View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 1996

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Coinbining Bank Supervision
and Monetary Policy·
by Joseph G. Haubrich

Pardon him Theodotus: he is a barbarian, and thinks that the customs of his
tribe and island are the laws of nature.
- George Bernard Shaw,
Caesar and Cleopatra, Act II
Many American organizations, from
corporations to government agencies,
have reengineered themselves, rethinking their businesses from the ground up.
On a larger scale, the former Soviet Bloc
countries are in the process of transforming their entire economies-and governments- as they join the free world.
Developing countries reengineer as they
modernize.
Bank regulation and monetary policy
form a key part of this basic restructuring, and countries, like corporations,
have several models from which to
choose. The central bank of the United
States combines monetary policy and
bank supervision. The Federal Reserve
Act established the Federal Reserve System to "furnish an elastic currency," but
also to "establish a more effective supervision ofbanking." 1 In Germany, the
Bundesbank conducts monetary policy,
but the Federal Banking Supervisory
Office (FBSO) regulates the banks.
Are there good economic reasons for
combining or separating monetary policy and bank supervision? This article
reviews the various arguments and
attempts to put them into perspective. It
also presents some other reasons behind

ISSN 0428- 1276

the diverse choices that countries have
made, because, in the end, economics is
only one element of the picture.

• Geography
No obvious line divides those central
banks that combine, and those that separate, monetary policy and bank supervision. In the United States, the Federal
Reserve combines these two functions,
but the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency (OCC), the FDIC, and individual state banking departments also
supervise banks. In Germany, the Bundesbank collects and processes banking
information, even though the FBSO is
the primary regulator, and private
accounting firms are responsible for
most of the on-site supervision. In Japan,
the Ministry of Finance is the chiefregulator, but it alternates on-site inspections
with the Bank of Japan.
There are even differences between official responsibilities and actual practices.
In Germany, the central bank and the
FBSO consult closely with each other,
often collaborating on regulations. In Japan, banks treat the "suggestions" of the
Bank of Japan as binding regulations. 2
Still, after all the judgment calls, central
banks do tend toward one camp or the
other, as table 1 makes clear. The 24
countries listed cluster around two traditions: Those with an English influence,
including the United States, the United
Kingdom, Australia, and Hong Kong,
generally combine monetary policy and

-

I n the United States, the Federal Reserve has responsibility for both monetary policy and bank supervision.
Other countries separate these functions to varying degrees. What lies
behind this global diversity? Should a
central bank be charged with conducting monetary policy and regulating banks, or does it make more sense
-both economic and political-to
keep these activities separate? The answer is not a simple yes or no. Rather,
it appears that the right choice depends on a country's prevailing conditions, including its financial system,
its political environment, and the
preferences of the public.

supervision. Countries with a more German influence, such as Austria, Germany, Denmark, and Switzerland, prefer
separation. Canada also maintains separate functions, despite its past links to
the United Kingdom and France, both of
which have opted for combination.
In part, these different traditions reflect
different historical circumstances. Early
in the century, the German banking system used few checks (people preferred
cash) and encouraged high levels of capital. Consequently, bank runs were rare,
and the Reichsbank played little role in
bank regulation. When a major banking
crisis did occur in the 1930s, the monetary authorities had insufficient resources to save the banking system,
which forced the government to intervene more directly.
English-style banking systems were
more prone to bank runs. In response,
the clearinghouse emerged, an organization that cleared checks, supervised
banks, and at times issued its own currency. Central banks in these countries
were modeled quite explicitly on clearinghouses and naturally took on the
responsibility of bank rescues, whether
as a lender of last resort or as a coordinator of bank consortia.3

• Combination vs. Separation:
The Economic Debate
A geopolitical description may serve to
classify central banks, but it ignores the
larger issue: Should a central bank
undertake both monetary policy and
bank supervision? 4 Just as different corporations reengineer in different ways,
the "right" answer often depends on prevailing conditions - the financial system, the political environment, and the
preferences of the public.
Central bank structure influences both
monetary policy and bank supervision.
Since the physical production of the two
activities is largely unrelated (unlike,
say, the production of cars and trucks),
the economics of combination is the economics of information and incentives.

