View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

economic brief
april 2010, eb10-04

comparing labor markets
across recessions: a Focus
on the age composition of
the population
by marianna Kudlyak,

There has been substantial debate about how to most fruitfully compare
the recent recession to those of the past. This Economic Brief seeks to
shed some light on this important issue by taking a look at a few
conventional measures of employment and output declines during
recessions dating back to 1948. Yet it diverges from the conventional
treatment of these statistics by acknowledging that the workforce today
looks different than it did in the past. One important feature of the current economy is that the population is older today. Thus, simply looking
at unadjusted versions of traditional statistics may not be the best way
to compare the state of the current economy to previous periods.

devin reilly, and Stephen Slivinski

Simply looking at unadjusted versions of
traditional statistics may not be the best
way to compare the state of the current
economy to previous periods. When
comparing recessions, it is important to
account for demographic changes.

how bad waS the recent receSSion?
To put the discussion about the recent recession in perspective, it is
important to compare it with previous episodes. Figure 1 shows the
cumulative growth rates of output and some of its components during
contractions of each postwar recession – the growth of employment
and weekly hours per employee in the nonfarm business sector (NBS).1
(Productivity growth, also a component of output, is a residual that is
not pictured here.) For our purposes, the beginning of a contraction is
defined as the first quarter in which the output growth turned negative.
As you can see, the drop in output during the 2008 contraction – which
started in the first quarter of the 2008 – was comparable to the declines
in the 1957 and 1973 contractions. However, the decline in employment
(7 percent) was much larger. In fact, it’s larger than any of the recessionary periods since World War II.
Figure 1: growth oF output and employment
during poStwar receSSionS (nonFarm buSineSS Sector)
0

Percent

-2
-4
-6
-8

Output
Employment
Hours/Week

-10
48:Q4 - 53:Q2 - 57:Q3 - 60:Q2 - 69:Q4 - 73:Q4 - 80:Q1 - 81:Q3 - 90:Q3 - 01:Q1 - 07:Q4 49:Q4 54:Q2 58:Q2 61:Q1 70:Q4 75:Q1 80:Q3 82:Q4 91:Q1 01:Q4 09:Q2

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

eb10-04 - the Federal reServe banK oF richmond

A way to gauge how quickly employment and output recovers after
each recession is to look at how many quarters it takes for the growth
rate of each measure to turn positive. For example, one may look at
employment growth during the first two quarters of each recovery.
(The beginning of a recovery is assumed to be the first quarter when the
NBS output growth turned positive. In the case of the 2008 recession,
that would be the third quarter of 2009.) By that standard, employment
growth has not picked up as quickly as it has in other recessions.2 It is
true that the first two quarters of the recovery after the 1957, 1960,
1991, and 2001 recessions also saw continued employment declines.
Yet, two quarters into the recovery, the 2001 and 2008 recessions saw
the biggest declines in employment growth when compared to prior
recessions, -1.8 percent and -1.35 percent respectively. On a positive
note, in contrast to the 2001 episode, the growth of weekly hours
per employee was small but positive in the 2008 recovery period
discussed here.
Another common measure used to gauge contraction in the labor
market is the unemployment rate. That rate reached 10 percent in the
fourth quarter of 2009, almost as high as the postwar high of 10.7 percent registered in the fourth quarter of 1982. However, looking simply
at the rate itself may not be the best way to compare recessions. The
demographic composition of the labor force differs substantially
between these two periods and that should be taken into account.
For instance, from 1982 to 2009 the share of young workers (16-19
years old) decreased from 7.6 percent to 4 percent. Typically, the unemployment rate among young workers is higher than the population as
a whole. Given these demographic changes, how does the unemployment rate in 2009 compare to the unemployment rate in 1982?
Figure 2 shows the actual and the age-adjusted unemployment rate,
which is constructed holding age composition of the labor force constant at the level present in the fourth quarter of 1982. As the figure
shows, the composition-adjusted unemployment rate in the fourth
quarter of 2009 is at a postwar high of 11.3 percent. Given that the
composition of the labor force is older today as compared to 1982, this
means that the“natural”rate of unemployment today is lower than it
was in 1982. Thus, a 10 percent unemployment rate today is likely



PAGE 2 EB10-04

Figure 2: unemployment rate,
unadjuSted and adjuSted by age
12

10

8
Percent

The decline in weekly hours worked per employee in the 2008 recession
(-2.0 percent) ranks third behind the downturns of 1969 (-3.0 percent)
and 1973 (-2.1 percent). Adding the decline in weekly hours worked
to the decline in employment puts the aggregate figure for the decline
in this component of output during the 2008 recession at almost 9
percent. Thus, the recent contraction was indeed the most severe of all
postwar contractions by this measure. The second largest decline of this
sort in the postwar period took place in the 1948 contraction when the
aggregate figure dropped 5.7 percent.

6

4
Adjusted Rate
Unadjusted Rate

2

0
1948

1953 1958

1963

1968

1973

1978

1983

1988

1993

1998

2003

2008

Source: Authors’calculations based on Bureau of Labor Statistics data.
note: Shaded areas correspond to recessions.

further from the current natural unemployment rate than the 10.7 percent rate in the 1982 recession was from the natural unemployment rate
then.3 This is consistent with the claim that labor market conditions in
the recent contraction are worse than other postwar contractions.4
labor Force participation and age
When economists consider the change in employment patterns, they
also look at a factor known as“labor force participation”(LFP). During a
recession, LFP tends to drop because workers become discouraged about
the prospects for finding a job. Thus, a large cyclical downswing in labor
force participation indicates a substantial slack in the economy. Consequently, as the economy picks up, these workers start looking for jobs,
re-enter the labor pool, and then are counted among the ranks of the
unemployed in the official statistics, which may cause a high unemployment rate to persist.
The monthly seasonally adjusted LFP rate rose steadily during much of
the postwar period, from 58.6 percent in January 1948 to a peak of 67.3
percent in March 2000. It has been falling since then, declining 2.6 percentage points by January 2010. Half of that has occurred since the beginning of the most recent recession – the LFP dropped from 66 percent
in December 2007 to 64.7 percent in January 2010. How much of the decline in the current recession is cyclical, implying that the workers will
join the labor force again when the recovery picks up, and how much is a
part of the downward trend?5
We focus on the part of the trend that is due to the aging of the population. Workers over 55 tend to have lower labor force attachment and
their share in the population has been consistently growing over the last

decade. The increase of life expectancy and the aging of the large cohort
of baby boomers have contributed to this change. Currently, the share of
persons 55 years of age and older in the total working-age population is
about 30.3 percent as compared to 26.8 percent in March 2000.

Figure 4: labor Force participation rate
adjuSted For age compoSition oF worK Force
68

Figure 3: labor Force participation rate

67

70
Percent

68
66

66

64
65

Adjusted LFP
Smoothed LFP
Unadjusted LFP

Percent

62
60
64
58

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

56

Source: Authors' calculations through December 2009 based on Bureau of Labor Statistics data.
Adjusted LFP
Smoothed LFP

54
52
50
1948

1953 1958

1963

1968

1973

1978

1983

1988

1993

1998

2003

2008

Source: Authors’calculations based on Bureau of Labor Statistics data.
note: Shaded areas correspond to recessions.

To understand how this influences the LFP, two of us (Kudlyak and
Reilly) constructed a data series that holds age composition at the level
it was at in December 2009 but reflects the actual measured LFP by age
group. As seen in Figure 3, the composition-corrected LFP doesn’t show
a noticeable and sustained downward trend after 2001 the way the official estimate does. A modest decline doesn’t appear until the middle of
2009 and it falls only to where it was in June 2005.
Figure 4 examines labor force participation since 1997. The adjusted
trend results from holding the LFP constant for each age group at the
July 1999 level (close to the highest aggregate LFP) and reflects only the
change in the age composition of the population. In fact, the aggregate
labor force participation rate was higher in 2005 and 2006 than is predicted by the age trend. These data seem to indicate that a large part of
a decline in the official labor force participation in the recent recession
is a part of a structural downward trend rather than due to a cyclical
downswing. This suggests that there will be fewer labor resources available to fuel future economic growth.

concluSion
When comparing the current recession to previous episodes, it is important to account for changes in demographics. Older Americans constitute a larger share of the entire population than we have observed in
any post-war recession. Preliminary analysis suggests that the high unemployment we have witnessed in the recent recession is much higher
in relative terms to what we have seen before. This implies that there is
much slack in the labor market. But the analysis also suggests that the
cyclical decline in labor force participation is not as high as in previous
recessions and that there are not abundant labor resources outside of
the official labor force to draw on as the economy recovers.


marianna Kudlyak is an economist at the Federal reserve bank
of richmond. devin reilly is a research associate in the bank’s
research department. Stephen Slivinski is senior editor of the
bank’s quarterly magazine, Region Focus.



EB10-04 PAGE 3

endnoteS
1

All of the numbers in this section pertain to the nonfarm business sector (NBS).

2

Based on the most recently available quarterly data available at time of publication.

3

See Robert Shimer,“Why is the U.S. Unemployment Rate So Much Lower?”NBER Macroeconomics
Annual 1998, vol. 13, pp. 11-74. This article provides a compelling argument for why the unemployment rate should be adjusted for age composition but not for education composition of the
labor force.

4

For an example of this, see Michael Elsby, Bart Hobijn, and Ayşegül Şahin,“The Labor Market in the
Great Recession,”unpublished manuscript, March 2010.

5

Note that the decline of LFP rate from its peak in 2000 cannot be explained by an increase in the
number of those who want a job but are counted as outside of the labor force.

The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal
Reserve System.