View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 15, 1989

qualified as an inversion. Occasional

I 7 business-cycle

episodes of a monthly average 3D-year
yield as much as 23 basis points lower
than the lO-year yield have appeared
over the past five years without the in-

(1926, 1945, 1948, and 1953). Emergence of a negative spread between the
one-year and lO-year maturities has
preceded each business-cycle peak

version subsequently spreading across a
broader range of the maturity spectrum.

since 1953, by an average of 10
months and within a range of eight to
16 months. On the other hand, a yieldcurve inversion has not always been associated with a business-cycle peak

Longest-term yields may be biased
downward because the innovation of
stripping has removed from the market
almost half of the par value of all
Treasury securities with maturities
longer than 17 years. Yields in the
longest maturity range may include a
smaller risk premium than in the intermediate range, reflecting the liquidity
assurance this additional source of
demand provides for portfolio investors in those bonds.
By the end of February 1989, inversion
undoubtedly had set in, with a peak
yield at two years, which was 36 basis
points above the 3D-year bond, but
still 53 basis points above the threemonth bill. Actually, inversion has extended all the way back to the threemonth yield on only two occasions in
the postwar period (one month in
1974 and six months in 1980-81).
With the February inversion
speculation about recession.
of some portion of the yield
been associated with all but

came
Inversion
curve has
four of the

peaks since 1910

and recession. False signals were
registered in 1965-67 (lasting 14
months), again in 1967 (one month),
and in 1968 (five months).
•

Conclusion

Changes in yield spreads are an ambiguous indicator of monetary policy, at
best, but so too are all intermediate indicators. The year-old narrowing and
recent inversion of the yield curve does
indicate that policy is tighter now than
it would be if the spread were positive
and wider, but that is not very useful information. Moreover, spreads can and
do change rapidly without any overt
policy actions, as swings in market sentiment change market yields.
The fundamental question is whether
the current yield curve reflects a
policy that is "too easy," so that the
trend inflation rate will continue to
rise. The yield curve fails to answer
that question.

•

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTaRY

Footnotes

1. The yield curve shown in figure 1 and

pictured in many publications is based on
data in the Federal Reserve's weekJy H.IS
release. The three-month, six-month, and oneyear maturity yields are composites of actual
yields reported by five dealers for the most
recent issues. Beyondthe one-year maturity,
however, the values are estimates of the
yields that would have emerged in active
trading had issues of the designated
maturities actually existed. The values are
taken from the Treasury's continuous yield
curve "fitted by eye" for actively traded issues, which tend to be the most recent issues.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Is There a Message in
the Yield Curve?

1

2. (1.092)2/ (1.090) = 1.094.
3. Other explanations are postulated for a

positive yield spread. One is that longer-term
instruments must provide a premium to compensate investors for lesser liquidity.Another
is that the nonnal slope would be either negative or positive, depending on whether
predominant coupon rates tend to be high or
low compared to the normal range within
which yields are expected to vary.

by E.J. Stevens

T

he yield curve, relating market
yields to the maturity of debt instruments, began to invert at the end of
1988. As yields on shorter-term
securities rose above those on longerterm securities, questions arose about
the significance of a downward-sloped
yield curve.

E.J. Stevens is an assistant vice president
and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.

Does a negatively sloped yield curve
prove that monetary policy is tight or

The views stated herein are those of the
author and 110tnecessarily those of the

that a recession is coming? Does a
steeply positively sloped curve indicate
that monetary policy is easy or that inflation will accelerate?

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

The Federal Reserve System could

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

produce recessions and decelerating inflation, or booms and accelerating inflation, by allowing the monetary base to

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

grow too slowly or too rapidly for sustained periods of time. Policy analysts
employ a variety of indicators to try to
distinguish between "too" slowly and
rapidly, between tightness and ease,
with fashions in indicators varying
over the years and among analysts.

the broader monetary aggregates, M2
and M3, to communicate its policy intentions to Congress and the public.
Policy analysts also use as indicators
the gap between actual and capacity
GNP and the gap between actual and
full employment.
Each of these is an intermediate indicator between the ultimate results of
policy, which are measured by actual
trend rates of economic growth and inflation, and day-to-day policy actions,
which are measured by changes in the
monetary base and the federal funds
rate. The yield curve can be considered
as another intermediate indicator,
blending short-term interest rates that
reflect policy actions with longer-term
interest rates that reflect investors' expectations of real returns to capital and
future inflation rates.
This Economic Commentary examines
the indicator value of the yield curve,
with the conclusion that its message is
no more distinct than those received
from other intermediate indicators.

The growth rate of the M I monetary

Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Research Department, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101
ISSN 042R·1276

aggregate was a popular indicator until
its relationship to output and prices
broke down during the 1980s under the
weight of deposit-rate deregulation and

• What Is the Yield Curve?
A yield curve plots term to maturity
against market yields to maturity on an
otherwise comparable set of debt instru-

a reversal of the postwar upward trend
in interest rates. The Federal Reserve's
policymaking arm, the Federal Open
Market Committee, continues to set an-

ments. A typical curve uses yields on
U.S. Treasury securities, so that differences in credit quality will not distort the relationship between yield and

nual target ranges for growth rates of

maturity (see figure I).

-

Short-term bond yields have moved
above long-term bond yields over the

past year. The resulting inverted
yield curve indicates that monetary
policy is tighter than it could be and
may be tighter than it has been, but
provides no basis for judging
whether policy is tight (or easy)
enough.

Even Treasury debt is not completely

quired to forestall portfolio shifts from

market perceptions of tighter policy if

uniform, so that differences in yields
among 250 or so marketable issues are
not due solely to maturity. "Flower
bonds," for example, now yield about 5

one-year to two-year securities.

we could know that the expected real
rate of return plus the risk premium in
long-term rates were constant.

percentage points less than other issues
of comparable maturity because the
Treasury must accept these old bonds
at par in payment of estate taxes.
Similarly, market yields may differ between high- and low-coupon bonds,
and between unstripped and stripped
bonds (those with coupons removed
and sold separately), reflecting different valuations of coupon income
and capital value at maturity.
These and other differentiating features
illustrate that the yield curve is an
abstraction that should be used with caution. Constant-maturity yields underlying the yield curve in figure I are not actual market yields, but rather estimates
of what yields on actively traded issues
would have been had comparable issues
of such maturities been in existence.
There is no basis for calculating a margin of error, but changes in constantmaturity yields and yield spreads of perhaps five to ten basis points and for
only one or two weeks should be interpreted with skepticism. I
• Expectations in the Yield Curve
Actual yields are set in markets. Ignoring questions of risk for the moment,
traders and investors will hold a particular security when their expectation of
total return before a future date (that is,
coupon payment plus expected change
in market price) is no better or worse

While a yield curve may suggest expected future yields, precise future
yields cannot be derived from a yield
curve. One must first know the
premiums that investors require to compensate them for the risk that realized
short-term yields on long-maturity assets will differ from expectations. Only
by assuming constant risk premiums
can one reach the popular presumption
that a change in the slope of the curve
reflects a change in expectations. For
example, a flattening of the curve
means that current short-term interest
rates have risen relative to future shortterm interest rates only if risk premiums
in long-term yields have not dropped.
A further ambiguity should be noted.
An expectation of rising or falling
nominal interest rates reflects beliefs
both about future real interest rates and
about future inflation. Thus, a steep
positive slope in the yield curve might
reflect perceptions of a very low real
rate of interest at the shortest end of the
curve because of weakness in the real
economy that, once passed, would bring
a resumption of stable growth at a
stable inflation rate. Alternatively, the

cent.

If the future one-year rate in this

example were expected to be lower
than 9.4 percent, then some combina-

short- and long-term rates would not be
mistaken for tighter policy. However,
the yield spread still would be no more
reliable an indicator than long-term

since 1910. Excluding the period 1930
through 1951, when they were prevented by the Great Depression and
then by Federal Reserve wartime rate-

7.5

pegging, inversions have appeared
every six years, on average.
The most common explanation for a
normal upward slope is that, in a grow-

6.5

ing economy in stable equilibrium at a
stable trend inflation rate, yields on
longer-term debt instruments would be
higher than those on shorter-term instruments, even though the series of future
short-term rates was expected to be flat.
a. Three-month, six-month, and one-year U.S. Treasury instruments are quoted
from the secondary market on a yield basis; all other instruments are constantmaturity series.

Of course, we cannot know these things

wider spread, because we cannot know
that the real return and risk premium in
long-term yields is unchanged. Third,
we do not know whether a given rate
spread is too tight, or not tight enough,
to stabilize trend inflation.

SOURCE:

Monthly averages from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release H.1S.

_FIGURE2
YIELD SPREAD CYCLESa
Percent
3.01TT--rr-,.------r-r-IT---rrIT------,
2.5
2.

O.OH-+-"WII--+H---H~r-Hr_+t-tt_-+-1l1Httt+_--~~
-0.5

This positive spread would reflect the
risk premium required to compensate
risk-averse investors for greater uncertainty about more distant events.r'
With a longer historical perspective, a
negative slope seems less unusual.
Prior to the Great Depression, business
cycles left their mark on short-term
rates, but had relatively less impact on
long-term rates-perhaps
because the
gold standard was a
anchor for the trend
the central bank has
gold standard began

more credible
inflation rate than
been since the
to break down.

Maintaining convertibility of the dollar
into gold at a fixed price meant that
the trend inflation rate incorporated in
bond yields could not deviate far from
zero for any length of time. The yield
curve therefore might have been expected to pivot around a relatively
stable long-term yield.

-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-3.0
-3.5 LLU..L..L.~~'-LI~"""""L....L:-~&..L.-:':':~..&...J.~~oLI.:'~I...L...L.I:-~

Reductions in the level of long-term

period. Despite successively greater
cyclical swings of the yield spread in
figure 2 from plus to minus, and
despite successively wider negative

interest rates would be an indicator of

spreads near business-cycle peaks in

this ultimate sense must mean management of the monetary base that will
lower or raise the trend inflation rate.

and 1980, we

negatively sloped yield curve is abnormal. Certainly, for the United States in
this century, a negative slope is not typical: only II episodes have occurred

yields if we could not know the values
of the expected real rate of return and
the risk premium.

the same could be said about a higher
level of short-term rates or about a
lower level of base money. Second, it is
not necessarily true that today's narrower spread is tighter than yesterday's

1957,1960,1969,1973,

know, with hindsight, that monetary
policy was not tight enough because
the trend inflation rate was rising
during much of the period.
• Yield Curve Inversions
A widespread presumption in financialmarket commentary seems to be that a

Consider the sequential episodes of
rising interest rates during the postwar

tion of a current two-year yield lower
than 9.2 percent and a one-year yield
higher than 9.0 percent would be re-

ments would be a more reliable indicator of tightening than rising
short-term rates, because increased expected inflation incorporated in both

spread represents tighter policy than an
alternative wider spread. This is not a
powerful conclusion, however, because

abandoned any specific gold parity in
1973, the trend rate of inflation is
primarily the result of central-bank
money creation. Tightness or ease in

2

Lacking that knowledge, a narrowing
positive yield spread between representative short- and long-term instru-

the future. Interpreting the slope of the
yield curve would require additional information to be free of this ambiguity.

9.2 percent while one-year issues yield
9.0 percent, the implication seems to
be that the one-year yield one year
from now is expected to be 9.4 per-

9.5r------------------------,

result in lower future short-term rates,
as in the prior numerical example, if
we could know that the trend inflation
rate and the long-term yield were unchanging.

slope might reflect perceptions that the
inflation rate would rise steadily into

A yield curve seems suggestive of
investors' expectations about future
levels of yields. For example, if twoyear issues currently are priced to yield

Percent

rates might be an indicator of tighter
policy in a different sense, reflecting a
short-run stringency in the supply of
base money. This would be expected to

with any certainty. Figure 2 illustrates
the difficulties of interpreting the yield
spread. First, it is trivially true that at
any point in time a narrower yield

• The Yield Curve as an Indicator
A policy indicator registers tightness
and ease, but what do those words
mean? Ultimately, the unique function
of the central bank in the U.S. economy
is to determine the trend rate of inflation. This function was once performed
by gold, but since the United States

than on any other available security.

Increases in the level of short-term

_FIGURE1
YIELD CURVESa

-2.5

a. Spread is the difference between the Treasury 1O-year and one-year
constant-maturity
yield. Shaded areas represent periods of recession. Last date
plotted is February 1989.
SOURCE: Monthly averages from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release H.1S.

