View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Home / Publications / Research / Economic Brief / 2024

Economic Brief
February 2024, No. 24-05

Diverging Trends in Market Concentration
By Nicholas Trachter and Lindsay Li

Researchers at the University of Chicago and the Richmond Fed uncover a
paradoxical trend of rising national market concentration and falling local
concentration across major economic sectors. Top firms — often thought to
displace local businesses — are found to instead accelerate this divergence by
enhancing (rather than stifling) local competition upon entry. This challenges
prevailing narratives that top firms wield the market power to negatively impact
consumer welfare by geographically expanding.
Market concentration measures the distribution of market shares among competitors, with
high measured market concentration implying that a small number of firms capture a large
market share within an industry. In highly concentrated markets, with limited alternatives
available to consumers, dominant firms may have lower incentives to engage in aggressive
price competition (that is, lower prices) or to innovate. More broadly, firms with particularly
large market shares may have the market power to engage in anti-competitive practices,
influencing prices and other market conditions to their advantage. This proves detrimental
for consumer outcomes while allowing these firms to enjoy high markups and profits.
While markups provide the ideal piece of evidence to gauge the extent of market power,
measuring them is challenging. The connection between market concentration and market
power is more tenuous, but market concentration is easy to measure. Thus, pundits,
policymakers and researchers usually use market concentration measures as indicators of
market power.
Since 1990, an increase in market concentration at the national level has been well
documented for nearly all industries. As such, concerns have been raised about this
increasing national market concentration and its perceived link to lower competition and

rising market power in product markets. Antitrust and regulatory bodies are called upon to
monitor (and, if necessary, break up) large corporations like those considered "big tech"
and "big retail," among many others.
Yet a key detail that should give pause is that product markets are not countrywide in
nature. For most industries, transportation costs induce firms to operate close to
customers, and travel costs induce customers to patronize local stores. Even in the internet
age, most product markets are local, so national market measures may be far-removed
from measures at the more relevant local levels. Indeed, my (Nicholas') paper "Diverging
Trends in National and Local Concentration" — co-authored with Esteban Rossi-Hansberg
and Pierre-Daniel Sarte — finds that this is the case.

Local Market Concentration Trends Are Decreasing on
the Whole
A well-known measure of market concentration is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI),
calculated by summing the squares of the market shares of competing firms. Using the
National Establishment Time Series dataset — which comprises the universe of U.S. firms
and their establishments between 1990 and 2014 — we construct HHI measures in two
ways.
In the first way, for each industry, the whole country is considered to be the relevant
market, and market shares are constructed accordingly. Then, the HHI for each industry is
aggregated to produce the overall HHI measure, weighting industries by their employment
level. In the second way, local markets are considered as the relevant unit, and the local HHI
for each industry is aggregated into the overall HHI by averaging the different local-industry
markets, where each local-industry market is weighted by its local-industry employment
level.
Figures 1 and 2 illustrate trends in the average change in overall HHI since 1990 for
different definitions of industry classification and local markets. Industry-wise, these
definitions consist of Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) 2, SIC 4, SIC 6 and SIC 8.
Geographically, these definitions consist of the U.S. as a whole, individual counties, corebased statistical areas (CBSAs) and ZIP codes, as seen in Figure 1. Divergence in market
concentration at the national level and at these disaggregated levels is clear. And the more
disaggregated the measure of concentration, the greater the divergence from aggregated
measures.

Enlarge
We also document that this diverging pattern holds across all major sectors within the
broader economy — manufacturing; services; retail trade; wholesale trade; and finance,
insurance and real estate (FIRE) — as seen in Figure 2. In fact, industries where national
concentration is increasing but local concentration decreasing account for roughly 70
percent of employment and sales in the nation. The divergence is pervasive. How should we
think about this seemingly paradoxical fact?

Enlarge
What's Behind These Diverging Trends? The Surprising
Role of Top Firms
As it turns out, top firms (in terms of share of sales) influence these documented diverging
trends in a marked and perhaps unexpected manner. Figure 3 considers SIC 8 industries
exhibiting diverging trends and depicts the same object of average change in HHI but
excludes the top firm. National concentration ends up being lower, which is expected since
the most concentrated firm has been excluded. But more surprisingly, local concentration is
higher. That is, top firms have contributed to both the increase in national concentration as
well as the decrease in local concentration. In other words, they've accelerated the
divergence of the two.

Enlarge
The underlying effect of top firms in influencing concentration becomes more striking when
looking at what happens when an establishment associated with a top firm enters a local
market. Figure 4 presents such an event study for all SIC 8 industries with diverging trends,
where the HHI change is normalized to zero in the year prior to entry.

Enlarge
After entry, local concentration falls, and this decline is persistent for at least the following
seven years. Crucially, this persistent reduction in local concentration stands in contrast to
the same scenario with the top firm excluded from the analysis: Absent local entry,
concentration would remain essentially unchanged over the seven-year timespan.
Accordingly, entry of the top firm is the main driving factor behind the observed effect on
concentration.
Such findings shed some light on the dynamic between top firms and local businesses:
Prevailing narratives may hold that the former outcompetes and displaces the latter. The
actual situation is more complex. Top firms, it appears, are not systematically driving out
and replacing smaller local stores. This is true even for firms with nationwide reach and
recognition like Walmart. A case studied in more detail in the paper, Walmart's opening of a
new establishment is associated not only with a significant decline in the HHI within the ZIP
code but also with an increase in the number of local establishments. So by and large, it
seems that top firms simply add another competitor into the mix of local producers rather
than displace them.

There are, of course, cases where these firms come to dominate and outcompete local
establishments, and this pattern is more apparent among industries with increasing local
market concentration (that is, those not exhibiting diverging trends). But on the whole, and
in industries that account for the majority of U.S. employment and sales, the above
suggests that such an occurrence is not as prevalent as might be feared.

Conclusion
The conventional association between high market concentration and reduced competition,
potentially affording increased market power to top firms, warrants more nuanced
consideration when considering the localized nature of product markets. This article details
a paradoxical finding whereby national market concentration is on the rise while local
market concentration is diminishing across major economic sectors. Top firms play an
unexpected role in this interplay: In the absence of their expansion, not only national but
also local concentration trends are less pronounced, suggesting that the effect of their
entry into local markets is to act as just another competitor in the mix, rather than to
exploit market power and displace local producers. To the extent that local concentration is
associated with product market competition, then, the local entry that top firms undertake
to geographically expand (thereby increasing their national market concentration) may be
infusing more competition, not less, into the local market landscape.
As debates around antitrust policies continue, concerns over monopolization and rising
market power harming consumer welfare — on the basis of national market concentration
measures, at least — may be unfounded.
Nicholas Trachter is a senior economist and research advisor and Lindsay Li is a research
associate in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
To cite this Economic Brief, please use the following format: Trachter, Nicholas; and Li, Lindsay.
(February 2024) "Diverging Trends in Market Concentration." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Brief, No. 24-05.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors,
source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement
below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Topics

Production and Investment

Small Business

Subscribe to Economic Brief
Receive a notification when Economic Brief is posted online.
By submitting this form you agree to the Bank's Terms & Conditions and Privacy Notice.

Email Address

Subscribe

Contact Us
RC Balaban
(804) 697-8144

© 1997-2024 Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond