View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE DISCOUNT AND DISCOUNT RATE MECHANISM

A Group of Special Studies Prepared "by
Selected Board and Reserve Bank Research Personnel

May 29, 1953

PREFACE

The studies submitted herein have the single purpose of
providing background information that m a y be helpful in finding
solutions to present-day issues of discount policy. B y
assembling relevant materials on past and current problems of
discounting and of determining discount rates these studies m a y
help to develop a f r a m e w o r k of principles for guiding S y s t e m
discount operations in the financial setting which n o w prevails.
While the objectives of the studies are primarily analytical and
educational, two of t h e m (Nos. VI and VII) are concerned with
specific approaches to current operational matters.
Early in April 1953, the B o a r d directed its senior staff
to undertake, with the cooperative help of the staffs of the
Reserve Banks, a comprehensive reexamination of the System's
discount and discount rate m e c h a n i s m . E a c h of the studies has
had the benefit of extensive critical discussion and c o m m e n t by
the S y s t e m working group participating in their preparation as
well as by the Subcommittee on Banking and Credit Policy of
the S y s t e m Research Advisory Committee. T h e y have all been
substantially revised in the light of suggestions developed in
the course of this review. In view of the complexities of the
subject matter under study, the authors naturally recognize that
substantive gaps in information and theory m a y r e m a i n in p r e s ­
ent drafts and that further revision of individual studies m a y be
needed.
T h e studies are being circulated at this time for such
help as they m a y provide in discussions of S y s t e m discount opera­
tions at the forthcoming joint meeting of the B o a r d and the
Presidents Conference to be held in Washington, D.C . , on
June m/.

M ay 29, 1953.




Revised June 1, 19$3
CONTENTS
I.

II.

III.

IV.

V.

VI.

VII.

VIII.

DEVELOPMENT OF FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT POLICY, 1919-2.3
Mona E. Dingle, Board of Governors
CRITERIA FOR CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE
Karl R. Bopp, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Charles E. Walker, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
COMPARISON OF HISTORICAL CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE
WITH CHANGES IN MARKET INTEREST RATES
Caroline H. Cagle, Board of Governors
DIFFERENTIALS IN DISCOUNT PATES AMONG FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS
Robert V. Roosa, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
APPROPRIATE AND INAPPROPRIATE USES OF RESERVE BANK CREDIT
Watrous H. Irons, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
A PREFERENTIAL RATE ON NONCONTINUOUS MEMBER BANK BORROWING
William J. Abbott, Jr., Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
TECHNIQUES FOR APPRAISING INDIVIDUAL BANK USE OF FEDERAL
RESERVE CREDIT
Robert C. Holland, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
SUMMARY AND HISTORY OF EOARD'S REGULATION A REGARDING
DISCOUNTS AFD ADVANCES BY FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS
Howard H. Hackley, Board of Governors




> /

(Each study is paged separately. Paging is shown
in the outline of studies which follows.)

OUTLINE OF STUDIES

I.

II.

DEVELOPMENT OF FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT POLICY, 1919-23
Summary and Conclusion
Special circumstances of period
Ideas concerning reserve banking action
Action taken during period
Development of theory concerning Federal
Reserve action

I - 1

Developments in Inflation, 1919-20
Banking developments
Federal Reserve action

i-5

Developments during Deflation, 1920-21
Banking developments
Federal Reserve action

i - n

Developments in Prosperity, 1922-23

1-17

CRITERIA FOR CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE
Preliminary Considerations
Influence of discount policy
The proper role of discount policy
The discount rate and market rates
Can be Devise Specific Criteria for Changes in
Discount Rates?
Criteria in the 1920*s
Recommended procedures
A moderately expansionary policy
A strongly expansionary policy
A moderately restrictive policy
A heavily restrictive policy
Should Criteria for Changes in the Discount Rate
Be Known by the Market?

HI.

I - 1

II - 1
II - 2

II - 7

II - 15

COMPARISON OF HISTORICAL CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE
WITH CHANGES IN MARKET INTEREST RATES

III - 1

Timing of Changes in the Discount and Selected
Money Market Rates

III - 1

Degree of Change in the Discount Rate and Market
Interest Rates

III - 2




OUTLINE OF STUDIES (Continued)

IV.

DIFFERENTIALS IN DISCOUNT RATES AMONG FEDERAL
RESERVE DISTRICTS
Proceeding by Stages toward a Nationwide Change in
the Discount Rate
Special District Problems Justifying Temporary
Deviations from National Policy
Regional Balance of Payments Problems
Sustained structural differences
Temporary balance of payments problems
Conclusions

IV - 1

IV - 3

IV - 6
IV - 8

IV - 13

V.

APPROPRIATE AND INAPPROPRIATE USES OF RESERVE BANK CREDIT

V - 1

VI.

A PREFERENTIAL RATE ON HONCONTINU0USMEMBER BANK BORROWING

VI - 1

VII.

Summary

VI - 1

Purpose

VI - 2

Operation

VI - 3

Advantages

VI - B

Disadvantages

VI - 6

TECHNIQUES FOR APPRAISING INDIVIDUAL BANK USE OF FEDERAL
RESERVE CREDIT

VII - 1

Appraising the Extent of Borrowing

VII - 1

Appraising Borrower Use of Funds

VII - h




June 1, 1953
OUTLINE OF STUDIES (Continued)

VIII.

SUMMARY AND HISTORY OF BOARD’S REGULATION A REGARDING
DISCOUNTS AND ADVANCES BY FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS

VIII - 1

Statutory Easis
Discounts for member banks
Advances to member banks
Discounts for Federal intermediate credit banks
Discounts and advances for individuals,
partnerships, and corporations
Paper endorsed by nonmember banks
Limit on discount of paper of one borrower
Discount rates
Responsibility of Federal Reserve Banks in
extending credit accommodations
Regulatory authority of Board of Governors

VIII - 1

Present Regulation A
General principles
Section 1. Discounts for member banks
Section 2. Advances to member banks
Section 3. General requirements as to discounts
and advances
Section h. Paper acquired from nonmember banks
Section 5. Discounts for Federal intermediate
credit banks
Section 6 . Bankers' acceptances
Appendix
Summary of principal regulatory provisions

VIII - 7

Historical Development of Regulation A
The formative years (191U-1916)
The bankers' acceptances period (1916-1923)
The period from 1923 to 1937
From 1937 to the present time
Improper use of Federal Reserve credit
Eligibility of finance paper for discount
Construction loans
Maturity of advances on eligible paper and
Government obligations
Marginal collateral
advances at par on Government obligations
Advances to member banks on any sound assets
Standards regarding real estate loans and
instalment loan paper

VIII - 20

Conclusion

VIII - ho




I.

DEVELOPMENT OF FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT POLICY, 1919-23

Summary and Conclusions

In general, the years 1919-23 constituted the formative period
in Federal Reserve policy.

During this period considerable progress

was made in the development of a mechanism for influencing credit and
monetary developments.

The mechanism in use during this period in­

cluded qualitative discount policy as well as discount rate action and
also the beginning of open market operations.

By the end of the period

these instruments were employed in much the same way as throughout the
later twenties and early thirties.
Prior to 1917 the problem of organizing the System, together
with the liquidity of the money market resulting in part from a gold
inflow, had prevented the taking of much positive action designed to
influence credit conditions.

Thereafter, all other aims had been

subordinated to the financing of the war.
During the period 1919-23, however, action began to be taken
to influence the level of economic activity and prices.

The particular

form of action was influenced by the peculiar conditions of the period,
as well as by prevailing theories of central banking.

The experiments

which had limited success, or which were manifestly appropriate only
to special circumstances, were discarded, and from the experience of
the period developed a considerable part of the philosophy of reserve
banking action which was to prevail during the 1920 's.




I - 1

Special Circumstances of Period
The following special features which characterized the condition
of the banking system and of the economy in general during the period
were significant for the credit and monetary actions which were taken:
(1) The condition of the banking system and of the
economy in general in 1919 was strongly influenced by the war
which had just ended. In particular, commercial bank portfolios
contained large quantities of loans made to enable customers to
purchase Government securities, as -well as Government securities
purchased for their own accounts, and the banks had become heavily
indebted to the Federal Reserve Banks in obtaining the reserve
funds needed to meet the currency outflow and to support the in­
crease in deposits resulting from the credit expansion. Treasury
financing operations throughout 1919 hampered the application of
measures designed to curb inflation.
(2) There were special difficulties in agricultural
areas in the period 1920-21. Loans to farmers proved impossible
to liquidate, and many banks in agricultural areas were highly
illiquid.
(3)
Many individual banks had unsound assets and in­
adequate capital; hence in supplying credit the Federal Reserve
Banks considered the solvency of borrowing banks as well as the
need of the economy for credit.
(U) The reserves of the Federal Reserve Banks were
subject to extreme influences over the period. Throughout 1920
the reserves of all Reserve Banks combined were only slightly
above legal requirements, and during the period 19 19 -2 1 indi­
vidual Reserve Banks had to borrow heavily from other Reserve
Banks at various times in order to maintain their required
reserves.
After 1921 there was such a high combined reserve
ratio as the result of the gold inflow, together with the
decrease in Federal Reserve liabilities resulting from the
return of currency from circulation, that the expansion possible
on the basis of these reserves would have been strongly inflationary.
Ideas Concerning Reserve Banking Action
The measures taken during the period were influenced by the
following ideas concerning credit regulation which were reflected




1 - 2

in the Federal Reserve Act or which were held widely enough to have some
influence on measures taken:
(1) It was believed in some quarters that a considerable
liquidation of commercial bank and Federal Reserve Bank credit and
a decline in prices were necessary.
(2) A philosophy which had been written into the Federal
Reserve Act, and which was widely accepted, was that the regulation
of credit should be concerned to a large extent with its qualita­
tive rather than its quantitative aspect, and hence that a major
task of the Federal Reserve was to see that borrowing commercial
banks used its credit for "productive" rather than "speculative"
purposes.
(3)
Closely related was the philosophy that the amount
of Federal Reserve credit to which individual banks were entitled
was related to their contribution to Federal Reserve lending power,
and hence that Federal Reserve action should be concerned with the
distribution of indebtedness among member banks.
(Li) It was widely believed that the discount rate
should be above some other rates, either market or customer
rates, on the identity of which there was not agreememt, and
that the discount rate should not be lowered as long as these
other rates were above it.
(5) There was widespread belief, on the basis of gold
standard theory, that discount rates and credit policy in general
should be influenced by the reserve ratios of the Reserve Banks.
(6 ) It was widely believed that the development of
a bankers' acceptance market should be fostered for the purpose
of increasing the importance of the United States in the finan­
cing of international trade and also developing a liquid asset
considered suitable for bank reserve adjustment.
Action Taken During Period
The following special features characterized Federal Reserve
action during this period:
(1) There was a complicated structure of discount rates
on different types of paper at the beginning of the period.
(2) Basic discount rates were raised only after infla­
tion was well under way and market rates had risen, and lowered
only after deflation had been in progress for almost a year and
market rates had begun to decline.




1 - 3

(.3) For a limited period of time four Federal Reserve
Banks imposed progressive rates on borrowings in excess of a
member bank's basic line of credit, which was generally defined
in terms of its legal reserves and ownership of Federal Reserve
stock.
();)

The use of moral suasion was relied on heavily.

($) The Federal Reserve buying rate on bankers'
acceptances was relatively low during most of the period.
(6 ) Individual Reserve Banks nought Government securi­
ties in 1922 for the purpose of improving their earning positions
and without regard to the influence of their actions on general
credit conditions.
Development of Theory Concerning Federal Reserve Action
The following points summarize the effects which the experience
during this early period had on Federal Reserve philosophy and action
in the latter 1920 »s:
(1) It was explicitly recognized that the quantitative
aspect of credit regulation is important. Attention was still
paid to the importance of qualitative influence, however; and this
aspect was to assume special importance again in 1928 - 29.
(2) It was clearly recognized that there is not
necessarily a close relationship between the paper offered for
discount and the use made of the proceeds of discounting.
This
recognition led to a discontinuation of differential rates,
which were not used again until 19b2 and then only for Govern­
ment securities.
(3) Somewhat more emphasis began to be placed on the
choice of a discount rate that would be appropriate in view of
existing conditions in the economy, and somewhat less emphasis
to be placed on rationing or moral suasion. This shift was
evidenced in part by the abandonment of progressive discount
rates. Surveillance of borrowing member banks by Reserve Banks
was continued, however, and moral suasion again assumed special
importance in 1928 -29.
(U) It was believed that the Reserve Banks should supply
credit freely in a period of depression. Only in the next decade
was it recognized that banks should be freed from debt in a period
of deep depression and of strong pressure for liquidity.




I -U

(5 ) It was concluded that the reserve ratio of the
Federal Reserve Banks should not determine credit and monetarypolicy under conditions such as faced the United States during
1922-23.
(6 ) The idea that Federal Reserve credit should be
made available to banks according to their contribution to
Federal Reserve lending power was abandoned.
(7) It was explicitly recognized not only that open
market operations affect reserves, but also that they are likely
to be followed by a movement in the opposite direction in the
level of discounts.
(8 ) It was apparently recognized that some tightening
or easing action should be taken earlier in an upswing or down­
swing than was characteristic in the period 1919-1921. The se­
quence among open market operations, changes of market interest
rates, and changes in the discount rate had not been worked out,
however.
(9)
Approximately the pattern of regional discount
rate relations which was to prevail until 1928 had been e stablished. Differentials in rates among districts were small,
however, and there was not general agreement as to the extent
to which such differentials should prevail.
(10)
The desire to foster the growth of a bankers'
acceptance market resulted in the maintenance of relatively
low buying rates on acceptance paper throughout the 1920 »s.
After the middle of the decade, however, the buying rates were
set with a view also to the seasonal reserve needs of the banks.
Developments in Inflation, 1919-20
Commercial banks were heavily in debt to the Federal Reserve
Banks when inflationary developments resumed in 1919.

During the war

investors had been encouraged to purchase Liberty bonds and to finance
their purchases by borrowing from commercial banks.

Commercial banks

in turn had been encouraged to make such loans to their customers and
to obtain needed reserve funds by borrowing from the Reserve Banks.
Discounting was made attractive by preferential rates on the discount
the so-called "war paper" —




that is, on the rediscount of customer

1-5

paper secured by Government obligations and on advances on the member
banks' own notes secured either by this type of paper or by their own
holdings of Government obligations.

Throughout the war these rates

had been closely tied to the rates at which such securities were
currently issued.
In order to obtain the reserves necessary to meet the currency
outflow and the reo^irements behind the deposit increase accompanying
credit expansion, commercial banks had increased their discounts with
the Federal Reserve Banks from a negligible level before the war to
1.8 billion dollars on June 30, 1919.

As a result of the preferential

discount rates on war paper, over 85 per cent of the 1 .8 billion was
obtained through the discount of such paper.

At this time there were

also differential discount rates for the various types and maturities
of commercial and agricultural paper.

These rates, however, were all

largely ineffective.
Banking Developments
During the inflationary upsurge beginning about the middle
of 1919, bank credit increased further, as loans for commercial,
industrial, and agricultural purposes and for purchasing and carry­
ing stocks more than offset the decline in loans on Government securi­
ties.

Many of the loans were made for speculative purposes or,

particularly in agricultural areas, to provide what was really long­
term credit, and many banks were seriously overextended in relation
to their capital.

The continued increase in currency in circulation

and the reversal of the gold inflow depleted bank reserves, while




1 - 6

legal reserve requirements continued to increase as the result of the
credit and deposit expansion.
by the middle of 1920.

Discounts reached 2.5 billion dollars

In addition, early in 1920 Reserve Bank hold­

ings of bankers' acceptances reached almost 600 million dollars, the
highest they were to reach prior to 19 3 1 ; these holdings were still
I4OO million at the end of June.
The increase in Federal Reserve deposit and note liabilities,
as well as the gold outflow beginning in 19 19 , was reflected in a
relatively low reserve ratio for the Federal Reserve Banks themselves.
The combined reserve ratio of all Reserve Banks averaged h5.7 per cent
in December 1919 and fell to U2.U per cent in March 1920.

Legal

reserve requirements for the Federal Reserve Banks were about 38 per
cent at this time.-/

Individual Reserve Banks had had to rediscount

paper with other Reserve Banks or sell acceptances to them in order
to keep their reserves from falling below requirements in periods of
seasonal or special needs.

Thus the Richmond, Dallas, and Atlanta

Reserve Banks had rediscounted with other Banks during the summer of
1919, when they experienced a seasonal loss of funds.

Late in the year

the Mew York, Boston, and Philadelphia Banks had been forced to obtain
accommodation from other Banks on a considerable scale as a result of
both normal seasonal losses and the purchase of bankers' acceptances
at favorable rates.

Through the purchase of bankers' acceptances,

these Reserve Banks utlimately supplied funds to other Districts.— /

1/
£/

the requirements were 35 per cent in gold or lawful money behind
deposit liabilities and I4O per cent in gold behind note liabilities.
There was considerable controversy among the Reserve Banks concerning
the provision of accommodation for other Reserve Banks, which was done
primarily at Board direction. Lending Reserve Banks objected when the
discount rates of borrowing Reserve Banks were lower than their own.
Reserve Banks in the West and South objected to taking over acceptances
purchased at the initiative of the Eastern Reserve Banks, while the latter
objected to having to buy and hold the preponderance of acceptances when
most of them originated elsewhere.
1-7




Federal Reserve Action
The effective rate on discounts was generally U per cent early
in 1919.

With minor exceptions there were no changes in Reserve Bank

discount rates until November 1919.

Prior to this date there had been

an increase in rates on brokers' loans, which had been freed in January
from the control formerly exercised by the Subcommittee on Money of the
Liberty Loan Committee; the average call loan renewal rate was 7-1/2
per cent in October, compared with slightly over h - l / 2 per cent in
January.

The lag in the rise in the discount rate during this period

was inconsistent with the prevalent philosophy which considered the
discount rate a penalty rate.
That the discount rate was not raised was due largely to the
demands of Treasury financing.

The Victory loan was floated in May 1919,

and the amount of certificates outstanding was not reduced significantly
until the end of the year.

Therefore, the Treasury requested that

there be no increase in discount rates until the beginning of 1920 .
Discount rates were raised somewhat in November 1919 and more
beginning early in 1920.

One effect of the rate increases late in 1919

was to eliminate most of the rate differentials and give a high degree
of uniformity to the rate structure.

The differentials according to

class of paper were restored under the rate increases in 1920 , however,
although the differentials for a given class of paper according to its
maturity were not restored.

During 1920 discount rates on paper secured

by Treasury certificates were generally kept in line with the rising rates
on certificates being issued.




According to the Annual Report of the

I - 8

Federal Reserve Board for 1920, these changes were in keeping with the
policy of "enabling the banks to carry the certificates without loss
pending their distribution to customers, but offering them no inducement
through a spread in rates to retain the certificates as an investment
instead of passing them on to the public."2/

Rates were higher on re­

discounts of and advances secured by paper other than certificates.

At

the middle of 1920 the discount rate at the New York Federal Reserve
Bank on paper secured by certificates of indebtedness was 5-1/2 per cent;
on paper secured by Liberty bonds and Victory notes, 6 per cent; and on
commercial paper, 7 per cent.

Despite the favorable rates on paper

secured by Government obligations, particularly certificates, the pro­
portion of discounts thus secured declined as some borrowing banks
presumably exhausted their holdings of such paper.
In the spring of 1920 four of the Federal Reserve Banks adopted
progressive rates for borrowing by individual banks.

Such rates had been

authorized by an amendment to Section lU of the Federal Reserve Act,
approved April 13, 1920.

As administered by three of the Reserve Banks,

the marginal rate was based on the relation of borrowing to the member
bank's basic line of credit, defined as 2-l/2 times the sum of the bank's
paid-in subscription to the capital of the Federal Reserve Bank plus 65
per cent of its total reserves.

This figure was chosen as representing

the contribution of the bank to the lending power of the Federal Reserve
Bank.

In the Atlanta, Kansas City, and St. Louis Federal Reserve Districts,

the basic discount rate applied to all borrowing up to the basic line of
credit; and the rate progressed by l/2 per cent for each 25 per cent by
i/ SevervEH Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board, 1920, p. 58.




1 - 9

which the borrowing exceeded the basic line of credit.

Advances secured

by United States Government securities owned by the borrowing bank were
generally exempted from the application of the progressive rate and were
also excluded from the computation of the amount of discounting*

In the

Atlanta District loans on agricultural paper up to 100 per cent of the
member bank's capital and surplus were also exempt from the progressive
rate.

The Dallas Federal Reserve Bank applied progressive rates to

borrowings in excess of the member bank's capital and surplus.
It should be noted that the progressive rates were directed to
a considerable extent at the distribution of borrowing as well as the
total amount.

The progressive rates were adopted to some extent as an

alternative to the 7 per cent basic rates which were being applied in some
districts.

As noted, reserves of the Reserve Banks were low at this time,

and there was concern that the available credit be equitably distributed,
In its Annual Report for 1920, the Kansas City Reserve Bank pointed to
the redistribution of indebtedness among member banks as an evidence of
the success of the progressive rate.

y

During this period the buying rate on bankers' acceptances
was kept at a low level relative to market rates, although it was generally

y

Annual~Report of the Federal Reserve Agent of the Tenth Federal Reserve
D m r i e t t° the Federal Reserve Board, 1920, p. 11. To the extent that
the shift of indebtedness reflected forced liquidations of customer
loans by borrowing banks, which resulted in adverse clearing balances
for other banks, it would be a factor increasing pressure for liquidation.
It is kno’-n, however, that a part of the shift in the Kansas City
District was the result of the withdrawal of credit to country banks
by city correspondents and the consequent direct resort of the former
to the Federal Reserve Banks.




I - 10

somewhat above the discount rate on advances secured by Treasury
certificates of indebtedness.

The low level of the buying rate, which

reflected the desire to foster the development of the market, resulted in
the concentration of a large proportion of total acceptances in the
Federal Reserve Banks.
During this period the increase in discount rates was preceded
and accompanied by the use of moral suasion.

In public speeches and

published reports, in meetings with bankers and contact with borrowing
banks, Federal Reserve officials reiterated the statement that banks
should discriminate between essential and nonessential loans and
between productive and speculative loans.

All Federal Reserve Banks,

including the eight not applying progressive discount rates, paid
considerable attention to the relation of individual bank borrowings to their
basic lines of credit, and statistics were published on the number of
banks borrowing in excess of basic lines and the relationship of total
bank borrowing to these lines.
Developments during Deflation, 1920-21
Because of the economic and banking developments in the preceding
inflation, many banks were already in illiquid and overextended positions
when deflation began about the middle of 1920.

In many cases their

positions deteriorated further in succeeding months.
Banking Developments
Discounts continued to increase until late 1920, at which time
they reached 2.7 billion dollars.

Total bank loans and investments showed

little change in this period, and deposits and legal reserve requirements




I - 11

declined slightly.

There was also a gold inflow on a small scale

beginning in the spring.

