recapitalizing these institutions

the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.
ISSN 0428-1276

Conspicuously absent from this
proposal are fundamental reforms to

The current

system of federal deposit

insurance subsidizes risk-taking by
depository institutions, resulting in
increased failure-resolution
costs and
decreased efficiency for the entire
financial system.

Reforms to the

deposit-insurance
system should consider both the policy objectives and
the attendant economic consequences
and costs of deposit guarantees.