View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 15, 1999

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

The Challenge of Stability:
Mexico’s Pursuit of Sound Money
by Jerry L. Jordan

M

exico needs a stable standard of
value. Indeed, no economy can achieve
its potential without a stable standard
of value.
Mexico needs to experience another
extended period of sustained prosperity,
as it did in the 1960s. A necessary condition for prosperity is sound money. So
long as fears of exchange rate or banking
crises persist, no country can sustain a
period of rising standards of living.
There is no mystery about what conditions will foster sustainable growth. The
experiences of the transition economies
of the former Soviet Union and Eastern
Europe have provided us with many valuable lessons. One of those lessons is that
a market economy requires a Hayekian
infrastructure. That is, there must first be
a foundation of enforceable property
rights, generally accepted accounting
principles, stable currency, and sound
financial intermediaries.
If public contracts are not honored and
private contracts are not enforced, markets are impaired. If title to property is
not certain, normal banking is not possible. If financial statements are not reliable, investment opportunities are
obscured.

■ Sound Money
Changes in the money prices of goods
and assets convey information. If an
economy’s monetary unit is known to be
a stable standard of value, then changes
in money prices will accurately reflect
changes in the relative values of goods
and assets. That is, price fluctuations signal changes in the demand for, or supply
of, goods or assets. Resource utilization
then shifts toward more valued uses and
away from those less valued.
However, if changes in money prices are
contaminated by the changing purchasing power of money, false signals are
sent to businesses and households. Bad
decisions are made, and resources are
misallocated. Standards of living fail to
rise at their potential rate. Nominal interest rates respond to shifting expectations
about the future purchasing power of
money. Changes in real interest rates are
obscured. Again, resources are misallocated. Saving and investment decisions
are affected, and growth is impaired.
Neither inflation nor deflation enhances
economic performance. Unanticipated
inflations and deflations induce redistribution of wealth—especially between
debtors and creditors—but they leave
the average standard of living lower.

How can Mexico best achieve a stable
standard of value and, hence, sound
money? Jerry L. Jordan, President
and Chief Executive Officer of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
explored this question in his address
to the DUXX Graduate School of
Business Leadership at its Forum on
Public Policy in Monterrey, Mexico.
This Economic Commentary is
adapted from his remarks.

A former Federal Reserve governor used
to say, “a place that tolerates inflation is
a place where no one tells the truth.” He
meant, of course, that true changes in the
relative values of things cannot be observed when the purchasing power of
money is not stable.

This pursuit of sound money has followed several paths. The gold exchange
standard, for example—with pegged
exchange rates in the post–World War II
period—helped war-torn countries establish the credibility of their new currencies and central banks.

The standard of value is stable—money
is sound—when people make decisions
in the expectation that all observed
changes in money prices are changes in
relative prices, and all observed changes
in interest rates are changes in real rates.

After the demise of the Bretton Woods
System, a few countries—such as Austria and Holland—were successful in
providing relatively stable domestic currencies by adopting a credible hard peg
to a stable foreign standard of value,
such as the deutsche mark. A few countries—Switzerland, and later Canada
and New Zealand—were relatively successful with floating exchange rates
despite their small, open economies.

■ The Challenge
There is no single best way to achieve
and maintain a stable standard of value.
Even the commodity-backed currencies
of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries were subject to periodic inflations
or deflations—as when new gold or silver mines were discovered, or mines
were depleted.
The choice of monetary regime has implications for fiscal policies; and that,
in turn, means political choices must be
made.
Under a true gold standard, a country’s
internally and externally held debt both
represent claims to its gold reserves.
This effectively limits the government’s
ability to engage in deficit spending. The
size of government is restrained by the
ability to raise taxes.

At times in history, currency boards also
have been successful means of importing stable standards of value. For countries with historically undisciplined
fiscal policies, currency boards have
proven an effective means of achieving
a fiscal regime that enables a more disciplined monetary environment.
The recent creation of a new currency—
the euro—to replace the national currencies of 11 European nations is yet
another method of insulating monetary
authorities from fiscal authorities. A successful, stable euro will require fiscal
reforms that might not have been possible in the political environments of the
individual member nations.

Under the gold exchange standard of the
Bretton Woods System,1 a country’s externally held debt still represents a claim
on its gold holdings. The government’s
ability to engage in deficit spending is
constrained primarily by the willingness
of its residents to add to their holdings of
government bonds.

And recently, “dollarization” has
emerged as still another approach to
importing a stable standard of value.
But, like all approaches, there are pros
and cons that must be carefully weighed
before a choice is made between alternative monetary regimes.

Under a pure fiat money system,2 such
as we have experienced since 1973, the
universal challenge has been to find
effective constraints on the growth of
government spending financed by the
issuance of new debt. In this fiscal environment, achieving and sustaining stable
currencies has been a worldwide challenge for central banks.

In principle, Mexico could acquire a
stable standard of value in several different ways. Some of the necessary conditions for success are common to all
approaches. However, the political difficulty of achieving and maintaining these
essential conditions depends on historical, social, and political developments
that vary greatly from country to country.

The ability to achieve and maintain fiscal
discipline is a key condition for success.
Even communist governments eventually learned the lesson that what can be
distributed and consumed is limited, ultimately, by what can actually be produced. But as we know, governments of
all types have had a tendency to promise
more than is likely to be produced.
Two crucial developments that led to
monetary instability earlier in the twentieth century were capital markets that permitted greatly increased debt-financed
spending by governments and the spread
of fiat currencies issued by central banks.
Successful fiscal discipline has been
threatened, most recently, by the growth
in unfunded pension liabilities of governments with adverse demographic trends.
In the early 1980s, this linkage between
the fiscal regime and the implications for
the monetary environments was labeled
the “dismal arithmetic of monetarism.”
This premise held that any country that
found it politically difficult to achieve
and maintain a disciplined fiscal policy
would ultimately resort to the unlegislated tax of debasing the currency. In
such circumstances, what we call monetary policy becomes a fiscal instrument
—a method of funding government.
This “fiscal dominance ” hypothesis of
the early 1980s—in an environment of
large national debts and annual deficits
all over the world—led to forecasts of
high and rising inflation in both industrialized and developing countries.
Instead, determined pursuit of disciplined
monetary policy in many countries imposed constraints on fiscal authorities. In
the case of the euro, political decisions
were agreed to in international treaties to
achieve and maintain the balanced fiscal
policies necessary for a successful monetary regime.

The experience with currency boards
has been similar. Once a decision is
made to give monetary stability the
highest priority, constraints on spending
and taxing authorities are inevitable.
Residual uncertainties about the durability of currency board arrangements stem
from uncertainties about the domestic
political will to maintain the fiscal discipline crucial to continued success of the
currency board.

■ Dollarization
In January 1999, following the devaluation of the Brazilian real, Argentine
President Carlos Menem suggested dollarization as a possible means of solidifying his country’s commitment to
sound money. Since 1991, Argentina has
operated a currency board,3 pegging the
peso one-for-one to the U.S. dollar and
backing its monetary base with dollars.
Under this arrangement, Argentina’s
central bank has been remarkably successful at fostering price stability in that
country, thereby satisfying a necessary
condition for sustained, long-term economic growth consistent with Argentina’s potential. Nevertheless, foreign
developments—such as the crises in
Mexico, Asia, and Brazil—have raised
questions about Argentina’s political
resolve to maintain a U.S. dollar standard of value.
President Menem’s words have been
echoed throughout Latin America,
where dollars already circulate widely,
but the cry is loudest in Mexico. Supporters see dollarization as a way to permanently protect Mexico’s growth and
prosperity from devastating, periodic
bouts of inflation and peso depreciation.
Like all monetary arrangements, dollarization would impose certain constraints
on political authorities. Public trust ultimately depends on reputations. Constraints on policy discretion are valuable,
because they buy time in which to build
these reputations. These constraints
involve both costs and benefits that
countries must consider on a case-bycase basis. I do not give policy advice on
the issue of dollarization, because not
everyone gains, or gains equally, from
the choice of one monetary regime versus another.

