View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

MARCH 2008
NUMBER 248

Chicago Fed Letter
The Value Chain Case for Health Care Reform—
A conference summary
by Sam Kahan, senior economist, and William A. Testa, vice president and director of regional programs

On April 24–25, 2007, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and the Detroit Regional
Chamber sponsored a two-day forum examining a “value chain” perspective of health care
delivery in the U.S. The program discussed how a value chain evaluation might lead to
improvement in health care quality, reduction in costs, and increased user accessibility.

Health care costs in the U.S. are high and

Materials presented at the
conference are available at
www.chicagofed.org/news_
and_conferences/conferences_
and_events/2007_detroit_
healthcare_agenda.cfm.

rising rapidly. The U.S. spent approximately $2 trillion on health care in 2005,
nearly 15% of real gross domestic product (GDP)—up from 5.9% in 1965 and
currently among the highest in the world.
More importantly, costs are rising rapidly
with no hint of any slowing. Since 1990,
medical care costs as measured by the
Consumer Price Index (CPI) have risen
at a compound annual rate of 4.6%,
nearly 2 percentage points faster than
the overall CPI. Without effective reforms
in the health care system, such trends are
likely to continue as the U.S. population
ages and the scope of medical technology
continues to broaden.
In Michigan, providing more cost-effective and customer-attuned health care is
especially important as the automotive
industry—the state’s primary industry—
bears the hefty legacy health care costs
of its retirees. This also implies that efficiency improvements in health care may
have profound effects on Michigan’s
competitiveness. Currently, the state is
burdened with both a slowly growing
economy and an aging population. At
the conference, academics, health care
providers, insurers, employers, labor
union representatives, and representatives of various governmental authorities gathered to discuss one particular
approach to addressing the health care

challenges in Michigan and across the
nation—the “value chain.”
Michael Porter has popularized the
term value chain to mean the entire
production process from the input of
raw materials to the output of the final
product consumed by the end-user.1 It
is called a value chain because each link
in the process adds some value before
the product or service is delivered to the
ultimate customer. Along the way, the
particular actors involved—which may
include government agencies, nonprofit
organizations, and other agents—and
the arrangements and incentives under
which the process takes place help to
determine the cost and quality features
of the final product or service. For value
chains involving public sector inputs,
such as health care, there are myriad
policy options, cooperative agreements,
regulatory regimes, and institutional
arrangements available at various stages
of the value chain. Such arrangements
characterize the quality, cost, and variety of the final product or service. In
contrast, for many goods and services
supplied by private firms, the value
chain process, while complex, has its
elements chiefly fashioned within or
between private firms, operating with
relatively fewer constraints than public
sector entities.

In the private sector, the value chain of
today’s automotive industry is often held
up as an ideal. Today, the automotive
value chain is a segmented string of automotive assembly firms and autonomous
parts suppliers, with each being highly
specialized and focused on particular
core competencies. Competition among
firms at each stage imposes cost-effective
production and product innovation.

party payer” arrangement may mean
that consumers are motivated to overpurchase some types of health care services or to avoid price shopping that they
might otherwise engage in if they were
paying directly. Physicians and hospitals
often act as informed agents for consumers of sophisticated health care services,
and they too may not be strongly motivated to ration services on the basis of

Two alternatives were presented as to who should be the
ultimate decision-maker in health care: the consumer
(patient) or the provider (hospital/physician).
Despite this specialization and competition, greater overall cost-effectiveness
of the final automobile is also brought
about by particular cooperative relations
among firms along the value chain.
Given the level of cooperation in this
system, quality and competitive price
information are communicated quickly
upstream in the value chain. Consumers
downstream also have ready information
on the final product’s quality and price.
This availability of information along
the value chain imposes market discipline on many competing automakers,
which must in turn exert discipline on
their suppliers, while also acting cooperatively on specific preassembly activities, such as automotive design and
production planning.
In contrast to today’s automotive market,
the partnerships in the markets for health
care services have not given rise to costefficiencies and delivery innovation.
Fundamentally, many health care services are complex and only purchased
intermittently, if at all. This means that,
often, consumers are not well informed
in their purchase decisions. Even if the
consumer understands what to shop for,
information on cost and quality among
providers is often sparse. Many needs for
health care services are associated with
costly and unpredictable episodes of
illness, so that the services are often
paid for under insurance arrangements
rather than with direct fees for services.
But insurance often gives rise to especially difficult “moral hazard” issues in the
health care arena. That is, this “third

cost in third party payer systems or to
tightly control the cost-efficiency of their
own operations. Also, a significant part
of health care responsibilities may fall
on the consumers so that their behaviors
in prevention, self-medication, and lifestyle must often be considered in achieving desired outcomes. So, too, in the U.S.,
governments and nonprofit agencies
commonly serve as direct health care
providers or as insurers and regulators.
Private sector employers often include
health care insurance as part of their
employee compensation package. Such
arrangements thereby introduce yet
more actors into health care transactions and payments.
Value chain overview

To open the proceedings, Robert Burns,
Wharton School of the University of
Pennsylvania, gave an overview of the
value chain approach, noting that this
approach has not been effective in the
health care arena. Some of the reasons
include an inability to create and coordinate strategic alliances, a lack of information regarding value/cost at each
link, and an insufficient sharing of
knowledge in health care. Attempts at
vertical integration, whether initiated
by providers, insurers, or employers,
have largely proved ineffective, probably because the coordination costs exceeded the gains from agglomeration.
The only partial success at vertical integration has been at the U.S. Department
of Veterans Affairs’ Veterans Health
Administration—an organization that
by its very nature has greater control

over the whole process from individual
payer to service provider.
Burns also suggested that better technology should be used in many parts of the
health care value chain to create greater
efficiencies. He said that approximately
$554 billion, or 28%, of the nearly
$2 trillion spent on health care is currently technology-related; and this area
of spending is growing rapidly.
According to Burns, currently, physicians
have the central role in the health care
value chain. They are the decision-makers
for many products, such as medical devices and drugs, as well as for services at
hospital-based programs and alternative
sites, such as outpatient clinics. As a result, physicians’ preferences are the focus
of attention by medical equipment and
drug producers, and they are probably
the key determinant of value. But Burns
sees an increasing role for the payer in
the value chain. Through an expanded
collection of data on cost, utilization, and
product and service performance, he
argued that efficiencies and cost savings
can be discerned and the information
dispersed to the health care providers
and producers—and ultimately, to consumers. While there has been a very recent movement to gather data on the
quality and cost of medical services, especially those of hospitals, there is still a
dearth of comparative information on
health care. Burns stated that the patient
needs to be more active in the value chain
process, particularly as an informed
purchaser of goods and services.
Pros and cons of value chain

Uwe E. Reinhardt, Princeton University,
questioned whether the value chain concept can be very helpful to the health
care industry until society decides who
should determine value. The concept of
the value chain can be a highly useful
analytical tool in many contexts, but it
runs into a host of conceptual and methodological problems if applied to health
care. The driving force for change in wellfunctioning value chains is competition
to provide the best value to the ultimate
customer. For health care in the U.S.,
two important questions in applying this
framework are: Who should set the “value” in the value chain; and how should

the value of services be determined (that
is, by market forces or by some other process)? These are open questions because
health care is often viewed by some as
a social good to be distributed to all who
need it regardless of ability to pay, but
by others as a private good. Under our
current system, there are several potential candidates to be the ultimate customer, Reinhardt said, including the
individual patient, the insured person,
the insurance company, the taxpayer, and
the employer. Since they all have varying
motivations and requirements, there will
not necessarily be an alignment of values
along the value chain. He buttressed his
argument by noting that current spending on health care varies across regions
and procedures by a wide margin. For example, U.S. personal health care spending per capita in 1998 averaged $3,759,
but it ranged from a low of $2,731 in Utah
to a high of $4,810 in Massachusetts.
Dean G. Smith and Leon Wyszewianski,
both of the University of Michigan School
of Public Health, and Jeffrey R. Taylor,
Michigan Public Health Institute (MPHI),
discussed the merits of the health care
value chain approach. Smith noted that
the purpose of the health care system is
“not to minimize overall or total expenditures but to deliver value to patients,
that is, better health per dollar spent.”
He argued that greater attention should
be paid to the patient, particularly the
financial incentives needed to influence
patient behavior. As an example, he noted that, while lower co-payments tend to
increase usage of drugs (statins in his
example), there is a marked decline in
usage by individual patients over time;
by year three, only 10% of patients continue using statins (as directed by their
physicians) if the co-payment is greater
than $20, but slightly more than half continue when payments are less than $10.
In this instance, there is apparently a
need to provide patients with an incentive to continue using medication. More
generally, medication charges should be
better aligned with potential future costs.
An implication of this approach, to minimize total costs over a patient’s lifetime,
is that someone who is at low risk might
have a high co-payment for treatment,
while someone at high risk should pay

little or maybe even receive a refund.
Smith noted that the University of
Michigan, in its role as an employer, is
experimenting with funding similar preventive actions, which in the short run can
be expensive but which in the long run
may actually result in lower costs because
the client base will be healthier.
Wyszewianski observed that in the current system the physician has a near
monopoly in decision-making that is
difficult to change in several important
ways. His experience has been that physicians are not fully aware of the array of
alternative approaches or procedures
available; are not always fully apprised
of the effectiveness of procedures; and
are sometimes reluctant to implement
different methods. He pointed to the
Greater Detroit Area Health Council’s
Save Lives Save Dollars program that has
adopted performance metrics and issued
evidence-based guidelines as one way of
lessening physicians’ reluctance to change.
Taylor reported that a shift from a paper
to an electronic form of recordkeeping
by fiscal intermediaries, such as Michigan
County Health Plans, to MPHI has reduced costs from $15 to about $6 per
processing in the past two years. Electronic recordkeeping enhances the search
for Medicare eligibility, thereby reducing
labor costs, errors, and time-to-service.
Taylor estimated that this enhancement
represents 1.3 million transactions per
month and reflects an annual cost saving
of about $7.7 million.
Perspectives from the value chain

