View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 1,1989

•

References

___

Bailey, Elizabeth E., Graham, David R., and
Kaplan, Daniel P., Deregulating the Air.
.
lines, Cambridge,I MA: Th e MIT Press,
1985.
Bauer, Paul

w.,

'''Don't Panic': A Primer on

Airline Deregulation."

Economic Review,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, IVQ:86.
_. __

, "Competition, Concentration,

and

Fares in the U.S. Airline Industry,"
Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, September 15, 1987.
___

, and Zlatoper, Thomas 1., Deter-

minants of Direct Air Fares to Cleveland:
How Competitive","

Economic Review,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, IQ:89.
Baumol, William J., Panzar, John

c., and

Willig, Robert D., Contestable Markets and

, and Huston, John H., "Deregula-

•

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY

Footnotes

tion and Mergers: How Have They Affected

1. For a short description of the airline in-

Airline Service to Small Communities?,"

dustry under CAB regulation and the early

paper presented at the Southern Economic
Association Meetings, San Antonio, Texas,

years of deregulation see Bauer (1986).

November 1988.

2. See Douglas and Miller (1974).
3. See Kahn (1988).

Call, Gregory D. and Keeler, Theodore E.,
"Airline Deregulation,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Fares, and Market

Behavior: Some Empirical Evidence," in
Andrew F. Daughety, ed., Analytical Studies
in Transport Economics, New York:

4. See Butler and Huston (1988).
S. See Call and Keeler (1985), Bailey

Airline Deregulation:
Boon or Bust?

Graham, and Kaplan (1985), and Butler and
Huston (1987) for some of the tests for con-

Cambridge University Press, 1985.

testability. See in particular Butler and Hus-

Congressional

contestability.

ton (1987) for a test of imperfect

Budget Office, "Policies for

the Deregulated Airline Industry," July 1988.
Douglas, George W. and Miller, James

c.,

Economic Regulation of Domestic Air
Transport: Theory and Policy, Washington,
D.C., Brookings Institution, 1974.

the Theory of Industry Structure, New York:

Regulation,

Borenstein, Severin, "Hubs and High Fares:

by Paul W. Bauer

8. See Rose (1988).

T

Kahn, Alfred E., "I Would Do It Again,"

Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1982.

6. See Bauer (1987).
7. See Meyer and Oster (1987) p. 15.

1988,2.

Meyer, John R. and Oster, Jr., Clinton Y.,

Paul W. Bauer is an economist at the Federal

Airport Dominance and Market Power in

Deregulation and the Future of Intercity

Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author

the U.S. Airline Industry," Institute of

Passenger Travel, MIT Press, 1987.

would like to thank Randall W. Ebertsfor his
helpful comments.

Public Policy Studies Discussion Paper No.
278, University of Michigan, March 1988.

Morrison, Steven, and Winston, Clifford,
"Empirical Implications and Tests of the

Butler, Richard Y., and Huston, John H.,

Contestability

"Actual Competition,

Law and Economics, April 1987,30,53-66.

Potential Competi-

tion, and the Impact of Airline Mergers on
Fares," paper presented at the Western
Economic Association Meetings, Vancouver, British Columbia, July, 1987.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
PO. Box 6387

Hypothesis,"

Rose, Nancy L., "Profitability

The Journal of

and Product

he Airline Deregulation Act of

1978 took the operational decisions of
running an airline (what routes to fly
and what fares to charge) away from
government regulators and returned
them to the airlines. 1

The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the

Over the last decade, the airlines have
used this new freedom to institute a
number of fundamental changes in the
structure of the industry. Since 1978,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Quality: Economic Determinants of Airline
Safety Performance," MIT, Sloan Working

discount fares have been more widely
used and the variety of restrictions on
these fares has increased, frequent flier
plans have proliferated, carriers have
come and gone, and hub-and-spoke
operations have emerged.

Paper #2032-88, June 1988.

This Economic Commentary examines
the benefits and problems that have

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

resulted from the deregulation of the
airline industry and makes some recommendations for changes in public
policy to preserve the benefits and to
mitigate the problems.

Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Research Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101

• Benefits of Deregulation
Deregulation increased both the degree
and scope of competition in the airline
industry. From 1938 to 1978, the Civil
Aeronautics Board (CAB) essentially
controlled the routes airlines could fly
and the fares they could charge. Airlines could only compete with one

Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

another by offering higher quality service than their rivals. Since the CABalso charged with promoting the industry-would raise fares to cover higher
ISSN 0428-1276

operating costs to ensure the financial
health of the industry, there was little incentive for the airlines to work to hold
costs down. The result was higher fares
and higher quality of service than the
average traveler preferred. 2
In a deregulated market, airlines have
had to adopt productivity-enhancing
techniques, such as the hub-and-spoke
route networks, to stay competitive.
As a result, labor productivity has increased greatly. Since deregulation, the
number of workers in the industry has
increased only 48 percent, while the
number of passengers flown has increased 86 percent and the number of
miles flown has increased 109 percent.
The gains in operating efficiency
brought about by competition were
largely passed on to travelers in the
form of lower fares and more frequent
flights. Although fares have risen some
in the past year, average revenue per
passenger declined 30 percent in real
terms between 1976 and 1987.3 Some
of the price reduction came at the expense of more restrictions on tickets
(not fully refundable, for example, requiring advance purchase, or requiring
a stay over a Saturday night). About 90
percent of passengers now fly on discounted tickets at an average discount
of 60 percent off the "regular" coach
fare according to the Air Transport
Association.

-

Deregulation of the airline industry
has produced wide-ranging changes
that have created benefits and some

problems for the public. The promotion of safety, high-quality performance, and beneficial competition
within the industry should be a goal
of public policy. These policy goals,
however, must be based on a sound
understanding of the market forces
behind the post-deregulation changes
in the airline industry.

The hub-and-spoke route systems now

the route.5 In recent research looking

In part, the higher fare for flights into

fie controllers continue to use vacuum-

commercial flying is still a much safer

In the meantime, scarce airport re-

used by the airlines have resulted in
more frequent flights. Most destinations can now be reached with, at most,
a one-stop flight; densely traveled

at the determinants of direct fares to
Cleveland, Bauer and Ziatoper (1989)
found that for each additional carrier
serving a route, fares were lower, but
by less and less as the number of car-

and out of the hub reflects the higher
quality of service offered to these passengers (more nonstop flights and more
frequent flights), but it also reflects the
market power of the hub airline, which
is further entrenched by its computer
reservation system, its frequent-flier
plan, and its target commission rates-

tube technology.

mode of travel than the private auto or
private plane.7 Yet there is no reason to
be complacent given the current strains
on the air traffic control system. Cur-

sources would be more efficiently utilized if they were priced correctly. If
takeoff and landing fees varied by time
of day, then price-sensitive passengers

rently there are fewer FAA inspectors
than there were eight years ago, while
there are many more planes in commercial service.

would fly off-peak, thus reducing the
peak demands on the system and freeing up resources for users who value
them more highly. This would reduce
congestion and increase the margin of
safety in the system.

routes still receive nonstop service.
Morrison and Winston (1987) studied
the effect of hub-and-spoke networks
and found the total benefits to passengers were on the order of $5.7 billion dollars a year in 1985.
While the majority of travelers have
benefited from deregulation, gains

riers in a market increases. Fares
decline as additional carriers are added
to the route, but only until about four
carriers are serving the route.
The increase in the national market
shares of the largest airlines, resulting
from the merger wave of the mid-

all of which serve to deter entry by
other carriers. The trade-off between
fares and quality of service benefits
business travelers, who tend to be timesensitive and price-insensitive, much
more than tourist travelers, who tend to
be price-sensitive and time-insensitive.

have not been distributed evenly.
While very few cities have lost air service, some did lose service by major
carriers. These cities may be better off
with more frequent commuter airline
service than they were under relatively
infrequent major carrier service.4

1980s and the operating agreements of
the major carriers with local service airlines, has worried some analysts. Both
of these developments have trade-offs
between higher operating efficiency
and quality of service on one hand and
potential anti-competitive effects on
the other. Since fares are determined by

dividual route level, concentration has
actually fallen slightly since deregulation. A recent Congressional Budget Office study found that the number of car-

The benefits of lower fares are also not

individual route and airport factors, it
is not clear how concerned
policymakers should be by the increase
in concentration at the national level.

riers per route has actually increased
for most types of routes. Currently, an
average of 2.5 carriers serve the typical
route. Easing the entry of additional

evenly distributed among classes of
passengers. Fares tend to be higher on
routes served by fewer carriers. In addition, business travelers often cannot
meet the requirement for discount
fares. Passengers who could afford to
fly before the discount fares of
deregulation must endure more closely
packed seats, a higher percentage of
seats being filled, and the general in-

A second source of concern is the increase in concentration at airports with
only one carrier offering hub service,
creating what are known as "fortress

crease in c.ongestion at the airport. All
in all though, there is little doubt that

hubs." Market shares at such airports
tend to overstate the market power that
the hub airline has since most of the
passengers of the hub airline are only

passengers are on average better off.

making connections at the airport."

•

However, these hub airlines usually
have sufficient market power so that
they can price discriminate between
passengers traveling to or from the airport and passengers only making connections at the airport. Borenstein
(1988) and Butler and Huston (1987)

Industry Competitiveness

Unfortunately, competition does not
work as well at "regulating" the airline
industry as some proponents of deregulation had predicted. Some felt the airline industry was an example of a perfectly contestable market. Fares would
be set just high enough to cover costs
because, if they were set any higher,
other carriers would enter the market
and undercut the incumbent carrier.
Every study that has examined this
issue has failed to find evidence that
the airline industry is perfectly contestable. However, there is evidence that
the industry is imperfectly contestable:
the number of carriers that could quickly enter a route does limit how high incumbent firms can raise their fares on

find that the fare from a rim city to a
hub city, plus the fare from that hub
city to another rim city, is usually
much higher than the connecting farethrough the same hub city-for the
flight between the two rim cities. The
reason is that there are usually other
hub cities where passengers could
make connections to go between the
two rim cities, but passengers flying to
the hub city will most likely have to fly
on the airline that has a hub there.

It must be remembered that at the in-

At some point, the air traffic control system will have to be modernized and expanded, but until then, existing facilities
could be utilized much more efficiently
by using prices to allocate scarce gate
space and takeoff and landing slots. If
takeoff and landing fees varied by time
of day, with higher fees during the peak
times, airlines would have an incentive
to use these facilities more uniformly
throughout the day. High fees at the
most congested airports might induce
some airlines to shift some flights to
less congested airports, particularly
those flights involving a high percentage of connecting passengers.

• Service Quality
Under deregulation, airlines can compete with fares in addition to quality of
service. This has resulted in meal service and other amenities being cut
back, since most passengers have

carriers onto routes should continue to
be a policy objective, since the industry
is not perfectly competitive.

revealed a preference for lower fares
even at the expense of lower quality.

• Congestion

Requiring airlines to publish their ontime performance records provides pas-

The congestion of the air traffic control
system should be viewed as evidence
of the success of deregulation. Put
another way, if fares were set higher,
fewer travelers would fly and there
would be less congestion. This would
hardly be a welfare-enhancing public
policy either from the standpoint of
equity or economic efficiency. The congestion stems primarily from the air
traffic control system failing to expand
rapidly enough and from the inefficient
way scarce gate space and takeoff and
landing slots are allocated.
Little has been done over the last eight
years to expand the air traffic control
system despite the large growth in its
use. This has occurred despite the $3.5
billion surplus in the Airport and Airway Trust Fund-a fund financed by
users' fees that can only be spent on
maintaining and improving the air traffic control system. Two decades into
the age of semiconductors,

the air traf-

sengers with better information with
which to plan their trips. On balance, it
was a positive development; however,
it has led the airlines to change their be-

Proponents of deregulation never intended for the government to slacken
its efforts in regulating the safety of the
industry. In fact, government regulation of safety is more important in a
deregulated environment than it was in
a regulated environment, since the
financial condition of an airline may influence its safety choices (such as
spending on maintenance and pilot
training).8 Under deregulation, the
FAA should be even more vigilant.

expanding the benefits brought about
by airline deregulation, but government
regulation of the routes airlines can fly
and the fares they can charge is not
good policy. Government enforcement
of existing safety, antitrust, and consumer protection laws is beneficial.
Government investment in improving

•

the air traffic system (airports and air
traffic control) is essential.

