View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Home / Publications / Research / Economic Brief / 2022

Economic Brief
June 2022, No. 22-21

A Historical Perspective on Digital Currencies
By Huberto M. Ennis, Zhu Wang and Russell Wong

This article reviews private currencies in U.S. history to shed light on the
contemporary issue of digital currencies. This perspective suggests that
government interventions have a critical role in creating a well-functioning money
and payments system. Particularly, a central bank digital currency (CBDC) can be
a useful tool to supplement regulation in addressing long-standing concerns and
risks associated with private currencies.
This article is the second in a series on central bank digital currencies.

The emergence of cryptocurrencies has brought to the forefront of policy debates many
long-standing questions related to the viability of private currency, the impact of
competition on banking and payment, and how governments (and, in particular, central
banks) should address associated effects. Importantly, assuming there is significant
demand for cryptocurrencies in the current environment, a fundamental question is:
Should the U.S. central bank issue its own digital currency? Or should it instead limit itself to
regulating private digital currencies and let market mechanisms and entrepreneurial
ingenuity do the rest?
Our main focus for this discussion is private currencies, or "tokens" issued by a private
entity that, in principle, can act as an alternative medium of exchange to national fiat
currencies. Recent examples of private currencies are bitcoin and Diem (formerly Libra,
which was proposed and later withdrawn by Meta [formerly Facebook]), and historical
examples include bank notes issued by private banks. Depending on the design, private
currencies can be backed by bullion or government debt (which is how bank notes operated
in the past and most stablecoins currently operate), or they are backed by nothing at all
(which is how bitcoin operates).

Private currency used to be widespread in the U.S. before and around the creation of the
Federal Reserve System. The role of private currency has also been debated extensively in
the economics literature. The lessons learned from the past can shed light on current issues
regarding what the government's role should be with respect to digital currencies.

Private Currency in U.S. History
In the U.S., private banks issued circulating bank notes prior to the 1930s. The U.S.
government also issued currency during much of that period: Gold and silver coins have
been produced by the U.S. Mint since 1793, and the Treasury Department issued paper
currency called Demand Notes in 1861 and United States Notes starting in 1862.
The years between 1837 and 1863 are known as the free banking era: Money and payments
were, to a large extent, in turmoil. There was a large variety of distinct private notes issued
by lightly regulated state banks.1 The multiplicity of different notes facilitated
counterfeiting. Furthermore, bank notes were converted into one another at complex and
volatile exchange rates, and note holders often faced substantial redemption risks. For
currency to function effectively as a means of payment, stability of its value is critical. In this
respect, the free banking era was not ideal.
The free banking era ended with the 1863 National Banking Act.2 National banks were
chartered and regulated by the newly created Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, an
agency of the U.S. Treasury Department. Under the act, national banks issued bank notes
that were unified in design (as dictated by the federal government) and backed by
government bonds as collateral. In return, national bank notes were fully insured by the
federal government in case the issuing banks failed.
As a result, national bank notes traded at par with one another, forming a uniform currency
with minimal counterfeiting and no redemption risk. Initially, many existing state banks
continued issuing bank notes, benefiting from the lighter regulation relative to national
banks. Eventually, however, the National Banking Act was revised to impose a 10 percent
tax on bank notes issued by state banks. This drove state bank notes out of existence and
caused many state banks to convert to national banks.
Private currency during the national banking era worked rather successfully. Federal
Reserve notes were introduced in 1914 (shortly after the Fed was established), while
national bank notes continued to circulate until 1935.
Federal Reserve notes were not a superior means of payment relative to national bank
notes during that period. The initial idea behind issuing Federal Reserve notes was that,
since the supply of national bank notes was deemed not sufficiently elastic to appropriately
accommodate in times of financial distress, issuing its own notes would allow the Fed to

provide an elastic supply of currency and act as a lender of last resort.3 Eventually, issuance
of national bank notes was banned in 1935 based on concerns about the Fed's ability to
effectively control the supply of base money to appropriately conduct monetary policy.
In sum, the U.S. historical experience suggests that some government intervention plays an
important role in supporting a well-performing payments system with private currencies:
one with low transaction cost and minimal counterfeiting and that is conducive to a robust
and stable financial infrastructure. Private currencies' desirability depends on how they
function in this payments system as well as on how they affect the efficacy of monetary
policy implementation.

The Economic Debate About Private Currencies: Hayek
vs. Friedman
The roles of private currency and the lessons learned from U.S. history have been debated
in the economics literature for a long time. In fact, the intellectual roots of cryptocurrencies
such as bitcoin can be traced back to the Austrian school of economics and its criticism of
the government monopoly over fiat money.
According to Friedrich Hayek's 1976 book "Denationalisation of Money: The Argument
Refined (PDF)," instead of a national government issuing a unique currency and imposing
legal tender laws, private businesses should be allowed to issue their own forms of
currencies. That is, currency issuance should be open to competition. Currencies able to
guarantee a stable purchasing power would eliminate other less stable currencies, which
would yield an efficient monetary system.
Hayek's ideas, however, have not been broadly adopted. Rather, in his 1960 book "A
Program for Monetary Stability," Milton Friedman pointed out that "monetary
arrangements have seldom been left entirely to the market, even in societies following a
thoroughly liberal policy in other respects, and there are good reasons why this should
have been the case." According to Friedman, those good reasons are:
The high resource costs of issuing currency
The difficulty of enforcing contracts and preventing fraud
The difficulty with limiting the amount issued
Possible externalities on other parties
In general, these reasons continue to be relevant today when thinking about digital
currencies and whether or not to leave them entirely to the market.
High Costs

The resource costs of running a cryptocurrency system can be very high. Bitcoin is a striking
example: At its current level, bitcoin consumes electricity exceeding the electricity used
annually in, for example, Norway.4 Other cryptocurrencies may not rely on such huge

energy consumption, but their resource costs for monitoring and maintaining cybersecurity
can still be significant.
Fraud Possibilities

The possibility of fraud remains a challenge. Recently, there have been several major cases
of scams and financial misconduct involving digital currencies.5
Currency Overissuance

Overissuing is another relevant concern. Money is a "network good," meaning that the
value increases with the number of users. On one hand, once a centralized issuer gains a
dominant market position in the provision of currency, it may exploit the profit from
inflation without properly accounting for the losses experienced by users. On the other
hand, for decentralized digital currencies based on predetermined algorithms for their
supply, overissuance could happen on the extensive margin via excessive entrants given
that the cost of creating such a currency is relatively low.
Externalities

Externalities can be pervasive. Because private digital currencies are currently not regulated
or insured by any government, the risk of runs is high. The recent crash of stablecoin
TerraUSD is a pertinent example. Such crashes could spread to other markets, causing fire
sales and disruption in the financial sector and the economy.6 Furthermore, moral hazard
can arise if a private currency becomes deemed "too big to fail."

Adding a Central Bank Digital Currency to the Mix
With respect to issues related to providing digital currencies, the central bank could take
the role of regulator rather than direct service provider. However, we can think of various
reasons for a central bank to still consider the possibility of issuing a central bank digital
currency (CBDC) as a way to complement regulation:
Issuing private digital currencies, as we discussed before, involves significant resource
costs. A widely trusted central bank that can dominate the landscape by issuing a CBDC
could produce substantial savings for society.
A CBDC may help discipline the digital currency space, competing away fragile or
fraudulent digital currencies and, in this way, enhancing financial stability.
A CBDC may improve the central bank's payment services. In the case of the U.S., it may
also help strengthen the international reserve currency status of the dollar.
For a central bank seeking to minimize waste of resources from operating multiple private
currencies, it is important to realize that issuing a CBDC will not necessarily drive out all
private digital currencies. U.S. history instead suggests that private notes were driven out of

circulation (mainly) by taxation or regulation. Short of that, private currencies are likely to
survive and differentiate themselves from a CBDC by targeting niches and certain specific
users or by employing special pricing strategies.7
We read history as telling us that as long as private digital currencies fulfill legitimate
economic functions and do not impede the central bank's monetary policy operation, then
there would be no need for the central bank to become the monopoly issuer of digital
currency. However, the thinking around this topic is evolving, and many important
considerations remain to be thoroughly investigated before a definitive conclusion can be
reached.8

Closing Thoughts
In the past, the private currencies that circulated in the U.S. were issued by banks that
mainly operated locally with well‐understood business models. This made those institutions
relatively easy to regulate. In contrast, regulating potential issuers of digital currencies
could become a more challenging matter. Global firms (or, in some cases, global platforms
based on computer algorithms) issuing digital currencies and forming complicated
networks in multiple jurisdictions can make tight regulation a tall order.
Absent effective regulation, it seems reasonable to expect complications in payments
arrangement, possible abuse of market power and undetected systemic risk. Losing tight
control of monetary policy can also be a major concern for a central bank. Issuing a CBDC
might be a way to get ahead of these issues and keep a more orderly financial system.
Yet, there are still significant challenges in effectively rolling out a CBDC. For a CBDC to be
widely adopted, it would have to provide security, functionality and services to not be
dominated by private currencies. This, together with other policy trade-offs, makes the
appropriate design and operation of a CBDC and the question of whether to issue a CBDC
in the first place a non-trivial matter.9
All three authors are economists in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond.
Additional Resources
Follow the Series
Are There Compelling Reasons to Consider a Central Bank Digital Currency for the
U.S.?
A Historical Perspective on Digital Currencies
Why Stablecoins Fail: An Economist's Post-Mortem on Terra

Central Bank Digital Currencies and Regulatory Alternatives: the Case for
Stablecoins
Related Materials
Economic Brief, March 2021: Should the Fed Issue Digital Currency?
Economic Brief, May 2021: Should Central Banks Worry About Facebook's Diem and

Alibaba's Alipay?

Econ Focus, Second Quarter 2022: Fed Eyes Central Bank Digital Currency
Econ Focus, Fourth Quarter 2021: When Will Firms Issue Digital Currencies?
Speaking of the Economy, April 2022: The Fed's Role in Payments Innovation

1 See the 2014 working paper "The Efficiency of Private E-Money-Like Systems: The U.S.

Experience with State Bank Notes."
2 See the 2015 working paper "The Efficiency of Private E-Money-Like Systems: The U.S.

Experience with National Bank Notes."
3 See the 2015 working paper "Government and Private E-Money-Like Systems: Federal Reserve

Notes and National Bank Notes."
4 According to the 2022 article "Why Does Bitcoin Use So Much Energy?," it's estimated that

bitcoin currently consumes electricity at an annualized rate of about 127 terawatt-hours (TWh).
5 See the 2021 articles "SEC Sues BitConnect and Founder, Alleging Massive Cryptocurrency Scam

of World-Wide Investors" and "Tether's Latest Black Eye Is CFTC Fine for Lying About Reserves."
6 See the May 2022 articles "Yellen Renews Call for Stablecoin Regulation After TerraUSD

Stumble" and "Fed's Brainard Sees Need for Regulation Around Crypto Assets."
7 See, for example, the 2021 working paper "The Digitalization of Money" and the 2020 book

"Distributed Ledgers: Design and Regulation of Financial Infrastructure and Payment Systems."
8 For a related discussion of the history of private currencies and its implications for the CBDC

debate, see the forthcoming paper "Taming Wildcat Stablecoins."
9 For further discussions of the policy trade-offs from issuing a U.S. CBDC, see the 2021 article

"Should the Fed Issue Digital Currency?" and the 2022 article "Are There Compelling Reasons to
Consider a Central Bank Digital Currency for the U.S.?"

To cite this Economic Brief, please use the following format: Ennis, Huberto M.; Wang, Zhu; and

Wong, Russell. (July 2022) "A Historical Perspective on Digital Currencies." Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Economic Brief, No. 22-21.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors,
source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement
below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Subscribe to Economic Brief
Receive an email notification when Economic Brief is posted online:
Email address

Subscribe

Contact Us
RC Balaban
(804) 697-8144

© 1997-2022 Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond