View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 15, 1996

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

CoIDpeting Currencies:
Back to the Future?
by Ben Craig

S ometimes, an emerging or rapidly
changing currency experiences a period
in which it competes with a second currency as a medium of exchange. The
competing currencies are not like quarters and dollar bills, where the relative
price is fixed, or like checks and dollar
bills, where the unit of account is always
the same. During an episode of dual currencies, prices are often denominated in
each currency, and the relative price of
an item fluctuates as the advantages
offered by a particular currency change.
In Colonial America, wampum and silver competed for more than 100 years,
until wampum "inflation" required a
prohibitive number of beads to purchase
even small household items. During the
American Civil War, greenbacks and
gold certificates were both used for
many years without either currency
becoming dominant. In modem-day
Russia, U.S. dollars - not rubles- are
used in many domestic transactions.
The outcomes of these three episodes
are of more than historical interest. Although U.S. dollars in cash and checking
accounts are still the primary means of
conducting financial transactions in the
United States, credit cards, "smart
cards," and new electronic forms of
money are expected to become increasingly competitive.

These episodes also offer a unique
opportunity to study what is important
about money in its use as a medium of
exchange. Specifically, they allow us to
focus on 1) the qualities ofa commodity
that enable it to become a dominant currency, 2) the route by which a nationally
man.dated paper currency becomes
acceptable as a medium of exchange,
and 3) the way in which competition
between currencies sustains the
exchange value of a fiat currency by
restricting the actions available to the
monetary authority. But first, it is necessary to look at what makes money valuable in exchange.

•

WhyMoney?

In a barter economy (without money),
potential buyers of a particular good
must search for potential sellers of a
good they want. These potential sellers
· must, in tum, want the good offered by
the buyer. Searching for this double
coincidence of wants takes time, and
time is costly. 1 The purpose of a noncommodity money in such an economy
is to allow a trade to occur in those more
common instances where only one of the
traders has a good the other trader
desires. lfl, the seller of a good, believe
that money will be acceptable to someone else who has a good that I desire,
then I will be willing to accept money in
trade for my good. Future acceptability
is the key to whether I am willing to
accept money in a current transaction.

-

Most financial transactions in the
United States are still conducted
using U.S. dollars in cash and checking accounts, but new technology has
spawned an array of competitors,
including credit cards, "smart cards,"
and e-cash. Although little theoretical evidence exists on the potential
effects of this growing competition,
........
historical evidence on currencies that
have traded side by side-including
wampum and silver, greenbacks and
gold certificates, and rubles and dollars-could help guide monetary policy if electronic forms of money continue to gain ground.

Current acceptability of a currency
depends on two conditions. First, there
must be enough of it in the locality to
sustain local transactions. Otherwise, the
would-be buyer/seller would have to
find a money trader, impairing the role
of money in reducing search time. Second, the currency's future purchasing
power (and acceptability) must not
degrade too quickly. The American
Colonial period offers a good example.
During these years, many commodity
currencies competed for the role of
money, but because none of them satisfied both conditions, no one currency
quickly won out.

• Wampum and Silver
The Colonial period produced a wide
variety of currencies that fluctuated
freely in their relative prices and that
were used extensively in domestic transactions. The international currencies of
trade-silver and gold coin-were in
short supply in the colonies. As a result,
most exchanges occurred through barter,
but substitutes for silver rapidly emerged.
Perhaps the most important of these
substitutes in the earliest Colonial years,
especially in New England, was wampum, the chief currency of the Northeast
Woodland tribes. The standard unit of
wampum was a string of shell beads
made from a clam that flourished in
eastern Long Island and Narragansett
Bay. Massachusetts declared wampum
legal tender~ 1643. In New York,
wampum remained legal tender until
1701 , and on the frontier, it was used
until the early 1800s. The monetary
conditions of the time are illustrated in·
the following journal entry of a Boston
schoolmistress, Madam Knight, who
wrote from New Haven in 1704 (in the
spelling of the original):
The traders ... Rate their Goods
according to the time and spetia they pay
in: viz Pay, many, pay as many, and trusting. Pay is Grain, Pork, Beef, etc. at the
prices sett by the General Court that year;
many is pieces ofEight, Ryalls, or Boston
or Bay shillings .... also Wampom, viz.
Indian beads which serves for change.. ..

Now, when the buyer comes to ask for
a comodil)1, sometimes before the merchant answers that he has it, he sais, is
Your pay redy? Perhaps the Chap Reply

s

Yes: what do You pay in ? says the merchant. The buyer having answered, then
the price is set; as suppose he wants a sixpenny knife, in pay it is J2d- in pay as
money eight pence, and hard money its

does not perceive the money's intrinsic
value, he rationally assumes that it must
be of the worst quality. The other trader
thus has an incentive to make sure that
the commodity is of the worst quality,
since no benefit would derive from
offering a better-quality good. Hence,
bad commodity money drives out the
good commodity.

own price, viz. 6d. It seems a ve1y Intricate way of trade and what Lex Mercatoria [the English merchant lawJ had not
thoughto/ 2

Wampum production was limited during
early Colonial times by the amount of
labor required to make a shell bead
under native techniques. With the introduction of European tools and manufacturing processes, production expanded
drastically. The resulting wampum inflation - more than 50 strings of beads
were required to purchase a single
beaver fur by the late seventeenth
century-reduced the commodity's
value as a medium of exchange. As a
result, its use in the colonies died out. 3
A decline in the purchasing power of
commodity monies also caused the
demise of the commodity currencies
used in other colonies. For example,
tobacco, which was used as a medium of
exchange in Virginia, fell rapidly in
quality until it could no longer serve that
purpose. As a medium of exchange, only
the quantity of tobacco mattered, and
thus Gresham's law - that bad money
drives out good- caused more lowquality than high-quality tobacco to be
produced. The resulting inflation
reduced tobacco's use not only as a
medium of exchange, but also as a commodity in a colony where it was the primary good produced.
"Fiat money" refers to that commodity
(or token) declared by the government as
acceptable in the settlement of claims
and the payment of taxes. One reason for
the popularity of fiat money is that its
value becomes transparent to everyone. 4
With commodity money, some people
can recognize its intrinsic value (as
opposed to its exchange value) better
than others. When a participant in a trade

The outcome of the competition between
wampum and silver was not a foregone
conclusion. Wampum was a more familiar currency on the frontier. Further, silver was not permitted to be coined in the
colonies and could not be exported from
England because of mercantile legislation. Foreign coins, scarce and unfamiliar on the frontier, were used, but traders
found them difficult to evaluate.

In the case of wampum, new production
technologies reduced its future acceptability as a medium of exchange. By
contrast, technical limitations on the
production of silver prevented an oversupply, which helped ensure its future
acceptability. Moreover, coinage of silver added transparency of value. By
1800, enough familiar coins were available in the colonies to effectively drive
out all of the other commodities used in
domestic exchange.

•

Greenbacks and Gold

A second episode in our history when
two currencies were traded side by side
at changing prices was the Greenback
Era of 1862- 1879. Gold certificates,
backed by the government's promise to
pay in gold, competed with legal tender
notes, which were backed only by an
unspecified understanding that they
might be fully convertible to gold at
some future date. 5
The first use of legal tender notes (greenbacks) in the United States, in April
1862, resulted from the enormous cost of
the Civil War and from the federal government's inability to convert its currency to gold. Greenbacks were a debt of
the U.S. government, redeemable in gold
at a future unspecified date. The greenback experiment was an important innovation in money, as greenbacks were the
first notes backed only by themselves.

FIGURE 1 PRICE AND VOLATILITY OF GREENBACKS
(in gold)
D
ollars
115

Dollars
40

105

35

95

30

85

25

75

20

65

15

55

10

not to continue reaping seigniorage revenues by inflating the currency and reducing its value. The convertibility factor continued to be a useful source of
credibility not only for the United
States, but for many other countries as
well. It was not dropped by our government until 1932. 7

45
1864

1866

1868

1870

1872

1874

1876

1878

In the case of the Greenback Era, competition between the currencies was
maintained for two reasons: there were
more greenbacks than gold certificates
in circulation (because the gove=ent
lacked sufficient gold reserves), and
people were willing to accept greenbacks because of the promise that they
would be fully convertible to gold.

a. Defined as the di fference between the high and low price over each year.
SOURCE: Wesley C. Mitchell, Gold, Prices, and Wages under the Greenback Standard, Berkeley: University
of California Press, 1908.

They became the major medium of exchange during these years, partly because
they were more common than gold.
The drawback of fiat paper money lies in
the incentive provided by seigniorage,
the revenue gained from its production
(because the money's nominal value
exceeds the cost of production). Since
producers of money- whether counterfeiters or gove=ents- collect
seigniorage revenue, the temptation
exists to inflate the currency and reduce
its exchange value.
Inflation during the Greenback Era was
controlled, in part, by congressional
limits on the number of greenbacks in
circulation and by the understanding
that the currency would be made fully
convertible to gold when the government could make the exchange. The
price of the greenback in gold, the international currency of trade, was established in several large currency markets
and was traded freely, usually without
much gove=ent intervention.

Figure 1 shows the price of a greenback
dollar (denominated in dollars backed by
gold) on the dominant New York gold
market. Although greenbacks initially
sold for gold at a discount, reaching an
average monthly low of 50 cents in April
1864, they appreciated strongly over the
next few years and accounted for more
than 75 percent of the total U.S. currency
stock by 1867. Much of the remaining
currency consisted of gold certificates.
Both greenbacks and gold certificates
were widely used in domestic exchange.
Thus, prices were quoted in the two currencies until Congress legislated a
phased convertibility, which was completed in 1879.
As the date of full convertibility became
more certain, the price of the greenback
behaved like an option price on convertibility.6 As is evident in figure 1, the
volatility of the price diminished as market expectations concerning full convertibility in 1879 were fulfilled.
Convertibility to gold was the mechanism by which the U.S. gove=ent
maintained the credibility of its promise

The lesson here is that competition from
the gold certificates forced the government to adopt policies that maintained
the value of the greenback. Neither gold
certificates nor greenbacks drove the
other currency out of circulation. Because the gove=ent maintained the
credibility of the greenback by making it
fully convertible to gold, the two currencies in effect became a single currency.

• Rubles and U.S. Dollars
in Modern-day Russia
Without the credibility of convertibility
to specie, a country may have an incentive to inflate its currency in order to
provide seigniorage revenues, especially
if it legislates monopoly privileges for
its fiat currency. Indeed, the history of
nonconvertible fiat currencies is often a
history of inflation. With greater freedom of international trade, however, a
competing foreign currency may provide the discipline that keeps the domestic fiat currency sound. This is well
illustrated in the case of modem-day
Russia, where a rapidly inflating local
currency lost some of its medium of
exchange privileges in the modem era
of flexible exchange rates.
When the Russian Republic was formed
in 1991 , the Russian central bank did not
adopt the discipline that would have

FIGURE 2 SHARE OF FOREIGN CURRENCY IN THE TOTAL
RUSSIAN MONEY STOCK3

1992

1993

1994

The lesson here is an important one.
Two currencies were able to compete in
Russia because each offered certain
advantages. The ruble was needed for
official transactions, including payment
of taxes. The dollar, however, provided
an exchange medium that was sure to
maintain its future acceptability. The
ruble became dominant in domestic
exchanges only when the monetary
authority initiated a policy of lower
inflation. The competing foreign currency provided an outside discipline to
make the monetary authority more
responsive to the users of its domestic
currency.

1995

•
a. Defined as foreign currency deposits as a share of domestic broad money plus foreign currency deposits.
SOURCE: International Monetary Fund.

been provided by pegging the ruble to a
fixed rate of exchange. Users of the currency did not have the well-defmed
avenue of opposition that might have
been provided by a more mature
democracy. Further, the central government's authority to collect taxes was
degraded by widespread noncompliance
and a lack of enforcement. Russian tax
revenues fell more than 15 percent in
real terms from 1992 to 1993. How did
the Russian central bank respond to this
fiscal debacle? By printing more money.
The inflation that followed in the domestic ruble was extreme. Prices rose 9,400
percent in 1993 alone. However, in order
to increase foreign-trade opportunities,
the Russians had legislated convertibility
of the ruble in 1986. 8 The result was
that by 1993, many domestic exchanges
were being accomplished not in Russian
rubles but in American dollars.
Figure 2 shows the relative size of Russia's foreign currency deposits compared to its total domestic money stock
over the 1992-1995 period. Clearly,
foreign currency (primarily the U.S.
dollar) has played a large but changing
role in the nation's economy.

Whether the dollar or the ruble is used
in Russian domestic trades depends on
the currency's acceptability in future
trades. People may trade either with a
highly inflating currency, the ruble, or
with a black-market currency, the dollar.
Trading in dollars is illegal, and a dollar
trader faces a penalty if caught.
In order to eliminate the dollar/ruble
dual-currency system, the Russian central bank needs to inflate the ruble less,
which will lower the acceptability of
the dollar and drive it out of circulation.9 This message seems to have
been received by the Russian monetary
authorities. The inflation rate of the
ruble has been trending down since
1994, and the use of the dollar in domestic transactions has decreased.
Against the competition provided by a
stable foreign currency, the costs of
inflation were considered too high relative to the benefits provided by the
increase in seigniorage revenues.

Whither Money?

