View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 15, 2001*

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

On the Cost of Inflation
by Paul Gomme

S

o far this year, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has lowered the
targeted federal funds rate by 275 basis
points. Twice, it has reduced the target by
50 basis points following unscheduled
meetings. Some commentators have
questioned why it took the Committee so
long to take these decisive steps. After all,
real output growth clearly slowed in the
second half of 2000, and inflation measures had apparently ceased the upward
trajectory that characterized 1998 and
1999. As late as November of last year,
the FOMC had maintained the perspective that the balance of risks in the U.S.
economy were weighted in the direction
of heightened inflationary pressures, and
its public assessment of risks did not shift
toward economic weakness until the
December meeting.
There are several potential explanations
for the FOMC’s behavior. One is that
business cycles are characterized by
sharp ups and downs in economic activity. Consequently, a fair amount of evidence must accumulate before one can
be fairly certain that the economy is
entering a period of sustained real-side
weakness. (Remember that the so-called
softening in the second half of 2000
came on the heels of a remarkably robust
first half.)
The Committee must also strike a balance
between its—at times—mutually inconsistent goals. While the FOMC is charged
with ensuring sustainable economic
growth, it is also responsible for maintaining a low-inflation environment.
While overall CPI inflation leveled off
in 2000–2001, “core” measures of inflation—those that attempt to identify the

ISSN 0428-1276
*Printed August 2001

underlying trend in price growth—have
been rising, suggesting that inflationary
pressures may be building once again.
There are, perhaps, important reasons
why central bankers only reluctantly
shift their focus from inflation to economic growth. It is a widely held belief
that, in the long run, the primary channel
through which monetary authorities can
promote economic growth is by maintaining the purchasing power of the
nation’s currency. Granted, monetary
policy can have positive short-run
effects on real economic activity, but
such gains would represent a pyrrhic
victory if they were purchased at the
price of accelerating inflation.
The economy has likely entered a phase
during which attention will, with some
justification, shift to concerns over the
immediate course of real economic activity. It is also an opportune time to remind
ourselves of the costs of inflation—the
avoidance of which remains the ultimate
long-run goal of monetary policy.

■

Measuring the Costs of
Inflation

In any product market, the socially efficient quantity of output is determined by
the quantity at which the marginal costs
of production equal the marginal social
benefit of an additional unit of output. In
general, we can think of the latter as the
price of the product in question. In the
case of money, the relevant “price” is a
nominal interest rate since it tells us the
return that must be foregone to hold dollars instead of some other asset that
yields the market interest rate.

The FOMC has two objectives: maximizing sustainable economic growth,
and maintaining price stability. At
times—like the past year—these
goals appear to be in conflict. This
Economic Commentary outlines some
economic theory that suggests that in
the long run the FOMC can achieve
its two objectives by focusing primarily on its price stability target.
What is the marginal cost of producing
money? In the United States, the Federal
Reserve is the sole supplier of central
bank money (currency and bank
reserves—the accounts that commercial
banks hold with the Fed). The marginal
cost of producing central bank money is,
effectively, zero. Applying the principle
that the most desirable level of production
requires setting the price equal to marginal cost, the socially efficient quantity
of money would be that amount at which
the nominal interest rate (the “price” of
money) equals zero. An implication of
this analysis is that an optimal monetary
policy would result in nominal interest
rates equal to zero—a proposition widely
known as the Friedman rule.1
If optimal monetary policy implies a
zero nominal interest rate, what should
the inflation rate be? A relationship
known as the Fisher equation tells us
that the nominal interest rate is (approximately) equal to the inflation rate plus
the real rate of interest. Consequently,
the optimal inflation rate is the negative
of the real interest rate. For example, if
the real interest rate is 3 percent, then the

optimal rate of inflation is –3 percent.
By similar reasoning, the value of the
nominal interest rate tells us how much
the inflation rate exceeds its socially
optimal level.
Clearly, the zero nominal interest rate
implied by the Friedman rule typically is
not observed in practice. How large are
the implied costs of deviations from the
socially optimal rate of inflation? In
extreme cases, these costs can be substantial. Using evidence for seven European hyperinflations between 1920 and
1946, Martin Bailey found that the
largest welfare cost was on the order of
half of income, while a “typical” cost
was around a third of income.2
What “real-world” phenomena do these
welfare cost calculations capture? Bailey
describes them as the costs associated
with changes in habits and payment procedures. For example, during hyperinflations, it is common to see people eschew
the use of currency in favor of less efficient barter transactions. (Barter is less
efficient than using money because
barter requires a double coincidence of
wants, while money only requires a single coincidence since everyone will
accept money.) As inflation becomes
more severe, workers demand to be paid
more frequently. Having received their
wage payments, households rush to purchase consumers goods or assets like
foreign currencies. All of these activities
are costly and disruptive to an economy.
What about more modest inflation experiences? Stanley Fischer, using money
demand estimates for the United States,
calculated that lowering the inflation rate
from 10 percent to 0 percent would generate a welfare gain of between 0.3 and
0.8 percent of output.3 While this figure
may seem fairly modest, when applied
to U.S. GDP for 1999, it implies a deadweight loss of between $28 billion and
$74 billion. The magnitude of this welfare cost is comparable to that associated
with other distortionary taxes. Furthermore, this welfare gain can be achieved
each and every year—it is not a once-off
gain.

■

A More Sophisticated
Approach

In obtaining their estimates of the costs
of inflation, Bailey and Fischer use the
simple supply and demand analysis
familiar to any student of elementary
economics. More recent estimates of
these costs have been obtained using

more sophisticated models that are an
outgrowth of real business cycle theory,
which arose in the 1980s. The key feature of the real business cycle program is
the adoption of a methodology in which
economic phenomena are modeled by
explicitly specifying the features of the
basic microeconomic structure, such as
preferences and technologies.
To explore the costs of inflation within a
real business cycle model, we first need
to specify why economic agents hold
money. One way to do this is to adopt
the cash-in-advance constraint, which
states that individuals must have cash
balances in their pocket at the start of the
period in order to purchase goods. That
is to say, these goods cannot be purchased on credit. Somewhat more flexible formulations allow money balances
to help conserve on either shopping time
or the pecuniary costs of making transactions. For the present purposes, these
details are of secondary importance. It is
sufficient that there is a well-defined
“demand” for cash balances.
A feature that this class of models shares
with some simpler frameworks is that
increases in inflation can arise only
through increases in the growth rate of
money. When the rate of inflation rises,
its proximate effect in these models is to
distort the household’s choice of how
much to work. Owing to the cash-inadvance constraint, $1 earned today cannot be spent until tomorrow, when the
price of goods will have risen. Consequently, the $1 earned today will garner
fewer goods than it could purchase
today. From the household’s perspective,
an increase in inflation acts in much the
same way as an increase in the tax on its
labor earnings; both serve to reduce the
real wage received by the household. In
the face of a fall in its real wage, we
expect that the household will reduce the
quantity of labor it is willing to supply.
As a result of less labor, real production
in the economy will fall.
A secondary channel through which
inflation affects real activity operates via
capital accumulation. Since households
supply less labor, a given unit of capital
is less productive in the sense that it produces less output (given the quantity of
labor now being supplied). Since the
return on capital has fallen, firms will
curtail their investment activity in order
to bring the return on capital in line with
the long-run real interest rate, which is
determined by the household’s rate of
time preference. (The “rate of time pref-

erence” is related to the real interest rate
and refers to the idea that people prefer a
unit of consumption received today over
a unit received in the future.) To summarize, the long-run response to higher
inflation is lower employment, capital,
and output.
Suppose that in the model just described,
the rate of inflation increases from 0 percent to 10 percent. To evaluate the costs
of inflation, we ask the following hypothetical question: How much consumption would the representative household
be willing to forego in order to avoid living in the 10 percent inflation world?
The answer gives us the welfare cost of
10 percent inflation relative to 0 percent
inflation; this figure is typically
expressed as a percentage of output.
Thomas Cooley and Gary Hansen were
among the first to try to quantitatively
assess the costs of inflation in an environment like the one outlined above.4
Relative to an optimal inflation rate
(–4 percent per annum in their model),
they found that an inflation rate of
10 percent resulted in a welfare cost of
0.4 percent of income. This figure is
fairly typical of the estimates other
researchers have subsequently obtained.
A slightly different way of casting the
Cooley and Hansen result is to say that a
reduction in the inflation rate from
10 percent to –4 percent would result in a
0.4 percent welfare gain. As with the simple supply and demand case, remember
that this is a gain which can be enjoyed
each and every year into the future.

■

The Costs of Fighting
Inflation

The analysis thus far suggests that there
is a “free lunch” to be had by reducing
the rate of inflation. Yet the U.S. experience in the early 1980s shows that
reductions in inflation are often bought
at considerable short-term costs in terms
of lower output and higher unemployment. These costs are absent from the
calculation in the previous section
because they are derived by assuming
that the relevant comparison is between
two distinct economies that differ only
with regard to their rates of inflation and
the economic effects that these differences imply.
Policymakers often use the “sacrifice
ratio” to try to get a handle on these shortterm costs. In brief, the sacrifice ratio gives
the cumulative loss in output (over some
time horizon) associated with a 1 percentage point reduction in the inflation rate.

