View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

MARCH 1996
NUMBER 103

Chicago Fed Letter
Unemployment duration
and labor market tightness
Since the last recession, average unemployment durations have been
surprisingly high given levels of other
labor market indicators. Recently,
some have pointed to this as evidence
that there is more labor market slack
than is commonly believed.1 Their
argument is that the long-term unemployed are willing to accept almost any
job, even jobs with reduced wages.
Thus, though there currently are
relatively few unemployed workers,
enough of them are sufficiently desperate that wage pressures are minimal. (A possible corollary is that
inflation concerns have been exaggerated and monetary policy has been
overly restrictive.)
However, one could also argue that
given any level of the unemployment
rate, higher average durations should
be associated with greater labor market tightness. This might be the case
if many of the long-term unemployed
lack the skills employers require and,
consequently, exert less restraint on
wages than the short-term unemployed. This Fed Letter examines these
arguments and offers some preliminary time-series evidence on the significance of unemployment durations
for current inflationary pressures.

Unemployment durations
Unemployment statistics are derived
from the Current Population Survey
(CPS), a monthly mini-census of
U.S. households. Respondents aged
16 years and older are classified as
either employed, unemployed, or out
of the labor force. The unemployment rate is the fraction of the labor
force that is unemployed and the
average unemployment duration is
the mean number of weeks the unemployed have been looking for work.

Most unemployment spells are relatively short, but an important minority are
quite long. This skewness is reflected
in the median duration being considerably shorter than the mean. For example, in December 1995 the mean duration was 16.2 weeks, but the median
duration was only 8.2 weeks. Thus,
the majority of the unemployed were
looking for work significantly less than
16.2 weeks. However, those experiencing very long spells brought the mean
up to 16.2.
The fact that most unemployment
spells are short is evidence that the
labor market is more dynamic in
the U.S. than Europe, where long
spells are the norm. Even in the
U.S., however, long spells account
for a significant portion of unemployment. For instance, in December 1995, 16.4% of the unemployed
had been out of work for more than
26 weeks. (This is still low compared
with Europe, where typically more
than 60% have been unemployed
six months or more.)
The longer workers are unemployed,
the less likely they are to find work
in the next month. There are two
possible reasons for this. First, most
of those who can find work easily do
so quickly, leaving the remaining
pool of unemployed workers weighted toward those facing special obstacles. Second, long-term unemployment may erode skills and demoralize workers, causing them to take
even longer to find work.
Finally, it is worth noting that average duration is a mean calculated
over spells that are “in progress” at a
given date. For two reasons, this
differs from the expected duration
of a completed spell. First, most of
the unemployed will continue to be
unemployed after they have been
surveyed (which will not be accounted for in the calculation). Second,

the calculation weights long spells
more heavily than short. For instance, a two-week spell will at most
be counted in the calculation one
month, while a 26-week spell could
be counted six months in a row.
This second effect is stronger, so that
a random worker becoming unemployed in December 1995 will on
average find work in something closer to 14 weeks.

Evolution over time
Figure 1 plots the unemployment
rate and average duration over the
last 30 years. These series historically
have moved up and down together
over the business cycle, with average
durations lagging the unemployment
rate by a few months. Since the unemployment rate is itself a lagging
indicator, it is not surprising that
average unemployment duration is
one of the last economic indicators to
show improvement after a recession.
Durations have been abnormally high
relative to the unemployment rate
since at least the 1990–91 recession
(figure 1). Durations were higher
during that recession than during the
1975 recession, even though the latter was much worse in terms of unemployment. Nearly five years after the
end of the last recession, average
durations remain near the highest
levels experienced during the 1975
recession, and are comparable to
those prevailing in December 1984
when the economy was barely two
years out of its worst postwar recession and the unemployment rate was
1.7 percentage points higher.
Figure 1 shows that average unemployment durations recently have
been falling quite rapidly. It is too
soon to tell, however, whether durations are returning to a more normal
level relative to unemployment.

1. Unemployment rate and average unemployment duration
11

percent

weeks

23

Duration
(right scale)

9

19

7

15

5

11

Unemployment rate
(left scale)

3

7
1967

’71

’75

’79

’83

’87

’91

’95

Note: Shaded area indicates recession.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, various releases.

Figure 2 shows the flip side to high
unemployment durations. That is, it
plots the total unemployment rate
along with the fraction of the labor
force unemployed one month or less.
The latter series also moves up and
down with the unemployment rate.
(In contrast to average duration,
though, it slightly leads unemployment over the business cycle.) For the
last two years, the fraction of the labor
force newly unemployed has been as
low as anytime since the 1960s.

Underlying forces
During the last recession an unusually
high fraction of layoffs were permanent rather than temporary. Since the
transitions associated with permanent
layoffs are obviously more difficult,

this trend may have played a part in
the rise of average durations.
The last recession was also unusual
in that it was relatively severe for
white-collar workers, but relatively
mild for blue-collar workers. This is
not to say that white-collar workers
had it worse than blue-collar workers, just that blue-collar unemployment rates exceeded white-collar
rates by less than usual. At any point
in time, white-collar workers are less
likely to be unemployed. However,
perhaps because they have more
specialized skills, once unemployed
they typically take longer to find
appropriate reemployment. Thus,
increased white-collar unemployment also may have contributed to
higher durations.

Longer-term trends also may have
played a role in increasing durations.
Indeed, if one looks closely at figure 1,
the trend towards longer durations is
visible well before 1990. For instance,
while durations were substantially higher relative to unemployment following
the last recession than following the
1981–82 recession, they were also
somewhat higher relative to unemployment after the 1981–82 recession than
after the 1975 recession.
Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991) examined the trend towards higher male
unemployment from 1967 to 1989
using individual workers’ CPS records.2
They found that increasing unemployment durations, which began to appear
about 1970, accounted for much of
the increased unemployment over
the period. They also found that the
increase in unemployment was most
pronounced at the low end of the skill
distribution. For instance, unemployment in the lowest decile of the wage
distribution more than doubled, while
it was essentially unchanged for those
above the sixtieth percentile of the
wage distribution.
Juhn et al. interpreted the increase in
unemployment (as well as a parallel
increase in nonparticipation) for
workers with lower skills as a labor
supply response to an adverse shift in
the demand for their skills. Consistent with this interpretation, the real
wages of these workers declined precipitously over the 1970s and 1980s,
while those above the sixtieth percentile of the wage distribution had
approximately constant real wages.

2. Unemployment rate and rate of new unemployment
11

percent

percent

Labor market tightness
3.8

New
unemployment rate
(right scale)

9

3.3

7

2.8

5

2.3

Unemployment rate
(left scale)

3

1.8
1967

’71

’75

’79

’83

Note: Shaded area indicates recession.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, various releases.

’87

’91

’95

The long unemployment durations
experienced by many workers may
represent an important economic
problem, especially if the root cause
is the failure of those workers to obtain skills necessary for long-term
labor market success. It is less clear,
however, what this phenomenon
implies about inflationary pressures.
The view that high durations imply
the labor market is less tight than
the unemployment rate would ordinarily suggest appears consistent with
the first two possible explanations

3. Forecasts of 1996 CPI inflation
Information

Forecast
12/95–12/96

Changes in inflation
and unemployment

2.0%

Changes in inflation,
unemployment, and
unemployment durations

2.5%

Source: Author’s calculations based on U.S.
Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, various releases.

mentioned in the last section. Workers who have been permanently laid
off are presumably more receptive to
jobs entailing wage cuts than those
who expect to be recalled to their old
jobs. Similarly, white-collar and other
workers who have lost jobs where
specialized skills were important likely
realize their need to show flexibility
with regard to wages.
Those who argue that high durations
imply less inflationary pressure apparently believe inflation is largely determined by labor market conditions.
This view is controversial because, in
its extreme form, it ignores the role
of money in determining inflation.
However, even within such a framework, high durations could mean
more inflationary pressure. First, the
low rates of new unemployment which
are the corollary of high durations
may imply less fear of job loss and,
hence, more aggressive wage demands. Second, the long-term unemployed are less likely to take jobs in a
given month and thus may be less
relevant to wage determination.
Moreover, if the current rise in unemployment durations reflects a
continuation of the long-term trends
identified by Juhn et al., then many
of those experiencing long unemployment spells may lack the skills
demanded by prospective employers.
Thus, they may be less relevant for
the determination of wages than
other unemployed workers and high
durations may be taken as a sign of
labor market weakness.
Even if the reason for higher durations is the increased prevalence of
permanent layoffs or job loss by

white-collar workers, it may still be
that, given the level of the unemployment rate, high durations signal tightness. Both of these phenomena could
be signs that important structural
change is occurring. Such change
should tend to raise the “natural rate”
of unemployment as workers are
forced to make difficult transitions
from one job to another. Because
inflationary pressures should depend
on the gap between the natural rate
and actual unemployment, high durations would then signal greater labor
market tightness.

on unemployment durations to the
analysis of inflationary pressures.
They ignore other indicators such as
capacity utilization, the gap between
actual and potential GDP, commodities prices, and numerous monetary
and financial variables that contain
useful information about inflation.
When these are factored into the
analysis, Chicago Fed staff economists
arrive at a 1996 inflation forecast of
approximately 2.75%.

Time-series evidence

1

Figure 3 displays forecasts of the rate
of CPI inflation for 1996 based on
two simple statistical models. Both
are vector autoregessions that contain
changes in the monthly rate of CPI
inflation. In addition, the model
whose forecast is shown in the first
row contains changes in the unemployment rate, while the model generating the second row contains
changes in the unemployment rate
as well as changes in the level of average unemployment duration.
The detailed specification of these
models follows that in King, Stock,
and Watson (1995).3 They contain
12 lags of the monthly data and are
estimated over the period from January 1974 to December 1995. The use
of changes of the unemployment rate
and average duration is motivated by
evidence that secular movements in
these series are unrelated to inflation.
Using only the recent history of inflation and unemployment yields an
inflation forecast of 2.0% for 1996.
However, when recent data on average unemployment durations are
added to the model, the forecast
rises to 2.5%. Thus, at least at the
present time, accounting for unemployment durations increases estimates of inflationary pressures. This
is consistent with the view that the
long-term unemployed are less relevant to wage determination than
other unemployed workers.
Finally, it should be noted that these
forecasts are intended only to illustrate the effect of adding information

—Daniel Sullivan
Assistant vice president
See, for example, Gene Epstein, “How
low can it go?—Jobless rate hasn’t slid to
optimum level yet,” Barron’s, September
25, 1995, p. 46.

2
Chinhui Juhn, Kevin Murphy, and
Robert Topel, “Why has the natural rate
of unemployment risen?” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, 1991,
pp. 75–126.
3

Robert G. King, James H. Stock, and
Mark W. Watson, “Temporal instability
of the unemployment-inflation relationship,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 19, No. 3,
May/June 1995, pp. 2–12.

Michael H. Moskow, President; William C.
Hunter, Senior Vice President and Director of
Research; Douglas Evanoff, Assistant Vice President,
financial studies; Charles Evans and Kenneth
Kuttner, Assistant Vice Presidents, macroeconomic
policy research; Daniel Sullivan, Assistant Vice
President, microeconomic policy research; William
Testa, Assistant Vice President, regional programs;
Anne Weaver, Manager, administration; Helen
O’D. Koshy, Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are
the authors’ and are not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the
Federal Reserve System. Articles may be
reprinted if the source is credited and the
Research Department is provided with copies of
the reprints.
Chicago Fed Letter is available without charge
from the Public Information Center, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834,
Chicago, Illinois, 60690-0834, 312-322-5111.
ISSN 0895-0164

Tracking Midwest manufacturing activity
Motor vehicle production (millions, seasonally adj. annual rate)
7.5

Manufacturing output indexes
(1987=100)
MMI
IP

Dec.

Month ago

Year ago

142.1
124.8

142.7

141.4
123.8

124.7

Cars
6.0

Motor vehicle production
(millions, seasonally adj. annual rate)
Dec.

Month ago

Year ago

6.1

6.1

6.8

Light trucks 5.4

5.4

5.4

Cars

Light trucks

4.5

Purchasing managers’ surveys:
net % reporting production growth
Dec.

Month ago

Year ago

MW

55.7

52.5

68.9

U.S.

47.0

46.1

59.4
3.0

Other measures of manufacturing activity suggest more underlying strength to
regional production. For example, purchasing managers’ surveys for Chicago,
Milwaukee, and both the auto and nonauto portions of Detroit indicated improvements in production for December, while western Michigan showed contraction. Auto production, both nationally and regionally, actually increased
slightly in December after being flat for two months.

1996

Sources: The Midwest Manufacturing Index (MMI)
is a composite index of 15 industries, based on
monthly hours worked and kilowatt hours. IP represents the Federal Reserve Board industrial production index for the U.S. manufacturing sector.
Autos and light trucks are measured in annualized
units, using seasonal adjustments developed by the
Board. The purchasing managers’ survey data
for the Midwest are weighted averages of the seasonally adjusted production components from the
Chicago, Detroit, and Milwaukee Purchasing Managers’ Association surveys, with assistance from
Bishop Associates, Comerica, and the University of
Wisconsin–Milwaukee.

Chicago Fed Letter

In December 1995, Midwest manufacturing activity experienced its biggest
decline since last March. After reaching its highest level of the year in September, the MMI began a slight trend downward. In contrast, the national measure of manufacturing activity was virtually flat in December and only slightly
below its September peak.

1995

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

1994

Public Information Center
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834
(312) 322-5111

1993

PRESORTED
FIRST-CLASS MAIL
ZIP + 4 BARCODED
U.S. POSTAGE PAID
CHICAGO, ILLINOIS
PERMIT NO. 1942