View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Home / Publications / Research / Economic Brief / 2021

Economic Brief
April 2021, No. 21-13

GameStop, AMC and the Self-Ful lling Beliefs of Stock
Buyers
Article by: Gaston Chaumont, Grey Gordon and Bruno Sultanum

The recent stock market gyrations of GameStop and AMC Entertainment illustrate
that companies' fates can sometimes hinge on self-ful lling beliefs. Pessimistic
expectations can raise the specter of bankruptcy, while optimistic expectations
can allow for survival and eventual success. We show how it is sometimes
possible for small coalitions of buyers — such as those that formed on the online
forum Reddit — to tip the balance in favor of an optimistic scenario. By doing so,
a coalition can reap large pro ts and fundamentally improve a company's
prospects.

A cash-strapped company's survival can depend on the self-ful lling beliefs of investors. It is
possible for the company to fall prey to a vicious cycle in which pessimistic expectations bar
it from raising additional funds and thereby force it into bankruptcy. Alternatively, the
company may bene t from a virtuous cycle in which optimistic expectations permit it to
raise additional funds and thereby allow it to survive and even prosper.
These divergent possibilities were demonstrated by the recent market swings of GameStop
(GME) and AMC Entertainment (AMC). The pessimistic cases for GME and AMC were
obvious: Reduced tra c at malls and movie theaters, respectively, decimated their
revenues, and the persistence of these tough operating conditions could have saddled the
companies, which were heavily indebted, with even larger debt burdens, possibly resulting
in bankruptcy. Many hedge funds acted on this pessimistic view by "short selling" the
companies' stocks.1
But there were also optimistic cases to be made for GME and AMC. Michael Burry (the
investor portrayed in The Big Short movie) argued that GME, a retailer of video games and
consoles, was given an extension for its current business model when manufacturers
revealed that next-gen video consoles would continue to include physical media.2 As for the
movie-theater chain AMC, it had been pro table before the pandemic and could
conceivably be so afterward, provided it could continue servicing its debts.
In dramatic fashion, the now famous (or infamous) Reddit WallStreetBets (WSB coalition)
appears to have tipped the balance in favor of the optimistic scenarios for GME and AMC.
By buying large quantities of the companies' stock, the WSB coalition drastically bid up the
share prices. For example, a $10,000 investment in GME shares on Jan. 4 was worth
$250,000 on Jan. 28. This giant leap in GME's price increased the mark-to-market value of
outstanding shares by $20 billion and cost hedge funds (who were shorting the stock) $12.5
billion, according to one report.3 The story was similar for AMC.
For both AMC and GME, the emergence of optimistic scenarios turned out to have very real
e ects on the companies' fundamentals. On Jan. 28, AMC issued 44.4 million shares and
paid o $600 million in debt. Notably, its share price went up when it announced this plan,
indicating that buyers, sellers and holders of the stock believed on average that it was
worth diluting the existing shares to recapitalize the company. As for GME, it announced a
3.5 million share stock o ering on April 5 worth approximately $670 million at April 5
prices.4 The company may use those proceeds to pay o some of its $485 million in debt,5
and GME had said previously it was considering issuing stock to fund its new focus on ecommerce.6
By buying GME and AMC stock aggressively, the WSB coalition reaped massive rewards and
fundamentally improved the companies' prospects. Of course, it is di cult to say how well
GME and AMC will fare in the future, but they are much stronger nancially and better
positioned to take advantage of demand increases if they occur.

A Model of Self-Ful lling Expectations
Our research sheds light on the stock price dynamics of GME and AMC.7 We built a model
of a company that is fundamentally solvent but illiquid in the sense that it needs access to
nancial markets to continue operating. In the model, both pessimistic and optimistic
outcomes are mathematically possible, and only investor expectations determine which
outcome will occur.8 In the model's optimistic scenario, the company is able to nance
productive investments that increase the company's fundamental and market values. In the
pessimistic scenario, the company is forced to cease operations.
We show that when the pessimistic case is initially expected, there is an arbitrage
opportunity — that is, an ability to make riskless pro t — for a coalition of investors.
Provided that the coalition has su cient buying power, it can bid up the value of the
company's securities, thereby allowing the company to raise money by issuing additional
shares. By doing so, the coalition can e ectively push the company into the optimistic
outcome. A key result of the model is that a pessimistic outcome cannot be sustained if
investors anticipate a "short squeeze" — that is, an aggressive bidding up of the stock price
by the coalition of buyers.9 Importantly, the model does not require the coalition to invest
in a bubble or be irrational. However, the model does require that the coalition can buy
additional shares, which became impossible at a number of brokerages at the peak of the
short-squeeze turmoil in the case of GME and AMC.
The model provides a natural explanation of the recent stock price swings of GME and AMC
(shown in Figure 1). Speci cally, early this year, the market appeared to anticipate that a
pessimistic outcome would prevail and did not expect a short squeeze. However, as buying
by the WSB coalition intensi ed, the companies' stock prices increased substantially, and
investors became increasingly aware that a coalition of optimistic investors existed and that
a short squeeze was happening. This condition temporarily ceased when trading
restrictions were put in place during late January amid rallies in the companies' stock prices.
After the restrictions hit, GME and AMC stock prices declined. However, those restrictions
have been lifted. And, with the possibility of a short squeeze now rmly in investors' minds,
GME and AMC stock prices have remained at elevated levels.

