View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

T H E FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
O F C H IC A G O

JU LY 1991
N U M B E R 47

Chicago Fed Letter
Unemployment Insurance:
Countercyclical or
counterproductive?
According to estimates by the Con­
gressional Budget Office (CBO), near­
ly 8.5 million people are expected to
be unemployed in 1991, up almost 25
percent from 1990. The Unemploy­
ment Insurance (UI) system’s goal of
providing income maintenance, and
thus economic stability, will surely be
put to a test this year. Policy issues
relating to the program’s effectiveness
as a countercyclical tool will also be­
come increasingly important.

cal balance, supporting the incomes of
unemployed workers and thereby
allowing them sufficient funds to seek
new employment while preventing
further deterioration in the nation’s
aggregate demand for goods and ser­
vices. But many critics of the system
feel that it no longer serves its primary
purpose.
According to the original design, the
UI system accumulates sufficient funds
during good times to pay benefits
during bad times. This worked fairly
well during the early years and
through the early 1970s. The first big
draw on the system occurred in the
1970s when unemployment rose
sharply and high benefit payouts de­
pleted individual state funds. Several
states, including Illinois and Michigan
in the Seventh District, found them­
selves in need of federal loan assis­
tance. Critics of UI believe that the
need for federal loans, coupled with
the availability of federal loans, erodes
the cyclical nature of the UI system.

Rather than accumulating adequate
funds during good times, states came
to rely on federal loans as a regular
source of funds during downturns,
according to this view.1
Until 1981, federal loans for UI were
interest free. But increased loan activi­
ty in the late 1970s and early 1980s
prompted the federal government to
change the rules regarding federal
loans, by requiring that loans be paid
in the same fiscal year as borrowed to
avoid interest.
States of the Seventh District were
among the heaviest borrowers.
Throughout the 1980s, unemploy­
ment in most of the District states was
higher than the national average,
forcing District states to borrow as
their individual trust funds dwindled.
The five District states accounted for
roughly 37 to 46% of total federal
loans outstanding from 1980 through
1987. As shown in Figure 1, trust fund
balances and loan activity at both the

In this Chicago Fed Letter, we review
the UI system’s role as a countercycli­
cal tool and address concerns about
the system that have developed over
time, including how changes in the
U.S. labor force over the last 55 years
have affected the UI system and how
underfunding of Employment Services
has compounded the system’s prob­
lems. Where relevant, we
present a regional perspec­
1
H
.1
S I H■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ mssmmmM1
tive of these issues as they
U District trust Fund reserves and end-of-year loan balances ($000), 1980-90
relate to the five states with­
Unemployment trust fund reserves*
Outstanding loan balance year-end
in the Seventh Federal Re­
% of
% of
serve District: Illinois, Indi­
IL
IN
IA
Ml
Wl
IN
U.S.
IL
IA
Ml
Wl
U.S.
Year
ana, Iowa, Michigan and
Wisconsin.
1980
271
7.7
984
0
66
231
115
209
842
0
0
36.6
Does it work as intended?

The UI system was first au­
thorized by the Social Secu­
rity Act of 1935 to provide
income to those workers
who, through no fault of
their own, are temporarily
out of work. As originally
envisioned, the system was
supposed to come into play
during economic downturns
by providing a countercycli­

1981

25

176

101

9

54

3.0

1,405

0

0

1,075

0

39.5

1982

0

63

0

0

0

0.8

2,069

0

63

2,186

413

44.5

1983

0

100

0.7

0

0.8

1.3

2,418

0

127

2,322

628

41.1

1984

0

245

0

0

124

3.2

1,707

0

38

1,666

534

41.6

1985

45

392

51

454

88

6.4

1,124

0

0

1,289

256

43.7

1986

474

436

145

880

68

9.9

889

0

0

1,121

0

41.8

1987

314

509

283

978

404

9.9

0

0

0

953

0

46.4

1988

824

634

427

982

756

11.4

0

0

0

782

0

1,00.0

1989

1,268

770

518

972

1,032

12.2

0

0

0

603

0

1,00.0

1990

1,459

879

575

740

1,210

11.6

0

0

0

418

0

1,00.0

^ D e c e m b e r 31 b a la n c e .
SO U R CE: U n e m p lo y m e n t In s u ra n c e F in a n c ia l D ata, D O L/E TA .

national and Seventh District level
displayed a pattern of increased reli­
ance on federal assistance.
Work disincentives