Conclusion

Effective public policy must be based
on a sound understanding of the forces
driving the changes in the airl ine industry after deregulation. The benefits of
airline deregulation have been substantial, but they have not been uniformly
distributed among passengers and between cities. Care must be taken to
preserve the benefits to travelers.
Informed enforcement of the antitrust

havior in ways that are not necessarily
optimal. First, since the on-time arrival

laws should be sufficient to preserve
competition at the route level. So far,

rate refers to the plane, not to the passengers, airlines may not wait as long
for connecting passengers on delayed
incoming flights as they used to in
order to preserve their "on-time" performance. Another problem is that the on-

even with the wave of mergers in the
mid 1980s, there are still more carriers
per route on average than in 1983 and
certainly more than there were under
CAB regulation. Steps to make acquisition of gate space and takeoff and land-

time arrival rate masks the true extent
of the congestion problem. One way
airlines increased their on-time arrival
rate was by adding time to their flight
schedules into congested airports.
These scheduled congestion delays
result in millions of lost man-hours in
the course of a year.

ing slots easier would also help reduce
the market power an airline has at its
hubs.

The safety dimension of service quality
is a more serious issue. To date, there
have been fewer accidents per passenger mile flown than was the case
under regulation. By most measures,

In short, there is a useful role for
government to play in preserving and

Though safety will always be a concern, there have been fewer accidents
per passenger-mile since deregulation.
With rigorous enforcement of the existing FAA safety regulations and with a
modernization of the air traffic control
system, there is every reason to expect
this trend to continue.

The hub-and-spoke route systems now

the route.5 In recent research looking

In part, the higher fare for flights into

fie controllers continue to use vacuum-

commercial flying is still a much safer

In the meantime, scarce airport re-

used by the airlines have resulted in
more frequent flights. Most destinations can now be reached with, at most,
a one-stop flight; densely traveled

at the determinants of direct fares to
Cleveland, Bauer and Ziatoper (1989)
found that for each additional carrier
serving a route, fares were lower, but
by less and less as the number of car-

and out of the hub reflects the higher
quality of service offered to these passengers (more nonstop flights and more
frequent flights), but it also reflects the
market power of the hub airline, which
is further entrenched by its computer
reservation system, its frequent-flier
plan, and its target commission rates-

tube technology.

mode of travel than the private auto or
private plane.7 Yet there is no reason to
be complacent given the current strains
on the air traffic control system. Cur-

sources would be more efficiently utilized if they were priced correctly. If
takeoff and landing fees varied by time
of day, then price-sensitive passengers

rently there are fewer FAA inspectors
than there were eight years ago, while
there are many more planes in commercial service.

would fly off-peak, thus reducing the
peak demands on the system and freeing up resources for users who value
them more highly. This would reduce
congestion and increase the margin of
safety in the system.

routes still receive nonstop service.
Morrison and Winston (1987) studied
the effect of hub-and-spoke networks
and found the total benefits to passengers were on the order of $5.7 billion dollars a year in 1985.
While the majority of travelers have
benefited from deregulation, gains

riers in a market increases. Fares
decline as additional carriers are added
to the route, but only until about four
carriers are serving the route.
The increase in the national market
shares of the largest airlines, resulting
from the merger wave of the mid-

all of which serve to deter entry by
other carriers. The trade-off between
fares and quality of service benefits
business travelers, who tend to be timesensitive and price-insensitive, much
more than tourist travelers, who tend to
be price-sensitive and time-insensitive.

have not been distributed evenly.
While very few cities have lost air service, some did lose service by major
carriers. These cities may be better off
with more frequent commuter airline
service than they were under relatively
infrequent major carrier service.4