Scott P. Serota, Blue Cross Blue Shield
Association, argued that the future health
care model should be much more consumer centric and information driven.
The insurer’s role in such a world would
be to provide consumers with information on the comparative quality of care
by provider, institution, and even individual physician; to assess the various
procedures; and to provide the costs of
alternatives. At the center of all this would
be personal health records of consumers
that would be electronically portable.
Janet Olszewski, Michigan Department
of Community Health, described how
the state of Michigan is attempting to

contain costs and maintain access. She
noted that a government agency is not
merely a purchaser of health services and
products; rather, it is also a provider, regulator, convener (bringing interested
parties together), and occupier of a
“bully pulpit” for policy and process reform. One effort at cost containment
involved the pooling of Michigan’s
Medicaid purchases with those of other
states. This enabled Michigan to slow
the trend growth of expenditures and
to experience an absolute drop in
pharmaceutical expenditures of 5.2%
in 2006. Health plan contracting was
another area of success. The health plans
were rated on their performance in
areas such as children’s care and chronic
illnesses (e.g., diabetes) and awarded
bonuses for outstanding performance.
Olszewski cited three keys to the success
of health care in the future—namely,
ensuring access to health care, especially
to the uninsured; increasing the usage of
health care information technology; and
emphasizing beneficial lifestyle practices.
Vernice Davis Anthony, Greater Detroit
Area Health Council, reported on her
organization’s efforts to improve quality,
accessibility, and cost-effectiveness in
the health care arena under the rubric,
Save Lives Save Dollars, which was

Charles L. Evans, President; Daniel G. Sullivan,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; Jonas Fisher,
Economic Advisor and Team Leader, macroeconomic
policy research; Richard Porter, Vice President, payment
studies; Daniel Aaronson, Economic Advisor and
Team Leader, microeconomic policy research; William
Testa, Vice President, regional programs, and Economics
Editor; Helen O’D. Koshy, Kathryn Moran, and
Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita Molloy and Julia Baker,
Production Editors.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2008 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
on the Bank’s website at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

mentioned earlier. She attributed the
program’s success to the creation of a
broad-based coalition consisting of business, labor, health care, government, and
consumer groups, which provided a critical mass of support for change. Rather
than tackling all health care issues, this
multistakeholder group selected specific
target issues, such as diabetes, heart
attack/heart failure, and surgical site
infections. The targets were selected because of the potential for improvement,
opportunity to reduce costs, and availability of measurable metrics. A major
achievement was the agreement by the
major participating health plans to focus
on a common set of metrics and to provide physicians with financial incentives
for performance. Save Lives Save Dollars
has created a website (www.gdahc.org/
save.asp) that reports on hospital quality
as well as the performance metrics. Within a year, data on health plans and the
performance of individual physicians
will also become available.
Peter W. Carmel, American Medical
Association and New Jersey Medical
School, presented the physician’s perspective. Carmel said that value criteria
should be focused on the patient, the
ultimate receiver of benefits, and organized around medical conditions and
care cycles rather than specific procedures or incidents. Further, the metric
should be the value of improved health

care outcome divided by cost. He argued
that physicians should take the lead in
making decisions on health care products and processes because they are aware
of the best ways to safely cut waste, are
best equipped to evaluate new technology, and can implement change. He
acknowledged that, under most current
arrangements, costs, procedures, and
the whole care cycle are largely hidden
from physicians—a shortcoming that
needs correction.
Conclusion

The value chain approach offers some
merit as a framework for understanding
decision-making in health care provision. In business sectors like advanced
manufacturing, where value chains are
observed to work well, conditions are
often controlled by one or more principal agents—such as competing auto
assembly companies—which can manage the entire value chain so as to deliver final products of high value at low
cost. At the conference, two alternatives
were presented as to who should be the
ultimate decision-maker in health care:
the consumer (patient) or the provider
(hospital/physician). To be an effective
principal agent, the consumer (patient)
and the enabling agencies will need considerable time and effort to build up the
knowledge base and skills to access and
assimilate information concerning price

and quality. Insurers, nonprofits, and
governments also may play important
roles in assisting consumers to obtain
comparative information.
Determination (and delivery) of the appropriate health care services has always
entailed trust between physician and
patient. Physicians have the advantages
of relevant and educated information to
inform health care decisions, although
they are often isolated from background
administrative processes that generate
significant costs. Thus, like others in the
chain, physicians would also benefit from
a broader understanding of the total
health care cycle.
The health care market is generally
characterized by a lack of transparency
and a shortage of information among
all the agents along the value chain.
Market participants need information
on costs; quality of care; and availability
of procedures, techniques, and equipment. Many of the presenters described
ways in which they were trying to increase
the quantity and quality of information.
Such efforts will be useful in stimulating
competition and innovation where it is
most needed.
1

Michael E. Porter, 1998, Competitive Advantage:
Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance,
New York: Free Press.