Some critics believe that the UI system
fosters work disincentives. Economic
theory suggests that any benefit system
such as UI will lead to some degree of
work disincentive. In essence, UI
recipients can, in practice, collect
benefits even if they could find a job.
In other words, some unemployed
workers will choose to delay re-entry
into the labor force because they are
collecting UI benefits. The extent to
which this actually occurs remains a
topic of heated debate.
Research on the disincentive effects of
UI investigates the relationships be­
tween the UI system and variables such
as unemployment duration, reserva­
tion wages, and the job-search behav­
ior of benefit recipients. In a compre­
hensive analysis of the work disincen­
tive effects of UI, the Upjohn Institute
for Employment Research presented
various work disincentive evidence,
including analysis of similar or related
programs, as well as direct evidence—
empirical analysis of the UI system
itself.2
The Upjohn study concluded that
reviews of labor supply studies and
social experiments, and comparison of
the UI system to related transfer pro­
grams such as Aid for Dependent
Children, were inconclusive. Exami­
nation of direct evidence of work dis­
incentives was conducted through
analysis of the ratio of benefits to prior
wages (also called an earnings-replacement ratio) with duration of unem­
ployment; demographic characteristics
of exhaustees (people who have used
up or exhausted their UI benefits) as
compared to other claimants; patterns
of post-exhaustion experience; and
partial-benefits analysis (people who
collect partial benefits because they
chose part-time or reduced wages
while seeking full-time employment).
Analysis of direct evidence tended to
provide more support for the work
disincentive theory. In summary, the

Upjohn authors noted that the weight
of the evidence suggests work disincen­
tive effects do exist, but that there may
be some economic and social benefits
resulting from the work disincentive
effects (such as better or more stable
jobs arising from recipients’ ability to
be more selective due to UI benefits),
and that there are also some work
incentive effects of the UI system.3 For
example, marginal unemployed work­
ers may continue to look for employ­
ment as a result of receiving UI bene­
fits. In the absence of UI benefits,
these workers may withdraw from the
labor force.
The changing mix o f the labor force

The changing industry mix in the U.S.
may have also affected the UI system.
Some economists believe that the
evolution to a service economy has
changed the demands on the UI sys­
tem funds over the course of the busi­
ness cycle. Service jobs tend to pay
less, and, because of the larger num­
ber of service jobs, unemployment
spells tend to be shorter. As a result, a
shift towards a service economy means
reduced weekly unemployment bene­
fits for workers, because benefits are
based on past earnings, and a shorter
period of unemployment for each
individual.
Changes in family demographics have
also affected the UI system. In the
1930s, most families relied on one
“breadwinner” as their sole source of
income. Accordingly, the UI system as
originally devised was supposed to
provide income maintenance when
the family’s sole earner is unem­
ployed. A 1990 study by the Congres­
sional Budget Office on family income
of UI recipients looked at how chang­
es in the number of wage earners in a
family has compromised this aspect of
the UI system.4,5 In particular, this
study looked at family income of long­
term UI recipients (defined as recipi­
ents who received at least four consec­
utive months of benefits). The CBO
study showed that nearly 60% of long­
term recipients were in families with at
least one other person working and
that family income averaged just under
80% of its level prior to UI benefits.

The implication is that while the UI
system was designed to provide assis­
tance to the family’s sole earner, it
now supplements family income.
However, this must be weighed against
the fact that, according to the study,
although few family incomes were
below poverty levels prior to unem­
ployment, 20% were below poverty
levels while receiving UI benefits and
45% would have been below poverty
levels in the absence of UI.
Declining coverage ratios

Those who believe that the UI system
works well as an income-support pro­
gram are concerned with the declines
in both coverage, or the number of
people eligible for benefits, as well as
the share of wages replaced by UI
benefits, or the earnings-replacement
ratio. The heart of this issue is that
states, through stricter eligibility re­
quirements, are reducing the number
of people eligible for benefits. Most
analysts believe that this is a direct
consequence of enhanced state effort
to keep individual UI trust funds sol­
vent. In addition, the actual level of
benefits paid to recipients as a percent
of former earnings has also declined.
These actions, whether intentional or
not, erode the countercyclical nature
of UI by reducing the level of income
replacement and thus the purchasing
power of the unemployed.
One measure of declining coverage is
the ratio of insured unemployment
(people receiving UI benefits) to total
unemployment. This ratio, called the
IU /TU ratio, is presented for the U.S.
and District states over the 1978-1989
period in Figure 2. The IU /TU ratio
for the entire U.S. has declined from
44.4% in 1980 to a low of 28.5% in
1984. Since then, the ratio showed a
slight rebound to 30.8% in 1985, with
a leveling off thereafter.
District states have followed the gener­
al U.S. pattern of declining IU /TU
ratios, with Michigan and Wisconsin
showing higher levels of volatility than
the rest. For example, in 1980 when
the U.S. IU /TU ratio peaked at
44.4%, Michigan’s peaked at 52.7%
and Wisconsin’s at 58%. Both states

tem. If the UI system no longer serves
as a countercyclical tool nor provides
adequate income maintenance during
unemployment, then we need to de­
termine whether, and if so how, these
goals can be accomplished.
—Linda M. Aguilar and
William A. Testa
‘On the other hand, money managers
might argue that the accumulation of
large balances is not prudent budget
management because the dollars could be
used for more current, pressing issues.
2Munts, Raymond and Irwin Garfield,

The
work disincentive effects o f unemployment
insurance,, The W.E. Upjohn Institute for