Currently, the Federal Reserve is concerned about new exchange media that
might provide competition to the Federal Reserve note. Changing technology
continues to generate potential competitors. Most Americans would not leave
on an extended trip without a credit
card. Smart cards, plastic cards with
electronic hardware added to upgrade
their security, are being used in France
as a cash substitute, and many believe
they will soon be used extensively here.
The Internet will also offer new ways of
handling exchanges. 10
We do not have a wide body of theoretical literature with which to analyze the
effect of the potential competition
offered by these new instruments. However, the three historical episodes
described above may offer a lesson.
Competing currencies force the monetary authority to concentrate its attention
on maintaining the value of the fiat currency. To the extent that policymakers
fail to do this, a competing currency
may provide a necessary discipline.

I

I

I

• Footnotes
1. For a formalized look at the exchange role
of money, see Shouyong Shi, "Money and
Prices: A Model of Search and Bargaining,"
Journal ofEconomic Theory, vol. 67, no . 2
(December 1995), pp. 467 - 96. See also
Alberto Trejos and Randall Wright, "Search,
Bargaining, Money, and Prices," Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 103, no. I (February
1995), pp. 118 - 41.

2. See Albert Bushnell Hart, ed., American
Hist01y Told by Contemporaries, vol. 2, p.
288, quoted in Arthur Nussbaum, A Hist01y
of the Dollar, New York: Columbia University Press, 1957, p. 13.

3. A second reason wampum was discouraged is that it was produced and used by
native tribes rather than by the Colonial
authorities. When Massachusetts required
taxes to be paid in silver in 1661 , this was
probably due more to a native policy (or lack
thereof) than to the difficulty of using wampum in exchange.

4. For a complete discussion of the advantages of fiat money over commodity money,
see Armen Alchian, " Why Money?" Journal
ofMon ey, Credit and Banking, vol. 9, no. 1,
part 2 (February 1977), pp . 133 - 40.

5. Although silver was also used during this
period, for simplicity, I will refer to metallic
currency as gold.
6. ln this case, accepting a greenback in
exchange was like accepting the option to
convert it to gold after convertibility was
established. See Charles Calomiris, " Greenback Resumption and Silver Risk: The Economics and Politics of Monetary Regime
Change in the United States, 1862-1900,"
in Michael Bardo and Forrest Capie, eds.,
Monetary Regimes in Transition, New
.York: Cambridge University Press, 1994,
pp. 86- 132.

7. For international transactions, convertibility was maintained until 1971.

-

Ben Craig is an economist at the Federal

8. Prior to 1986, Soviets had two currencies:
a trade ruble, which was backed by a commodity, and a domestic ruble, which was not
convertible to the trade rub le. Over the years,
there were several episodes in which the
communists backed the domestic ruble with
gold to give it credibility. Starting in 1986,
the domestic ruble was pennitted to be used
in international transactions, and it had an
exchange rate in terms of foreign currencies.

9. For a new theory on dual currencies, see
Elizabeth Soller and Christopher J. Waller,
"Dual Currencies in a Search Model of
Money," Indiana University, unpublished
manuscript, July 1996.

10. Most discussions of how these alternative media will operate asswne that the dollar
will be the unit of account. This is not an
inevitable conclusion, however.

Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author
would like to thank David Altig and Michael

Bryan for helpful comments and suggestions.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Economic Commentary is now available

electronically through the Cleveland Fed's
home page on the World Wide Web:
http://wwwclev.frb.org.

The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and
the Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking announce:
Comparative Financial
Systems: Theory
and Evidence
November 6-7, 1997
Cleveland, Ohio

increasingly connected yet diverse

Call for Papers

experiences have created a need for crit-

The conference proceedings will be

ical reflection on all aspects of financial

published in the Journal ofMoney,

markets and institutions. What will be

Credit and Banking, and authors will

the impact of new payments system

receive an honorarium. Prospective

technologies? How have intermediaries

contributors are invited to send a

The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

and the financial sector helped, or hin-

completed paper or detailed abstract

and the Journal ofMoney, Credit and

dered, economic growth? How will

by March 30, 1997, to:

Banking are jointly sponsoring a confer-

emerging markets affect those that are

ence on Comparative Financial Systems:

more established? Will universal bank-

Theory and Evidence.

ing prove a viable model for global
banks? Responsible policies need a

The global financial system has been

solid base of understanding and a realis-

changing at a revolutionary pace. The

tic appraisal of how policies- past and
present-have fared.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

Joseph G. Haubrich
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, Ohio 44101-1387
e-mail: jhaubrich@clev.frb.org.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385