FIGURE 2 ONGOING GAINS AFTER
DISINFLATION: ECONOMIC
APPROACH

FIGURE 1 OUTPUT LOSS AFTER
DISINFLATION: SACRIFICE
RATIO APPROACH
Percent deviation
0.6

Percent deviation
0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

0

0

–0.2

–0.2

–0.4

–0.4

–0.6

–0.6

–0.8

–0.8
–1.0

–1.0
–2

0

2

8
6
4
Time since disinflation

10

A typical exercise is the following: Estimate
a simple relationship between real growth
and inflation.5 Next, generate an artificial
time series while imposing a reduction in the
inflation rate. Finally, add up the shortfall in
output (the deviation of output from the path
that it would have taken) and divide by the
resulting fall in inflation (in order to express
the lost output relative to a 1 percentage point
fall in inflation). A stylized example of such
an exercise is presented in figure 1.
There are at least two problems with the
sacrifice ratio approach. First, the statistical
techniques used typically provide no room
for subsequent benefits of lower inflation.
More specifically, in the long run, this statistical exercise produces an output growth rate
equal to that in the data sample used to
estimate that relationship.
Roughly speaking, common practice would
involve adding up the shaded area in figure 1.
If inflation is costly, we would expect to
observe either an increase in the level of output, an increase in its growth rate, or both.
Thus, following a disinflation, we might
expect output to follow a path like that given
in figure 2, in which the short-term losses in
output are offset by medium- and long-term
gains. Of course, one could argue that ignoring
the growth effects of lower inflation is appropriate since the long-run benefits of a disinflation are so far off in the future that they can
safely be ignored. One would hope that
policymakers are not so short sighted.

12

–2

14

0

2

8
6
4
Time since disinflation

Second, and more importantly, the sacrifice ratio gives the loss in output, not the
loss in utility (or its output equivalent).
This is an important distinction since the
well-being of the typical American
depends only in part on his or her material consumption. A different way to see
this point is to realize that while we could
all have more goodies to enjoy if everyone would work 60-hour weeks, we are
unlikely to be happier since we would
have much less leisure time in which we
could enjoy these goodies.
That is not to suggest, however, that the
transition costs from higher to lower
long-run inflation rates are, or should be,
of no concern. An important agenda for
economists working within the methodology of general equilibrium macroeconomic models is to design models in
which the long-run rate of inflation periodically changes. Doing so would allow
a more complete assessment of the welfare benefits of a disinflation, incorporating the short-run losses in utility along
with the long-term gains.6

■

Summary

There can be little doubt that the disinflation of the early 1980s was costly. The
United States suffered the worst recession
since the Great Depression, and the
unemployment rate reached its highest
level in post–World War II history.
However, those short-term costs have
hopefully been paid for by the subsequent
strong economic performance of

10

12

14

the U.S. economy, including the
longest expansion in U.S. history.
This is not to suggest that all of the
positive economic performance
since the early 1980s can be attributed to judicious monetary policy.
However, it is probably fair to say
that good monetary policy was a
necessary precondition for this
unprecedented performance.
In the 1979–80 period, the annual
rate of inflation averaged over
121/2 percent; by 1982, it was under
4 percent. The quantitative literature
on the costs of inflation suggests
that sustained differences of this
magnitude have substantial welfare
consequences for the economy.
Maintaining the gains from lower
inflation is not, however, automatic.
It is useful to recall that prior to the
last recession, inflation was accelerating rapidly, rising from just over
1 percent in mid-1986 to over
6 percent by mid-1990. Had this
trend continued, the gains of the
1990s would have very much been
at risk. As the short-run risks to the
U.S. economy shift, for now, in the
direction of economic weakness, it
is important to remember why the
central bank’s focus can never stray
too far from its primary role in
delivering the gains made possible
by maintaining the purchasing
power of the nation’s currency.

■

Footnotes

1. See Milton Friedman, “The Optimum Quantity of Money,” in The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other
Essays, Chicago: Aldine, 1969,
pp.1–50.
2. Martin J. Bailey, “The Welfare Costs
of Inflationary Finance,” Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 64, no. 2 (April
1956), pp. 93–110.
3. Stanley Fischer, “Towards an Understanding of the Costs of Inflation: II,”
Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, vol. 15 (Autumn
1981), pp. 5–142.
4. Thomas F. Cooley and Gary D.
Hansen, “The Inflation Tax in a Real
Business Cycle Model,” American Economic Review, vol. 79, no. 4 (1989),
pp. 733–48.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

5. This simple relationship is often estimated using a vector autoregression
(VAR). The VAR gives a reduced-form
or unstructured estimate of the relationship between inflation and growth.
6. One attempt to incorporate such
monetary policy regime-switching is
found in David Andolfatto and Paul
Gomme, “Monetary Policy Regimes
and Beliefs,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Working Paper no. 99–05.

Paul Gomme is an economic advisor in
the Research Department at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
The views expressed here are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, or its staff.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your
request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or
fax it to 216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is also available at the Cleveland Fed’s
site on the World Wide Web:
www.clev.frb.org/research, where glossaries
of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385