• Recent Experience
The yield curve became quite flat in
December 1988, with the 30-year yield
to maturity 10 basis points lower than
the IO-year yield. However, this hardly

Even Treasury debt is not completely

quired to forestall portfolio shifts from

market perceptions of tighter policy if

uniform, so that differences in yields
among 250 or so marketable issues are
not due solely to maturity. "Flower
bonds," for example, now yield about 5

one-year to two-year securities.

we could know that the expected real
rate of return plus the risk premium in
long-term rates were constant.

percentage points less than other issues
of comparable maturity because the
Treasury must accept these old bonds
at par in payment of estate taxes.
Similarly, market yields may differ between high- and low-coupon bonds,
and between unstripped and stripped
bonds (those with coupons removed
and sold separately), reflecting different valuations of coupon income
and capital value at maturity.
These and other differentiating features
illustrate that the yield curve is an
abstraction that should be used with caution. Constant-maturity yields underlying the yield curve in figure I are not actual market yields, but rather estimates
of what yields on actively traded issues
would have been had comparable issues
of such maturities been in existence.
There is no basis for calculating a margin of error, but changes in constantmaturity yields and yield spreads of perhaps five to ten basis points and for
only one or two weeks should be interpreted with skepticism. I
• Expectations in the Yield Curve
Actual yields are set in markets. Ignoring questions of risk for the moment,
traders and investors will hold a particular security when their expectation of
total return before a future date (that is,
coupon payment plus expected change
in market price) is no better or worse

While a yield curve may suggest expected future yields, precise future
yields cannot be derived from a yield
curve. One must first know the
premiums that investors require to compensate them for the risk that realized
short-term yields on long-maturity assets will differ from expectations. Only
by assuming constant risk premiums
can one reach the popular presumption
that a change in the slope of the curve
reflects a change in expectations. For
example, a flattening of the curve
means that current short-term interest
rates have risen relative to future shortterm interest rates only if risk premiums
in long-term yields have not dropped.
A further ambiguity should be noted.
An expectation of rising or falling
nominal interest rates reflects beliefs
both about future real interest rates and
about future inflation. Thus, a steep
positive slope in the yield curve might
reflect perceptions of a very low real
rate of interest at the shortest end of the
curve because of weakness in the real
economy that, once passed, would bring
a resumption of stable growth at a
stable inflation rate. Alternatively, the

cent.

If the future one-year rate in this

example were expected to be lower
than 9.4 percent, then some combina-

short- and long-term rates would not be
mistaken for tighter policy. However,
the yield spread still would be no more
reliable an indicator than long-term

since 1910. Excluding the period 1930
through 1951, when they were prevented by the Great Depression and
then by Federal Reserve wartime rate-

7.5

pegging, inversions have appeared
every six years, on average.
The most common explanation for a
normal upward slope is that, in a grow-

6.5

ing economy in stable equilibrium at a
stable trend inflation rate, yields on
longer-term debt instruments would be
higher than those on shorter-term instruments, even though the series of future
short-term rates was expected to be flat.
a. Three-month, six-month, and one-year U.S. Treasury instruments are quoted
from the secondary market on a yield basis; all other instruments are constantmaturity series.

Of course, we cannot know these things

wider spread, because we cannot know
that the real return and risk premium in
long-term yields is unchanged. Third,
we do not know whether a given rate
spread is too tight, or not tight enough,
to stabilize trend inflation.

SOURCE:

Monthly averages from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release H.1S.

_FIGURE2
YIELD SPREAD CYCLESa
Percent
3.01TT--rr-,.------r-r-IT---rrIT------,
2.5
2.

O.OH-+-"WII--+H---H~r-Hr_+t-tt_-+-1l1Httt+_--~~
-0.5

This positive spread would reflect the
risk premium required to compensate
risk-averse investors for greater uncertainty about more distant events.r'
With a longer historical perspective, a
negative slope seems less unusual.
Prior to the Great Depression, business
cycles left their mark on short-term
rates, but had relatively less impact on
long-term rates-perhaps
because the
gold standard was a
anchor for the trend
the central bank has
gold standard began

more credible
inflation rate than
been since the
to break down.

Maintaining convertibility of the dollar
into gold at a fixed price meant that
the trend inflation rate incorporated in
bond yields could not deviate far from
zero for any length of time. The yield
curve therefore might have been expected to pivot around a relatively
stable long-term yield.