Employment Research, September 1974.
had substantial increases in total un­
employment that year relative to the
total U.S. increase. Another consider­
able deviance occurred in 1988 when
Wisconsin’s IU /TU ratio jum ped to
40% (from 33.6% in 1987) while the
U.S. rate remained flat. Again, this
variance can be explained by the fact
that the state’s unemployment rate fell
sharply from 6.1% to 4.3%, or nearly
30%, while the weekly insured level
fell only 14%. What might be gleaned
from this very small sample is that the
U.S. figures contain a high degree of
state variability and geographic disper­
sion. Nonetheless, the downward
trend in coverage has been pervasive.
Funding Employment Services

Another concern about the UI system
involves the funding of Employment
Services. In concept and practice, UI
programs are also charged with the
responsibilities for speeding the tem­
porarily unemployed back into the
labor force. Funded by federal taxes
on employers, activities of the Employ­
ment Services, which include job list­
ings and counseling of unemployed
workers, have been hampered over
the 1980s by serious underfunding.
For example, staff levels have declined
from about 30,000 in 1980, to 17,000
today.6
In this instance, actions by the federal
government may be directly responsi­

ble for diminished activities of the
Employment Service. An estimated
$2.5 billion in funds will have been
accumulated but left unspent in the
Employment Security Administrative
Account by the end of this fiscal year.7
As part of the federal unified budget,
unspent funds reduce the size of the
federal deficit.
Conclusion

Changing demographics, industry
mix, and state UI statutes have all con­
tributed over time to create a UI sys­
tem that is no longer countercyclical
and may be counterproductive. Sug­
gestions to change the system range
from eliminating the system and re­
placing it with a needs based system, to
pumping more money into the system
by raising the employee tax base, per­
haps from $7,000 per covered employ­
ee up to the present Social Security
base of $53,400.
The issues presented here are by no
means new—they have been, in most
cases, well documented and discussed
in a variety of research by concerns
such as the W.E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research, the Congres­
sional Budget Office, and the Depart­
ment of Labor. In addition, the UI
system’s problems are well-known to
the public and legislators. The time
has come for a rethinking of and reso­
lution to the problems of the UI sys­

Nbid.,

p. 48.

4Family incomes o f unemployment insurance
recipients and the implications fo r extending
benefits, Congressional Budget Office,

February 1990.
5While the CBO study did provide these
results, its focus was to assess the eco­
nomic condition of long-term unem­
ployed workers both while receiving
benefits and thereafter.
6See Paula Duggan’s article entitled
“Failing net,” Northeast Midwest Economic
Review , May 6, 1991, for a more complete
review of this issue.
7Ibid., p.7.

Karl A. S cheld, S en io r Vice P re sid e n t an d
D irecto r o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P re sid en t a n d A ssistant D irecto r o f R esearch;
C arolyn M cM ullen, E ditor.
Chicago Fed Letter is p u b lish ed m o n th ly by th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t o f th e F ed eral Reserve
B ank o f C hicago. T h e views ex p ressed are th e
a u th o rs ’ a n d are n o t necessarily th o se o f th e
F ederal Reserve B ank o f C hicago o r th e F ed eral
Reserve System. Articles m ay b e re p rin te d if
th e source is c re d ite d a n d th e R esearch
D e p a rtm e n t is pro v id ed with copies o f th e
rep rin ts.
Chicago Fed Letter is available w ith o u t ch arg e
fro m th e Public In fo rm a tio n C e n te r, F ed eral
Reserve B ank o f C hicago, P.O . Box 834,
C hicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.

ISSN 0895-0164

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

Manufacturing in the Midwest appeared to reach a low point this March, rebound­
ing 2.9% from that trough in April (current data reflect the 1990 rebenchmark­
ing) . Industry performance was mixed, however, with roughly one third of the
seventeen industries continuing to decline. Solid gains were posted by primary
metals, machinery, and especially transportation equipment, coinciding with a
pick-up in auto production.
The region has closely followed the national pattern during the recession. The
Midwest decline since mid-1990 was greater than the nation’s, largely because of
the transportation equipment industry. But that industry should continue to be a
major source of strength to the Midwest in the coming months.

1969

1990

1991

N O T E: T h e MMI a n d th e USMI are co m p o site
in d ex es o f 17 m a n u fa c tu rin g in d u stries a n d are
derived from e c o n o m etric m odels th a t estim ate
o u tp u t fro m m o n th ly h o u rs w orked an d
kilow att h o u rs data. F or a discussion o f th e
m ethodology, see “R eco n sid erin g th e R egional
M a n u fac tu rin g In d e x e s,” Economic Perspectives,
F ederal Reserve B ank o f C hicago, Vol. XIII,
No. 4, Ju ly /A u g u st 1989.

U19-ZZS (ZIS)
06909 siouini <o§Eotq3
f£ 8

O d

iaiua3 uopnuuojui :>H9nd
O O V O IH O T O M N V a 3 A * I 3 S 3 t f T V t f 3 (3 3 3

IS SHI!I 1® i l l ! WSBii H i H i 1.;*1111m 111n

j T U o q p a j o x t e jiu Q