Monetary Policy
The most common criticism of combining monetary policy and bank supervision is that it can create a conflict of
interest. Giving a central bank supervisory powers could make it reluctant to
raise interest rates and stem inflation
whenever such actions would hurt the
banks. The central bank might view its
primary function as protecting banks,
not the public interest. The banking
industry, which is better organized and
more directly affected than the public,
could "capture" the central bank and
gain undue influence.
Regulatory capture has other sources besides overt political pressure. Voters,
politicians, and oversight committees
might view bank failures as evidence of
poor supervision and hence low supervisory skill. If so, making banks look
bad could make bank supervisors look
bad. The central bank, conscious of its
reputation, might then refrain from monetary policy that would stress certain
banks or lower the industry's profits.
Again, monetary policy would suffer.
Countries that are very concerned with
the independence and credibility of their
central banks may opt for separation,
even of an extreme variety. Estonia isolated its monetary policy from bank
supervision by establishing a currency
board, a move that effectively cut off
discretionary monetary policy of all
sorts. 5 In the long run, the more stable
and disciplined policy that arises from
this kind of separation might benefit the
banks as well.
Defenders of combination do more than
deny this conflict of interest: They
reverse it. In their view, separation leads
the central bank to neglect a legitimate
concern-the impact of monetary policy on the health of the banking system.
The central bank might misjudge the
effect of policy on the nation's banks,
and perhaps thereby on the entire economy. This tendency could snowball as
central bankers lose the knowledge and
experience that come with supervisory
responsibilities. Given the grave consequences of financial panic, collapse, or
simple ill-health of the banking system,
it is imperative that monetary policy
consider these effects.

Historically, a concern for banks has not
necessarily generated poor monetary
policy. In the United States, the combined function has not prevented the
Federal Reserve from tightening interest
rates even when banks might be adversely affected. 6 Another good example
is post-communist Poland, where a concern for banks was responsible for significantly improving monet;irrY policy.
As it became apparent in the late 1980s
that monetary rules were driving money
out of Polish banks and into foreign currency, drying up lending, the government undertook a series of successful
monetary reforms. 7
Combination is particularly needed, proponents argu. , in times of financial
e
crises, when only direct supervision can
deliver the essential information on
time. 8 The informal, "inside" information on how managers react and what
strategies they pursue- the "feel" of an
operation-simply cannot be duplicated
by reading reports or consulting with
other agencies. Supervisory powers also
give the central bank additional leverage, which can be useful in forging a
consensus for unified action.9
Supporters of separation disagree. They
argue that documents and consultations
provide sufficient information, and that,
if anything, the close connections that
develop between bankers and their regulators under a combined system can
again lead to a conflict of interest, giving banks priority over taxpayers. The
Anglo-German division regarding appropriate powers may reflect this difference. A German-style central bank,
with little responsibility for rescuing
banks, may have less need for information. Indeed, the Bundesbank and the
FBSO rely on reports from independent
auditors.
Separation has its own claim to producing the most information: Separate agencies with differing agendas will each
search for evidence supporting their own
position, whereas a combined agency
might not. 1 For a simple explanation of
this reasoning, consider only three pol-

°

TABLE 1 MONETARY POLICY AND BANK SUPERVISORY AGENCIES

Country

Monetary Policy Agency

Bank Supervisory Agency

Status

Australia

Reserve Bank of Australia

Reserve Bank of Australia

Combined

Austria

National Bank of Austria

Ministry of Finance

Separated

Belgium

National Bank of Belgium

Banking and Finance Commission

Separated

Canada

Bank of Canada

Office of the Superintendent
ofFinancial Institutions

Separated

Denmark

Danmarks Nationalbank

Finance Inspectorate

Separated

Finland

Bank ofFinland

Bank Inspectorate, Bank ofFinland

Separated

France

Banque de France

Banque de France, Commission Bancaire

Combined

Germany

Deutsche Bundesbank

Federal Banking Supervisory Office

Separated

Greece

Bank of Greece

Bank of Greece

Combined

Hong Kong

Hong Kong Monetary Authority

Hong Kong Monetary Authority

Combined

Ireland

Central Bank of Ireland

Central Bank of Ireland

Combined

Italy

Banca d'Italia

Banca d' Italia

Combined

Japan

Bank of Japan

Ministry of Finance, Bank ofJapan

Separated

Luxembourg

Luxembourg Monetary Institute

Luxembourg Monetary Institute

Combined

Mexico

Banco de Mexico

National Banking and
Securities Commission

Separated

Netherlands

De Nederlandsche Bank

De Nederlandsche Bank

Combined

New Zealand

Reserve Bank ofNew Zealand

Reserve Bank of New Zealand

Combined

Norway

Norges Bank

Banking, Insurance and
Securities Commission

Separated

Portugal

Banco de Portugal

Banco de Portugal

Combined

Spain

Banco de Espana

Banco de Espana

Combined

Sweden

Sveriges Riksbank

Swedish Financial Supervisory Authority

Separated

Switzerland

Swiss National Bank

Federal Banking Commission

Separated

United Kingdom

Bank of England

Bank of England

Combined

United States

Federal Reserve System

Federal Reserve System,
OCC, FDIC, State governments

Combined

SOURCE : Adapted from Charles Goodhart and Dirk Schoenmaker, "Should the Functions of Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Be Separated?"
(footnote 14).

icy options-one favorable to banks
(lower interest rates), one favorable to
savers (higher interest rates), and the status quo (keeping rates the same). A combined, unbiased central bank may find
evidence favoring either higher or lower
rates, or it may find nothing at all. If it
finds evidence supporting both policies,
the information cancels out, and the
monetary authority has expended much
effort to justify no change in policy. If it
finds evidence favoring one policy, it
may stop searching because any new
information could contradict the existing
evidence, rendering useless the time,
effort, and expense.

In a separated system, the supervisory
branch will make the case for lower rates
and the monetary branch will push for
higher rates, with both using formal and
informal channels to set forth their views.
This is the theory behind the adversarial
legal system-that contending sides produce the most information. Proponents of
separation believe that in relatively stable
economies, where policymakers' concern is justifiably less with crises and
more with understanding the market, this
argument can be decisive.

Not all concerns are purely informational, however. In Mexico, an undeveloped financial sector has meant, until
very recently, that effective monetary
control relied on direct bank controls,
such as interest rate ceilings and credit
limitations. 11 In such cases, the monetary authority may need to supervise the
banks until the fii?.ancial system develops
further. The Banco de Mexico has a representative on the National Banking and
Securities Commission, the independent
body that regulates the nation's banks.12

Bank Supervision

•

Monetary policy is just one side of the
coin. Central bank structure also influences bank supervision. Proponents of
combination argue that banks which are
regulated by the central bank can better
withstand shifting monetary policy. 13
The central bank looks for vulnerable (as
opposed to merely weak) commercial
banks, aiming its supervisory practices
more at identifying firms that will do
poorly in stressful times than at firms
that will do poorly in normal times.

Another area of dispute-central bank
reputation-is necessarily more vague
and verges on the political. A central
bank known for keeping prices stable
looks and acts very differently from one
perceived as soft on inflation. Commercial banks take fewer risks if they face
a regulator known to play hardball. Reputation constitutes a key part of the
corporate culture and determines how
the public reacts to the central bank. It is
an implicit contract shaping people's
expectations.

This may be particularly necessary in
developing countries, where the banking
system is undergoing reform as well.
Evidence from a recent study shows that
countries that combined their supervisory and monetary functions had signi£cantly fewer bank failures in the 1980s
and early 1990s than did nations that
chose separation. 14 Opponents, of
course, chalk this up to the conflict of
interest that results in an overly protective monetary policy.
The benefits of combination do not rest
solely on what happens in stressful
times. Combining bank supervision
and monetary policy allows central
bankers to consider the broader consequences of supervision. Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan
put it aptly in testimony before the
Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs:
Indeed, a single regulator with a narrow
view ofsafety and soundness and with
no responsibility for the macroeconomic
implications of its decisions would
inevitably have a long-term bias against
risk-taking and innovation. It receives
no plaudits for contributing to economic
growth through facilitating prudent
risk-taking, but it is severely criticized
for too many bankfailures. The incentives are clear. 15

Central Bank Reputation

Combining monetary policy and bank
supervision can both help and hurt a
central bank's reputation. Confusion
may reign as the monetary authority's
conflicting objectives make it harder for
the public to sort through the organization's many responsibilities and judge
its performance. 16 Does letting a bank
fail mean that central bankers are incompetent, and therefore soft on inflation as well? Or does it mean that they
are tough all around? Depending on the
context, either interpretation makes
sense. While combination may give a
central bank strong incentives to establish a good reputation, exactly how to
accomplish that may become less clear.

•

Conclusion

So many "on the one hand" and "on the
other hand" arguments bring to mind
Harry Truman's wish for a one-handed
economist. Yet the diversity and success
of actual practice around the globe belie
the existence of any simple answer to
the combination/separation question.

This does not mean that the arguments
don't matter. They do. But different
conditions imply different choic~s.
Local conditions and preferences (the
state of financial development or the
degree of central bank independence,
for example) make particular advantages and disadvantages more compelling. Creating a monetary authority
free from bankers ' influence may mean
restricting the information available to it
-in some situations a wise choice, but
certainly one that should be made with
open eyes.
Global diversity may arise for another
reason as well. Combination and separation are more like two poles of a continuum than two discrete boxes. Many
countries mix the two systems in an
attempt to gain the advantages of both.
Thus, the split between multiple regulators in the United States, the data collection activities of the Bundesbank, and
the alternating inspections by the Bank
of Japan represent strategies aimed at
grasping both horns of the dilemma and
producing a superior system.
As technology, finance, and the global
economy change, so too may the shape
of the world's central banks. In the
United States, broader powers for commercial banks may mean that bank regulation will begin to overlap with securities regulation. New electronic payments
vehicles-offered by banks and nonbanks alike-will create new problems
for monetary policy. This should serve
as a reminder that the regulatory structure keeps evolving and needs continuous reappraisal. Deposit insurance took
50 years to show its flaws. Perhaps a
reasoned assessment of bank supervision
will prevent a similar debacle.

I

I

•

Footnotes

1. See Herman E. Krooss, Documentary
Histoty of Banking and Currency in the
United States, vol. 4. New York: Chelsea
House Publishers, 1983, p. I .
2. See General Accounting Office, "Bank
Regulatory Structure: The Federal Republic
of Germany," GAO/GGD - 94 - I 34BR,
May 1994; and "Bank Oversight Structure:
U.S. and Foreign Experience May Offer
Lessons for Modernizing U.S. Structure,"
GAO/GGD - 97 - 23 , November 1996.

3. See Herman E. Krooss, Documentary
History ofBanking and Currency in the
United States, vol. 3 (footnote I), p. 364.
4. I put aside political arguments as potentially important but outside the scope of
this article.

5. See Owen F. Humpage and Jean M.
Mcintire, "An Introduction to Currency
Boards," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review, vol. 31 , no. 2
(1995 Quarter2), pp. 2- 11.
6. For a different view, see Thomas F.
Cargill, "Central Bank Independence and
Regulatory Responsibilities: The Bank of
Japan and the Federal Reserve," Salomon
Brothers Center for the Study of Financial
Institutions, Monograph Series in Finance
and Economics No. 1989-2, 1989, section X.
7. See International Monetary Fund, "The
Adoption of Indirect Instruments of Monetary Policy," I.MF Occasional Paper No. 126,
Jiine 1995.
8. For one statement of this view, see
Richard F. Syron, "The Fed Must Continue
to Supervise Banks," Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, New England Economic Review,
January/February 1994, pp. 3- 8.

9. The Federal Reserve Board ofGovemors
refers to this as "the clout that comes with
supervision." See "The Views of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve on the
Consolidation of Bank Supervision and Regulation," Banking Industry Regulatory Consolidation Hearings before the Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs. U.S.
Senate, S. Hrg. 103 - 692 , 1994, pp. 132 - 56.

10. This argument is based on the analysis in
Jean Tirole, "The Internal Organization of
Government," Oxford Economic Papers, vol.
46, no. I (January 1994), pp. 1-29.
11. See International Monetary Fund, "The
Adoption oflndirect Instruments of Monetary Policy" (footnote 7).

-

Joseph G. Haubrich is a consultant and
economisl at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the

12. The Mexican central bank has somewhat
more power over payments activities. For
details, see General Accounting Office,
"Mexico's Financial Crisis: Origins, Awareness, Assistance, and Initial Efforts to
Recover," GAO/GGD - 96- 56, February
1996; and Banco de Mexico, The Mexican
Economy 1994, Planta Baja, Mexico, May
1994 (especiaUy chapter 6).
13. See Bernard Shull, "How Should Bank
Regulatory Agencies Be Organized?" Contemporary Policy Issues, vol. 11 , no. 1 (January 1993), pp. 99 - 107.

14. See Charles Goodhart and Dirk Schoenmaker, "Should the Functions of Monetary
Policy and Banking Supervision Be Separated?" Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 47,
no. 4 (October 1995), pp. 539 - 60.
15. Alan Greenspan, testimony given at the
Banking lndustry Regulatory Consolidation
Hearings before the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs (footnote 9),
pp. 130- 32.

16. See David M. Kreps, "Corporate Culture
and Economic Theory," in James E. Alt and
Kenneth A. Shepsle, eds. , Perspectives on
Positive Political Economy, N.ew York: Cambridge University Press, I 990, pp. 90 - 143 .

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Economic Commentary is now available

electronically through the Cleveland Fed's
home page on the World Wide Web:
http://www.clevfrb.org.

Economic Commentary is published 20 times a year by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Copies of the titles listed below are
available through the Corporate Communications & Community Affairs Department. Call 1-800-543-3489 (OH, PA, WV) or 216579-2001, then immediately key in 1-5-3 on your touch-tone phone to reach the publication request option. If you prefer to fax your
order, the number is 216-579-2477.
Glass-Steagall and the
Regulatory Dialectic
Joao Cabral dos Santos
February 15, 1996

A Simple Proposal for
Privatizing Social Security
David Altig and Jagadeesh Gokhale
May 1, 1996

Discrimination in Mortgage
Lending: What Have We Learned?
Stanley D. Longhofer
August 15, 1996

Are Successful Interventions
Random Events?
Owen F. Humpage
March 1, 1996

The Credit Union IndustryAn Overview
Barbara A. Good
May 15, 1996

Reducing Working Hours:
American Workers' Salvation?
Terry J. Fitzgerald
September 1, 1996

State Employment 1995:
Slowing to a Recession?
Mark E. Schweitzer and
Kristin M. Roberts
March 15, 1996

Welfare Reform and the
Cyclicality of Welfare Programs
Elizabeth T. Powers
June f996

The Future of Banking
Supervision
Jerry L. Jordan
April 1, 1996
Where Is All the U.S.
Currency Hiding?
.John B. Carlson and
Benjamin D. Keen
April 15, 1996

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

Interest Rate Rules for Seasonal
and Business Cycles
Charles T. Carlstrom and
Timothy S. Fuerst
July 1996
Inflation Targets: The Next Step
for Monetary Policy
Mark S. Sniderman
August 1, 1996

The Functions and Future
of Retail Banking
Jerry L. Jordan
September 15, 1996
Jobs Creation and
Government Policy
Jerry L. Jordan
October 1, 1996
Competing Currencies:
Back to the Future?
Ben Craig
October 15, 1996

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385