A further increase in currency in circulation

and a decline in Federal Reserve holdings of bankers' acceptances and
of United States Government securities, however, necessitated an
increase in discounting.

During 1921 a liquidation of commercial bank

assets resulted in a decline in deposits and reserve requirements, the
gold inflow was accelerated, and currency in circulation began to
decline.

Discounts of all member banks combined declined to 1.8

billion dollars on June 29, 1921, and 1.1 billion at the end of the year.
The decrease in discounts was heavily concentrated in banks in
industrial and financial areas.

The liquidity of commercial banks in

these areas had generally increased by the middle of 1920 , although the
Ne’f York banks suffered end-of-year diffulcities as a result in part of
loans outside the area and the -ithdrawal of balances by outside banks.
The arricultural sector of the economy was hardest hit by the decline in
general economic activity and took longest to recover. Banks in agricultural
areas lost reserves and at the same time found their loans frozen.

Many

of these banks were faced with solvency as well as liquidity problems,
discounts generally reached their peaks in agricultural districts in the
late summer of 1920, when they are at a seasonal high.

For example, the

discounts of member banks with the Federal Reserve Banks of Dallas,
Atlanta, Minneapolis, and Richmond combined reached $2lj million dollars
on September 2 I4, 1920, compared with 3^2 million a year earlier.

Many

banks in agricultural areas, however, were not members of the Federal
Reserve System and thus had access to Federal Reserve credit only indirectly.




1-12

Others exhausted their supply of eligible paper and hence were unable
to obtain credit.

In some cases banks permitted reserves to remain below

legal requirements for considerable periods of time.
The outflow of funds from primarily agricultural districts
depleted the reserves of Federal Reserve Banks as well as commercial
banks in these areas.

On September 2k, 1920, the total reserves of the

Dallas, Atlanta, Minneapolis, and Richmond Federal Reserve Banks, after
adjustment for the rediscount of paper with other Reserve Banks, were
only 12 ? million dollars, compared with 203 million a year earlier.
The adjusted reserve ratios of the Dallas, Atlanta, Minneapolis, and
Richmond Reserve Banks on this date were 10, 17, 22, and 29 per cent,
respectively.
The agricultural districts experienced a seasonal improvement
in their financial position relative to other areas of the country after
Fepterrber.

Beginning in April, however, the reserve position of the

Federal Reserve Banks in agricultural districts, especially Richmond,
Atlanta, Minneapolis, and Dallas, again deteriorated rapidly.—^

At the

end of riugust adjusted reserves of these four Reserve Banks had reached
137 million dollars, and their adjusted reserve ratios ranged from 9
to 36 per cent.

Discounts, which had declined to 383 million dollars at

the end of March, were stabilized at about this level, as the effects
of a currency inflow largely offset the effects on bank reserves of the
further flow of funds to other districts.

—/' J-he Kansas City, £t. Louis, and Chicago Reserve Banks, which had followed
approximately the same pattern of developments as the Richmond, Atlanta,
Minneapolis, and Dallas Ranks in 1920, were in considerably better
condition in 19 2 1 .




1-13

Late in 1921 the condition of banks in agricultural as well as
industrial areas began to improve.

Discounts at the Richmond, Atlanta,

Minneapolis, and Dallas Reserve Banks declined to 130 million dollars at
the end of June 1922.

The decline reflected in part a regular seasonal

movement of funds, in part an increase in demand for agricultural
products resulting from the revival of business activity in industrial
areas, and in part an inflow of funds resulting from loans by the
War Finance Corporation.

The Agricultural Credits Act of August 2h,

1921, had given the v/ar Finance Corporation authority to make loans to
banks or cooperative associations which had made advances for agricultural
purposes.

These loans were made on liberal terms.

In the seven months

September 1921 - March 1922, advances made under the terms of this Act
totaled 20lj million dollars, and the balance outstanding at the end of
March was 1 % million dollars.

The inflow of funds resulting from War

Finance Corporation loans provided banks in agricultural areas as a
group with reserve funds ”’hich were used to a large extent to reduce
indebtedness to the Federal Reserve Banks.
Federal Reserve Action
During this period the Federal Reserve System was often criticized
for pursuing too restrictive policies even after deflation was under ivay
and banking difficulties were common.
2/ In some cases individual member banks may have reduced their discounts
with their Federal Reserve Banks through the proceeds of loans received
from the War Finance Corporation. In other cases, member banks gained
funds as the result of the transfer of frozen loans to other banks or to
marketing associations receiving War Finance Corporation aid or as the
result of the liquidation of loans to correspondent banks with the pro­
ceeds of such aid. In yet other cases, banks were able to liquidate in­
debtedness to the Federal Reserve because of the receipt of deposits
resulting from the expenditure of the proceeds of new loans made by the
War Finance Corporation.




I - llx

Discount rates on paper secured by Government obligations were
raised in the second half of 1920 , and early in 1921 they were generally
brought into equality with the discount rate applicable to commercial
paper.

Progressive rates -"'ere abolished by the Atlanta Reserve Bank

in November 1920 and by the Dallas Bank in February 1921, but in each case
the basic rate was raised from 6 to 7 per cent.

Progressive rates

remained in effect in the Kansas City and St. Louis Districts until
mid-1921, although the Kansas City Reserve Bank set a maximum marginal
rate of 12 per cent in January and both Reserve Banks considerably
simplified the progressive rate schedule before eliminating it.
The failure to lower discount rates earlier in the course of the
deflation was largely due to consideration of the following factors:
First, the reserve ratios of the Federal Reserve Eanks themselves remained
relatively low until early 19 2 1 .

It was apparently thought that lowering

the rates would reduce the reserve ratios of the Federal Reserve Banks
still further by encouraging more discounting, thus increasing deposit
liabilities, and possibly also by reversing the gold inflow,—'
'

Second,

market rates had declined little prior to the spring of 1921 and remained
nigh relative to discount rates.

It was believed by many that discount

rates should not be reduced until market rates had begun to decline.
Open market operations had not been developed, and in any case they
could not have been used to ease commercial bank reserve positions without

I7~"ilhe Reserve Banks can carry deficiencies in reserves against either
their note or deposit liabilities upon the payment of a tax. In the
case of a deficiency against note liabilities, the tax has to be
passed on to borrowing banks in the form of higher interest charges.
Actually, no tax has ever been passed on, because deficiencies have
always been considered as being in reserves against deposits.




I - 15

risking a further reduction in the reserve ratios of the Reserve Banks;
therefore, the market could ease only to the extent that the demand for
loans declined or banks received excess funds as the result of the
Rold inflow or the reduction of currency in circulation.

Third, it was

believed by many that liquidation of commercial and Federal Reserve Bank
credit should take place to offset the wartime expansion of such credit.
By the spring of 1921 the increase in the gold stock, the
decline in money in circulation, and the decrease in member bank reserve
requirements accompanying the liquidation of loans and deposits in
industrial, commercial, and financial areas had resulted both in an
improvement in the reserve ratio of all Reserve Banks combined and in
a reduction in interest rates in the money market.

The Federal

Reserve Bank of Boston lowered its discount rate in mid-April, and other
Reserve Banks soon followed suit.

Discount rates at the various

Peserve Banks, which had ranged from 6 to 7 per cent at the beginning
of the year, were lj-l/2 to 9-1/2 per cent at the end of 19 2 1 ,
It was claimed also that the Peserve Banks were unduly restrictive
in their lending policies on the basis of the quoted discount rates.

Such

charges are always difficult to evaluate, particularly many years after
the event.

It •
,,ras undoubtedly true that pressure was put on some

inaividual banks to repay indebtedness, either because of the belief that
individual banks were abusing borrowing privileges, because of a fear
that the borrowing banks were in weak financial condition, or because
_ YN
concern about the reserve position of the Reserve Banks.

Moreover, in

some cases the Reserve Banks demanded collateral for loans, especially on
agricultural paper, which the borrowing banks considered excessive.




1-16

Furthermore, many banks in difficulty had exhausted their legally
eligible collateral, and others we re nonmember banks which could not
borrow directly from the Reserve Banks and which until July 1921 could
have their notes rediscounted through member banks only with explicit
permission of the Federal Reserve Board, except for notes secured by
Government obligations.
In July 1921 a conference was held between the members of the
Federal Reserve Board and the Governors of the Federal Reserve Banks of
Richmond, Atlanta, Dallas, and St. Louis which resulted in the issuance
of a statement affirming the willingness to discount paper arising in
connection with the harvesting and marketing of the cotton crop and also
in a specific ruling to the effect that paper originating in nonmember
banks would be accepted when endorsed by a member bank.

The statement

concluded as follows:
"In order, however, that these rediscount facilities
of the Federal Reserve Banks may be made fully effective, it
will be necessary that member banks in the cotton States place
their loaning facilities freely at the disposal of cotton pro­
ducers and dealers in their respective localities with the
knowledge and assurance that the Federal Reserve Board and the
Federal Reserve Banks recognize the urgency of rendering all
proper assistance to these important interests during such
abnormal times."
Developments in Prosperity, 1922-23
The developments of interest in the period 1922-23 were
primarily developments in the use of Federal Reserve instruments other
than the discount mechanism and in the formulation of theories of central
banking.
By 1922 considerably less reliance was being placed on moral
suasion than earlier, and considerably less attention was being paid to




I - 17

the distribution of indebtedness among member banks.

During this period

the importance of a discount rate appropriate to the general credit and
fl /
monetary situation was emphasized._•

Moreover, a single rate was generally

applied to discounts of all classes of paper.

These developments were all

related to a shift from emphasis on the qualitative elements of credit
regulation to greater emphasis on the quantitative elements.

This shift

0/
was made clear in the Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board for 1923r
Attention was still paid to the qualitative aspect in this Annual Report,
however, and it was stated that "it is the belief of the Board that there
will be little danger that the credit created and contributed by the
Federal Reserve Banks rail be in excessive volume if restricted to pro­
ductive uses."— /

Nevertheless, the increasing reliance on the quantitative

aspect was made clear both in this report and in action taken at the time.
The uniformity of discount rates for all classes of paper also reflected
the recognition that there is not necessarily any direct relationship
between the paper which is offered for discount and the purpose of the
borrovdng.il/
The regional pattern of rates was similar in the period 1922-23
to the pattern which was to prevail until 1928.

The differentials in

rates among districts, however, were small and were probably considerably
less than had been envisaged at the time that the Federal Reserve Act was
Passed.

There was not general agreement at this time as to the degree

to which uniformity among districts was desirable because of national
l7~~See Annual Reoort of the Federal Reserve Board. 1923, p. 9.
Ibid— "pp. 53-35.----------------------------10/ ibid., p. 3U.
11/ Ibid., p. 35 .




I - 18

money market characteristics or the degrSfe to which discount rates in

the various districts should reflect regional differences in market

12/

and customer interest rates. — '

Developments in System open marie t policy in the period 1922-23
were closely related to the increasing emphasis on the quantitative
aspects of credit regulation.

Individual Reserve Banks began to purchase

Government securities in order to maintain their earnings early in 1922 ,
when there was a low level of discounts as the result of the gold inflow
in conjunction with the decreases in currency in circulation and in
requirements for reserves resulting from credit and deposit contraction.
It soon became clear both that such purchases may have disrupting
effects on the securities market, which could be partly avoided by joint
Federal Reserve Bank action, and also that open market transactions have
an important effect on the level of reserves and the discounting operations
°f member banks.

A.t a meeting of the Governors of the Federal Reserve

Banks in May 1922, a Committee on Centralized Execution of Purchases and
Sales of Government Securities, consisting of the Governors of four
Federal Reserve Banks, was organized to execute investment orders for
aH

of the Reserve Banks.

In October the Committee was enlarged to five

members, and its duties were extended to include the making of recommenda­
tions from time to time concerning the advisability of purchasing or
selling securities.

On March 22, 1923, the Federal Reserve Board passed

a resolution creating the Federal Open Market Committee and requiring that
the Committee give primary consideration to the accommodation of commerce
a^d business and the effect of purchases or sales of securities on the
general credit situation.




2 and 9.
I - 19

The Annual Report for1 1923 emphasized the importance of open
market operations in influencing the level of discounts and in the func­
tioning of the discount mechanism.— /

The explanation of the distinction

between borrowed and unborrowed reserves from the standpoint of the
functioning of credit policy had not yet been clearly stated, howeverj
nor had any theory been stated concerning the sequence of open market
operations and changes in discount rates.— /
The level of business activity increased during 1922 and most
of 1923.

During this period the gold inflow continued, supplying banks

with reserve funds without resort to the use of Federal Reserve credit.
The Federal Reserve sold United States Government securities in the market
in late 1922 and 1923 > and in 1923 discount rates were raised at the three
Reserve Banks which had reduced rates to U per cent in 1922 .

It was

explicitly recognized at this time that the reserve ratio of the Federal
Reserve Banks could not be permitted to determine credit policy, at least
with the international situation then prevailing.il/

It was apparently

recognized also that Federal Reserve tightening or easing action should
be prompter in relation to changes in business activity than it had been
in 1919 - 21 .— /
Despite the change in emphasis in discount and open market
Policy, the desire to encourage the growth of the acceptance market re­
gained a dominant factor in the establishment of buying rates.

ci/

Acceptance

Ibid7, pp. 1 1 and 13-lU.
For the discussion in the Annual Report for 1923 concerning the
relationship between reserves supplied by commercial bank borrowing
and those supplied by open market operations, see pp. 13-15 of that
report.
Ibid., pp. 30-31.
Ibid., p. 10




1-20

holdings of Federal Reserve Banks had been almost entirely liquidated in
1921 as the result of a decline in the amount outstanding and the increas­
ing liquidity of money market banks.

Beginning late in 1921 the Reserve

Banks purchased acceptances at rates which were favorable relative to
market rates and to the discount rate, and acceptances again began to
be concentrated in the Reserve Banks.

3y the end of 1923, Federal

Reserve holdings of acceptances exceeded 3^0 million dollars.




Mona E. Dingle, Banking Section
Division of Research and Statistics
Board of Governors

1 - 2 1

II.

CRITERIA FOR CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE

The basic purpose of the Federal Reserve System is to exert
monetary discipline on the economy.

It can exert this discipline only

■with "the consent of the governed."

In the long run, such consent should

be based on understanding and should be earned through merit in operations.
If the principles of monetary policy are understood, every action— or in­
action— by the System should be consistent with them and, except when
based on information available only to Reserve authorities, should seldom
come as a complete surprise to informed observers.

Thus, as stated by

Dr. Goldenweiser:
Monetary action should be simple, direct, nonsubtle, and easily
understandable. It depends for its effects not only on the
actual measures taken but also on the fact that these actions
are meant to indicate attitudes . V
If this premise is correct, the question arises as to whether
Reserve authorities should establish fairly definite criteria for specific
actions— criteria which in turn would become known to the market so that
the informed observer could anticipate and better understand major policy
moves.

With the re-emergence of member bank borrowing as a primary method

°f obtaining reserves, guides to changes in the discount rate are again
°D interest.

The purpose of this memorandum is (1) to explore the possi­

bility of devising some specific criteria for changes in the discount rate,
and (2 ) to discuss the advisability of divulging this information to the
market along with either an implied or expressed promise that the announced
criteria will be followed in shaping policy.

i/

A. Goldenweiser:




American Monetary Policy, p. 233*

II - 1

I.

Preliminary Considerations

These purposes can be achieved only if the broader aspects of
the discount mechanism are understood.

It is therefore appropriate to

preface the analysis with a discussion of several basic questions relat­
ing to discount policy.

A*

These questions are:

A.

In what ways does discount policy exert influence as a
device of credit control?

B.

What is the proper role of discount policy in the over­
all complex of monetary action?

C.

What, if any, is the "normal" relationship between dis­
count rates and market rates?

Influence of Discount Policy
The discount mechanism influences the flow of expenditures in

four ways:
1.

Through the effects exerted by the discount rate as a price.

2.

Through the effects on expectations of a change in the dis­
count rate.

3.

Through the effects resulting from the reluctance of member
banks to borrow from and remain in debt to the Reserve
Bank3 .
Through the selective effects of the "policing" action
which accompanies Reserve Bank lending.
It may seem that only the first two influences are significant

the problem of devising specific criteria for changes in the discount
rate.

But the fact is that all four are interrelated.

For example, as

market rates move up relative to the discount rate the reluctance of mem^er ^anks to borrow tends to be overcome and the problem of policing grows
difficulty and extent.

In other words, the reluctance to borrow on the

Part of member banks reduces the effectiveness of the discount rate as a




II - 2

price when expansion is desired, and reinforces it when a restrictive pro­
gram is pursued.

As will be shown later, the asyrsnetrical character of

the mechanism is of importance in the timing of changes in the discount
rate in different stages of the business cycle.
The effects on expectations of a change in the discount rate
are not always predictable.

Ana]ysis is complicated by the fact that re­

actions to a given increase or decrease are influenced by such things as
the business outlook, the level of the new discount rate relative to
market rates, the nature of past Federal Reserve policy, market judgment
as to the reason underlying the rate change, and so on.

For example, an

increase designed to bring the discount rate in line with existing market
rates (this was the interpretation on the part of the market of the most
recent increase) might have only minor effects on expectations because
ihe increase would be viewed as a confirmation of past events rather than
a forerunner of future movements.
Some changes in the discount rate, on the other hand, are in­
terpreted by the market as presaging either higher or lower market rates.
Unpredictability may still be present, however, because such changes tend
to affect borrowers and lenders in opposite ways.

In the case of an in­

crease, borrowers, in anticipation of higher rates in general, may try to
borrow more and lenders may attempt to curtail their extensions.

The net

result vrili probably be a speedier increase in market rates than would
°therwise be the case, thus accentuating tightness in the credit market
with uncertain effects on the total volume of credit.
Hence, the effects of changes in the discount rate on expectaions

sometimes referred to as the psychological influence— vary with




II - 3

circumstances and are not always predictable.

This does not mean, how­

ever, that such effects should be ignored in the formulation of credit
policy.

Whenever possible, policy should be designed to make profitable

use of the effects on expectations.

If nothing more, the possibility of

perverse reactions should be taken into consideration.
For purposes of this memorandum, the most important conclusion
to be drawn from this brief discussion of the different types of influ­
ences exerted through the discount mechanism is that the influence of
"the discount rate as a price, although important, is by no means the
°nly route through which the supply, availability, and cost of credit are
affected.

As a consequence, decisions concerning changes in the discount

rate should be based on much broader considerations of the over-all credit
situation than would otherwise be the case.
The Proper Role of Discount Policy
Discount policy cannot be considered in isolation.

It is but

one of three major techniques for influencing the supply, availability,
and cost of credit.

Thus any discussion of guides to rate changes should

be based on an understanding of the role of discount policy in the overaH

complex of monetary action.
So long as the tradition among member banks against borrowing

from Reserve Banks exists, discount policy is likely to be of secondary
importance to other instruments when economic events move so as to re^uire a strongly expansionary policy.

When the trend of economic forces

CaH s f°r a restrictive monetary policy, however, discount policy has an
important role to play and may become the most important instrument of




II - li

the three.

When inflationary forces are present and credit demands are

strong, the discount mechanism provides an excellent device for supplying
reserves to meet temporary and unusual needs.

The reluctance of member

banks to remain in debt to Reserve Banks means that the new reserves have
a "string" on them, and they are more likely to be returned when the tem­
porary or unusual need has passed.

At the same time, open market pur­

chases and/or reductions in reserve requirements can be used to supply
the funds needed to support secular growth of the economy.
Discount policy, therefore, may be considered as a leading in­
strument of Federal Reserve policy when it is desirable to exert restraint
or possibly when recessionary forces are mild.

Throughout all stages of

the cycle, however, discount policy and open market operations can and
should be used as complementary instruments.

In this respect, the instru­

ments might be used in a manner similar to that developed in the 1920's.
When contraction is desired, open market policy can be directed so as to
force member banks to discount, which in turn would make them less willing
expand credit; and the discount rate could be moved up relative to
market rates.
Used:

VJhen expansion is desired, the opposite technique would be

securities could be bought in order to get member banks out of debt
Reserve Banks, which in turn would promote more liberal lending

Policies.

The advocacy of this technique is based on the generally ac-

CePted premise that member banks are more hesitant to expand loans and
Investments while in debt to the Federal Reserve.

At the same time, the

discount rate might be moved lower in relation to market rates.

If

market rates, in turn, moved lower still, a further reduction of the disUnt rate might be called for if business showed no signs of improvement.




II - 5

The assumption that discount policy and open market operations
are to be used as coordinated instruments implies that no separate set of
criteria can be set up for changes in the discount rate alone.

To be

workable, any set of criteria must apply to monetary policy as a whole
rather than the individual instruments of policy.
C • The Discount Rate and Market Rates
Two basic difficulties are confronted in any attempt to postu­
late a "normal" relationship between the discount rate and the market
rates.

The first refers to definition.

represent market rates?

What rate should be taken to

The second difficulty arises from the fact that

the "normal" relationship will vary with such things as business condi­
tions, monetary policy, the relative supply of and demand for short- versus
long-term funds, and so on.
The first difficulty we shall dispose of by selecting the yield
°n Treasury bills as the representative market rate.

Although it is by

n° means a "representative" rate, the bill rate does possess the advantage
applying to short-term, open market paper on which there is no credit
r^-sk, and the Treasury bill is currently the most widely held money-market
instrument.

Furthermore, it is a sensitive rate and its level is closely

related to tightness or ease in the money market.

But, at the same time,

this very sensitiveness gives rise to erratic fluctuations that limit its
Usefulness as a short-run guide to changes in discount rates, which ordinrily should not be changed with every temporary stringency or ease in the
marke t.
The second difficulty is not so easily overcome.

If the over-all

rces of demand and supply are fairly well balanced so that no pressure




II - 6

toward tightening or loosening is being exerted by the market itself, and
if Reserve policy is neutral in the strict sense of the term, one might
anticipate that the bill rate would be closely related to the discount
rate.

If the market suddenly received funds (e.g., from an increase in

float, net Treasury disbursements, etc.), the bill rate might fall below
the discount rate; if the market were suddenly deprived of funds, the bill
rate might rise above the discount rate.
If, however, the over-all demand for funds should increase, it
■would tend both to force up the bill rate and to increase the volume of
discounting.

The System must decide whether to supply additional funds

0n its own initiative or to permit the tightening to occur and, if so, how.
Its decisions on these points will influence both the volume of discount­
ing and the bill rate.

In other words, neither market rates nor the volume

°f discounting— nor both— is an adequate independent guide to changes in
fhe discount rate.
II.

Can We Revise Specific Criteria
for Changes in Discount Rates?

At the outset, it should be made clear that no one rule-of-thumb
Can serve as a guide to rate policy.
°f“thumb are tempting.

The operational advantages of rules-

It would be convenient if some simple, easy-to-

follow guide— such as the reserve ratio, the volume of discounting, or the
Ievel of market rates— were available.
^°n

But, as is so often the case, adop-

an automatic operating technique in one area merely transfers the

asic necessity of using judgment to some other aspect of policy.




II - 7

A.

Criteria in the 1920's
In retrospect, it appears superficially that during most of the

1920's the rates on 90-day bankers' acceptances and four- to six-month
open market commercial paper were the most important criteria of the level
and changes in the discount rate. When these market rates moved suffi­
ciently in either direction to touch the discount rate, the rate was
changed to restore its position between the two market rates.

Specifically,

as the money market eased, the discount rate (Federal Reserve Bank of
New York) was reduced when the commercial paper rate fell to the discount
ratej and as the market tightened, the discount rate was increased when
the bankers' acceptance rate rose to the discount rate.
So WeH

The rule worked

that Reserve officials encouraged the market to place this interpre­

tation on rate changes.— ^
Once the market becomes habituated to following such objective
criteria, deviations in practice will become the subject of widespread
Interest and concern.

For example, the discount rate was not increased

the spring of 1929* when the rate on bankers' acceptances rose above
t*

The market soon interpreted this as a change in the rules and possibly

as an indication— later confirmed— of disagreement within the System as to
aPPropriate policy under the circumstances.

Inability to anticipate all

Possible developments is, of course, one of the dangers of following
Mechanically any objective guides.
The fact that typically the discount rate was adjusted to market
63 °oes not mean that System policy as a whole was directed by a rule-




example, W. R. Burgess: The Reserve Banks and the Money
> 1927 edition, pp. 291-293.
II - 8

of-thumbj nor does it imply that the System was passive in the money market.
It meant merely that the change in the rate simply became, in a sense, the
last link in a chain of actions.

The sequence of actions is clearest if

we lay aside at the outset such independent factors as gold and currency
movements.

If the System felt that expansion was proceeding too rapidly,

it would "probe" the market through sales of Government securities.
withdrawal of funds would tend to tighten the market.

The

Member banks would

tend to become short of reserves and would borrow to replenish them.

This

shift in the source of funds would also tighten the market because of the
tradition against rediscounting— a tradition that was fostered by the
Reserve officials.
rates.

The added pressure would be reflected in rising market

if in the process the rate on bankers’ acceptances rose to the

discount rate, the latter would be increased.—/

This process implies, in

turn, that willingness to change the rate, when and if indicated, was
reached some time before the change— namely, when the sale of securities
was initiated.
An advantage of this process was that the System could experiment
or probe with open market operations.

Then, depending on subsequent busi-

ness developments, it could renew the operation or reverse it, without
upsetting" the market.
^ ^ C c L T T iP

The change in rate as the last link in the process

*

in a sense, a formal confirmation of a judgment expressed tenta-

ively in the open market.

tv!6
that the System's buying rate was the major determinant of
e ievel of the market rate on acceptances supports the contention
at the System was not passive in the money market. In raising its
yang rate on acceptances, the System was in fact indicating a willngness subsequently to raise the discount rate.




II - 9

In practice, of course, the mechanism was much more complicated
primarily because discounts and Government securities are only two of
several ways in which member banks may acquire reserves.

Other means are

changes in the other accounts of the Reserve Banks, such as Federal Reserve
notes, gold holdings, nonreserve deposits, and float.

Open market opera­

tions were adjusted to changes in these independent accounts in such a way
as to increase the pressure or ease on the money market as a whole.

For

example, an opportune loss of gold could be utilized instead of sales of
securities to probe the market; on the other hand, an inopportune receipt
°f gold would require larger sales of securities to put pressure on the

market.
Experience in the 1920's holds important lessons for the 1950's.
As recommended below, the coordinated use of open market operations and
discount policy— the former being used to probe the market in advance of
changes in the discount rate— would be a suitable procedure under present
conditions.

The specific guides to changes in the discount rate which

Proved so helpful in the 1920's can no longer be used, however.

Open

^ r k e t commercial paper and bankers' acceptances are no longer as signif­
icant

as formerly as money-market instruments, and no other instruments

^ave entirely replaced them.

For reasons noted in Section I. C, the rate

°n Treasury bills is not an appropriate criterion on a day-by-day basis.
Spared with the 1920's, the Treasury bill resembles in a measure the call
311 as 311 instrument utilized in adjusting bank reserves.

Although not so

ratic as the old call loan rate, which often varied several points in one
the bill rate is still too unstable to use as a literal guide for




II - 10

day-by-day policy.

It seems clear, on the other hand, that a tendency for

the bill rate to remain above or below the discount rate for an extended
period of time might indicate that a change in the discount rate is desirable.
m

As was shown in Section I. C, however, the rate schedule existing

the market at any given time is itself partially a product of Federal

Reserve policy, including open market policy, and therefore cannot serve
as an independent guide for setting the discount rate.
Recommended Procedures
The fact that market rates do not provide specific criteria for
discount action does not mean that we cannot make some generalizations con­
cerning the timing of changes in the discount rate.

This is most easily

acc°mplished by discussing the use of the discount mechanism when Federal
Reserve policy in general is designed to be (1) moderately expansionary,
(2) strongly expansionary, (3) moderately restrictive, (ij) heavily
restrictive.
1.

A moderately expansionary policy.

In practice, decisions of

Reserve authorities to reverse or to strengthen policies come gradually.
Thus the inauguration of a policy of mild expansion is likely to be merely
the reflection of a tentative judgment which may be confirmed later.

As a

consequence, it might be appropriate to probe the market initially with open
narket purchases before relaxing discount rate.

Then, if the judgment proves

be erroneous, policy can be reversed before a change in the rate— which
always somewhat dramatic--is ordered.

Furthermore, open market policy

may be
successful in correcting the situation without reliance on discount
Ticy,

jf the judgment proves correct, on the other hand, the discount

can be lowered as the final step in the chain of events.




II - 11

At times the need for prompt expansionary action may be clearcut.

if so, a good case can be made for lowering the discount rate con­

currently with open market purchases.

Simultaneous action is recommended

because of the member bank tradition against discounting.

It was observed

earlier that this tradition, although useful when restrictive policies are
m

order, reduces the effectiveness of discount policy when expansion is

desired.

When recessionary forces are dominant, a prompt lowering of the

discount rate may tend to offset the tradition against discounting to a
certain extent."^
2.

A strongly expansionary policy. When economic events call

for strong measures to promote expansion, the problem of specific criteria
rate changes should be negligible.
all controls will be justified.

Swift and decisive relaxation of

Reductions in reserve requirements and

Purchases of securities in the open market might serve to ease conditions,
and a sharp downward movement in the discount rate would tend to reduce
the reluctance of member banks to borrow.
In short, strong measures will be necessary to prevent banks from
dumping assets in their efforts to obtain liquidity.

Since the Federal

Reserve Banks have sufficient power to supply the liquidity, the problem

V

This discussion raises the question as to whether it is to the long-run
interests of the System to foster the tradition. Many students of cenral hanking believe that the System has greater power to curtail than
n promote expansion. Accepting this belief for purposes of discussion,
. w °uld appear that the tradition adds to the System's power to restrict
subtracts from its power to expand. It, therefore, adds to the Systhp S P°wers when they are already strong and subtracts from them when
to
already weak. In addition, the policing activities carried on
expansion are likely to be remembered most vividly, particularly
rat aller .nks, when expansion is desired. There is always the discount
If + aS a ^T^ce
faH hack on when use of the privilege becomes excessive.
givpne+^^?coun^ mechanism is to be a two-way street, thought should be
airpo+ 0 fhe T°ng~run effects of unduly discouraging its use through
ecu action during periods of expansion.




II - 12

is primarily one of getting the funds to the places where they are needed
as soon as possible.

The discount mechanism, if properly handled, can be

very useful in this respect— provided that the tradition against borrowing
can be overcome.
It is clear that under conditions such as these the volume of
discounting as such will be an unsatisfactory guide to rate changes.
Because of the tradition against borrowing, a major purpose of heavy open
market purchases is to reduce member bank indebtedness to the Reserve
Banks.

The volume of discounting may fall so low that further changes

will be insignificant, but further lowering of rates may well be in order
the forces of deflation continue.
3.

A moderately restrictive policy.

The problem of setting up

criteria for discount policy becomes most interesting— and most perplexing-when restrictive policies are called for.

Here, however, the tradition

against discounting— so long as it lasts— will facilitate control and can
utilized effectively in preventing excessive expansion of member bank
credit.

When contemporary events require a slightly restrictive policy,
°Pen market operations should first be used to probe the market.

Initial

action of this type may be sufficient and thereby avert the need for a
change in the discount rate.

If demand for reserves is very strong, how-

ever, member banks are likely to come to the discount window for accommo^ation.

At the same time, market rates on short-term Government securities

are likely to rise.

Under these circumstances, Reserve authorities should

Specially watch the volume of discounting.




II - 13

A rapidly rising volume,

accompanied by increasing market rates, would seem to be sufficient indi­
cation for an increase in the discount rate.
This is not meant to imply, however, that the volume of discount­
ing is itself the basic criterion for changes in the discount rate.

The

increase in the volume of member bank borrowing, in the situation just
described, is merely the confirmation of a decision made earlier to re­
strict credit expansion, provided that the judgment leading to the deci­
sion is confirmed in the market.— ^

The point should be re-emphasized

that the basic criteria are the economic events which lead to the adoption
°f a restrictive policy in the first place.

The volume of discounting

serves only as a procedural device— something which aids in decisions
concerning the timing and extent of rate increases after the authorities
have decided that increases may be in order.
Since there is nothing inviolate about the procedure of first
Probing the market before changing the discount rate, it would be unwise
ho lead the market to believe that Reserve authorities will always use
hhis procedure.

This is especially important because an increase in the

discount rate may be wise policy at times when the volume of discounting
13 stationary or even falling.
h.

A heavily restrictive policy.

During a period of high-level

business activity when inflationary forces are very strong, a heavily re­
strictive program may be in order.

If a situation of this type follows a

Still a further indication that a rise in discount rate might be ad­
visable would be the growing complexity of the policing problem. It
was pointed out earlier that the lower the discount rate relative to
market rates, the more difficult the policing problem becomes.




II - Hi

period of mild restriction, the proper policy might involve a tightening
of controls all along the line.

Open market policy might be more aggressive

and the discount rate might be raised, both at the same time.

If the eco­

nomic situation shows signs of turning into a runaway, however, a sudden and
relatively large increase in discount rates may serve a useful purpose.
Many more situations could be analyzed.

Enough has been said,

however, to indicate that ultimately discount policy must be empirical and
based on the judgment of responsible and intelligent men rather than on a
widely recognized rule-of-thumb.

The extent and timing of each action—

whether in regard to the discount rate, open market policy, or reserve re­
quirements— should be guided not so much by the behavior of individual
indicators as by an appraisal of the over-all economic situation.
III.

Should Criteria for Changes in the
Discount Rate Be Known By the Market?

Even if criteria for rate changes could be enumerated precisely,
there is a serious question as to whether the market should be informed of
^be guides and the intention of Reserve authorities to follow them.

Of

course, one advantage of public disclosure of broad criteria to be followed
w°uld be a reduction of uncertainty in the market concerning movements in
interest rates, bank credit, and possibly other economic quantities.

This

reduction of uncertainty might in turn be conducive to greater economic
stability.

In addition, disclosure of criteria for policy actions might be

Justified on the grounds that it would indicate a desire on the part of
Reserve authorities to "play fair" with the market.
But the disadvantages are even more compelling.

In the first

Pluce, it should be clear from the discussion presented above that any




II - 15

set of criteria will have to be in rather general terms if it is to be
universally applicable throughout the stages of the business cycle.

This

necessary generality would no doubt reduce the effectiveness of public
knowledge of the criteria, and there is some question as to whether in­
formation so general in nature would reduce uncertainty.
In the second place, and much more important, is the fact that
once the criteria have been disclosed the authorities will always run the
risk of becoming caught in a situation where they will have to break faith
with the market.

Once this happens, the difficulties of administration of

effective monetary policy will be multiplied.

This risk outweighs the

advantages which might accrue from disclosure of the criteria.
On the other hand, it is clear that the market should not be
wholly uninformed concerning the objectives— both short- and long-run—
°f contemporary Federal Reserve policy.

The long-run purpose of the

System, as stated by Chairman Martin in his reply to the Patman Questionnaire, is "to minimize economic fluctuations caused by irregularities in
"the flow of money and credit, foster more stable values, and thus make
Possible the smooth functioning of monetary machinery so necessary to growth
°f the country and to improve standards of living."
Simply stated, the short-run objective of the Federal Reserve
System is to further the attainment of the long-run purpose by exerting
Varying degrees of pressure on the credit market.

As was pointed out

earlier, the degree of restraint or ease that is exercised will vary with
economic conditions.

The public should be informed of the short-run ob­

jective— i.e., whether the System is attempting to tighten, ease, or




II - 16

remain neutral.

But the procedures that will be used are solely a matter

of circumstance

and will vary as the situation changes, and can be fully

rationalized after the event has taken place.

There is danger that a

promise to follow a given procedure will by inference elevate that proce­
dure into the objective.
It would seem to follow that public information concerning criteria
for changes in the discount rate should be in terms of objectives rather
than procedures.




Karl R. Bopp, Vice President
Charles E. Walker, Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

II - 17

III.

COMPARISON OF HISTORICAL CHANGES IN THE DISCOUNT RATE
WITH CHANGES IN MARKET INTEREST RATES

This memorandum presents statistics relating to (1) the timing
and (2) the degree of past changes in the discount rate in relation to
changes in market interest rates.
Timing of Changes in the Discount and Selected Money Market Rates
Changes in the most sensitive money market rate have with only
two exceptions preceded changes in the discount rate, as shown on Table 1,
which compares changes in the discount rate with similar movements in the
prevailing rate on 90 -day bankers' acceptances prior to 193U and the rate
on three-month Treasury bills thereafter.

The money market rate change

has generally occurred from 1 to 8 months prior to the discount rate change;
■this period was somewhat shorter in periods when the discount rate was
lowered rather than when it was raised.

The only cases in which a change

in the discount rate led a change in money market rates occurred in 19^2
and 19li6 when a preferential discount rate on advances secured by short­
term Government securities was first adopted early in World War II and then
removed after the War.
Following a discount rate change, short-term as well as long­
term market rates have generally moved somewhat further in the same direction.
This does not imply, of course, that a change in the discount rate caused
a change in other interest rates.

All rates may have moved in response to

independent forces.
Table 2 shows that during the past 30 years both the commercial
paper rate and the yield on Moody's Aaa corporate bonds have moved after
ihe discount rate change with considerable regularity upward or downward




III - 1

with the discount rate.

The similarity of movement is particularly strik­

ing in the case of the commercial paper rate; in no case did this rate
move in the opposite direction and in only three instances did it remain
unchanged when there was a change in the discount rate.

The yield on cor­

porate Aaa bonds also followed the discount rate whenever the rate declined
and in most of the cases in which it increased.

The divergencies in move­

ment between the discount rate and the bond yield occurred for the most
part in the period 1925-28, when long-term interest rates were tending
downward.
As was pointed out earlier, a change in market short-term rates
has generally preceded a change in the discount rate.

Since changes in

market short-term and long-term rates are quite closely correlated, this
means that some change in long-term rates also usually preceded a change
in the discount rate.
Degree of Change in the Discount Rate and Market Interest Rates
Generally speaking, the relative changes in the discount rate
have been greater than the relative changes in market rates.

Each dis­

count rate action has usually increased or decreased the rate by from
10-25 per cent.

Commercial paper rate changes following the discount rate

change have usually been somewhat smaller than the discount rate change
but more nearly comparable to it than changes in the yield on Aaa bonds.
For the latter, the relative changes either upward or downward have been
small— usually less than 5 per cent.

This is to be expected in view of

the smaller range of fluctuation of long-term as contrasted to short-term
rates.

Moreover, in view of the differing maturities of long-term and




III - 2

short-term securities, a specific percentage change in the yield of a
long-term security means a much greater percentage change in its price
than the same percentage change in the yield of a short-term security.




Caroline H. Cagle, Banking Section
Division of Research and Statistics
Board of Governors

III - 3

Table 1

Comparison of the Timing of Changes in the Discount and Money Market Rates
(The money market rate prior to 193U is the bankers’ acceptance
rate and thereafter the Treasury bill rate,)
A.
i' change in F. R.
unt rate (N. Y . )

Cases in which discount rate was raised
Cases in which discount rate change:
Led money market rate by:
Lagged money market rate by:

Nov. 3 )
Jan. 23)
June 1 )

1 month

1923 - Feb. 23

5 months

1925 - Feb. 27

7 months

1926 - Jan. 8

8 months

1926 - Aug. 13

3 months

1928 - Feb. 3 )
May 18 )
July 13)
1929 - Aug. 9 )

1* months

1931 - Oct. 9 )
Oct. 16)

Less than 1 month

1933 - Mar. 3

Less than 1 month

191*6 - Apr. 25

Less than 1 monthi^

Less than 1 month

I91i8 - Jan. 12)
Aug. 13)

6 months

1950

Aug. 21

7 months

1953

Jan. 16

3 months

Referential discount rate on advances secured by short-term Government
Cities.

<5
Successive discount rate changes in the same direction within a relatively
Co ^ Period of time have been grouped, and the lead or lag shown in the table
Phted from the date of the first discount rate change in the group.

Note




III - U

Table 1 - Continued

Comparison of the Timing of Changes in the Discount and Money Market Rates
(The money market rate prior to 193k is the bankers' acceptance
rate and thereafter the Treasury bill rate.)
B.

Cases in which discount rate was lowered

Date of change in F. R.
discount rate (N. Y.)

Cases in which discount rate change:
Led money market rate by:
Lagged money market rate by;

1921 - May £
)
June 16 )
July 21 )
Sept. 22)
Nov. 3 )
1922
June 22 )

ii months

l92k - May 1 )
June 12)
Aug. 8 )

2 months

1926 - Apr. 23

3 months

^ 7

1 month

- Aug. 5

1929

Nov. 1 )
Nov. 15)
Feb. 7 )
Mar. Ik)
May 2 )
June 20)
Dec. 2k)
May 8 )

1930

1931

ll months

1?32 “ Feb. 26)
June 2k)

2 months

1933 - Apr. 7 )
May 26 )
Oct. 20)
*931i

1 month

- Feb. 2
_

Less than 1 month

Aug. 27

. Oct. 30

ii months

1/

Less than 1 month-:

* f°°tnote see preceding page.




III - 5

Table 2

Comparison of Relative Changes in the Discount Rate with Similar Changes
in the Commercial Paper Rate and Moody's Aaa Bond Yields
A.

Cases in which discount rate was raised

Federal Reserve discount rate
Date of change

Percentage
change

Percentage change (within period of approximately
3 months after discount rate change) in—
Moody's Corporate Aaa
Commercial paper rate
bond yield

■*•919 - Nov. 3

+ 19

+

lli

+ :h

■*-920 - Jan. 23
June 1

+ 26
+ 17

+
+

15
10

+
+

5
1

•*•923 - Feb. 23

+ 13

+

20

+

li

^ 2 5 - Feb, 27

+ 17

+

10

-

2

•*•926 - Jan. 8
Aug. 13

+ lli
+ Hi

0
16

-

+

2
0

■*•928 - Feb. 3
May 18
July 13

+ lli
+ 13
+ 11

+
+
+

10
8
19

+
2/ +

0
3
1

^■929 - Aug. 9

+ 20

+

11

2/ +

*

*931 - Oct. 9, 16

1/ +133

2/ + 100

•*•933 - Mar. 3

t liO

2/ + 117

l9li6 - Apr. 25

+ 100

+

^8

- Jan. 12
Aug. 13

+ 25
+ 20

■*•950 - Aug. 21

+ 17

^53 - Jan. 16

+ lli

+ 17
2/ +

7

3

+

1

+
+

16
13

+

1
1

+

32

+

2

+

3

+

5

l
Change amounted to less than 0.5 of 1 per cent.
Covers several successive discount rate changes, as indicated, The total
in the rate is expressed as a percentage of the discount rate prior to
‘le first change.
2/ Change within period of approximately one month after the last discount rate
ch
^ge.




Ill - 6

Table 2 - Continued

Comparison of Relative Changes in the Discount Rate with Similar Changes
in the Commercial Paper Rate and Moody’s Aaa Bond Yields
B.

Cases in which discount rate was lowered

Federal Reserve discount rate
Date of change
1921 - May 5 )
June 16)
July 21)
Sept. 22
Nov. 3

Percentage
change

Commercial paper rate

Moody's Corporate Aaa
bond yield

1/ - 21

2/ - 20

- 9
- 10

- 10
- 11

- 7
- 6

- 11

-

6

- 3

2/ - 2lt

2/ - 3

1922 - June 22
l92i| - May 1 )
June 12)
Aug. 8

Percentage change (within period of approximately

1/ - 22

2J

~ 1

- lit

-

it

- 1

1926 - Apr. 23

- 13

-

9

- 1

1927 - Aug. 5

- 13

-

6

- 2

1929 - N^v. 1 )
Nov. 15)

y

- 25

- 22

- 2

1930 - Feb. 7 )
Mar. lit)

y

- 22

- 23

- 1

1/ - 29

- 20

- it

- 20

- 13

- 3

1931 - May 8

- 25

- 16

- 1

1932 - Feb. 26
June 2it

- lit
- 17

- 10
- 28

- 1
- 8

l933 - Apr. 7)
May 26)

1/ - 17

- It6

- 7

Oct. 20

- 20

May 2 )
June 20)
Dec. 2it

2/ -

9

- *

l93lt - Feb. 2

- 25

- 33

- 6

l937 “ Aug. 27

- 33

0

- *

^ 2 ^ - Oct. 30

- $0

0

- *

0l> footnotes see preceding page.




Ill - 7

IV.

DIFFERENTIALS IN DISCOUNT RATES AMONG FEDERAL

RESERVE~DISTRiCTSl7
For more than a decade there have been no differences of more
than a few days duration among the discount rates established (under
sections 13 and 13a of the Federal Reserve Act) by the various Federal
Reserve Banks.

The differences which persisted through the decade of

the 'thirties appear to have mainly reflected inertia at a time when
general cheap money conditions had rendered the discount mechanism
largely dormant.

It has thus been a long time since the

System has had

to face the question of developing purposeful criteria for establishing
differentials among the discount rates of the various Federal Reserve
Banks.

Moreover, much that has happened in the development of wartime

and postwar financing methods has appreciably furthered the integration
of various regional credit markets into a functioning nationwide credit
system.

The changes have been so profound, both in narrowing regional

differences in credit conditions and in discrediting the early reliance
upon qualitative differences in types of discounted paper, that few
analogies remain to suggest bases on which differentials in discount
rates might again emerge.
Nonetheless, at a time when the System is again exploring
Possibilities for strengthening the use of the discount mechanism as an
instrument of credit control, it is important to examine the possible
contribution that differences in discount rates could make toward

y ' T h i r memorandum represents the writer's attempt to reflect a wide
variety of views expressed by various members of the research com­
mittee engaged in studying the discount mechanism. It is not
intended to present the writer's personal views.



IV - 1

improving the sensitiveness of credit control to varying economic and
credit conditions.

It must be recognized from the beginning that the

discount mechanism is itself one of the most important tools of national
monetary and credit control.

Consequently, the underlying principles

of discount rate action are likely to be broadly similar in all of the
Federal Reserve districts.

However, the Federal Reserve Act does con­

template the Independent setting of discount rates for each Federal
Reserve Bank, subject to the over-all review and determination of the
Board of Governors; that leaves open the possibility that differences
may exist, and persist, among the discount rates of the various Federal
Reserve Banks.

While such differences, if they should develop, would

have to be conditioned by the over-all considerations growing out of the
national monetary policy, there may be room within the over-all framework
°f System discount policy for differentials that could give credit con­
trol a closer and more direct effectiveness within the circumstances
characteristic of individual Reserve districts.
So long as many questions of national policy concerning the
discount rate mechanism remain undecided, the scope for differentials
among the discount rates of various Federal Reserve districts cannot
be marked out with assurance.

Without attempting to suggest firm con­

clusions, however, three broad grounds for possible differentials seem
likely to deserve consideration in the future.

One would be to provide

for a step-by-step approach toward a nationwide change in the discount
rate, with initial exploratory rate increases undertaken by those
districts in which the Reserve Bank directors are most firmly convinced,




IV - 2

in the light of their own local conditions, that some change in the
discount rate is necessary.

A second ground for differentials would

arise when a district or districts encountered special problems, per­
haps reflected in the difficulty of "policing" member bank borrowing
requests, that justified temporary deviations from the national policy.
A third basis for differentials might be found in regional balance of
payments problems, either of a short-run or longer-run nature, which a
higher or lower discount rate in a given district might help to correct.
Proceeding by Stages toward a Nationwide
Change in the Discount Rate
As a further refinement of the probing through open market
operations that often precedes a change in the discount rate, it might
he possible to raise the rate experimentally in one or two districts in
advance of a Systemwide increase in the rate.

Such an approach might be

considered at a time when some further warning of a need for caution
seemed desirable, but when the over-all credit situation had not yet
fully crystallized to show a clear basis for a nationwide advance in the
discount rate.

Perhaps an experimental increase might be made in one or

two districts where inflationary pressures seemed considerably stronger,
and where the Reserve Bank directors were more firmly convinced of the
need for immediate action.

Should such warning steps prove sufficient,

&ud should no need for further action appear, the discount rates of these
districts might subsequently be lowered.
The direct effects of a local tightening through an increase
dn the discount rate would come about partly through increasing the
actual cost of member bank borrowing in the affected districts, but it




IV - 3

would also be reinforced as the relatively high discount rate led local
banks to rely to a greater extent upon borrowing from banks in other
districts, or upon sales of short-term securities in the national money
market.

These direct effects would be greater, of course, if the mem­

ber banks in the districts with higher discount rates were already
heavily in debt, and if their portfolios of marketable short-term Gov­
ernment securities had already been drawn down close to the prudent
minimum.

Raising the discount rate in one or two districts would also

exert a further effect, however, upon all banks throughout the country
by creating an expectation that the discount rates of other Reserve
Banks might soon follow.
It is possible, too, though perhaps less likely, that nation­
wide reductions in the discount rate might at times be desirably initiated
in this step-by-step manner.

If disturbing economic developments were

localized within one or a few Federal Reserve districts, the encourage­
ment given to member bank borrowing by a decisive reduction in the
discount rate of the districts involved might help to prevent a spreading
°i* the initial disturbing influences throughout the remainder of the
economy.

Or there might be occasionswhen, without the occurrence of

dramatic episodes, the

System wished to move cautiously in the direction

°f a slight easing in the national monetary policy.

An exploratory

reduction in discount rates by those districts whose Reserve Bank
directors felt most inclined to move in the direction of ease might serve
some purpose under such circumstances.




IV -

h

The judgment rendered in specific instances must find a
balance between the considerations favoring use of the step-by-step
approach, and a recognition of the inherent implications of the exist­
ence of a national credit market, such as has been developing over the
lifetime of the Federal Reserve System.

In so far as discount rate

action is taken in stages with a view to exerting a nationwide in­
fluence upon the psychology of the banks, the existence of the nation­
wide credit market presents no barrier.

But in so far as the direct

effects of a higher discount rate upon the affected banks are concerned,
they might under some circumstances be largely negatived if these banks
were, as a matter of course, accomplishing needed reserve adjustments
through transactions in the short-term Government security market.

Of

course, some banks might have relatively small portfolios of short-term
Government securities; other banks might reach such a position if they
unloaded short-term Governments over a long period in order to avoid
borrowing from their own Reserve Bank at the higher discount rate.

In

effect, then, the measure of local tightness likely to be directly
achieved through a higher district discount rate will be conditioned by
the portfolio positions of the banks in that district.
The existence of a nationwide market in short-term Government
securities thus serves to limit, to the extent that banks customarily rely
uPon it for reserve adjustments, the local impact of a regional change
iu discount rate.

Unless a higher discount rate in one district could

expected to produce a corresponding increase in shorter-term interest
rates in the national money market, the effect of a higher regional




IV - 5

discount rate would be confined to those banks which were marginally
dependent upon borrowing, and had not adjusted their affairs suffi­
ciently to enable them to meet their expected reserve adjustment needs
through transactions in the national market for Treasury bills or re­
lated instruments.

For the banks equipped to meet their needs through

the national market in

Treasury bills, a rise in the discount rate of

their own Federal Reserve Bank would be limited to its symbolic signifi­
cance -- any effective marginal restraining influence for these banks
vould be that exerted through increases in Treasury bill (or related)
yields in the national market.

Thus, if market conditions are such

that the banks rely upon adjustments through Treasury bills and related
instruments, and so have little occasion for dependence upon borrowing,
the scope for local effectiveness of regional discount rates would seem,
t>y implication, to be narrowed.
Special District Problems Justifying Temporary
Deviations from National Policy
While it may be generally agreed that some surveillance of
Member bank borrowing will always be necessary on the part of each
Federal Reserve Bank, the difficulties encountered in exercising that
surveillance in an equitable and impartial manner may vary among dis­
tricts depending upon the intensity of local credit demand.

In keeping

v ith the general principle that credit control should rely, so far as
Possible, upon the impersonal workings of the price mechanism, some
districts may find at times that they could reduce the burden and difficulty of "policing" their borrowings by imposing instead a higher




IV - 6

discount rate.

Judgment of such a need WbUld depend, of course, upon

the experience of the individual Reserve Bank concerned, and upon its
conviction that a change in its discount rate (within whatever range
would be considered a practical possibility) could materially alter
the complexity of the "policing" problem.

In appraising whether or

not itB "policing" program is working satisfactorily, the individual
Reserve Bank would probably also wish to take into account the intan­
gible advantages of the special kind of restraining influence that is
exerted upon banks when they are in debt, and subject to surveillance.
Such considerations might have little weight, however, if the System
should have determined that such intangible aids to the fulfillment of
credit policy objectives are not worthwhile.
If a Reserve Bank should decide, on the basis of the types of
Policing" difficulties being encountered, that it would like to experi­
ment with the effectiveness of a higher discount rate, the principle of
Regional administration of the discount mechanism (as embedded in the
Federal Reserve Act) would suggest that the individual Reserve Bank
should be permitted to make the experiment.

The Board of Governors, on

"the other hand, in deciding whether or not to approve the recommended
increase, would also have to take into account the possible nationwide
Repercussions upon banking psychology of the change in a given district.
1’he basis for approving the change might be relatively simple, however,
if such action should also coincide with a general desire to take initial,
experimental steps toward further tightening in the national discount
Rate, as described above.




IV - 7

. I

11

Regional Balhhtie cjf,I?agents Problems
An important segment of the classical theory of central bank
discount rate action concerned the need to raise or lower the discount
rate as a means of correcting balance of payments difficulties.

A

nation losing reserves was expected to raise its discount rate in order
to attract funds; a nation gaining reserves was expected to lower its
rate, and thus through a resulting general decline of other money market
rates discouraged a further inflow of capital and help to reduce the
"unbalance" in its balance of payments.

While the classical theory

sometimes ran aground, in attempting to reconcile these principles of
international adjustment with the domestic need for economic stability
(as witness the System's own experience in 193l)> there were nonetheless
many times when appropriate discount rate action exerted a helpful cor­
rective influence upon balance of payments maladjustments.

There may be

Qome analogous grounds for considering discount rate differentials among
the Federal Reserve Banks.
Two broad classes of possibilities exist in which there may at
times be a place for differential discount rates as one of the appropriate
®eans of helping to smooth out regional economic differences reflected
in inter-regional balances of payments and the flow of funds.

One would

he longer-run structural differences, as between a region that has re­
gained relatively depressed over a long period and the rest of the country.
The other possibility relates to the temporary emergence in a given dis­
trict of depressed, or unusually stimulated, economic activity -- which
May have its counterpart in a temporary outflow of funds to the rest of
the country, or a temporary inflow from the rest of the country.




IV - 8

Sustained Structural Differenced

One district, or group of districts, might he lagging
considerably behind the economic growth of the remainder of the country,
and as a consequence might be steadily losing funds on capital account
to the rest of the country.

In such circumstances, under the classical

theory of the international central bank discount mechanism, the affected
district might wish to increase its discount rate in an effort to check
the persistent drain on its funds.

It might be objected by some within

the district that such action, in so far as it tended to make money
more costly within the district than elsewhere in the country, might
exert unwanted effects, perhaps dampening the prospects for further
local development.

Such critics might suggest, instead, that a lower

rather than a higher discount rate was appropriate in relation to the
remainder of the country.

Such conflicting judgments cannot be recon­

ciled in any generalized theory of regional behavior, any more than
they can be reconciled in the classical theory of central bank discount
rate action.

The reconciliation, leading to a choice of one course or

the other, has always depended upon a detailed analysis of the circum­
stances prevailing in the individual case.

However, to mention these

conflicting prescriptions is not to deny that a case may at times exist
for a differential discount rate in order to help correct an outward
r
flow of funds from a relatively depressed economic area.
If in the actual circumstances of a given case there is general
agreement within a district that individual action affecting its own
discount rate could prove helpful, it is important to keep open the




IV -

9

opportunity for such independent hCtidhi

Because of the opportunities

for conflicting interpretation of the need, however, it would seem
essential that a district embarking on such action should do so only
when the case is definite and clear.

One further technical difficulty

that would have to be considered is the fact that interest rates in a
Federal Reserve district, quite unlike the interest rates in a given
nation under the classical theory, do not move up and down sympatheti­
cally with independent changes in the district's discount rate.

Owing

partly to the pervasive influence of the existing nationwide market for
short-term credit instruments, a regional discount rate may have rela­
tively little effect in changing the interest rates at which market
lending and investing decisions are taking place.

Perhaps the direct

path of influence in the case of a regional increase in the discount
rate, for example, is likely to be through discouraging member bank
borrowing, and thus encouraging member banks to obtain needed funds
from others by paying slightly higher rates.

How widespread and

effective this influence might be in checking or offsetting an outward
3rain of funds would depend in part, at least, upon the extent to which
member banks in that district were actively borrowing.

If the district

Were suffering sustained depression, that volume of borrowing might be
less than sufficient to produce the effects envisaged by the classical

At the other extreme, a given district or region might be in
"the throes of a sustained developmental boom, fed in considerably part
by a continuing expansion in local bank credit.




I V - 10

If the local Reserve

i

I

Bank decided that this boom had readhedj or threatened to reach, dan­
gerous proportions, it might want to consider specific local action
aimed at slackening the tempo of credit expansion by local banks.

In

such circumstances, a strict reading of the classical doctrine might
suggest that it should raise its discount rate in order to check this
expansion and force the investment boom to proceed, if at all, on the
basis of savings drawn from local and outside sources.
Decision to raise the local discount rate would not neces­
sarily reflect lack of concern over a speculative boom based on an
inflow of funds from outside, but would imply somewhat greater emphasis
upon the need to sound a note of caution with respect to the rate at
which local bank credit was flowing into expansion projects, and to
limit the direct access of local banks to Federal Reserve credit.
Again in this situation, as in that of a depressed region, the impact
of any independent discount rate action might be somewhat diffused
because of the close interrelations between the money market instruments
used in that district and those in the national money market.

However,

even after taking all of these factors into consideration, the directors
of the given Federal Reserve Bank might find that independent action
w ith respect to the discount rate would serve a helpful purpose.

If no

harmful consequences would be likely to result in terms of the national
monetary and credit policy, a case would then exist for separate discount
rate action in this district.




IV - 11

Temporary Balance of Payments P r o b l e m
i

In contrast with the conditions that might justify sustained
differentials for balance of payments reasons over a period of many
months, or perhaps years, there may also be short-run developments that
give rise to particular local problems.

In years past, depressed condi­

tions in agriculture might have justified independent action to assist
banks in carrying the credit needs of farmers.

While such needs might

still arise, the growing diversification that has taken place within all
Federal Reserve districts over the past two decades makes it difficult
to classify very many districts any longer as primarily agricultural in
character.

Nonetheless, should there be a particularly bad year for

crops or livestock in one or more districts, and should the related
problems become of dominant importance in the economy of the given dis­
tricts, some special discount rate action might be one of the appropriate
methods used to ease the strain.

Conversely, in years of unusual agricul­

tural surpluses, there might be an overriding need for special credit
accommodation, provided any action taken with respect to the discount
rate could be made consistent with the prevailing national policy con­
cerning the appropriateness of facilitating borrowing by the member banks.
Agriculture offers only one illustration; there can be many
others.

In general, these temporary circumstances producing dangerous

local booms, or local depression, could justify independent action in
one or more Federal Reserve districts so long as it was clear that the re­
straint or inducement exerted by the discount rate action could produce
tangible results in the local circumstances.




IV - 12

The need here is not for a

detailed delineation of cases> but mefely for a recognition of the
possibility that reasons for considering separate action might arise.
Conclusions
This memorandum has not attempted to develop a case for, nor
a case against, the use of discount rate differentials by the various
Federal Reserve Banks.

Instead, it has proceeded from a recognition of

the need to study all possibilities for further development of the dis­
count mechanism as a flexible and adaptable instrument, in meeting not
only the national needs for credit control, but also the differences
among local situations that may arise from time to time.

The need to

rely upon the discount mechanism as an instrument of national policy
■will always necessarily impose some limitations upon the extent to which
individual districts may experiment with differentials intended to meet
unique local situations.

Moreover, the further integration of various

regions into a national credit market, at least for the marketable short­
term instruments of credit, has greatly changed the environment within
■which individual Reserve Bank discount rate action can take place, in
contrast with the environment of even twenty or thirty years ago.

Also,

the growing diversification as among industry and agriculture throughout
the nation has also tended to remove the basis for differentials which
existed when System policy could effectively distinguish between the
Predominantly agricultural and the predominantly industrial sections of
the country.
These developments change the context within which differen­
tial discount rates may be developed.

They also indicate a need for

Reliance upon somewhat different criteria in establishing differentials




IV - 13

from those used in the 'twenties.

They do not indicate, howeVer, that

the regional administration of the discount rate and the discount
mechanism has become an historical anachronism.

Within the three broad

areas surveyed in this memorandum, the directors of individual Federal
Reserve Banks may still, from time to time, find a justifiable basis for
establishing different discount rates in their own districts from those
prevailing elsewhere.

These bases for establishing differentials are

sufficiently different, and the environment within which they will work
has sufficiently changed, however, to

.suggest that any action to be taken

will have to depend upon extensive study of the new ground and the specific
conditions of the given case.
precedents of the 'twenties.

It will not be possible to rely upon the
This is now a frontier calling for cautious

exploration.




Robert V. Roosa, Assistant Vice President,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

IV - lb

V.

APPROPRIATE AND INAPPROPRIATE USES
OF RESERVE BAI'lk CREDIT

During the past 2 years member bank borrowing from Federal
Reserve Banks has increased substantially, as the availability of
reserves derived from open market operations has been restricted rela­
tive to the demand for reserve funds.

Furthermore, as market prices of

Government securities have declined, numerous member banks have been
inclined to make short-term adjustments in their reserve accounts
through the use of discounts and advances, rather than selling Govern­
ment securities at prices involving a principal loss.

In brief, since

the Federal Reserve-Treasury accord, in carrying out a moderately re­
strictive credit policy, the System has not provided member banks with
an amount of reserves through its own initiative that the market has
judged as adequate to meet its requirements.

This development - i.e.,

the revival of the use of the discount process - has raised problems
which justify a re-examination of some of the basic principles under­
lying the use of Reserve Bank credit.
The Federal Reserve Act places upon the directors and officers
°f the Reserve Banks responsibility for the extension of Reserve Bank
credit to member banks through discounts and advances.

The Act charges

the Board of Directors of each Reserve Bank to "administer the affairs
°f said bank fairly and impartially and without discrimination in favor
°f or against any member bank or banks."l/
ment of each Reserve Bank

In other words, the manage­

must administer its affairs, including the

extension of its credit to member banks, in a consistent and impartial

P




Federal Reserve Act, Section h, paragraph 8.
V - 1

manner with respect to all member banks that seek Reserve Bank credit
under the same set of conditions or for the same general purposes.

Uses

of Reserve Bank credit that are considered appropriate (or inappropriate)
in the case of one member bank also must be so considered in the case
of any other member bank.
Fair and impartial administration of Reserve Bank credit
extension requires not only that the officers and directors of the
Reserve Banks be in possession of adequate quantitative and qualitative
information regarding discounts and advances but also that they observe
consistent policies with respect to appropriate and inappropriate uses
of Reserve Bank credit.

The Federal Reserve Act, recognizing the need

for adequate information as an aid to policy determination, directs the
management of each Reserve Bank to "keep itself informed of the general
character and amount of the loans and investments of its member banks
with a view to ascertaining whether undue use is being made of bank
credit for the speculative carrying of or trading in securities, real
estate, or commodities, or for any other purpose inconsistent with the
maintenance of sound credit conditions; and, in determining whether to
grant or refuse advances, rediscounts or other credit accommodations,
the Federal Reserve Bank shall give consideration to such information."2/
The mere fact that the demand for Reserve Bank credit by mem­
ber banks is strong or has increased sharply may not in itself be a re­
flection of an excessive or improper use of Reserve Bank credit; such a
development may indicate merely a credit demand that is consistent with
high-level or expanding production, employment, and incomes.

Moreover,

it may involve uses of Reserve Bank credit that are consistent with a




reasonable interpretation of appropriate uses of Reserve Bank credit.
There have been occasions in the past, however, when the demand for
credit was strong, when member banks have sought Reserve Bank credit
for purposes not consistent with the spirit of the Federal Reserve Act
or with sound principles of central banking.

Since such occasions

undoubtedly will recur, the directors and officers of the Reserve Banks
must be in a position to determine whether the purposes for which mem­
ber banks seek Reserve Bank credit will be appropriate or inappropriate
uses of such credit.
Neither the Federal Reserve Act nor Regulation A of the Board
of Governors, relating to discounts for and advances to member banks,
defines explicitly and exclusively the meaning of "appropriate uses” of
Reserve Bank credit borrowed by member banks.

This failure to be spe­

cific, however, is not surprising because legislation and official
interpretations of legislation rarely spell out in a specific manner
the full meaning, intent, and applicability of the legislation.

The

Federal Reserve Act, however, does set forth certain general principles
as guides to the administration of Reserve Bank credit.

In addition,

regulations, rulings, and official statements of the Board of Governors
have reiterated and clarified those principles.
The Federal Reserve Act states that the Board of Directors of
each Federal Reserve Bank may "extend to each member bank such discounts,
advancements, and accommodations as may be safely and reasonably made
with due regard for the claims and demands of other member banks, the
Maintenance of sound credit conditions, and the accommodation of comMerce, industry, and agriculture."3/

Regulation A of the Board of

^7~~Federal Reserve Act, Section h, paragraph 8.




V - 3

Governors paraphrases this general principle and adds, "The guiding
principle underlying the discount policy of the Federal Reserve Banks
is the advancement of the public interest."U/
In discussing guides to credit policy as early as 1923* the
Board of Governors stated:
"The Federal Reserve Act has laid down as the broad prin­
ciple for the guidance of the Federal Reserve banks and of the
Federal Reserve Board in the discharge of their functions with
respect to the administration of the credit facilities of the
Federal Reserve Banks the principle of 'accommodating commerce
and business.' . . . further guides are to be found in Sec­
tion 13 of the Federal Reserve Act* where the purposes for
which Federal Reserve credit may be provided are described as
'agricultural, industrial, or commercial purposes.' It is
clear that the accommodation of commerce and business contem­
plated as providing the proper occasion for the use of the
credit facilities of the Federal Reserve banks means the ac­
commodation of agriculture, industry, and trade. The exten­
sion of credit /against paper/ for purposes 'covering merely
investments or issued or drawn for the purpose of carrying on
trading in stocks, bonds, or other investment securities, ex­
cept bonds and notes of the Government of the United States,'
is not permitted by the Federal Reserve Act. The Federal Re­
serve System is a system of productive credit. It is not a
system of credit for either investment or speculative pur­
poses. Credit in the service of agriculture, industry, and
trade may be described comprehensively as credit for produc­
tive use. The exclusion of the use of Federal Reserve credit
for speculative and investment purposes and its limitation to
agricultural, industrial, or commercial purposes thus clearly
indicates the nature of the tests which are appropriate as
guides in the extension of Federal Reserve credit."5/
The productive character of the intended use of Reserve Bank
credit also is indicated in Regulation A, where, in discussing the
eligibility of paper for rediscount, it is stated "which has been issued
°r drawn, or the proceeds of which have been used or are to be used, in
Producing, purchasing, carrying or marketing goods in one or more of
the steps of the process of production, manufacture, or distribution,
57

Regulation A, Statement of general principles, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System* October 1, 1937* revision.
5/ "Tenth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1923, page 33*




V-

h

or in meeting current operating expenses of a commercial, agricultural,
or industrial business, or for the purpose of carrying or trading in
direct obligations of the United States . . ."6/
On March 2, 1951, the Federal Open Market Committee directed
its Executive Committee "to arrange for such transactions for the
System Open Market Account . . .

as may be necessary, in the light of cur­

rent and prospective economic conditions and the general credit situation
of the country, with a view to exercising restraint upon inflationary
developments, to maintaining orderly conditions in the Government security
market, to relating the supply of funds in the market to the needs of com­
merce and business . . ."7/

This directive, which was repeated during the

remainder of the year and in 1952 , also reflects the basic characteristic
that appropriate uses of Reserve Bank credit are intimately and directly
associated with the requirements of the productive economy; only the
concept of maintaining orderly conditions in the Government security
market is added.

Later in 1953, the phrase "correcting disorderly condi­

tions" was substituted for the phrase "maintaining orderly conditions."
The responsibility assumed by the Federal Reserve System to
correct disorderly conditions in the Government security market, however,
does not alter the concept of appropriate uses of Reserve Bank credit borrow­
ed by member banks,

within the Federal Reserve the initiative and decisions

vdth respect to correcting disorderly conditions in the Government security
market rest solely in the Open Market Committee.

That responsibility

is not implied in any degree to the member banks; in fact, it may be
5"/
7/

Regulation A, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
October 1, 1937, revision, page 1.
"Thirty-Eighth Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System," 1951, page 101.




V- 5

worth noting that no initiative in this respect is permitted even to
the Federal Reserve Banks.
From the foregoing discussion, it seems apparent that the
administration of discount policy by the Reserve Banks involves a quali­
tative, as well as quantitative, approach.

Moreover, this position is

just as valid when member banks obtain Reserve Bank credit through ad­
vances on Government securities as when they rediscount eligible paper.
Furthermore, the use of eligible paper as a means of access to the dis­
count window is not necessarily more revealing in its qualitative aspects
than the use of Government securities underlying advances.

It is rarely

ever possible to trace the exact use of a specific borrowing.
In directing the management of each Bank to keep itself in­
formed regarding the general character of the loans and investments of
its member banks, as well as the amounts, in order to determine whether
undue use is being made of bank credit for certain specific purposes,
Section U of the Federal Reserve Act emphasizes the qualitative aspect
of the use of Reserve Bank credit.

Moreover, on a number of occasions

System officials have ruled against the use of Reserve Bank credit for
specific qualitative purposes.

In brief, there is a degree of selectivity

inherent in the discount process that is not present in such Federal
Reserve powers as changes in reserve requirements or open market opera­
tions.

Furthermore, that degree of selectivity is based on both quan­

titative and qualitative considerations, with the responsibility for such
determinations resting with the officers and directors of the Reserve
Banks.




V - 6

Referring again to the Annual Report of 1923, the Board
stated, "The Federal Reserve banks are the country’s supplementary res­
ervoir of credit and currency, the source to which the member banks
turn when the demands of the business community have outrun their own
/member bank/ unaided resources. . . .

It is its /Federal Reserve Sys­

t e m ' ^ responsibility to regulate the flow of new and additional credit
from its reservoirs in accordance with solid indications of the economic
needs of trade and industry."8/
In addition to the reference to the economic needs of trade
and industry, the foregoing statement of the Board emphasizes two very
important fundamental principles:

(1 ) the supplementary character of

Reserve Bank credit and (2) the presumption that member banks will meet
the requirements of agriculture, commerce, and industry with the use of
their own resources fully, before seeking Reserve Bank credit.

The

extension of Federal Reserve Bank credit to member banks through dis­
counts and advances is primarily intended to assist them in meeting
certain seasonal requirements and temporary or short-term emergency
situations arising out of developments in commerce, industry, and agri­
culture.

It is not intended that member banks shall borrow from the

Reserve Banks to obtain reserves to meet all of their seasonal credit
requirements; nor is it intended that member banks shall, in effect,
increase their capital for lengthy periods through the use of Reserve
Bank credit.
With respect to seasonal borrowing from Reserve Banks, indi­
vidual member banks may be expected to meet those normal seasonal
$/

"Tenth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1923, page 10.




V - 7

requirements which may be anticipated, largely through adjustments in
their asset positions.

In other words, certain secondary reserves,

such as Treasury bills and other short-term Government securities,
should provide member banks with considerable flexibility in being able
to meet seasonal loan requirements; moreover, such adjustments should
be resorted to before Reserve Bank credit, through discounts or advances,
is sought.

The fact that member banks may be in a "fully invested"

position with substantial holdings of high-quality, relatively liquid
secondary assets at a time of strong seasonal loan demand is not in it­
self a justification for resort to Federal Reserve credit through
borrowing; in fact, it may represent a strong case against such borrow­
ing.
It is recognized that the Federal Reserve Banks are the prin­
cipal source of new reserves to the banking system.

Consequently,

to the extent that an increment to reserves is necessary to meet the
total credit requirements of the seasonal period, such reserves must
be provided by the System.

Provision of such marginal reserves to

the market, however, is a different matter than providing individual
member banks with reserves to meet their full seasonal loan require­
ments.

For instance, the System, through open market operations,

might provide the market with reserves to meet' a substantial part
of the seasonal requirements, thus making it possible for member banks
to make adjustments in their asset positions through operations in the
market.

Member banks should attempt to obtain such funds through asset

adjustments in the money market before seeking Reserve Bank credit.




V - 8

Member bank borrowing from Reserve Banks for seasonal purposes is appro­
priate and justifiable only to the extent that the supply of reserves in
the market is not adequate to permit secondary reserve adjustments or
that rigidities or imperfect market situations impede such adjustments.
The short-term characteristic of Reserve Bank credit is
clearly established by provisions of the Federal Reserve Act.

The

rediscount provisions of the Act limit the maturity of such credits to
90 days, with the exception of rediscounts of agricultural paper, which
may carry a maturity of 9 months, 9/

Advances against member bank notes

secured by Government securities are limited to I S days under the sec­
tion of the Act dealing specifically v.ith this type of credit,10/ al­
though the Board of Governors has ruled that such advances may be made
for 90 days under the section of the Act dealing with "advances to in­
dividuals, partnerships, and corporations."11/

The rediscount period
•»
of 90 days generally permitted by the Act tends to coincide roughly

with the seasonal and productive cycles in commerce and industry, while
the 9-month period tends to relate more nearly to the full agricultural
cycle.

Fifteen-day advances to member banks against the security of

Government securities were designed to enable member banks to obtain
Reserve Bank credit quickly and economically to meet very short-run
unanticipated situations.
Official statements made at different times during the history
of the System also tend to support the short-term character of Reserve
Bank credit.

~9/
10/
11/




For instance, when the Federal Reserve Act was amended to

FederalReserve Act,
FederalReserve Act,
FederalReserve Act,

Sections 13 and 13a.
Section 13, paragraph 8.
Section 13, paragraph 13.

V - 9

permit 15-day advances to member banks against Government securities,
the Board in its recommendation to the Congress stated that such ad­
vances should be permitted "in order to enable member banks to obtain
prompt and economical accommodations for periods not to exceed 15 days,"i§/
Later, referring to the same privilege, the Board stated that the amend­
ment promised to be very helpful, "as it affords them /Reserve banks7
the means of supplying more economically the requirements of member banks
1T /

for short-time accommodation."_£/

Finally, in 1917, still on the

same subject, the Board stated, "It seems that in some districts Federal
Peserve banks have been encouraging renewals of paper of this kind.
While the Board does not wish to prohibit the renewal of a 15-day note,
it feels that the renewal should be an exception, rather than the rule."— /
Although the short-term characteristic of Eeserve Bank credit
is recognized, there remains the problem that may arise out of very frequent,,
or continuous borrowing.

/>s previously noted, it is not within the

spirit or intent of the Federal Reserve Act that member banks shall, in
effect, increase their capital for lengthy periods through the use of
Eeserve Bank credit.

The Board of Governors has spoken on this question

on a number of occasions.
In its Annual Report issued in 1926 the Beard stated:
"Even -where the paper is unexceptionable in every re­
spect, the Peserve bank must be fully assured in addition
that further credit may be granted to this member, not only
'safely and reasonably,' but also 'with due regard for the
claims and demands of other member banks.' This question
arises not infrequently in cases where a member bank remains
127"''Second Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1915, page 22.
1 3 / "Third Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1916, page 5.
Y U / "Federal Reserve Bulletin," 1917, page 879.




V - 10

continuously in debt to a Reserve bank for a considerable
length of time. In such cases, inquiry may fairly be made as
to whether the member bank's use of Reserve bank credit does
not in effect amount to incieasing its own capital out of Re­
serve bank funds. Such use of funds . . . would not be in
accordance with the spirit of the Federal Reserve Act and
would not be fair to the other member banks which may be
active competitors of the borrowing bank. . . . Though there
are circumstances that may explain and justify continuous
borrowing by a member bank over a considerable period of time,
particularly if the need for the borrowing arises from general
economic conditions in the borrowing bank's locality, the
funds of the Federal Reserve banks are primarily intended to
be used in meeting the seasonal and temporary requirements of
members, and continuous borrowing by a member bank as a gen­
eral practice would not be consistent with the intent of the
Federal Reserve Act. In most cases the member bank can make
adjustments of different kinds in its own affairs . . ."15/
Again, in 1928 the Board stated:

"It is a generally recog­

nised principle that . , . continuous indebtedness at the Reserve banks,
except under unusual circumstances, is an abuse of Reserve bank facilities.
In cases -here individual banks have been guilty of such abuse, the
Federal Reserve authorities have taken up the matter with officers of the
offending banks and have made clear to them that their reserve position
should be adjusted by liquidating a part of their loan or investment
account, rather than through borrowing. . . . The tradition against con­
tinuous borrowing is well established, and it is the policy of the
Federal Reserve banks to maintain it."— /
The meaning of continuous borrowing is not explicitly defined
in the statements of the Board of Governors, but the implications of such
statements are sufficiently clear to indicate, in general, the broad
meaning of the term.

For instance,

frequent references to "seasonal

borrowing" or "temporary borrowing" or "short-term borrowing" are
Tj?/ "Thirteenth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1926, page lw
15/ "Fifteenth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1928, page 8.




V - 11

associated with appropriate uses of reserve Bank credit.

On the other

hand, such phrases as "considerable period of time" or "continuous use"
or "continuously for a month or more" are used to indicate in a general
way improper uses of Reserve Bank credit.
The administrative difficulty inherent in the problem

of so-

called continuous borrowing is not as marked in the case of those member
banks which attempt to borrow for prolonged, unbroken periods as it is
in the case of those member banks which attempt to borrow for very
frequent, intermittent periods of from several to, say, 15> days per
borrowing.

In the latter case, over a period of a year the intermittently

borrowing member bank may be increasing its capital through the use of
Reserve Bank credit just as surely and just as substantially as the "long­
term" borrowing member bank,

Yet, it does not seem practical or sound

to establish an arbitrary "debt-free" period - e.g., perhaps 1.5 days for there may be cases in which closely intermittent but very occasional
borrowing might be appropriate and justified.

To illustrate, a bank

might have a justifiable reason for borrowing two or three times in the
course of a year, but those occasions might be closely intermittent,
although borrowing on each occasion might cover only a period of a few
days.

Such a bank vrould not be increasing its capital appreciably through

the use of Reserve Bank credit and, thus, should not be penalized by the
insistence upon a "debt-free" period of some more or less arbitrary length.
In essence, therefore, it seems that the managements of the
Reserve Banks must be guided in their decisions by (l) a clear understanding
of the intent and spirit of the Act with respect to continuous borrowing,




V - 12

(2) a recognition that an attempt by a member bank to maintain a "fully
invested" position undisturbed is not in itself justification for borrowing,
(3) an acceptance of the principle that a member bank should adjust or
strengthen its asset position so as to meet normal situations or those
which the bank might be expected to anticipate through the use of its
own funds rather than Reserve Bank credit, and (/>) the rule of reason
or judgment administered by well-informed reasonable men.
It should be emphasized, however, that administration of discount
policy, in accordance with such principles as those outlined in the
preceding pages of this memorandum, does not require a continuous
restrictiveness.

Federal Reserve credit policy, including policy with

respect to discounts and advances, must be and is intended to be flexible.
It must be adaptable to the type of economic situation that prevails,
4t times when economic activity is declining or when emergency
situations of an economic character prevail or threaten, expansive or
"easy" monetary and credit policies are appropriate.

The Federal Reserve

Act recognizes the importance of placing with the System the power and
authority to be expansive, as well as restrictive or contractive in its
credit policies.

For instance, such sections as Section 13, paragraph 3;

Section 13, paragraph 13; and Section 10b are designed to provide the
System with means of helping to relieve certain emergency economic situations.
This recognition of a flexible, "two-way" power and intent
with respect to credit policy does not void the principles - previously
discussed.

It simply recognizes that the discount policy of the System

should be administered in accordance with the demands of the economic




V - 13

situation at the moment.

In fact, running through the various statements

of System authorities that have been quoted in the preceding pages is the
strong emphasis that discount policy should be considered in the light of
assisting member banks to meet the needs of commerce, industry, and
agriculture.

Those needs ■win be different under conditions of inflation

and expansion from those which might prevail under conditions of deflation
and declining business activity.
Other statements of the Board or officials of the System also
tend to indicate the position of the System with regard to other uses of
Reserve Bank credit.
In 1925 an official of the Federal Reserve System, in a private
publication, made the following statement with respect to borrowing for
profit:
"Since member banks can borrow at the Reserve banks at a
lower rate than they receive from their customers, the ques­
tion arises why member banks do not borrow as much as possibleon the basis of available eligible paper and United States
securities in order to profit by the margin between the dis­
count rate and their own rate to customers. This is due in
part to a banking tradition . . . that a bank must not borrow,
except in emergencies . . . It is also due to the fact that
Federal Reserve banks disapprove the px-actice of bori'owing
Reserve bank funds . . . for the purpose of increasing the
earnings of an individual bank. When a Reserve bank finds
that a member bank is borrowing for such a purpose it uses .
its influence against the continuance of such borrowing."±1/
Later, in its Annual Report for 1928, the Board of Governors
stated, "It is a generally recognized principle that Reserve bank credit
should not be used for profit, . . ."i^/

17/ hFederal Reserve System in Operation," E. A. Goldenweiser, 1929, page 1*8.
lE)/ "Fifteenth Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Board," 1928, page 8.




v -

ik

On certain occasions, the question of borrowing by member banks
from their Reserve Banks for the purpose of increasing borrowed capital
in order to lessen or avoid excess profits taxes has arisen.

The

position of the System with regard to this practice is clearly outlined
in a confidential letter addressed to the presidents of all Federal
Reserve Banks by the Secretary of the Board of Governors in April

19h5.

"Illustrations of the kind of transaction that raised
the question /borrowing against Government securities to in­
crease borrowed capital/ have been presented by reports that
member banks had discounted with Reserve banks their notes
for very large amounts secured by short-term Government obli­
gations currently purchased in the open market. Aside from
any profit due to the difference between the discount rate
and the yield upon the securities used as collateral, it was
apparently thought that the amounts borrowed would enable the
borrowing banks in their income tax returns to set up average
indebtedness that ’rould be sufficient to produce some savings
in, or to eliminate entirely, excess profits taxes which
otherwise would be applicable.
"bhile the practice mentioned above appears to be in its
infancy, it has the possibility of further growth as member
banks approach from an earning standpoint the exposure to the
excess profits tax. The Board of Governors, in bringing this
matter to your attention, suggests that you arrange to review
any unusual application for discount facilities and ascertain
before granting the discount whether the reasons for such ap­
plication are consistent with the proper needs of the bank
for replenishing reserves. The application may come after the
applicant bank has purchased or committed itself to purchase
new securities. Under such circumstances, you may feel that
it is advisable to grant the accommodation temporarily, in
order to avoid ■undue embarrassment to the applicant bank.
If so,
a maturity date should be fixed which will allow the
applicant only sufficient time to liquidate the purchases in an
orderly manner."1 2 /

19/ "Federal Reserve Loose-Leaf Service," Volume IT, #5129.




V - 15

The several quotations from the Federal Reserve Act and from
other official Federal Reserve sources that are presented in the preceding
pages of this memorandum should provide for the directors and officers
of the Reserve Banks adequate tests as to "appropriate" and "inappropriate"
uses of Reserve Bank credit borrowed by member banks.

As indicated

previously, such a determination by Reserve Bank officials must be reached
to a large extent on the basis of rule of reason or judgment and not by
a legalistic or mathematical formula; however, certain broad conclusions
can be drawn regarding proper and improper uses of Reserve Bank credit.
Member bank borrowing from. Reserve Banks for the purpose of
adjusting reserves may be considered as involving an appropriate use of
Reserve Bank credit when such borrowing is for one or another of the
following purposes*
a.

To assist member banks in their responsibility of providing

productive short-term and - to a limited extent - seasonal credit to
business, industry, and agriculture to facilitate the movement of goods
through the productive process from the raw material producer to the
ultimate consumer.
b.

To assist member banks to make such occasional, very

short-term adjustments in their accounts as may be required by such
adverse developments as, for example, a temporary loss of deposits
resulting from shifts of funds or a temporary impairment in the liquidity
of assets.
c.

To assist member banks to meet more or less temporary

situations arising out of adverse economic conditions which appear to




V - 16

threaten the maintenance of sound banking and credit policies, the
achievement of economic stability, or the public interest.
d.

To assist member banks through periods of money panic or

other economic crisis, regardless of the length of the periods.
On the other hand, member bank borrowing from Reserve Banks
should be considered as involving an inappropriate use of Reserve Bank
credit if such borrowing is for such purposes as the following:
a.

To facilitate or support speculative or unproductive

economic transactions.
b.

To borrow primarily for "profit" - i.e., to take advantage

of the arbitrage possibilities in the differential between the rate
charged the member bank for Reserve Bank credit and rates obtainable
by member banks in the open market, or to use Reserve Bank credit for
the primary purpose of obtaining tax avoidance gains, or for any other
such direct and primary "profit" motive.
c.

To borrow "continuously" - i.e., to the extent that the

use of Reserve Bank credit, in effect, tends to represent essentially
an increase in the member bank's capital, rather than merely a temporary
or seasonal supplement to the member bank's funds.
d.

To expand the investment account of the member bank, either

through the purchase of Government securities (other than such purchases
as are related to a secondary distribution of new Treasury issues or
which are in support of Treasury deficit financing during an emergency,
such as a general war) or other securities beyond that point justified by
the inherent continuing

carrying ability of the member bank's o”n asset

structure.




V - 17

e„

To expand loans beyond the member bank's inherent con­

tinuing carrying ability as reflected by its asset structure.

This

limitation should be considered as including the use of Reserve Bank
credit to provide member banks with funds for normal seasonal require­
ments which should have been anticipated and provided for by adjustment
of the member banks' asset accounts.
f.

To engage in any transactions that are either inconsistent

with the objectives of sound credit policy as measured in terms of the
economic situation or inconsistent with the public interest.




V.'atrous H. Irons, Vice President
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

V - 18

V't. A PREFERENTIAL RATE ON
NONCONTINUOUS MEMBER BANK BORROWING

Summary
A preferential discount rate, in addition to the basic rate,
has been suggested to bolster the tradition against borrowing and thereby
strengthen the System's discount and discount rate mechanism.
One plan - for illustrative purposes - would fix a lower
preferential discount rate for borrowing on Government obligations for
15 days or less following at least a 15-day free-of-debt period.

Thus

a spread ’"ould be created between the cost of noncontinuous and other
types of reserve accojnmodation.
The preferential and basic rate plan would have certain
advantages.

It v/ould (1) make noncontinuous borrowing less costly and,

ln effect, penalize abuse, not use of Reserve Bank credit; (2) be flexible
(3) temporarily provide greater freedom to adjust the operative discount
rate; (I4) serve as another guide for a change in System action; (5) bring
the self-interest of borrowers into play to assist Reserve Banks in
Policing use of the discount mechanism, and (6 ) tend to increase
liquidity of borrowing banks.
Certain disadvantages.

On the other hand, the plan would have

It might (l) discriminate in practice against

hanks with heavy seasonal loan demands, (2 ) add - in another respect - to
Reserve Bank policing chores, (3) be exploited to impair some Reserve
Banks' relations with their member banks.

Further, partial alternatives

(more frequent flexing of the basic rate and closer supervision of
borrowing by Reserve Banks) are presently available without the
disadvantages noted.




VI- 1

It has been suggested that a preferential discount rate, in
addition to the basic discount rate, be brought into play to improve
the wtjrking of the discount and discount rate mechanism in Reserve
banking.

This memorandum describes the plan in some detail and notes

the purposes, advantages, and disadvantages of a two-rate device.
Purpose
To put the proposal in proper perspective, it should be noted
that nothing new is proposed in Reserve banking tools.

A preferential

rate on certain member bank borrowing should not be viewed as a new
control gadget.

It is to do nothing more than sharpen the discount and

discount rate mechanism and, like that mechanism, would have its
principal effectiveness in a period of restrictive credit policy.
The return of borrowing as an important means of adjusting
member

bank reserve positions has been accompanied by some weakening

°f the tradition against being in debt to Reserve Banks (or, for that
matter, to correspondent banks).

This wearing thin of the tradition

against borrowing appears to be the result of many things, but,
Particularly, of the example of more and more banks borrowing safely
and profitably.

Furthermore, for the most effective System resistance

bo total bank credit expansion, each borrowing member bank should be
Under pressure to repay funds borrowed from a Reserve Bank.

Continuous

r

borrowing would hamper credit regulation.
The preferential rate device is designed to implement a sagging
tradition against being in debt, thereby strengthening the System's discount
and discount rate mechanism - nothing more.




VI ~ 2

Operation

The essence of the suggested two-rate plan is a spread between
the basic discount rate and a lower preferential rate which would apply
only when certain standards of "noncontinuous" borrowing were met.
Assume, for illustrative purposes, that "noncontinuous" borrowing is
defined as borrowing for 1£> or less days following at least a 15-day
free-of-debt period.i/
Under such a plan, each Reserve Bank would fix a preferential
rate, subject to review and determination by the Board of Governors, that
would apply to all 15-day or less borrowing by member banks, under
Section 13 and collateraled by short-term United States Government
securities, when the borrowing bank had been out of debt to its Reserve
Bank for at least 15 days.

Thus a spread would be created between the

i/ T,,,o points should be emphasized here:
(l) no attempt is made to treat
the legal aspects of the proposed preferential rate and (2 ) no final
determination is made as to the basis of the preferential rate. With
reference to point one, classification of Reserve Bank credit and fixing
discount rates on the basis of the length of time in the past during
which a borrovring member bank has been out of debt to its Reserve Bank
has been questioned. And possible discrimination against certain
seasonal borrowers has been noted. In connection with point two,
several variations as to the basis for the preferential rate are available.
A different out-of-debt and borrowing period might be selected for each
reserve-class of member banks. Access to a preferential rate could be
determined by the ratio of borrowings to reserves. For example, the
preferential rate could apply when daily average borror/ings in a given
reserve computation period amounted to (say) 5 per cent or less of
daily average required reserves in the current or preceding period.
Preferential accommodation could be supplied by means of re-purchase
agreements in connection with short-term United States Government
securities, if this means of establishing a spread between the basic
discount rate and the preferential rate appeared more practicable. A
final choice is not made in this memorandum as to the basis for a
preferential rate. The discussion is grounded on the 15-day or less
borrowing following at least a 15-day out-of-debt period for convenience.




VI - 3

cost of obtaining reserves by other types of discount and rediscount
accommodations and the noncontinuous accommodation.
The preferential rate could be varied from time to time and from
district to district by action of the Boards of Directors of the Reserve
Banks, subject to review and determination by the Board of Governors.
Presumably the spread between the preferential and the basic discount
rates would be sufficient whenever the plan was inaugurated to effectively
promote noncontinuous use of Reserve Bank credit,
Advantages
In performing its limited function, a two-rate or preferentialbasic rate device directed against continuous borrowing would have certain
advantages.
(1)

By means of a spread, borrowing by member banks on Government

securities could be made less costly to those who borrowed irregularly and
infrequently and more expensive to those who borrowed continuously.

In

the sense that continuous borrov/ing is unsound, the device would penalize
abuse rather than use of Reserve Eank credit,
(2 ) A two-rate device has the flexibility to adjust to particular
situations.

The spread between preferential and basic discount rates could

be varied one time as against the next and also by districts.

At a given

time an advantage of (say) l/ h percentage point might be effective
enough to restrain continuous borrowings; at another, the spread might
have to be 1/2 percentage point.

Or at any given time l / h percentage

Point might do an effective job in one district while l/2 might be necessary
■'•h another.




VI -

h

(3) A preferential rate might be flexed without the full psychological
repercussions in the business community that attend a change in the basic
discount rate inasmuch as announcements of preferential-rate changes could
point out (if such emphasis were desirable) that no change was being made
in the basic discount rate,

(to the extent, however, that banks tended

to resort to the discount window soley by way of the preferential rate,
in other words, as this rate became the operative rate and the basic rate
became just another rate posted by the System, changes in the preferential
rate would tend to acquire the psychological significance that basic rate
changes now have for nonborrowers.

Thus this advantage, which would

exist in the early stages, might tend to diminish over time.)
(U) With both rates in effect, increasing use of the higher, basic rate
would serve, along with the aggregate level of borrowing, as an indicator
of the degree of pressure on member banks for reserves.

In addition to

serving as another guide for System action, greater member bank use of
the higher basic rate would tend to tighten the money market without any
further steps by the System, the degree of tightening generated being a
function of the spread between preferential and basic rates and of the
extent of use of the basic rate.
(5) The existence of a lower rate for noncontinuous borrowing would bring
the self-interest of the borrowers into play and to that extent assist
heserve B?nks in their "policing" chores.

(Objection has been raised that

with a two-rate technique banks which borrowed continuously could counter
^Policing objections to such continuous borrowing by noting that they were
Paying the Reserve Bank's prescribed penalty in the form of the higher rate.




VI - 5

It might be pointed out, however, that the spread is a flexible one and
might be widened sharply on a regional basis - by raising the basic rate for short periods to reinforce the Reserve Bank's position and, further,
that policing of the use of its credit cannot be avoided by a Reserve Bank
at any time.

In other words, having the self-interest of the borrowers,

generally, as an aid in preventing continuous use does not absolve a
Reserve Bank from policing the use of its credit in all cases and taking
the drastic step of refusing to grant credit in those instances where
certain situations make continuous use profitable even at the higher rate.)
(6) Readjustment of earning assets by borrowing banks to take advantage
°f the preferential rate might tend to increase the over-all liquidity
of these banks.
disadvantages
On the other hand certain disadvantages would attach to a
preferential rate for noncontinuoug borrowing.
(1) Certain member banks with heavy seasonal loan demands might tend to
be discriminated against.
There are two points of view on the question of discrimination
Against certain seasonal borrowers.

One holds that a preferential rate

^or noncontinuous borrowing would not result in discrimination.
Seasonal Reserve credit demands are supplied for the banking system as a
'"hole (when and to the extent such provision is appropriate) and no
individual bank is discriminated against by being forced to rely on the
national pool of excess reserves or on the national market for
United States CJovernment obligations for all but short-term (15 day)




VI - 6

Reserve assistance through the discount window.

Reserve credit, to the

extent it should te provided seasonally, cannot be made available to a
few member banks to the amount of the entire seasonal bulge in needed
reserves for the full season, even at a rate above the suggested
preferential rate.

Each bank getting into debt to its Reserve Bank should

adjust its assets to repay, even though in the process of such adjustment
the borrowing burden is merely shifted to another bank and the aggregate
level of member bank borrowing is left unchanged.

In fact to provide a

member bank's entire seasonally required reserve needs for the full
season would in effect be favoring this particular bank over other
members and would run counter to the requirements of Section k as to
fair and impartial treatment of all member banks by their Reserve Banks.
The contrary position is that discrimination may exist when noncontinuous borrowing is defined in such a manner as to preclude certain
seasonal borrowers from access to the cheaper rate.

For example, it would

difficult to justify no-discrimination in the case of a borrower
Ceding Reserve assistance for three or four successive reserve computation
Periods when the borrower had substantially reduced its holdings of
^0vernment securities and had made an effort to locate idle reserves
elsewhere in the banking system (either buying Federal funds or laying-off
Part of its seasonal paper to other banks).

If some part of a member bank’s

Seasonally needed reserves may appropriately be supplied via the discount
vindo", ’•hy may not this portion be made available at the preferential
rate (that is, without penalty), particularly if eligible paper is
°ffered for rediscount on a 90-day basis?




VI - 7

In other words, while it is

correct, as pointed out above, that Reserve credit should not be made
available to a member bank to the extent of the entire seasonal
S’lng in its needed reserves, this is not to say that the minimum
seasonal accommodation which is appropriate must be fitted into a noncontinuous pattern or else bear a higher rate.

The contention that there

will always be an appropriate volume of reserves somewhere in the banking
system to accommodate an individual member bank's needs assumes a free
flow of excess funds to the point of need.

In practice, on the contrary,

the process is sticky and otherwise imperfect.
In practice, the proposed preferential rate based on a l£-day
out-of-debt period v'ould appear to discriminate against certain seasonal
member bank borrowers - especially those in the rural areas and those
financing the movement of some crops.
(2) While the Reserve Banks might find their policing burden lightened in
most cases with respect to continuous borrowing, they could find it extended
in another.

Reserve Banks might feel obliged, on occasion, to police the

use of their credit to prevent excessive borrowing by one member bank at
the preferential rate to lend to a bank which had access to Reserve credit
°nly at the higher, basic rate.

(In this connection it should be noted,

however, that even with some leakage through mis-use of Reserve credit in
this manner, continuous borrowing ^ould probably be penalized to some
r

extent by higher costs, although by less than the full spread between
preferential and basic rates.)
O ) A preferential-basic rate spread might be exploited, bank-relationswise,
V

field representatives of large, city banks with adverse effects on

relations between Reserve Banks and smaller member banks.




VI- 8

Such a development

would be of particular importance in those districts with relatively
small proportions of banks in membership.
In addition to these disadvantages, it might be pointed out as
an argument against a two-rate plan that it is possible to gain much of
the broad objective (sharpening the discount tool through restraining
continuous borrowing and strengthening the tradition against borrowing)
in alternative ways without incurring the disadvantages noted.
First, reluctance to borrow, and thus the tradition against
borrowing, can be bolstered by more frequent changes in the existing basic
discount rate.
Second, member banks abusing their use of the discount mechanism
can be disciplined and that discipline can be tailored to fit individual
cases (something that cannot be done with a two-rate device applying
uniformly to all member banks in a district) by shortening the term
°i' the loan requested or by denying the borrowing privilege completely
in extreme cases «•




t

W i l i a m J. Abbott, Jr., Director of Research
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

VI- 9

VII.

TECHNIQUES FOR APPRAISING INDIVIDUAL
BATIK USE OF FEDERAL RESERVE CREDIT

The existence of standards of accommodation governing Federal
Reserve loans, discounts and advances requires the use of administrative
techniques to differentiate between borrowers which do and do -not meet
such standards.

When "eligibility" was the chief standard of accommoda­

tion, analysis concentrated on the determination of the "eligible" status
of paper presented for discount.

Currently, accommodation standards

embody increasing emphasis upon the frequency and magnitude of borrowing
and the use to which borrowed funds are put.

Judging the conformity of

applicants to these latter standards involves detailed appraisals of
individual bank operations.

The purpose of this paper is to describe

techniques which may simplify and sharpen such appraisals.
Appraising the Extent of Borrowing
Accommodation standards governing the extent of individual
"bank borrowing may be set in terms of one or both of two measures: (l)
frequency of borrowings; and (2) relative magnitudes of borrowings. The
method of measurement in either case should be fair and equitable from
the point of view of all member banks which may come under consideration.
Since the primary aim of any borrowing by a member bank is the
acquisition of reserve credit, equal proportions of reserve credit
r
supplied by a Federal Reserve Bank should appear identical in adminis­
trative appraisals.

A complication is introduced by the fact that member

tank required reserves are specified in terms of cumulative totals over
varying periods of time (seven days for central reserve and reserve city
tankB, from fourteen to sixteen days for country banks).




VII - 1

As a result,

all "borrowings "by a bank in any one reserve period are in reality parts
of a single operation.

Thus, among four banks with a $500 million re­

serve requirement in a single reserve period— one reserve city bank
obtaining a one-day loan of $60 million; another with a six-day loan of
$10 million, and a third with two two-day loans of $15 million, and a
country bank with a twelve-day loan of $10 million^/— all obtain an
equal degree of assistance from the lending Federal Reserve Bank in meet­
ing their reserve requirement.

The most convenient statistic for showing

this equality is "average daily borrowing within each reserve period."
This statistic also pinpoints the contrast between a reserve city bank
which borrows $10 million for four days during one reserve week, and
another which borrows $10 million for one day in each of four consecutive
deserve weeks.

It emphasizes the fact that the former bank, while more

heavily dependent upon Federal Reserve credit in one week, is neverthe­
less willing and able to adjust its own assets so as to dispense with
Federal Reserve assistance in three of the four reserve accounting periods.
To be sure, the figure "average daily reserve period borrowings"
Will obscure some secondary differences in borrowing operations.

For ex-

^Ple, a bank which habitually confines its borrowing to the last day of
its reserve period is undoubtedly more precise in its reserve adjustment
than one that does not.

More importantly, country banks have at least

twice as long a reserve period in which to adjust to reserve needs by shifts
ih their own assets as do reserve city and central reserve city banks.
this reason perhaps no figures on borrowings can be strictly com­
parable between country banks and other members.

Such shortcomings,

£/ During a fourteen-day half month reserve period.




VII - 2

however, can be offset in marginal cases by supplemental analysis of
figures.

As a general measure, "average daily reserve period borrowings"

is an equitable and realistic basis upon which to analyze bank borrowing
patterns.
With bank borrowing figures presented on this basis, continuity
of borrowing would be determined by the sequence of reserve periods during
which daily average indebtedness to a Reserve Bank appeared.
If accommodation standards require consideration of the relative
magnitude of borrowing, further refinements in the data become necessary.
Raw data on average dollar indebtedness in each reserve period would need
to be put in relative terms.

For this purpose deposit figures are of

little use because of varying reserve requirements among banks and types
of deposits.

Total capital accounts may be a pertinent measure, but

Primarily when questions of solvency and funds at risk are important.
For general purposes, the most logical comparison is between the amount
of funds provided for reserve credit by the Reserve Bank and the amount
provided by the borrowing bank out of its own resources.

Such a compu­

tation can be made for each reserve period by dividing average daily
"borrowings by either average reserve balances or average required re­
serves.

The difference is usually not significant.

Use of required

reserves as a divisor would avoid variations as banks utilized the
Privilege of carrying

up to a two per cent deficiency over from one

Reserve period to the next; while the use of reserve balances would
give borrowers credit for any average excess reserves which they might
accumulate over the period.




VII - 3
\

Appraising Borrower use of Funds

Accommodation standards may also be set in terms of "acceptable"
uses of funds by banks borrowing from the Federal Reserve.

For example,

current policy might dictate the discouragement of borrowing by banks
vhich are voluntarily draining their reserve position by expanding certain
types of earning assets.

Pertinent questions might be:

teen financing an unseasonal loan expansion?
chasing short-term Governments?

"Has the bank

Has it recently been pur­

Does it now hold Treasury bills which

it can or will sell to replenish reserves?

Upon acquiring excess reserves

subsequent to borrowing, has the bank invested these funds in securities
rather than repaying indebtedness?" Or, in a different vein: "Has the bank
experienced a deposit drain?

For how long?

To what extent has it been

able and willing to meet the drain out of its own resources?" To test
borrower qualification under standards such as these, discount adminis­
trators need to make objective evaluation of changes in bank assets and
liabilities.
A device which can be useful as a starting point in this analysis
Is the requirement that borrowers state a reason for their need of credit.
The proximate reason in almost all cases, of course, will be a prospective
reserve deficiency; but a potential borrower can be asked to describe the
chief cause or causes of the deficiency (e.g., "loan increase," "deposit
decline," "securities purchases").

Such a procedure would (l) serve notice

on borrowers that use of reserve funds is a consideration in granting ad­
vances; (2) give administrative officials a basis for preliminary judgment
°T appropriateness of borrowing; and (3) make easier any administrative
action if quantitative figures subsequently indicate that the actual use
°f funds was different from the purpose originally stated.




VII -

k

Nevertheless, to permit the formation of independent judgment
on borrowing purposes, administrative appraisals must rely primarily upon
analyses of quantitative changes in bank balance sheet items.

The best

measure of the effects on reserves of changes in bank assets and deposits
would be changes in average reserve period holdings.

The calculation of

such changes should be based upon daily data for fluctuating items, and
at least end-of-reserve-period data for all othe’rs.

Such information

will not be uniformly available within a Reserve Bank, however, unless
special reports of this nature are required of borrowers by the Discount
Department.
On the basis of typical Reserve Bank records, reserve period
daily averages of required reserves, excess reserves, and deposits can be
obtained by the discount officer from the Member Bank Accounts Department.
Daily average reserve period figures on purchases of "Federal funds" can
be inferred from records in the wire Transfer Department.

Short-term

movements in some other bank asset items, on the other hand, can be
measured only from one Wednesday close to the next (in the case of
weekly reporting member banks) or from the last Wednesday close of one
month to the last Wesnesday close of the next (in the case of all other
member banks).

This estimation of reserve period averages of asset

holdings by averaging reported Wednesday figures is not always reliable.
Changes in bank assets are reasonably controllable by bank management,
and a number of institutional factors suggest that many management
decisions are not spread randomly over the period between Wednesdays
(e»g., purchases of new Treasury bills each Thursday; final adjustments
°f reserve positions for central reserve and reserve city banks each




VII - 5

Wednesday).

On balance, any adjustment of asset figures (except reserve

balances) based upon an assumption of random changes seems as likely to
introduce new distortions as to remove existing ones.

The expedient

solution is the measuring of asset changes by the simple difference
between reported Wednesday totals; and this has the advantage of con­
forming exactly with the duration of the reserve period for the bulk of
large borrowers.
Further refinement of the measure of deposit changes can be
carried out if so desired.

Since the concern of the appraiser is primarily

with the reserve effect of a condition item change, a given dollar change
in average reserve period deposits could be adjusted to account for the
partially offsetting change in the dollar reserve requirement which would
automatically result.
Given the mechanics of measurement outlined above, the number of
items to be so measured depends upon the degree of comprehensiveness re­
quired.

Since a change in every bank condition item either increases

reserves, decreases reserves, or offsets a change elsewhere in the balance
sheet, all items have to be considered if a perfect balance of sources and
uses of reserve funds is to be obtained.
all-inclusiveness is not required.

For most purposes, however, such

As a minimum, those items or groups

°f items should be isolated which are directly considered in established
accommodation standards.

Items of first importance and most likely

significance are total loans, total securities, total deposits, and bor­
rowings from the Reserve Bank.

Added detail is often desirable to

segregate those particular assets and liabilities which typically show
the effects of a bank adjusting its reserve position without recourse




VII - 6

to the Federal Reserve (i.e., Treasury bills, excess reserves, purchases
of Federal funds).

Experimentation indicates, however, that a comparison

of changes in deposits (change in reserve period average), loans (dif­
ference between Wednesday close figures), Treasury bills (difference between
Wednesday close figures) and all other securities (difference between
Wednesday close figures) usually accounts for the bulk of changes in
average daily reserve period borrowings.
Such comparison can be made on a reserve week basis for central
reserve and reserve city banks which are also weekly reporting member banks ;
but only on a monthly basis (without the Treasury bill segregation) for
most other member banks.

On occasion when apparent inconsistencies are

significant for administrative decisions, the reserve effects of additional
items for which data is available can be calculated as a supplementary
operation.
These figures lend themselves to presentation in a traditional
sources and uses of funds table.

For rapid perusal of a bank’s position

over time, cumulated changes in earning asset and deposit figures can
be charted, by reserve periods, against daily reserve period averages of
borrowings.

(Daily reserve period averages of excess reserves or Federal

funds purchases could also be included if warranted, as in the expectation
that a bank is borrowing for EPT purposes and allowing the funds so
°btained to lie unused in its account.)

A cumulative presentation has

the advantage of indicating any persistent leads and lags in timing.




VII - 7

Once bank balance sheet figures are set up in this fashion, each
drop in deposits or increase in loans or securities can be regarded as a
drain of reserves; and each rise in deposits or decline in loans or

2/

securities as a source of reserves.— '

The interpretation of these reserve-

affecting changes as causes of borrowing changes can then be framed in
terms of the accommodation standards governing the use of Reserve Bank
credit.

As an illustration, if it is determined that borrowing from a

Reserve Bank should not be used to sustain purchases of Treasury securities,
a rise in borrowings and securities holdings in one reserve period which
was not reversed in succeeding reserve periods would be prima facie
evidence of unqualified use of Reserve Bank credit.

Similar generalizations

could be made concerning any other asset or deposit change which is not
considered appropriate for financing by Reserve Bank credit.

The technique

should be equally useful whether standards of accommodation are phrased
in terms of the type of reserve-affecting drain or in terms of the time
lapse between a drain financed by borrowing and the ultimate reduction
in bank liquid assets to repay such borrowing.
It should be stressed, of course, that no single reserve period
summary of this type can be utilized as conclusive evidence of the use to
which borrowed funds were put.
2/

The methods of computing condition item

The fact that some of these changes may be merely bookkeeping offsets
does not detract importantly from the analysis. A loan may be repaid
by check drawn on a deposit in the bank, thus reducing both loans and
deposits without producing any change in total reserve balances; but
the analysis indicated above would assume reserve receipts from the
loan decline equivalent to the reserve drain from the deposit decline,
with no net change in total reserves.




VII - 8

changes will not clearly distinguish, in one reserve period, between a
bank which borrowed funds early in the period specifically to buy bills,
and one which bought bills early in the period expecting to be in surplus
funds only to find that an unexpected last-day deposit drain forced it to
borrow to avoid a deficiency.

But such a distinction would not be called

for unless the latter bank liquidated its bill purchases in succeeding
reserve periods to pay off indebtedness; and this operation would usually
be reflected in the analysis of the following periods.
Nevertheless, this method of appraisal of the use of Reserve
Bank credit becomes more definitive the larger the number of reserve
periods which are considered.

Thus it can be of greatest assistance in

testing conformity with accommodation standards which are set in terms
of protracted or repeated uses of Reserve Bank credit for specific purposes
As an illustration of how changes in bank assets and liabilities
can be organized for appraisal purposes, a sample bank chart covering the
year 19^2 is attached.

Significant interrelationships between borrowings

and other balance sheet changes at this bank might be summarized as follows
This bank underwent a sharp January drop in deposits which was
not recouped until June.

The broad outline of the deposit drain was

financed by the bank without recourse to increased borrowings, although
smaller deposit fluctuations around this trend were often compensated for
by borrowing changes.

While it is a Chicago bank, its deposits did not

drop sharply around the April 1 tax date in 195>2; the bank apparently
serviced its customers by borrowing to buy short bills at the end of
March for quick sale and repurchase with depositors.

In the first half

°f 1952 , the bank occasionally reduced indebtedness by selling bills.




VII - 9

After June, however, the bill portfolio was held fairly stable.

A sub­

stantial total of long Governments were purchased in late June and early
July, and this total was later raised on three occasions.

Beginning at

midyear, very few reserve adjustments were made through sales of Govern­
ments; borrowings were relied upon to bear the brunt of any net differ­
ences between loan and deposit changes.

Deposit swings were quite large,

with short-term movements continuing to be closely matched by offsetting
changes in borrowing.

On the whole, borrowing levels averaged higher in

the second half than in the first half, despite a considerably higher
average level of deposits.

Increases in holdings of loans and longer-

term Governments more than absorbed the excess reserves acquired in
deposit growth after June.




Robert C. Holland, Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

VII - 10

b o r r o w in g s

fro m

f e d e r a l r eser v e b a n k c o m pa red

WITH CHANGES IN PRINCIPAL BALANCE SHEET ITEMS
FOR A SELECTED BANK
Cu mu l at i v e

Mi l l i ons of

Changes From J a n u ar y 2 , 1 9 5 2 ,
W h i c h A r e W e e k l y A v e r a g e s Of

Dollars




Except F o r B o r r o w i n g s
Daily F i g u r e s

Weekly

Millions

CHANGES

19 5 2

OF

ARE

BASED

AMOUNTS

BEGINNING

ON

of

Dollars

AVERAGES

OUTSTANDING

AND

END

OF

AT

WEEK.

ected Balance Sheet Items
mi
2C

pie Borrowing Central Reserve City Bank in Chicago
iary 2, 1952 - August 12, 1953
ion dollars
cum ulative change since January 2, 1952
■■■-—

16

loans and discounts
Treasury bills
all other governments
deposits
average daily borrowings
by reserve weeks

12

8

4

0

"4

'8




i i i I i i i I i t_I 1—J I l 1 -L i i i I— i—L j_l_
30

V27

26

730

V

28

6/

25

\o

l

j __ L

JL i

8
27

7
24

,0/

i i i Jl__I__1__L
II
12,

29

726

31

J ___L

28

1II I

’/
25

l

1 1 J___1___L

3/
25

I

I

4/
29

I

I

I

l_

5/
27

< I I II I

6/
24

7/
29

j

RESERVE ITEMS, BY DAY OF RESERVE PERIOD
(in millions of dollars)

Cumulated
totals
RESERVE CITY BANK A:
Reserve requirement........

1

2

3

k

5

6

8

7

9

11

10

Ik

13

12

Daily
average

Per cent of
total reserves
required

Number
of days
in debt

15

10 10 10 10 10 10 10 (reserve period of seven days)

70

10

100$

Reserves provided:
From own resources......

8

8

8

8

8

8

8

56

8

80$

From discounting--- --

2

2

2

2

2

2

2

Ik

2

20$

70

10

100$

56

8

80$

lU

2

20$

7

RESERVE CITY BANK B:
Reserve requirement........

10 10 10 10 10 10

10 (reserveperiod

of sevendays)

Reserves provided:
From own resources.....

8

8

8

8

8

8

8

From discounting.....

14

COUNTRY BANK C:
Reserve requirement.......

(reserve period of fifteen days)
10 10 10 10 10 10

10 10 10 10

10 10

10

10

10

150

10100$

8

120

8

80$

20

30

2

20$

Reserves provided:




From own resources...

8

8

8

8

8

From discounting.,„

2

2

2

2

2

8

8

8

8

8

8

8

8

8

1

VIII.

SUMMARY AND HISTORY OF BOARD'S REGULATION A

REGARDING DISCOUNTS AND ADVANCES BY FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS

'It is the purpose of this memorandum to summarize the contents
of the Board's present Regulation A, relating to discounts and advances
by the Federal Reserve Banks, and to review the historical development
of the regulation, not with the thought that such a memorandum will
necessarily suggest the need for any changes or modification, but with
the thought that it may provide background material which will be help­
ful in connection with the current study of the discount mechanism of the
Federal Reserve System.

Regulation A was last revised in 1937 and has

been amended since that time in only a few relatively minor respects.

I.

STATUTORY BASIS

For an understanding of the nature of Regulation A, and
particularly the extent to which it is purely regulatory, it is desirable
to have in mind the various provisions of the law upon which the regu­
lation is based.

Vfhile the basic authority for discounts and advances

is contained in section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act, other provisions
relating to this subject are to be found in seations ii, 10(a), 10(b),
13a, li*(d), 19, and 2h of the Act.

Briefly, and without reference to

details, these provisions may be summarized as follows:
1.

Discounts for member banks. - The primary authority for

extension of Federal Reserve credit is contained in the second paragraph
of section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act which authorizes the Federal
Reserve Banks to discount for their member banks paper drawn for




-2-

agricultural, industrial or commercial paper, i.e., "eligible paper".
Such paper must have a maturity at the time of discount of not more than
90 days, except that, by virtue of other provisions of the Act, agricultural
paper (including paper of cooperative marketing associations) having a
maturity of not more than nine months is made eligible for discount.
(sec. 13a)

By special provisions, the Reserve Banks are also authorized

to discount factors' paper drawn to finance producers of agricultural
staples (sec. 13 , par. 2 ); sight drafts growing out of the domestic
shipment or the exportation of readily marketable staples (sec. 1 3 ,
par. I4.)j and bankers' acceptances which arise out of the importation or
exportation of goods, domestic shipments of goods, or storage of readily
marketable staples, or which are drawn to create dollar exchange (sec. 1 3 ,
Pars. 7 and 12).

Notes representing loans to finance residential or farm

construction with maturities of not more than six months are expressly
declared eligible for discount as "commercial paper" (sec. 2l|).

No paper

may be discounted if it is drawn merely for investments or for the purpose
°f carrying or trading in securities other than United States obligations,
(sec, 1 3 , par. 2 )
2.

Advances to member banks. - The Federal Reserve Banks are

authorized to make advances to member banks for periods not exceeding
90 days on their notes secured by paper which is eligible under the law
Tor discount or purchase by the Reserve Banks, and to make advances with
futurities not exceeding I S days on notes secured by obligations of the
United States and obligations of the Federal Intermediate Credit Banks,




-3-

the Federal Farm Mortgage Corporation, and the Home Owners' Loan
Corporation,

(sec. 13, par. 8 )

However, advances with maturities

up to 90 days may be made to member banks on direct obligations of the
United States by reason of the specific authority given the Reserve
Banks to make 90-day advances on such obligations to individuals, part­
nerships, and corporations,

(sec. 13, par. 13)

In addition, advances

for periods up to four months may be made to member banks on any security
satisfactory to the Federal Reserve Bank but at a rate of interest not
less than one-half of one per cent higher than the highest discount rate
in effect at the lending Federal Reserve Bank.

(sec. 10(b))

The law

also contains authority for emergency advances to groups of not less
than five member banks under certain conditions, but this authority has
never been utilized,
3.

(sec. 10 (a))
Discounts for Federal intermediate credit banks. - The

Reserve Banks may discount agricultural paper for Federal intermediate
credit banks and also notes payable to intermediate credit banks virhich
cover loans u.ade by such banks under the Federal Farm Loan Act and which
have maturities of not more than nine months and are secured by eligible
paper,

(sec. 13 a)

h . Discounts and advances for individuals, partnerships, and
corporations. - Advances may be made by the Reserve Banks for periods of
not more than 90 days to individuals, partnerships, or corporations on
their notes secured by direct obligations of the United States,
par. 13)




(sec. 13,

In unusual and exigent circumstances, the Board of Governors

-umay authorize a Federal Reserve Bank to discount eligible paper for
individuals, partnerships, and corporations, but this authority has
been exercised only on a few occasions,
5.

(sec, 1 3 j par. 3 )

Paper endorsed by nonmenber banks. - A member bank may

not act as the medium or agent of a nonmember bank in obtaining dis­
counts from a Federal Reserve Bank except with the permission of the
Board of Governors,

(sec. 19, par. 8 )

No paper may be rediscounted

for a Federal intermediate credit bank if it bears the endorsement of
a nonmember State bank which is eligible for membership in the System,
(sec. 13a)

6.

Limitation on discount of paper of one borrower. - The

aggregate of the paper of any one borrower which may be rediscounted
for a member bank may not exceed the amount for which such borrower
could lawfully become liable to a national bank under section 5200
of the Revised Statutes,

(sec. 13, par. 5)

A certificate to the

effect that the borrower's liability does not exceed this amount must
be furnished by every State member bank applying for discounts«
(sec. 9 , par. 1 3 )
7.

Discount rates. - Each Federal Reserve Bantc is required

to establish from time to time, subject to review and determination by
the Board of Governors, rates of discount to be charged for each class
of paper, and such rates must be fixed with a view of accommodating
commerce and business,




(sec. lU(d))

- 5

-

8 , Responsibility of Federal Reserve Banks in extending
credit accommodations. - The board of directors of each Federal Reserve
Bank is required to administer the affairs of such bank fairly and
impartially and without discrimination in favor of or against any
member bank or banks.

Such credit accommodations may be granted mem­

ber banks as may be safely and reasonably made with due regard for the
claims and demands of other member banks, the maintenance of sound
credit conditions, and the accommodation of commerce, industry, and
agriculture.

Each Reserve Bank is required to Keep itself informed

of the general character and amount of the loans and investments of
its member banks with a view to ascertaining whether undue use is
being made of bank credit for the speculative carrying of, or trading
in, securities, real estate, or commodities, or for any other purpose
inconsistent with the maintenance of sound credit conditions; and the
Reserve Bank must give consideration to such information in deter­
mining whether to grant or refuse credit accommodations,

(sec. U,

par. 8 )
9.

Regulatory authority of Board of Governors. - Many of

the provisions above mentioned authorizing discounts and advances
expressly provide that they shall be subject to such limitations and
regulations as the Board of Governors may prescribe.

In addition, the

Board is generally authorized to define the character of paper eligible
for discount (sec. 1 3 * par. 2 ); to regulate the discount and rediscount
of bills receivable, domestic and foreign bills of exchange, and




- 6

-

acceptances (sec. 13, par. 10); and to define the conditions under
which discounts, advances, and accommodations may be extended to member
banks, (sec. h, par. 8 )




-7II.

PRESENT REGULATIOH A

Reflation A includes a restatement, in identical or similar
language, of most of the provisions of law summarized above.

In ad­

dition, it contains certain provisions of an explanatory or interpretative
nature, some which relate to procedural matters, and a few which can
be regarded as strictly and purely regulatory.

These distinctions

will appear from a general summary of the more important provisions of
the regulation.

In this summary no attempt will be made to explain

why and when particular provisions became a part of the regulation;
that will be the purpose of the following historical section of this
memorandum.
The regulation consists of an introductory statement of
general principles; six sections relating respectively to (l) discounts
for member banks (2) advances to member banks, (3) general requirements
as to discounts and advances, (It) paper acquired from nonmember banks,
(5) discounts for Federal intermediate credit banks, and (6 ) bankers’
acceptances; and an Appendix setting forth certain recommendations of
the Board of Governors as to the minimum standards which should be ob­
served by member banks with respect to real estate loans and with
respect to installment paper offered as collateral for advances.
General Principles
The regulation vegins with a brief statement of general
Principles which justifies quotation in full:




-8-

"The guiding principle underlying the discount policy
of the Federal Reserve banks is the advancement of the
public interest. Accordingly, the effect that the granting
or withholding of credit accommodation by a Federal Reserve
bank may have on a member bank, on its depositors and on
the community is of primary importance.
"In extending accommodation to any member bank, the
Federal Reserve banks are required to have due regard to
the demands of other member banks, as well as to the
maintenance of sound credit conditions and the accommoda­
tion of commerce, industry, and agriculture, and to con­
sider not only the nature of the paper offered, but also
the general character and amount of the loans and
investments of the member bank, and whether the bank has
been extending an undue amount of credit for speculative
purposes in securities, real estate, or commodities, or
in any other way has conducted its operations in a
manner inconsistent with the maintenance of sound credit
conditions."
It should be noted that the second paragraph of this statement
of principles is almost a literal restatement of provisions contained
in the eighth paragraph of section I4 of the Federal Reserve Act.
Section 1 .

Discounts for Member Banks

The first section of the regulation follows closely those
provisions of section 13 and 13a of the Federal Reserve Act which
authorize the discounting for member banks of paper drawn for com­
mercial, agricultural, or industrial purposes ("eligible paper") and
of sight drafts growing out of domestic shipments or exportation of
readily marketable staples.

It includes the statutory requirements as

to maturity (90 days as to nonagricultural paper and nine months as
to agricultural paper); the statutory prohibition against discounting
paper brawn merely for investments or trading in securities (other
than United States obligations): the statutory authority for discounting




-9-

six-months residential or farm construction loans, paper of cooperative
marketing associations, and factors' paper drawn to finance producers
of agricultural products; and the statutory limitation on the aggregate
amount of the paper of one borrower which may be discounted.
The section also includes the following provisions which
appear to be intended to explain, clarify, or interpret the provisions
of the law:
1.

In describing "eligible paper" the regulation

spells out the statutory description of such paper as
meaning paper issued or drawn, or the proceeds of which
have been or are to be used, "in producing, purchasing,
carrying or marketing goods in one or more of the steps
of the process of production, manufacture, or distribution,
or in meeting current operating expenses of a commercial,
agricultural, or industrial business,"
2.

With respect to the prohibition against discounting

paper drawn for investments, the regulation makes it clear
that this covers paper the proceeds of which are to be used
for permanent or fixed investments of any kind "such as
land, buildings, or machinery, or for any other fixed
capital purpose."
3.

In keeping with the intent evieenced by section h

of the Federal Reserve Act, the regulation forbids the
discounting of any paper of a "purely speculative character".




-lo­

ll.

In connection with the discount of sight drafts

growing out of the exportation of readily marketable staples,
the regulation defines the term "readily marketable staple"
as meaning an article of such uses as to make it subject to
constant dealings in ready markets xdth such frequent quota­
tions of price as to make the price easily and definitely
ascertainable and the staple itself easy to realize upon by
sale at any time.

5.

The section defines "agricultural paper" as

including paper drawn, not only for the production of
agricultural products, but also for the marketing of such
products, the carrying of such products by growers pending
marketing, and the breeding, raising, fattening or market­
ing of livestock.

6.

It is made clear that paper of cooperative

marketing associations is not eligible for discount if
the proceeds are to be used to defray organization ex­
penses of such associations or for the purpose of acquiring
warehouses, real estate, or other permanent or fixed invest­
ments 0
Procedural in nature is a provision of section 1 which requires
a Federal Reserve Bank to take necessary steps to satisfy itself as to
the eligibility of paper offered for discount.

In this connection,

the regulation states that compliance with the requirement that paper
shall not be drawn for fixed investment purposes may be evidenced by a




-11-

statement reflecting the borrower's financial worth and a reasonable
excess of quick assets over current liabilities.
The only provisions of the section which are of a purely
regulatory nature are those which require all paper offered for discount
to be negotiable.
statute.

Negotiability is not expressly required by the

In this connection, however, the regulation waives the re­

quirement of negotiability in the case of notes evidencing loans made
under programs of the Commodity Credit Corporation, and notes evidenc­
ing loans guaranteed under the V-loan program pursuant to the Defense
Production Act of 1950.
Section 2.

Advances to Member Banks
In general, this section paraphrases the provisions of section 13

of the Act which authorize advances to member banks on eligible paper and on
Government obligations, and the provisions of section 10(b) authorizing
advances on any satisfactory collateral.

It contains no additional

provisions except some of an explanatory or interpretative nature.
Briefly, these are the following:

1.

It is made clear that, notwithstanding the

provisions of the eighth paragraph of section 13 limiting
advances on United States obligations to periods of 15 days,
a Federal Reserve Bank may make such advances with maturities
up to 90 days because of the authority contained in the last
paragraph of section 1 3 .
2.

Section 10(b) provides that advances under that

section shall bear interest at a rate not less than onehalf of one per cent higher than the highest discount rate



-12-

in effect at the lending Federal Reserve Rank.

The regulation

interprets this requirement as referring to the highest dis­
count rate applicable to discounts for member banks under
the provisions of sections 13 and 13 a.
3.

The regulation sets forth illustrative classes of

assets which may be used as collateral security for advances
under section 10(b).

These include not only eligible paper

and Government obligations, but such assets as investment
securities, obligations insured under the National Rousing
Act, obligations of Federal Home Loan Banks, revenue bonds
of States and political subdivisions, and paper representing
real estate loans and installment loans which complies with
the standards set forth in the Appendix to the regulation.
Section 3»

General Requirements as to Discounts and Advances
This section of the regulation is largely procedural in

nature. It restates the statutory requirement that every application
for discount must be accompanied by a certificate to the effect that
the borrower is not liable to the member bank in an amount greater than
that which could be borrowed from a national bank.

It repeats also the

provisions of section R of the Act and the language contained in the
"General Principles" at the beginning of the regulation regarding the
duty of the Federal Reserve Banks to keep themselves informed as to
the character and amount of the loans and investments of member banks
with a view to determining whether undue use is being made of Federal
Reserve credit.




-13In addition, section 3 requires that every application for
a discount or advance must contain a certificate to the effect that the
paper offered has not been acquired from a nonmember bank or, if so
acquired, that appropriate permission has been obtained from the Board
of Governors.

It is also provided that a Federal Reserve Bank may re­

quire a member bank to file financial statements with respect to any
of the parties to the paper offered for discount and with respect to
any corporations or firms affiliated with such parties.
Certain provisions of the section, while procedural in
character, have a bearing upon the effect of particular advances and
discounts upon general credit conditions. It is provided that a
Federal Reserve Bank may require such additional or marginal collateral
as it may deem advisable or necessary for its protection; but, in
determining the amount of any such additional collateral, the Reserve
Bank is expected to give due regard to the public welfare and the
general effects that such requirement may have on the position of the
member bank, its depositors, and the community.

It is stated that

in general a Reserve Bank should limit the amount of such additional
collateral to the minimum consistent with safety.

If the value of

the collateral required exceeds 25 per cent of the amount of the paper
discounted, or 125 per cent of the amount of the advance, as the case
may be, the Reserve Bank is required to include an explanation of the
facts and circumstances of the case in its loan schedule submitted to
the Board of Governors




-14-

Somewhat similar is a provision which requires that if the
amount of any advance made to a member bank on its note secured by
direct or guaranteed obligations of the United States is less than
the face amount of such obligations, the Reserve Eank shall likewise
include an explanation of the facts and circumstances of the case in
its loan schedule.
Section lu

Paper Acquired from Nonmember Banks
Based upon the provisions of section 19 of the Federal Reserve

Act which prohibit a member bank from acting as the medium or agent of
a. nonmember bank in obtaining discounts, this section of the regulation
provides that, without the Board's permission, no Federal Reserve Bank
shall discount or accept as security for an advance any assets acquired
by a member bank from a nonmember bank or which bear the endorsement of
a nonmember bank, unless the assets we re purchased by the member bank
in the open market or otherwise acquired in good faith and not for the
purpose of obtaining credit for the nonmember bank.

The regulation

Prescribes the manner in which any application for permission to dis­
count paper acquired from nonmember banks must be submitted to the Board
°f Governors.

Express permission is granted by the regulation for the

discount of paper bearing the endorsement cf or acquired from Federal
intermediate credit banks.
Section 5.

Discounts for Federal Intermediate Credit Banks
This section restates the provisions of section 13a of the

federal Reserve Act as to the kinds and maturity of paper which may
be discounted for Federal intermediate credit banks.




In addition,

-15-

the section requires any Federal Reserve Bank receiving a discount
application from a Federal intermediate credit bank to give preference
to the demands of its own member banks and due regard to the probable
future needs of its member banks.

A requirement made by the regulation

but not by the law is that, except with the Board's permission, no
Federal Reserve Bank shall discount paper for a Federal intermediate
credit bank when its ovm reserves are less than 50 per cent of its own
aggregate liabilities for deposits and Federal Reserve notes in actual
circulation.
Section 6 ,

Bankers' Acceptances
Ihe final section of the regulation, relating to the dis­

counting of bankers' acceptances, is again mostly a restatement of
the provisions of section 13 regarding the discounting of bankers'
acceptances, the kinds of acceptances which may be made by member banks,
and limitations upon the amounts of such acceptances.

However, the

section includes a number of explanatory or interpretive provisions
based largely on rulings made by the Board during the early years of
the System.
1.

The following examples may be mentioned:
Tire term "bankers' acceptance" is defined as a

draft or bill accepted by a bank or trust company or a
firm, person, company, or corporation engaged generally
in the business of granting bankers' acceptance credits.
2,

The descriptions of the three types of acceptances

set forth in the seventh paragraph of section 13 are some­
what elaborated in the regulation.

Ihus, the statutory

reference to "domestic shipments" is described as meaning




- 1

6

-

shipments of goods within the United States,

Also, the

statutory requirement that acceptances covering the storage
of staples must te secured by a warehouse receipt or other
document conveying or securing title is interpreted as
meaning that such a receipt must be issued by a party
independent of the customer or by a duly licensed ware­
house company; and the regulation specifies certain con­
ditions which must be observed if trust receipts or similar
documents are substituted in lieu of the original documents,
3.

In connection with the statutory requirement that

acceptances for any one customer in excess of 10 per cent
of the capital and surplus of the accepting bank must be
secured by attached documents or other actual security,
the regulation enumerates various types of documents which
will meet this requirement and specifically provides that
trust receipts will not te considered as "actual security"
if they permit the customer to have access to, or control
over, the goods,
U,

With respect to the maturity of bankers' acceptances,

the regulation provides that, in addition to the statutory re­
quirement that the acceptance must have a maturity of not
more than 90 days at the time of discount, any acceptance
discounted should not have a maturity in excess of the
usual or customary period of credit required to finance
the underlying transaction or in excess of the period
reasonably necessary to finance such transaction.




-17-

5.

As a procedural matter, the regulation states that

a Federal Reserve Eank must be satisfied that the acceptance
is eligible for discount and that the bill itself must be
drawn so as to evidence the character of the underlying
transaction, although, if it is not so drawn, evidence of
eligibility may be provided by a stamp or certificate af­
fixed by the acceptor.
Appendix
While not a part of the regulation, and while recognizing
the fact that requirements of individual banks in making loans will
vary according to the circumstances of particular transactions, an
Appendix to the regulation sets forth certain minimum standards which
the Eoard of Governors believes should be observed as a matter of
sound banicing practice in connection with loans on real estate and
loans made on an installment basis.

The Appendix states that these

standards should be taken into consideration by examiners in reviewing
loans of member banks and by the Federal Reserve Banks in passing upon
applications of member banks for credit accommodations supported by
real estate loans or by obligations drawn to finance the sale of goods
°n an installment basis.
With respect to real estate loans, the standards recommended
include those prescribed as a matter of law by section 2k of the Federal
Reserve Act with respect to real estate loans by national banks, i.e.,
that the loan should be secured by a first lien on improved real estate,




-18-

and that the amount of the loan should not exceed 5>0 per cent of the
appraised value of the real estate or have a maturity of more than five
years, except where the loan is to te amortized, in which event the
amount should not exceed 60 per cent of the appraised value of the real
estate, and maturity should not be greater than ten years.

In addition,

the recommended standards call for the maintenance by the member bank
of certain documents, including a recent appraisal of the real estate,
an adequate description of the real estate, evidence of title, and
evidence that there are no delinquent taxes and that the insurance
carried is adequate.
With respect to installment paper, the Appendix recommends
that such paper be secured by a first lien or retention of title to
goodsj that the goods te of such nature as to assure that upon resale
the sum realized will te sufficient to liquidate the loan; and that
isasonable steps will be taken by the member bank to satisfy itself -that
payments will be made in accordance with the terms of the obligation,
Summary of Principal Regulatory Provisions
From the foregoing discussion of the contents of the regulation,
it is evident that the purely regulatory aspects of the regulation are
few.

Most of the nonstatutory provisions merely reflect past rulings

°f the Board interpreting the provisions of the law, such as those
Elating to permanent or fixed capital investments, the meaning of
readily marketable staples, the necessity for an independent warehouse­
man in the case of bankers' acceptances covering storage of readily




-19-

marketable staples, and the insufficiency of a trust receipt as "actual
security" where it permits the customer to have access to the goods.
There are, however, a few provisions of the regulation which
go beyond the requirements of the law.

Of particular importance are

those which require a Federal Reserve Bank to furnish an explanation
of the circumstances of any case in which marginal or additional
security is required by the Reserve Bank beyond a certain percentage
and in which the amount of any advance on Government obligations is
less than the face amount of such obligations.

Additional provisions

not required by the statute are those which require paper offered for
discount to be negotiable and which prohibit discounts for Federal
intermediate credit banks when the reserves of the discounting Federal
Reserve Eank fall below a specified amount.




-20-

III.

HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF REGULATION A

Having in mind the nature and scope of the provisions of
Regulation A as it exists today, it may be of interest and of some
assistance in connection with the current study of the discount mechanism
to review the history of the regulation since 1913 with some indication
of the reasons for the various changes which have led to the develop­
ment of the regulation into its present form.

Such a review will show

the extent to which the regulation reflects changes from time to time
in the past in the discount policies of Congress and of the System different views at different times as to the extent to which Federal
Reserve credit should be made available and as to the proper uses of
such credit.
Certain of the older provisions of the regulation reflect
the emphasis placed on the granting of discounts for "productive"
Purposes during the very early years of the System.

Other provisions

date from the early 19?0's when it was the policy of Congress and the
System to encourage the development of an acceptance market.

Still

others bear witness to the stimulus given by the Agricultural Credits
Act of 1923 to the use of Federal Reserve credit as a means of financ­
ing agriculture.

Finally, many of the provisions of the present regula­

tion grew out of the economic depression of the early 1930's when a
Policy of making Federal Reserve credit more freely available, without
regard to formal reo,uirements as to eligibility of paper, was coupled
V/ith a new emphasis upon the public duty of the System to see that such
°nedit was not used for purposes inconsistent with sound credit conditions.




-21For convenience, and with the realization that such a divi­
sion is arbitrary, a review of the history of Regulation A may be
divided into four periods:

(1 ) the formative years between 1914 and

19 16 , when the regulation was relatively brief and when emphasis was
pieced on the use of discounts for productive purposes; (2 ) the period
between 1916 and 1923 when the regulation was concerned largely with
bankers' acceptances; (3) the period from 1923 to 1937, during the
first part of which emphasis shifted to agricultural credits; and
(4) the period since 1937, characterized chiefly by the major revision
of Regulation A in that year to reflect important changes made in the
law by the Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935.
It should be noted that in the following historical account
of the manner in which various provisions came to be a part of Regula­
tion A, there is necessarily considerable duplication of the material
contained in the preceding section of this memorandum describing the
provisions of the present regulation.

A.

THE FORMATIVE YEARS (1914-1916)

The original Federal Reserve Act contained relatively few
provisions regarding the discount operations of the Federal Reserve
Act.

Section 13 provided, as it does today, for the discounting of

90-day "eligible paper" drawn for agricultural, industrial, or com­
mercial purposes, with the prohibition against the discount of paper
drawn merely for investment or for the purpose of carrying or trading




-22-

in securities other than obligations of the United States.

Agricultural

paper with maturities up to six months was eligible for discount, but
only in an aggregate amount not exceeding a specified percentage of the
capital of the Federal Reserve Bank to be fixed by the Federal Reserve
Board.

Bankers' acceptances were also eligible for discount, but were

limited to acceptances covering the importation or exportation of
goods.

These were the only provisions on the subject, except for a

limitation on the discounting of paper of one borrower.
On November 10, 1914, before the Federal Reserve Banns had
opened for business, the Federal Reserve Board issued several circulars
and regulations relating to discounts by the Federal Reserve Banks.

In

a general statement the Board expressed the view that the functions of
the Reserve Banks were two-fold:

(1) to grant credit facilities, par­

ticularly when abnormal conditions create emergencies demanding prompt
relief, and, on the other hand, (2 ) to protect the gold holdings of
the country so that they may remain adequate to meet all demands.

The

Board felt that credit facilities should be liberally extended in some
parts of the country, but believed it advisable to proceed with caution
in districts not in need of immediate relief.

It stated that, while a

narrow interpretation should not be placed upon the meaning of paper
eligible for discount, there should be certain basic principles to guide
the Federal Reserve Banks and member banks.




These principles were:

-23-

(1) Paper to finance permanent investments should
not be admitted for rediscount.
(2) Only short-term paper with maturities of not more
than 90 days should be discounted; and maturities should be
so well distributed as to enable the Reserve Banks to be
in a position to liquidate, whenever such a course should
become necessary, substantially one-third of all their
investments within a period of 30 bays.
(3) Since single-name paper, unlike double-name paper
does not show on its face the character cf the underlying
transaction, each Federal Reserve Bank should insist that
member banks carefully examine the character of the business
and the general status of the concern furnishing single-name
paper in order to be certain that it was not issued for
purposes of an investment or speculative nature.

To this

end, the Board prescribed a general rule that no paper
should be rediscounted which did not bear on its face evi­
dence of its eligibility for rediscount.

This evidence

could be supplied by a rubber stamp placed on the paper by
the member bank stating that the paper was eligible for
discount and citing the number of the credit file of the
borrower.
The actual discount regulations issued by the Board in
November 191A did little more than restate the applicable provisions




of the lav.

They did, hovever, specifically provide that paper whose

proceeds were to be used for permanent or fixed investments and paper
drawn for merely speculative purposes would not be eligible for dis­
count.
In January 1915j the Eoard issued a regulation on the subject
of "commercial paper" which, after stating the statutory provisions
regarding discounts, provided that in order for a bill to be eligible
for discount, its proceeds must be used in producing, purchasing,
carrying, or marketing goods in one or more of the steps of the process
of production, manufacture, or distribution; that it must not be for
permanent or fixed investments; and that it must not be for invest­
ments of a merely speculative character.
Bankers' acceptances were separately treated in a regulation
issued in February 1915.

In issuing this regulation, the Board ex­

pressed the view that, while the acceptance business was still in its
infancy, its development was certain and, accordingly, the Board had
determined to allow the Reserve Banks latitude in fixing rates for ac­
ceptances within maximum and minimum limits.

It was also stated at

that time that, in accordance with the spirit of the Federal Reserve
Act, preferential treatment should be given to acceptances bearing
the endorsement of member banks even to the point of allowing lower
discount rates for such acceptances.
Separate treatment was also given to trade acceptances and
commodity paper in brief regulations issued in July and September 1915j




-25and it was indicated that discount rates for such paper could be expected
to be lower than the rates established for ordinary commercial paper.

B.

THE BANKERS' ACCEPTANCES PERIOD (1916-1923)

Certain changes were made in the discount provisions of the
Federal Reserve Act by the Act of September 7, 1916, especially with
reference to bankers' acceptances.

Vhereas acceptances previously

had been limited to those growing out of the importation or exportation
of goods, the amendments made by this Act for the first time authorized
the discount of acceptances growing out of domestic shipments of goods
and the storage of readily marketable staples and acceptances drawn to
create dollar exchange.

In addition, the 1916 amendments for the first

time authorized the Reserve Banns to make advances to member banks as
distinguished from discounts, but such advances were limited to 1 5 -day
advances secured by "eligible paper" or by bonds or notes of the United
States.
In the light of these amendments to the law, the Board on
September 15, 1916, issued a regulation which for the first time was
called Regulation A, and which included with slight changes, the pro­
visions regarding the discounting of the various types of paper which
had formerly been coveied by separate regulations, i.e., commercial
paper, trade acceptances, agricultural paper, commodity paper, and
bankers' acceptances.

The principal changes in the new regulation

were changes necessary to conform to the recent amendments to the law

re g a r d in g bankers' acceptances and advances on eligible paper.




-26TJith interest still focused on bankers' acceptances,
Regulation A was revised in 1920 to incorporate certain rulings and
interpretations of the Eoard as to the eligibility of acceptances for
discount.

Thus, the regulation for the first time interpreted

"domestic shipments" a 3 meaning shipments "within the United States";
provided that an acceptance covering domestic shipment of goods must
be supported by shipping, documents attached at the time the draft is
presented for acceptance; and provided that the maturity of'an accept­
ance at the time of rediscount should not be in excess..of the custortiatfy
period of credit required to finance the underlying transaction.
In 1922, the regulation was again revised and again the
changes related almost entirely to the subject of bankers' acceptances,
chiefly changes which eliminated some of the detailed interpretations
included in the previous draft.

In issuing the revised regulation,

the Eoard stated, however, that it was not in any way modifying its
former rulings on the subject, and that the intent of the changes was
merely to "allow greater latitude to Federal Reserve Banks for the
exercise, each in its own way, of their discretion and judgment".

The

Eoard stated also that it would watch carefully the development of the
acceptance business under the simplified regulation and would call to
the attention of the Federal Reserve Banks any apparent "abuse of the
acceptance privilege".




-27C.

THE PERIOD FROM 1923 TO 1937

Emphasis was shifted from bankers' acceptances to discounts
for agricultural purposes by the Agricultural Credits Act of March
1923.

That Act made the following changes in the discount provisions

of the Federal Reserve Act, most of which were for the purpose of making
Federal Reserve credit more available for agricultural purposes;




1.

Factors' paper to finance producers of staple

agricultural products in their raw state was made
eligible for discount;
2.

Reserve Banks were authorized to discount for

member banks sight drafts drawn to finance the domestic
shipment of agricultural products;
3.

As an exception to the requirement that bankers'

acceptances offered for discount must have a maturity of
mot more than 90 days at the time of discount, it was
provided that acceptances drawn for agricultural purposes
could be discounted with maturities of not more than six
months at the time of discount;

U.

By a new section 13a, the Federal Reserve Banks

were authorized to discount agricultural paper having
maturities of not more than nine months, including paper
drawn by cooperative marketing associations, and also to
rediscount paper for the Federal intermediate credit banks.

-28T’
nese changes in the law were incorporated in a revision of
Regulation A issued in July 1923* and only in a few respects did the
revised regulation go beyond the language of the law.

One purely

regulatory provision, however, required the Reserve Banks, in passing
on paper of Federal intermediate credit banks, to give preference to
the demands of their own member banks and to have due regard to the
future needs of their member banks.

It was also provided that no

Reserve Bank should discount such paper if its own reserves were less
than 50 per cent of its aggregate liabilities for deposits and Federal
Reserve notes in actual circulation, and that the aggregate amount of
Paper discounted by all Reserve Banks for any one intermediate credit
bank should not exceed the capital and surplus of such intermediate
credit bank.

Later, by an amendment to the regulation in 1928, these

restrictions with respect to the discounting of paper for Federal
intermediate credit banks were amended so as to authorize exceptions

7d.th the permission of the Federal Reserve Board.

It may be question-

able whether some of these restrictions are necessary under present con­
ditions.
In 192ii, Regulation A was amended so as to require that,
whenever the makers of notes offered for rediscount had closely af­
filiated or subsidiary corporations, separate financial statements
°f such affiliated corporations should accompany the financial state­
ment of the borrower.

This requirement, however, was modified in 1927,

and was further liberalized in 1937 so as merely to authorize a Federal




-29-

Reserve Bank to require the filing of statements reflecting the financial
worth of parties to the paper offered for discount or of any corpora­
tions or firms affiliated with such parties.
In a revision of Regulation A effective January 3> 1928, the
principal change was the insertion of a new section regarding the
discount of paper acquired by member banks from nonmember banks.

In

1921, the Board had granted general authority to member banks to apply
to their respective Reserve Banks for the discount of paper acquired
from nonmember banks, but that authority had been revoked in 19 23 .
In 1926, the Board granted general permission for the rediscount of
paper endorsed by Federal intermediate credit banks.

This general

permission was incorporated in the 1928 regulation, together with a
provision permitting the discount of bankers' acceptances and other
eligible paper endorsed by a nonmember bank, if the paper was purchased
by the member bank in good faith on the open market from a party other
than the nonmember bank.

These provisions are still in Regulation A,

although in 1937 the provision authorizing the discount of paper acquired
in the open market was broadened to permit the discount of nonmember
bank paper acquired either in the open market or otherwise acquired in
good faith and not for the purpose of obtaining credit for a nonmember
bank.
In 1930, certain minor changes were made in the regulation,
mostly for the purpose of conforming to technical changes in the law.
The most important was an amendment to the provisions regarding the




-30-

discounting of sight drafts in order to cover the discount of drafts
drawn for nonagricultural, as well as agricultural purposes, and to
finance the domestic shipment of goods, as well as the exportation of
goods.

These changes were in accordance with changes made in the law

by an Act of May 29, 1928.

D.

FROM 1937 TO THE PRESENT TIME

No changes were made in Regulation A between 1930 and 1937.
It was during that period, however, that the economic depression of
the early 1930 's directed new attention to the credit accommodations
available through the Federal Reserve Banks; and in various statutes
enacted between 1932 and 1935, the authority of the Reserve Banks to
make discounts and advances was broadened in a number of respects.

The

maturity of advances to member banks on notes secured by eligible paper
was increased from 15 to 90 days; and the collateral eligible for
15-day advances to member banks was broadened to include obligations of
Federal intermediate credit banks, bonds of the Federal Farm Mortgage
Corporation, and bonds issued under the Home Owners' Loan Act.

The

Reserve Banks were authorized to make advances to any individuals,
partnerships, or corporations on the security of direct obligations
°f the United States for periods up to 90 days; to make emergency
advances to groups of five or more member banks; and to discount
Paper, in unusual and exigent circumstances, for individuals,




-31-

partnerships, and corporations.

Most important of all, the Federal Reserve

Banks were empowered to make advances to member banks on the security
of any assets satisfactory to the Federal Reserve Banks.
Along with these measures expanding the discount authority
of the Reserve Banks, there was also a new emphasis placed upon the
responsibility of the Reserve Banks to see to it that Federal Reserve
credit was not being used for speculative purposes or for any purposes
inconsistent with the maintenance of sound credit conditions.
amendment to section

h

By an

of the Federal Reserve Act, the Banking Act of

1933 expressly required each Federal Reserve Bank to extend credit ac­
commodations with due regard to the maintenance of sound credit condi­
tions and to keep itself informed of the general character and amount
the loans and investments of its member banks with a view to ascer­
taining whether any undue use is being made of bank credit for the
speculative carrying of, or trading in, securities, real estate, com­
modities, or for any other purpose inconsistent with the maintenance
°f sound credit conditions.
In the light of these changes in the law, the Board of

Governors, after many months of consideration, revised its Regulation A
effective October 1, 1937*

The more important changes dealt with (1) the

Responsibility of the Reserve Banks to see that Federal Reserve credit
v,as not used for purposes inconsistent with sound credit conditions;
(2) the eligibility of finance paper for discount; (3 ) construction
loan paper; (U) the maturity of advances on eligible paper and




Government obligations; ($) marginal collateral; (6 ) extension of credit
on Government obligations at par; (7) advances on the security of any
sound assets; and (8 ) standards to be observed by member banks in mak­
ing loans on real estate or installment loan paper.
(l) Improper Use of Federal Reserve Credit
The revised regulation was prefaced by a statement of
"General Principles", which briefly restated the provisions of sec­
tion I4 of the Federal Reserve Act referred to above regarding the
responsibility of the Reserve Banks to see that credit was not used
tor speculative purposes or purposes inconsistent with the maintenance
of sound credit conditions.

It was also stated that the guiding prin­

ciple underlying the discount policy of the Federal Reserve Banks is
the advancement of the public interest.
In the regulation itself it was expressly provided that, as
stated in section 1* of the Act, each Reserve Bank should keep itself
informed of the general character and amount of the loans and investments of its member banks in order to ascertain whether undue use is
ksing made of credit for speculative credit purposes and that each
Reserve Bank should require such information from its member banks as
tt might deem necessary in order to determine whether any such undue
Use of bank credit is being made.
This responsibility of the Reserve Banks was emphasized in the
Board*s annual report to Congress for 1937* in which it was stated:




-33"Federal Reserve Banks differ from commercial banks
in that they are not organized for the purpose of making
profits but for the purpose of being of public service.
Accordingly, in a preface to the new regulation it is stated
that the guiding principle underlying the discount policy of
the Federal Reserve Banks is the advancement of the public
interest and that the effect that the granting or withholding
of credit accommodation by a Federal Reserve Bank may have on
a member bank, on its depositors, and on the community is of
primary importance".
(2) Eligibility of Finance Paper for Discount
As early as 1919, the Board had ruled that paper the proceeds
of which were to be used to lend to some third party was finance paper
rather than commercial paper and was therefore not eligible for dis­
count by a Federal Reserve Bank, even though the third party involved
might use the proceeds for a commercial purpose.

This ruling had been

incorporated in Regulation A in 1920.
This prohibition was eliminated in the 1937 revision of the
regulation.

In its annual report for that year the Board stated:

"•* -;<■ *• The elimination of this provision rendered eligible
for discount a large amount of paper of commission merchants
and finance companies, including paper drawn to finance in­
stallment sales of a commercial character."
(3) Constraction Loans
In connection with certain amendments to the National Housing
Act, the Act of June 27, 193U added to section 2la of the Federal Reserve



Act a paragraph stating in effect that loans made to finance the
construction of residential or farm buildings and having maturities of
not more than six months should not be considered as real estate loans
within the meaning of that section but should be classed as "ordinary
commercial loans".

Notes representing any such loans were made eligible

for discount as commercial paper if accompanied by a binding agreement
to advance the full amount of the loan upon completion of the building
entered into by a party acceptable to the discounting Federal Reserve
Bank.

This provision was incorporated in the 1937 revision of Regula­

tion A.
(U) Maturity of Advances on Eligible Paper and Government Obligations
The Banking Act of 1933 bad amended the eighth paragraph of
section 13 so as to permit maturities of not more than 90 days, in­
stead of 1$ days, on advances made to member banks on their promissory
notes secured by paper eligible for rediscount or for purchase by the
Federal Reserve Banks.

The 1937 revision of Regulation A incorporated

this amendment.
The Emergency Banking Act of March 9, 1933* had added a
Paragraph to section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act authorizing the
Federal Reserve Banks to make advances for not more than 90 days to
any individual, partnership, or corporation on their notes secured by
direct obligations of the United States.

The Board of Governors had

interpreted the term "corporation" in this provision to include any
incorporated bank, including a member bank.




This meant that, despite

-35the l£-day limitation on the maturity of advances to member banks on
Government obligations contained in the eighth paragraph of section 13*
the Reserve Banks could now extend credit to member banks on their notes
secured by Government obligations with maturities up to 90 days.
The revised Regulation A retained in the text the requirement
for a maximum 15 -day maturity on advances to member banks secured by
Government obligations; but there was added a footnote to this provi­
sion explaining that under the last paragraph of section 13 any Reserve
Bank might make advances for periods not exceeding 90 days to indivi­
duals, partnerships, or corporations (including banks) on their promis­
sory notes secured by direct obligations of the United States.
Notwithstanding this footnote, questions arose as to the
Permissible maturity on advances secured by Government obligations; and
in order to clarify the matter the regulation was amended in 19 U 2 so
as to provide expressly that advances to member banks on their notes
secured by direct obligations of the United States might have maturi­
ties up to 90 days.

The footnote to the provision was also revised

in order to explain why 90-day maturities were permitted with respect
to such advances notwithstanding the 1 5 -day limitation on maturities
prescribed by the eighth paragraph of section 1 3 •
(5) Marginal Collateral
New provisions of the 1937 revision of the regulation which
were not merely restatements of the law were those relating to marginal
collateral for discounts and advances.

It was stated that a Reserve

Bank could require such marginal or additional collateral as it might




- 3

6

-

deem necessary for its protection and that the requirements as to
eligibility of collateral would not apply to any such additional or
marginal collateral.

However, in keeping with the concept that the

Reserve Banks have a public responsibility in extending credit accom­
modations, the regulation also provided that, in determining the amount
of any such additional collateral, the Reserve Bank would be expected
to give due regard "to the public welfare and the general effects that
its action might have on the position of the member bank, on its
depositors and on the community".

It was stated that a Reserve Bank

would in general be expected to limit the amount of additional collateral
to a minimum consistent with safety.

If the amount of the required

collateral should exceed 2$ per cent of the amount of the paper dis­
counted or 125 per cent of the amount of the advance, the Reserve Bank
is required by the regulation to include an explanation of the facts
and circumstances of the case in its loan schedule to be submitted to
the Board of Governors.
(6) Advances at Par on Government Obligations
Another new provision of the regulation not required by
changes in the statute was that which required a Reserve Bank to ex­
plain in its loan schedule the facts and circumstances of any case in
which the amount of an advance to a member bank secured by direct or
guaranteed obligations of the United States is less than the face amount
°f such obligations.

Apparently the principal purpose of this provi­

sion was to encourage the use of Government obligations as collateral




-37for obtaining credit from the Reserve Banks and to discourage advances
on such obligations at less than par.

However, the provision was less

emphatic in this respect than one which had been considered during the
drafting of the revised regulation which would have expressly stated
that a member bank "may obtain credit in an amount equal to the face
amount" of direct or guaranteed obligations of the United States.
In this connection, it may be noted that in 1939 it was
announced that the Federal Reserve Banks were prepared to make ad­
vances on Government securities at par to all banks.

This policy was

reaffirmed in 19 hl and has never been expressly rescinded.
(7) Advances to Member Banks on Any Sound Assets
I.n February 1932, when most commercial banks had very little
paper eligible for discount with the Reserve Banks, Congress had added
to the Federal Reserve Act a new section 10(b) which gave the Federal
Reserve Banks temporary authority to make advances in exceptional and
exigent circumstances to any member bank having no assets eligible
for rediscount on the security of the note of such member bank "secured
to the satisfaction” of the Reserve Bank.

It was provided, however,

that any such advance should bear interest at a rate not less than one
Per cent higher than the highest discount rate in effect at the Reserve
Bank, and that the Federal Reserve Board might by regulation limit and
define the classes of assets which could be accepted as security for
such advances.
This authority was extended in 1933, and made permanent by
the Banking Act of 1935.




The 1933 amendment eliminated the authority

-38of the Federal Reserve Board to limit and define the classes of assets
eligible as security but gave the Board general authority to prescribe
rules and regulations vdth respect to such advances.

The amendment made

by the Banking Act of 1935 not only placed the authority on a permanent
basis but broadened the authority by eliminating the requirement that
advances should be made only in exceptional and exigent circumstances
and only to member banks which did not have paper eligible for discount.
It also lowered the premium rate of interest on such advances from one
per cent to one-half of one per cent above the regular discount rate.
On the other hand, the 1935 amendment limited to four months the maturi­
ties of advances made under this section.
The authority thus given the Reserve Banks to make advances
on any sound assets was something of a departure from prior concepts
of the discounting authority of the Reserve Banks which had been based
largely upon the form of the paper offered for discount.

In its annual

report for 1937* the Eoard stated:
"* -k-

These changes in the law, culminating in the

Banking Act of 1935* reflected a definite change in the
intention of Congress as to the character of assets which
may be used as a basis for credit accommodations at a
Federal Reserve Bank.

Under the original Federal Reserve

Act the concept of the rediscount function of the Reserve
Banks was limited to providing member banks with credit on
short-term paper arising out of specific commercial,




-39industrial and agricultural transactions, particularly to
meet seasonal requirements; whereas under the more recent
amendments to the lav; it is provided that any assets of a
member bank which are satisfactory to a Reserve Bank may be
used as a basis for obtaining credit.
"■if- *-

Experience has demonstrated that the solvency of

banks is better safeguarded by careful regard to the quality
of the paper that they acquire than by strict observance of
the form that this paper takes, and that greater emphasis on
soundness and less emphasis on form is a sound banking prin­
ciple. # *
Although the Board was authorized by section 10(b) to
prescribe rules and regulations with respect to advances under that
section, the revised regulation went no further than to paraphrase the
statute and to set forth certain enumerated classes of assets which
would be considered as satisfactory security for advances under this sec­
tion,

The regulation stated, however, that whenever circumstances make

it advisable to do so, a Federal Reserve Bank might accept as security
for a section 10(b) advance assets other than those listed in the
regulation which were satisfactory to the Federal Reserve Dank.

Never­

theless, although the regulation does not so state, the Board's annual
report for 1937 indicated that the enumerated classes of assets were
regarded as "preferred classes of assets which cover the principal
fields of financing".




-hO-

(8 ) Standards regarding Real Estate Loans and Installment Loan Paper
Under section 10(b) of the Federal Reserve Act, it had become
permissible for the Reserve Banks to make advances to member banks on
the security of any assets satisfactory to the Reserve Bank.

Also,

the lifting of the regulatory prohibition against the discounting of
finance paper had made it possible for the Reserve Banks to discount
paper drawn to finance installment sales.
In order to encourage member banks to have their real estate
loans and installment paper in a form which would make them acceptable
as a basis for advances by the Reserve Banks, the Board set forth in
an appendix to the revised Regulation A certain recommended minimum
standards which should be observed by member banks in making such loans.
These standards have been summarized earlier in this memorandum,

(see

Page I7 )

IV.

CONCLUSION

It is recognized that the foregoing review of the history
of Regulation A may not necessarily be helpful in determining whether
any changes should be made in the regulation, since it is most likely
that any need for changes would arise out of present-day conditions.
This review, however, may be of some assistance as background in con­
sidering whether any changes in the regulation are desirable at this
time.

One conclusion seems clear:

Regulation A is largely a restate­

ment of the law and only to a limited extent regulatory in nature.




Despite the Board's broad authority to prescribe regulations and
limitations with respect to discounts and advances, to define the
character of paper eligible for discount, and to define the conditions
under which credit accommodations may be extended to member banks, the
regulation indicates that this authority has not been extensively
exercised.




Howard H. Hackley, Assistant General Counsel
Legal Division
Board of Governors
June 1, 1953