-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-3.0
-3.5 LLU..L..L.~~'-LI~"""""L....L:-~&..L.-:':':~..&...J.~~oLI.:'~I...L...L.I:-~

Reductions in the level of long-term

period. Despite successively greater
cyclical swings of the yield spread in
figure 2 from plus to minus, and
despite successively wider negative

interest rates would be an indicator of

spreads near business-cycle peaks in

this ultimate sense must mean management of the monetary base that will
lower or raise the trend inflation rate.

and 1980, we

negatively sloped yield curve is abnormal. Certainly, for the United States in
this century, a negative slope is not typical: only II episodes have occurred

yields if we could not know the values
of the expected real rate of return and
the risk premium.

the same could be said about a higher
level of short-term rates or about a
lower level of base money. Second, it is
not necessarily true that today's narrower spread is tighter than yesterday's

1957,1960,1969,1973,

know, with hindsight, that monetary
policy was not tight enough because
the trend inflation rate was rising
during much of the period.
• Yield Curve Inversions
A widespread presumption in financialmarket commentary seems to be that a

Consider the sequential episodes of
rising interest rates during the postwar

tion of a current two-year yield lower
than 9.2 percent and a one-year yield
higher than 9.0 percent would be re-

ments would be a more reliable indicator of tightening than rising
short-term rates, because increased expected inflation incorporated in both

spread represents tighter policy than an
alternative wider spread. This is not a
powerful conclusion, however, because

abandoned any specific gold parity in
1973, the trend rate of inflation is
primarily the result of central-bank
money creation. Tightness or ease in

2

Lacking that knowledge, a narrowing
positive yield spread between representative short- and long-term instru-

the future. Interpreting the slope of the
yield curve would require additional information to be free of this ambiguity.

9.2 percent while one-year issues yield
9.0 percent, the implication seems to
be that the one-year yield one year
from now is expected to be 9.4 per-

9.5r------------------------,

result in lower future short-term rates,
as in the prior numerical example, if
we could know that the trend inflation
rate and the long-term yield were unchanging.

slope might reflect perceptions that the
inflation rate would rise steadily into

A yield curve seems suggestive of
investors' expectations about future
levels of yields. For example, if twoyear issues currently are priced to yield

Percent

rates might be an indicator of tighter
policy in a different sense, reflecting a
short-run stringency in the supply of
base money. This would be expected to

with any certainty. Figure 2 illustrates
the difficulties of interpreting the yield
spread. First, it is trivially true that at
any point in time a narrower yield

• The Yield Curve as an Indicator
A policy indicator registers tightness
and ease, but what do those words
mean? Ultimately, the unique function
of the central bank in the U.S. economy
is to determine the trend rate of inflation. This function was once performed
by gold, but since the United States

than on any other available security.

Increases in the level of short-term

_FIGURE1
YIELD CURVESa

-2.5

a. Spread is the difference between the Treasury 1O-year and one-year
constant-maturity
yield. Shaded areas represent periods of recession. Last date
plotted is February 1989.
SOURCE: Monthly averages from the Federal Reserve Statistical Release H.1S.

• Recent Experience
The yield curve became quite flat in
December 1988, with the 30-year yield
to maturity 10 basis points lower than
the IO-year yield. However, this hardly

March 15, 1989

qualified as an inversion. Occasional

I 7 business-cycle

episodes of a monthly average 3D-year
yield as much as 23 basis points lower
than the lO-year yield have appeared
over the past five years without the in-

(1926, 1945, 1948, and 1953). Emergence of a negative spread between the
one-year and lO-year maturities has
preceded each business-cycle peak

version subsequently spreading across a
broader range of the maturity spectrum.

since 1953, by an average of 10
months and within a range of eight to
16 months. On the other hand, a yieldcurve inversion has not always been associated with a business-cycle peak

Longest-term yields may be biased
downward because the innovation of
stripping has removed from the market
almost half of the par value of all
Treasury securities with maturities
longer than 17 years. Yields in the
longest maturity range may include a
smaller risk premium than in the intermediate range, reflecting the liquidity
assurance this additional source of
demand provides for portfolio investors in those bonds.
By the end of February 1989, inversion
undoubtedly had set in, with a peak
yield at two years, which was 36 basis
points above the 3D-year bond, but
still 53 basis points above the threemonth bill. Actually, inversion has extended all the way back to the threemonth yield on only two occasions in
the postwar period (one month in
1974 and six months in 1980-81).
With the February inversion
speculation about recession.
of some portion of the yield
been associated with all but

came
Inversion
curve has
four of the

peaks since 1910

and recession. False signals were
registered in 1965-67 (lasting 14
months), again in 1967 (one month),
and in 1968 (five months).
•

Conclusion

Changes in yield spreads are an ambiguous indicator of monetary policy, at
best, but so too are all intermediate indicators. The year-old narrowing and
recent inversion of the yield curve does
indicate that policy is tighter now than
it would be if the spread were positive
and wider, but that is not very useful information. Moreover, spreads can and
do change rapidly without any overt
policy actions, as swings in market sentiment change market yields.
The fundamental question is whether
the current yield curve reflects a
policy that is "too easy," so that the
trend inflation rate will continue to
rise. The yield curve fails to answer
that question.

•

eCONOMIC
COMMeNTaRY

Footnotes

1. The yield curve shown in figure 1 and

pictured in many publications is based on
data in the Federal Reserve's weekJy H.IS
release. The three-month, six-month, and oneyear maturity yields are composites of actual
yields reported by five dealers for the most
recent issues. Beyondthe one-year maturity,
however, the values are estimates of the
yields that would have emerged in active
trading had issues of the designated
maturities actually existed. The values are
taken from the Treasury's continuous yield
curve "fitted by eye" for actively traded issues, which tend to be the most recent issues.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Is There a Message in
the Yield Curve?

1

2. (1.092)2/ (1.090) = 1.094.
3. Other explanations are postulated for a

positive yield spread. One is that longer-term
instruments must provide a premium to compensate investors for lesser liquidity.Another
is that the nonnal slope would be either negative or positive, depending on whether
predominant coupon rates tend to be high or
low compared to the normal range within
which yields are expected to vary.

by E.J. Stevens

T

he yield curve, relating market
yields to the maturity of debt instruments, began to invert at the end of
1988. As yields on shorter-term
securities rose above those on longerterm securities, questions arose about
the significance of a downward-sloped
yield curve.

E.J. Stevens is an assistant vice president
and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.

Does a negatively sloped yield curve
prove that monetary policy is tight or

The views stated herein are those of the
author and 110tnecessarily those of the

that a recession is coming? Does a
steeply positively sloped curve indicate
that monetary policy is easy or that inflation will accelerate?

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

The Federal Reserve System could

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

produce recessions and decelerating inflation, or booms and accelerating inflation, by allowing the monetary base to

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

grow too slowly or too rapidly for sustained periods of time. Policy analysts
employ a variety of indicators to try to
distinguish between "too" slowly and
rapidly, between tightness and ease,
with fashions in indicators varying
over the years and among analysts.

the broader monetary aggregates, M2
and M3, to communicate its policy intentions to Congress and the public.
Policy analysts also use as indicators
the gap between actual and capacity
GNP and the gap between actual and
full employment.
Each of these is an intermediate indicator between the ultimate results of
policy, which are measured by actual
trend rates of economic growth and inflation, and day-to-day policy actions,
which are measured by changes in the
monetary base and the federal funds
rate. The yield curve can be considered
as another intermediate indicator,
blending short-term interest rates that
reflect policy actions with longer-term
interest rates that reflect investors' expectations of real returns to capital and
future inflation rates.
This Economic Commentary examines
the indicator value of the yield curve,
with the conclusion that its message is
no more distinct than those received
from other intermediate indicators.

The growth rate of the M I monetary

Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.
Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Research Department, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101
ISSN 042R·1276

aggregate was a popular indicator until
its relationship to output and prices
broke down during the 1980s under the
weight of deposit-rate deregulation and

• What Is the Yield Curve?
A yield curve plots term to maturity
against market yields to maturity on an
otherwise comparable set of debt instru-

a reversal of the postwar upward trend
in interest rates. The Federal Reserve's
policymaking arm, the Federal Open
Market Committee, continues to set an-

ments. A typical curve uses yields on
U.S. Treasury securities, so that differences in credit quality will not distort the relationship between yield and

nual target ranges for growth rates of

maturity (see figure I).

-

Short-term bond yields have moved
above long-term bond yields over the

past year. The resulting inverted
yield curve indicates that monetary
policy is tighter than it could be and
may be tighter than it has been, but
provides no basis for judging
whether policy is tight (or easy)
enough.