Enlarge
Methodology
We use a theoretical model with many potential investors and a single rm. There are three
periods in the model — zero, one and two. In period one, the rm generates revenue but
must repay its debt (or default) and make an investment decision. We assume that if the
rm invests during period one, the revenue it would produce in period two would be
su cient to make the investment lucrative for both the rm and its investors. Crucially, the
rm does not have enough revenue in period one to make the investment and repay its
debt, so to invest, it must raise funds by issuing stock.10 If the share issuance raises enough
resources for the rm to invest, it pays out its substantial net worth as a dividend at the end
of period two and dissolves. If it is not able to invest, it liquidates — and if its debt is larger
than period-one revenue, it les for bankruptcy.
In period zero, each investor owns initial shares of stock and debt (although this
assumption can be relaxed). They then engage in trading that establishes period-zero prices
for the shares and the bonds. However, their ability to do so might be limited by trading
frictions. In period one, they again trade stock, and their total demand for shares must
equal the supply, which is the initial shares plus the newly issued shares. This trading
determines the price in period one.

We rst consider the case of competitive equilibrium, which describes what outcomes are
possible when all investors take prices as given. Second, we consider the notion of a
coalition game. In this game, a coalition of investors can coordinate their actions, but they
only do so to the extent that it is in the self-interest of each individual coalition member —
which theoretically we characterize as a Nash equilibrium.11

Results
Our rst result is a standard one in the spirit of research published in 2000 by Harold L.
Cole of the University of Pennsylvania and Timothy J. Kehoe of the University of
Minnesota.12 We show that, for certain levels of debt and revenue, there are two
competitive equilibrium outcomes: an optimistic one, where the rm stays solvent in period
one and invests; and a pessimistic one, where the rm does not invest and liquidates
(possibly through bankruptcy). Either of these outcomes can occur, with the outcome
hinging exclusively on investor beliefs. In both outcomes, the price of the new shares issued
by the rm is competitive and does not entail a risk-adjusted pro t or loss for investors. The
pessimistic outcome features low prices for shares in periods zero and one and a low price
for bonds in period zero, while the optimistic outcome features high prices for shares and
bonds. In other words, the optimistic outcome is better for all investors than the pessimistic
one.
Our main result concerns the coalition game. We show that in the pessimistic outcome, an
arbitrage opportunity for a small coalition exists. Taking advantage of this opportunity
requires two steps. First, the investors in the coalition must buy stock or debt at extremely
cheap prices. For convenience, we assume investors already own debt in period zero, so
this step is not necessary; however, that assumption can be relaxed. Second, the coalition
of investors executes a short squeeze, o ering to buy the newly issued shares at their
optimistic values in an amount su cient to fund the rm's investment. At this price, the
coalition does not make pro t on purchasing the additional shares, but it does make a
massive return on the stock and/or debt it acquired in the rst step. When the coalition can
execute this strategy, the pessimistic-equilibrium prices cannot prevail.
Taking advantage of this arbitrage opportunity requires the coalition to collectively buy
shares at elevated prices. Therefore, the coalition members must jointly have enough
wealth or credit to do this. Additionally, the coalition's success requires the ability to buy
shares. In the actual case of GME and AMC, this last requirement was not met: At the peak
of the run-up, the popular trading rm Robinhood and other brokers drastically restricted
the ability of investors to buy shares.13 This coincided with the break in the explosive
growth in prices. (See Figure 1.) However, the ability to trade has improved, meaning the
threat of a short squeeze continues. And, according to the model, the threat alone is
enough to rule out the pessimistic outcome.