■ Why Sound Money Matters
Money serves to lower the real economic costs of engaging in economic
exchange, but its effectiveness in doing
so hinges on the stability of its purchasing power. If people suspect that a monetary asset will lose its purchasing
power, they will reduce their holdings of
it, look for substitute monetary assets
(dollarize), and devise alternative—and
less efficient—methods of exchange.
When this happens, the costs of undertaking daily transactions rise as the public diverts real economic resources away
from alternative and more productive
uses. Resources are wasted. By conserving these economic resources, stable
monetary institutions promote allocative
efficiency and economic growth.
Although governments generally understand the benefits of stable money, they
also have strong incentives to generate
unanticipated inflation. This is especially true of politically weak governments, who attach a low probability to a
long tenure and, therefore, heavily discount the more distant gains of economic growth. Through expansions of
the money supply, governments can
gain seigniorage and levy an inflation
tax—without the consent of the public
as expressed through a legislative process. In addition, through unanticipated
inflations, governments are sometimes
tempted to try to exploit a short-term
trade-off between employment and
inflation.
Once caught off guard, however, the
public will become more wary in the
future. For their own protection, they
will reduce their holdings of domestic
money. The spontaneous dollarizations
in Argentina and Mexico in the early to
mid-1980s exemplify this response.
Some Latin American governments initially resisted these unofficial dollarizations, but their responses to currency
substitutions (such as capital controls)
tended to compound the inefficiencies
associated with monetary instability.

Faced with the public’s clear preference
for a stable currency, governments may
adopt institutional constraints on their
ability to inflate—like independent central banks, exchange-rate pegs, or currency boards. All have been tried, some
have been successful, but most have
been abandoned when political circumstances changed. The small, but persistent, spread between interest rates on
Argentine peso-denominated debt and
interest rates on dollar-denominated debt
reflects the slight probability that Argentina might break its dollar peg, or
alter the rules under which its currency
board operates.
Institutional constraints on monetary
policy—by themselves—do not directly address the fiscal-policy and banking-structure problems that often give
rise to monetary instability in emergingmarket countries. Moreover, they do not
erase the need to re-think the political
and societal infrastructure that restricts a
nation’s ability to develop and grow.
Ultimately, the only way governments
can attain the optimal outcome to the fiat
money problem is by developing a reputation for behaving in a responsible manner. Switzerland, a small, open economy,
has achieved sustained economic growth
with reasonable price stability without
the aid of a currency board, the European Monetary Union, or pegging to
another currency.
Although the integrity of a stable purchasing power ultimately depends on
reputation, constraints on monetary policy discretion can enhance a government’s standing—though they do so
only as a signal of intentions with regard
to other institutional reforms. Argentina’s currency board has successfully
eliminated inflation while that country
adopted more general, market-based
economic reforms. Argentina’s intention
to develop the economic infrastructure
of a normal market economy has been
made clear. Monetary constraints alone,
however, would stand little chance in
countries like Russia that have made little progress in establishing the Hayekian
infrastructure essential for markets and a
liberal democratic order.

■ Economic Adjustments
Under a Common Currency
Regions, sectors, and industries do not
always prosper equally, even in a common currency area. Regional booms and
busts still occur. Some sectors or industries expand while others contract. This
kind of disparate economic performance
may have its origins in the domestic
economy or in developments in another
currency zone.
For the past couple of years, the U.S.
dollar has been relatively strong—
especially compared to currencies in
Asia and some in Latin America—and
overall, the U.S. economy is performing very well. Nevertheless, this prosperity is not universal. Steel companies
are losing money, declaring bankruptcy,
laying off workers, and shutting down
plants. I am certain that steel company
executives would like to see a weaker
dollar, especially relative to the Japanese yen and other Asian currencies. The
story in textiles is similar.
The U.S. oil sector is also depressed, so
Alaska, Louisiana, and Texas are not
doing so well. Likewise, the Midwest
agricultural sector that depends heavily
on exports, or has to compete with
imports, is having a hard time. The
economy of Hawaii has been depressed
for several years as a result of the
decade-long recession in Japan.
All of these adverse economic conditions create political pressures for government assistance. Sometimes the aid
comes in the form of subsidies, sometimes tax relief, sometimes protection
against competition from imports. Ultimately, though, both labor and other
productive resources will leave these
depressed sectors and regions and migrate to areas and industries where opportunities are more promising. The
greater the flexibility and efficiency
of labor and capital markets, the better
the odds of resisting pressures for
political relief that come from adverse
developments.

The recent launch of the euro—a common currency to be shared by 11 European nations—provides an opportunity
to learn more about political responses
to the pressures arising from diverse
economic conditions. Whether a single,
uniform monetary policy can serve both
the booming economy of Ireland and
the stagnating economies of Germany
and Italy remains to be seen.
In addition to labor and capital markets,
the health of the banking industry influences a nation’s ability to adjust to
changing economic circumstances. Even
within a common currency area, a lack
of diversification of assets or funding
sources can create problems for banks
faced with regional or sectoral booms
and busts. During the oil-price collapse
of the 1980s, for instance, U.S. banks
that were tied exclusively to oil-region
economies failed or were acquired by
healthy banks in other regions. More
diversified Canadian banks all survived.
Nationwide branch banking in the U.S.
is not yet two years old, but there is no
question that greater diversification has
contributed to the soundness of the
larger regional and super-regional companies. The U.S. found that maintaining
political boundaries to branch banking
in the common currency area of the 50
states was destabilizing. Under the currency board arrangement of the past
eight years, Argentina has seen the foreign ownership share of its banking sector grow to 50 percent. There is little
question that the continued success of
the currency board has been enhanced
by the financial stability attained by the
internationalization of banking.
For the banking system to remain
healthy, additional liquidity must be
readily available in times of heightened
uncertainty. When truly systemic events
occur—the public desires to hold more
currency because of century date
change uncertainties, or banks attempt
to hold more reserves against their
deposits during political crises—the
only source of additional currency or
reserves is the issuing central bank. This
classic “lender of last resort” function4

can be fulfilled only by the central bank
empowered to expand or contract its
balance sheet without limit. In a world
of fractional reserve requirements imposed on deposit liabilities, an elastic
source of central bank money is essential. However, that function need not be
provided domestically.
In the modern world, this so-called
lending function is typically performed
through open-market operations, without any need for direct central bank
lending to local institutions. All that is
necessary is that the supply of central
bank money in the market expands as
demand increases. Moreover, subsidiaries or branches of foreign banks effectively diversify a country’s banking
system, making it less vulnerable to
economic disturbances. Because of
their close ties to the parent banks and
access to global financial markets, they
may be more able and willing than
local banks to maintain lending when
faced with deposit outflows.

■ Market Choice and Change
Permitted the choice, people prefer to
hold money that will offer the most stable purchasing power over time. When
countries impose capital restraints or
establish legal tender rules, they limit
their citizens’ ability to protect their
income and wealth from inflation.
Argentina clearly signaled its intention
to maintain monetary stability by granting people the legal right to contract under any and all circumstances—including tax payments and other transactions
with the government—in any currency
they might choose. Legislation in Argentina requires courts to enforce contracts
in the currency specified therein. This
“specific performance” law5 provides
greater assurance that the effective dollarization will not be reversed.

A dollarization process is already under
way—without official sanction—in
many Latin American countries. Permitting parallel currencies would have
some of the benefits of officially sanctioned dollarization, but would maintain
greater flexibility during the transition
process. In fiat money regimes, Gresham’s law becomes inverted—highconfidence monies drive out low-confidence monies. The resulting discipline
from competing standards of value
strengthens the political resolve to
achieve the fiscal balance necessary for
monetary stability.
A fundamental principle of a market
economy is consumer sovereignty. People will act in a manner that enhances
their own well-being. In the process—
as if guided by an invisible hand (to
quote a wise man)—they generally will
promote the best interests of society at
large. The spontaneous, informal dollarizations in many countries over
recent decades demonstrate that people
know that sound money serves their
personal interests. National interests
also are served by providing a stable
standard of value.

■ Footnotes
1. Under the Bretton Woods System, the dollar was pegged in value to 1/35 of an ounce
in gold, and the currencies of the various
Allied nations (Great Britain, France, and
their allies) were pegged to the dollar.

Jerry L. Jordan is the President and Chief
Executive Officer of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.
The views stated herein are those of the

2. Money with little or no value in use relative to value in exchange. Modern paper currency, coins, and checkable deposits are
examples of fiat money; their value comes
from people’s willingness to accept them in
trade of goods.

author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Economic Commentary is published by the

3. Argentina does not have an orthodox currency board; rather, it established a currency
board-type arrangement, with related economic reforms, in 1991 under the “convertability” plan. Unlike traditional currency
boards, Argentina’s system has a central bank
and allows for some discretionary monetary
policy. See Steve H. Hanks and Kurt Schuler,
“A Dollarization Blueprint for Argentina,”
Cato Institute, Foreign Policy Briefing, March
12, 1999 (available at http://www.cato.org/
pubs/fpbriefs/foreignbriefs.html).
4. The expression “lender of last resort”
emerged when the primary method by which
central banks provided additional liquidity to
the banking system during banking panics
was by “rediscounting” commercial loans at
the discount window. The objective was to
reassure a nervous public that they could convert deposit balances to currency if they so
desired. In recent decades, the discount window at the U.S. central bank has declined in
importance as a source of central bank funds.
Instead, open-market operations have become
the primary method of satisfying increased
public desires to add to their cash balances.
5. Specific performance legislation is not
the same thing as legal tender laws. The latter require residents of a country to accept a
certain currency in settlement of a financial
obligation, even if they are owed a foreign
currency, gold, or bales of hay. Specific performance legislation means the courts must
require delivery of what was promised to
the contract, even if that is the currency of
another country, gold, or bales of hay.

Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to maryanne.kostal@clev.frb.org or fax it to
216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is
also available at the Cleveland Fed’s site on
the World Wide Web: http://www.clev.frb.org.

1998–99 Economic Commentary
Private Money: Everything Old
Is New Again
by Barbara A. Good
April 1, 1998

Generational Equity and
Sustainability in U.S. Fiscal Policy
by Jagadeesh Gokhale
April 15, 1998

In Search of the NAIRU
by David Altig and Paul Gomme
May 1, 1998

Government-Subsidized Training:
A Plan for Prosperity?
by Charles T. Carlstrom and
Christy D. Rollow
May 15, 1998

Productivity Measures and
the “New Economy”
by John B. Carlson and Mark E. Schweitzer
June 1998

Productivity Gains During Business
Cycles: What’s Normal?
by Mark E. Schweitzer
July 1998

Measuring Pricing Bias in Mortgages
by Stanley D. Longhofer
August 1, 1998

Global ATM Banking:
Casting the Net

Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

by Joseph G. Haubrich
December 1998

The Euro

by John D. Hueter and Ben R. Craig
August 15, 1998

by Ed Stevens
January 1, 1999

Bank Notes and Stored-Value Cards:
Stepping Lightly into the Past

Bringing the Unbanked Onboard

by William P. Osterberg
and James B. Thomson
September 1, 1998

What Fiscal Surplus?
by Jagadeesh Gokhale
September 15, 1998

Currency: Time for Change?
by Paul W. Bauer
October 1, 1998

Is the Current-Account
Deficit Sustainable?

by Barbara A. Good
January 15, 1999

Will Increasing the Minimum Wage
Help the Poor?
by David Neumark, Mark Schweitzer,
and William Wascher
February 1, 1999

Construction and Monetary Policy:
A View from the Sidelines
by Sandra Pianalto
February 15, 1999

by Owen F. Humpage
October 15, 1998

How Much of Economic Growth
is Fueled by Investment-Specific
Technological Progress?

Social Security’s Treatment of
Postwar Generations?

by Michael Gort, Jeremy Greenwood,
and Peter Rupert
March 1, 1999

by Jagadeesh Gokhale
November 1998

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Subordinated Debt:
Tough Love for Banks?

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385