1980s and the operating agreements of
the major carriers with local service airlines, has worried some analysts. Both
of these developments have trade-offs
between higher operating efficiency
and quality of service on one hand and
potential anti-competitive effects on
the other. Since fares are determined by

dividual route level, concentration has
actually fallen slightly since deregulation. A recent Congressional Budget Office study found that the number of car-

The benefits of lower fares are also not

individual route and airport factors, it
is not clear how concerned
policymakers should be by the increase
in concentration at the national level.

riers per route has actually increased
for most types of routes. Currently, an
average of 2.5 carriers serve the typical
route. Easing the entry of additional

evenly distributed among classes of
passengers. Fares tend to be higher on
routes served by fewer carriers. In addition, business travelers often cannot
meet the requirement for discount
fares. Passengers who could afford to
fly before the discount fares of
deregulation must endure more closely
packed seats, a higher percentage of
seats being filled, and the general in-

A second source of concern is the increase in concentration at airports with
only one carrier offering hub service,
creating what are known as "fortress

crease in c.ongestion at the airport. All
in all though, there is little doubt that

hubs." Market shares at such airports
tend to overstate the market power that
the hub airline has since most of the
passengers of the hub airline are only

passengers are on average better off.

making connections at the airport."

•

However, these hub airlines usually
have sufficient market power so that
they can price discriminate between
passengers traveling to or from the airport and passengers only making connections at the airport. Borenstein
(1988) and Butler and Huston (1987)

Industry Competitiveness

Unfortunately, competition does not
work as well at "regulating" the airline
industry as some proponents of deregulation had predicted. Some felt the airline industry was an example of a perfectly contestable market. Fares would
be set just high enough to cover costs
because, if they were set any higher,
other carriers would enter the market
and undercut the incumbent carrier.
Every study that has examined this
issue has failed to find evidence that
the airline industry is perfectly contestable. However, there is evidence that
the industry is imperfectly contestable:
the number of carriers that could quickly enter a route does limit how high incumbent firms can raise their fares on

find that the fare from a rim city to a
hub city, plus the fare from that hub
city to another rim city, is usually
much higher than the connecting farethrough the same hub city-for the
flight between the two rim cities. The
reason is that there are usually other
hub cities where passengers could
make connections to go between the
two rim cities, but passengers flying to
the hub city will most likely have to fly
on the airline that has a hub there.

It must be remembered that at the in-

At some point, the air traffic control system will have to be modernized and expanded, but until then, existing facilities
could be utilized much more efficiently
by using prices to allocate scarce gate
space and takeoff and landing slots. If
takeoff and landing fees varied by time
of day, with higher fees during the peak
times, airlines would have an incentive
to use these facilities more uniformly
throughout the day. High fees at the
most congested airports might induce
some airlines to shift some flights to
less congested airports, particularly
those flights involving a high percentage of connecting passengers.

• Service Quality
Under deregulation, airlines can compete with fares in addition to quality of
service. This has resulted in meal service and other amenities being cut
back, since most passengers have

carriers onto routes should continue to
be a policy objective, since the industry
is not perfectly competitive.

revealed a preference for lower fares
even at the expense of lower quality.

• Congestion

Requiring airlines to publish their ontime performance records provides pas-

The congestion of the air traffic control
system should be viewed as evidence
of the success of deregulation. Put
another way, if fares were set higher,
fewer travelers would fly and there
would be less congestion. This would
hardly be a welfare-enhancing public
policy either from the standpoint of
equity or economic efficiency. The congestion stems primarily from the air
traffic control system failing to expand
rapidly enough and from the inefficient
way scarce gate space and takeoff and
landing slots are allocated.
Little has been done over the last eight
years to expand the air traffic control
system despite the large growth in its
use. This has occurred despite the $3.5
billion surplus in the Airport and Airway Trust Fund-a fund financed by
users' fees that can only be spent on
maintaining and improving the air traffic control system. Two decades into
the age of semiconductors,

the air traf-

sengers with better information with
which to plan their trips. On balance, it
was a positive development; however,
it has led the airlines to change their be-

Proponents of deregulation never intended for the government to slacken
its efforts in regulating the safety of the
industry. In fact, government regulation of safety is more important in a
deregulated environment than it was in
a regulated environment, since the
financial condition of an airline may influence its safety choices (such as
spending on maintenance and pilot
training).8 Under deregulation, the
FAA should be even more vigilant.

expanding the benefits brought about
by airline deregulation, but government
regulation of the routes airlines can fly
and the fares they can charge is not
good policy. Government enforcement
of existing safety, antitrust, and consumer protection laws is beneficial.
Government investment in improving

•

the air traffic system (airports and air
traffic control) is essential.

Conclusion

Effective public policy must be based
on a sound understanding of the forces
driving the changes in the airl ine industry after deregulation. The benefits of
airline deregulation have been substantial, but they have not been uniformly
distributed among passengers and between cities. Care must be taken to
preserve the benefits to travelers.
Informed enforcement of the antitrust

havior in ways that are not necessarily
optimal. First, since the on-time arrival

laws should be sufficient to preserve
competition at the route level. So far,

rate refers to the plane, not to the passengers, airlines may not wait as long
for connecting passengers on delayed
incoming flights as they used to in
order to preserve their "on-time" performance. Another problem is that the on-

even with the wave of mergers in the
mid 1980s, there are still more carriers
per route on average than in 1983 and
certainly more than there were under
CAB regulation. Steps to make acquisition of gate space and takeoff and land-

time arrival rate masks the true extent
of the congestion problem. One way
airlines increased their on-time arrival
rate was by adding time to their flight
schedules into congested airports.
These scheduled congestion delays
result in millions of lost man-hours in
the course of a year.

ing slots easier would also help reduce
the market power an airline has at its
hubs.

The safety dimension of service quality
is a more serious issue. To date, there
have been fewer accidents per passenger mile flown than was the case
under regulation. By most measures,

In short, there is a useful role for
government to play in preserving and

Though safety will always be a concern, there have been fewer accidents
per passenger-mile since deregulation.
With rigorous enforcement of the existing FAA safety regulations and with a
modernization of the air traffic control
system, there is every reason to expect
this trend to continue.

May 1,1989

•

References

___

Bailey, Elizabeth E., Graham, David R., and
Kaplan, Daniel P., Deregulating the Air.
.
lines, Cambridge,I MA: Th e MIT Press,
1985.
Bauer, Paul

w.,

'''Don't Panic': A Primer on

Airline Deregulation."

Economic Review,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, IVQ:86.
_. __

, "Competition, Concentration,

and

Fares in the U.S. Airline Industry,"
Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, September 15, 1987.
___

, and Zlatoper, Thomas 1., Deter-

minants of Direct Air Fares to Cleveland:
How Competitive","

Economic Review,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, IQ:89.
Baumol, William J., Panzar, John

c., and

Willig, Robert D., Contestable Markets and

, and Huston, John H., "Deregula-

•

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTORY

Footnotes

tion and Mergers: How Have They Affected

1. For a short description of the airline in-

Airline Service to Small Communities?,"

dustry under CAB regulation and the early

paper presented at the Southern Economic
Association Meetings, San Antonio, Texas,

years of deregulation see Bauer (1986).

November 1988.

2. See Douglas and Miller (1974).
3. See Kahn (1988).

Call, Gregory D. and Keeler, Theodore E.,
"Airline Deregulation,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Fares, and Market

Behavior: Some Empirical Evidence," in
Andrew F. Daughety, ed., Analytical Studies
in Transport Economics, New York:

4. See Butler and Huston (1988).
S. See Call and Keeler (1985), Bailey

Airline Deregulation:
Boon or Bust?

Graham, and Kaplan (1985), and Butler and
Huston (1987) for some of the tests for con-

Cambridge University Press, 1985.

testability. See in particular Butler and Hus-

Congressional

contestability.

ton (1987) for a test of imperfect

Budget Office, "Policies for

the Deregulated Airline Industry," July 1988.
Douglas, George W. and Miller, James

c.,

Economic Regulation of Domestic Air
Transport: Theory and Policy, Washington,
D.C., Brookings Institution, 1974.

the Theory of Industry Structure, New York:

Regulation,

Borenstein, Severin, "Hubs and High Fares:

by Paul W. Bauer

8. See Rose (1988).

T

Kahn, Alfred E., "I Would Do It Again,"

Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1982.

6. See Bauer (1987).
7. See Meyer and Oster (1987) p. 15.

1988,2.

Meyer, John R. and Oster, Jr., Clinton Y.,

Paul W. Bauer is an economist at the Federal

Airport Dominance and Market Power in

Deregulation and the Future of Intercity

Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author

the U.S. Airline Industry," Institute of

Passenger Travel, MIT Press, 1987.

would like to thank Randall W. Ebertsfor his
helpful comments.

Public Policy Studies Discussion Paper No.
278, University of Michigan, March 1988.

Morrison, Steven, and Winston, Clifford,
"Empirical Implications and Tests of the

Butler, Richard Y., and Huston, John H.,

Contestability

"Actual Competition,

Law and Economics, April 1987,30,53-66.

Potential Competi-

tion, and the Impact of Airline Mergers on
Fares," paper presented at the Western
Economic Association Meetings, Vancouver, British Columbia, July, 1987.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
PO. Box 6387

Hypothesis,"

Rose, Nancy L., "Profitability

The Journal of

and Product

he Airline Deregulation Act of

1978 took the operational decisions of
running an airline (what routes to fly
and what fares to charge) away from
government regulators and returned
them to the airlines. 1

The views stated herein are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the

Over the last decade, the airlines have
used this new freedom to institute a
number of fundamental changes in the
structure of the industry. Since 1978,

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Quality: Economic Determinants of Airline
Safety Performance," MIT, Sloan Working

discount fares have been more widely
used and the variety of restrictions on
these fares has increased, frequent flier
plans have proliferated, carriers have
come and gone, and hub-and-spoke
operations have emerged.

Paper #2032-88, June 1988.

This Economic Commentary examines
the benefits and problems that have

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

resulted from the deregulation of the
airline industry and makes some recommendations for changes in public
policy to preserve the benefits and to
mitigate the problems.

Cleveland, OH 44101
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Research Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101

• Benefits of Deregulation
Deregulation increased both the degree
and scope of competition in the airline
industry. From 1938 to 1978, the Civil
Aeronautics Board (CAB) essentially
controlled the routes airlines could fly
and the fares they could charge. Airlines could only compete with one

Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

another by offering higher quality service than their rivals. Since the CABalso charged with promoting the industry-would raise fares to cover higher
ISSN 0428-1276

operating costs to ensure the financial
health of the industry, there was little incentive for the airlines to work to hold
costs down. The result was higher fares
and higher quality of service than the
average traveler preferred. 2
In a deregulated market, airlines have
had to adopt productivity-enhancing
techniques, such as the hub-and-spoke
route networks, to stay competitive.
As a result, labor productivity has increased greatly. Since deregulation, the
number of workers in the industry has
increased only 48 percent, while the
number of passengers flown has increased 86 percent and the number of
miles flown has increased 109 percent.
The gains in operating efficiency
brought about by competition were
largely passed on to travelers in the
form of lower fares and more frequent
flights. Although fares have risen some
in the past year, average revenue per
passenger declined 30 percent in real
terms between 1976 and 1987.3 Some
of the price reduction came at the expense of more restrictions on tickets
(not fully refundable, for example, requiring advance purchase, or requiring
a stay over a Saturday night). About 90
percent of passengers now fly on discounted tickets at an average discount
of 60 percent off the "regular" coach
fare according to the Air Transport
Association.

-

Deregulation of the airline industry
has produced wide-ranging changes
that have created benefits and some

problems for the public. The promotion of safety, high-quality performance, and beneficial competition
within the industry should be a goal
of public policy. These policy goals,
however, must be based on a sound
understanding of the market forces
behind the post-deregulation changes
in the airline industry.