Conclusion
A company's survival sometimes depends on the beliefs of investors. If investors have faith
in a company's long-term prospects, they may invest in its stock believing that, even though
their stakes will be diluted through new equity issuance, performance down the road will
compensate them for that loss. Conversely, if investors don't believe in a company's longterm prospects, they may sell the stock, driving down the price and limiting the rm's ability
to recapitalize by issuing additional shares. Our research shows that such a pessimistic
outcome cannot be rationalized if a small group of investors can coordinate their behavior,
buying newly issued shares in amounts su cient to keep the company solvent.
In our model, short squeezes do entail price manipulation but only in a limited sense. The
coalition of investors actively tries to bid up prices. However, the coalition does so because
it believes the rm has substantial fundamental value. And, in both the pessimistic and
optimistic outcomes, the stock trades at fair market value. Consequently, price
manipulation does not occur in the more general sense of distorting the price away from its
fair value. Regardless of the legality or ethics of such collusion, our theoretical results
indicate the threat of short squeezes (rather than the squeezes themselves) can actually
help achieve positive outcomes for investors and rms.
Gaston Chaumont is an assistant professor of economics at the University of Rochester.
Grey Gordon is a senior economist and Bruno Sultanum is an economist in the Research
Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

1

"Short selling" is a way to bet that a particular company's stock price will decline. To achieve a
short position, a short-seller borrows stock and then returns it later. If the stock price has
declined during the intervening period, the short-seller pro ts. However, if the stock price has
increased, the short-seller loses money. Since, in principle, there is no upside limit to a stock's
price, a short-seller's potential losses are also unlimited. This is why shorting a company's stock is
considered to be highly risky.
2

Ben Gilbert, "Why 'Big Short' Investor Michael Burry Is Going Long on GameStop, the VideoGame Retail Titan That's Been Crashing All Year," Business Insider, Aug. 28, 2019.
3

John McCrank, "Explainer: How Were More Than 100 Percent of GameStop's Shares Shorted,"

Reuters, Feb. 18, 2021.
4

"GameStop Announces At-The-Market Equity O ering Program," GameStop press release, April
5, 2021.
5

The company had $485.5 million in long-term debt, according to ycharts.com as of Feb. 18,
2021.

6

Maggie Fitzgerald, "GameStop Shares Fall 33 Percent on Lack of Transformation Detail, Possible
Share Sale," CNBC.com, March 23, 2021.
7

Gaston Chaumont, Grey Gordon and Bruno Sultanum, "Eliminating Pessimistic Outcomes
Through Collusion and Arbitrage: The Case of GameStop and AMC," Manuscript, 2021.
8

Our related work explores similar ideas in the context of sovereign default. See Chaumont,
Gordon and Sultanum, "Self-Ful lling Debt Crises and Limits to Arbitrage," Manuscript, 2021.
9

We use the term "short squeeze" loosely to mean bidding up share prices. More generally, a
short squeeze refers to the interaction between purchasers of a stock and short-sellers.
Speci cally, short-sellers borrow shares, expecting the share price to go down. If the share price is
bid up by purchasers, the short-sellers may either have to put up more collateral (make margin
calls) or buy the stock (cover their positions). Hence, when share prices increase, short-sellers
sometimes switch from sellers to buyers, further driving up the price. GameStop was particularly
vulnerable to such a short squeeze because there was more short interest than outstanding
shares — consequently, there were not enough shares in existence for all the short-sellers to
cover their positions simultaneously. Our model allows for short-selling, but at both the
pessimistic and optimistic price, there is no short-selling, so the model does not feature a short
squeeze in this traditional sense.
10

We can obtain the same results if we consider the issuance of new debt instead of equity.

However, the case for equity is the relevant one for the current application.
11

The Nash equilibrium of a game is a set of player strategies such that each player's strategy is
optimal when taking into account the strategies of all the other players.
12

Harold L. Cole and Timothy J. Kehoe, "Self-Ful lling Debt Crises," Review of Economic Studies,
January 2000, vol. 67, no. 1, pp. 91–116.
13

Mengqi Sun, "Robinhood Faces Civil Lawsuits Over Trading Restrictions," Wall Street Journal,

Feb. 3, 2021.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors,
source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement
below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Subscribe to Economic Brief

Receive an email noti cation when Economic Brief is posted online:
Email address

Subscribe

Contact Us
Karl Rhodes
(804) 697-8144

© 1997-2021 Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond