View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

MAY 1994
NUMBER 81

Chicago Fed Letter
School reform and tax
reform: a successful
marriage?
Over the past year, the state of Michi­
gan has profoundly changed the way
in which the state’s elementary and
secondary schools are funded and, at
the same time, fundamentally re­
formed the state’s revenue system.
With the passage of Senate Bill 1 dur­
ing the summer of 1993, the Michigan
legislature effectively abolished the
use of local property taxes as a prima­
ry funding mechanism for elementary
and secondary education. In doing
so, the state eliminated over $6 billion
in locally imposed property taxes that
would have provided more than 60%
of the cost of the state’s public ele­
mentary and secondary education. In
its place, Michigan recently put to­
gether a blend of other tax sources,
including a statewide property tax and
an increase in the sales tax. This new
state tax structure is intended to en­
hance the state’s competitiveness and
environment for growth and invest­
ment. At the same time, the state has
established an entirely new system for
distributing revenues for education
that will reduce disparities between
communities in per pupil spending.
Michigan’s new tax plan has been
more dramatic than most, but it re­
flects a combination of forces that has
put both education and tax reform
near the top of many states’ agendas
since the 1980s. For this reason, oth­
er states are examining the Michigan
reform package as one way of achiev­
ing both school reform and tax re­
form. In this Chicago Fed Letter, we
look at the Michigan education fi­
nance reform plan and the ways in
which it changes the state’s tax struc­
ture while attempting to improve the
delivery of educational services.

Michigan’s new plan

A ballot measure passed by Michigan
voters on March 15 makes wholesale
changes to the state’s tax structure in
order to replace property tax reve­
nues for education and boost overall
spending on education. The measure
raises the state sales tax from 4% to
6% effective May 1, 1994, increases
the tax on cigarettes from $.25 to
$.75, and levies a new real estate
transfer tax and a new 6% tax on outof-state phone calls. The proposal
also trims the state’s personal income
tax rate from 4.6% to 4.4%.
Michigan’s new plan does not elimi­
nate property taxes to fund education.
In place of a locally determ ined com­
mon rate on all types of property,
however, the state now has statewide
tax rates for different classes of prop­
erty. The plan significantly reduces
the school operating property tax rate
for homeowners and makes modest
average reductions for business prop­
erty. The new state property tax rates
will be 6 mills on primary homes (an
82% reduction from the previous
statewide average property tax rate for
homeowners) and 24 mills on second­
ary homes and businesses (a 30%
reduction).
Rather than being dedicated to local
school operation, tax revenues raised
from local real property will now be
pooled and distributed to local school
districts through the state’s school aid
allocation program. In the process,
some of the traditional disparity in
per pupil expenditure across districts
will be eliminated. Minimum per
pupil expenditures will be raised from
the current $3,000 to $4,200 in the
first year. Districts that have been
spending less than $4,200 per pupil—
primarily rural and some urban dis­
tricts—will be the major beneficia­
ries.1 Elsewhere, districts’ historic

decisions on school spending will
help determ ine prospective funding.
Districts that currently spend between
$4,200 and $6,500 per pupil (mostly
large urban and suburban districts)
may gain some additional revenues
because of increases in state aid for
districts with high concentrations of
at-risk pupils.
At the same time that low-spending
school districts experience enhanced
funding, the Michigan plan discourag­
es high-spending districts. Districts
that currently spend more than
$6,500 per pupil have two possible
avenues to maintain existing spend­
ing. However, both of these avenues
may discourage them from doing so
because they involve either obtaining
approval through a local referendum
or narrowing the local property tax
base from all property down to local
homesteads only. Additionally, em­
ployer contributions to teacher retire­
m ent funds and Social Security will
now become the responsibility of
individual school districts rather than
being funded by the state. Wealthy
districts tend to have higher salaries
and lower pupil-teacher ratios. These
districts will now have to pay their
own way for relatively costly pension
programs.
O ther features intended to equalize
spending are more binding than dis­
couraging. Beginning in 1995-96,
districts that currently spend $6,500
or more per pupil will be allowed to
increase their spending only within
prescribed limits.

Tax reform to spur economic
development

Over the last two decades, Michigan
has changed from a national leader to
a laggard in terms of economic
growth and living standards. Much of

this change is due to massive realign­
ments in the automotive sector that
have reduced the num ber of highpaying jobs in m anufacturing even
while new jobs have been generated in
lower-wage occupations. By 1992,
Michigan’s per capita personal income
had fallen to slightly below the U.S.
average.2 Part of this economic de­
cline has been ascribed to the high
cost of doing business in the state, with
the state’s sharp reliance on the prop­
erty tax portrayed as a contributing
factor.3 In 1990, for instance, on a per
capita basis, Michigan’s average prop­
erty tax was nearly 31% higher than
the U.S. average (see figure 1).
Michigan’s tax reform will do little to
lower the overall tax burden in the
state, especially since overall educa­
tional funding will be enhanced rather
than diminished.4 Yet the reforms are
expected to bring a much-needed
elem ent of balance into the state’s
revenue system. The principle of bal­
ance among revenue sources suggests
that overreliance on any one source
tends to retard economic performance
by distorting the prices that people
and businesses face when making
economic choices. It is still debated
just what the optimal balance of reve­
nue sources is. In practice, states tend
not to want their own state revenue
systems to fall too much out of line
with the nation or neighboring states.
While Michigan’s revenue system dif­
fered from the average, the case
against the state’s reliance on local
property taxes was not open and shut.
Average statewide property taxes were
high, but businesses enjoyed ample
choices among localities in Michigan,
with many communities having low or
average property tax rates. Moreover,
in Michigan and elsewhere, some types
of business activity may be acutely
noxious to a local community in terms
of creating a dangerous or unpleasant
environment, or in dem anding costly
levels of public services. If so, rather
than simply deterring business loca­
tion and investment, high property
taxes may be seen as a bargain struck
between community and business
concerning the use of land for indus­
trial purposes.

1. Property tax, 1990
Per capita
U .S .
I llin o is
In d ia n a
Io w a
M ic h ig a n
W is c o n s in
R ange

$626
754
472
660
820
738

Rank

Percent of
U.S. average

_

_

14
33
19
10
15

120.4
75.4
105.4
131.0
117.9

$163-1246

Percent of
personal income
3.6
3.9
2.9
4.1
4.7
4.4

Rank

__
20
32
17
9
12

1.2-6.1

Source: A d viso ry C om m ission on Interg o ve rn m e n ta l Relations, Significant Features
o f Fiscal Federalism, Volume 2:1992, W ashington, DC: ACIR, Septem ber 1992,
table R-2, p. 275.

In Michigan and other states, howev­
er, it appears that this mechanism
whereby property taxes act as a “fair
price” for the costs of development
has been overshadowed by a more
detrimental behavioral pattern of
business location. In the process of
searching out the lowest property tax
rates, businesses have tended to lo­
cate within certain school districts in
such great concentrations that they
more than compensate local residents
for the price of public services they
require or any noxious effects they
may generate. “Tax havens” have
come about where community tax
rates are very low while business prop­
erty concentration is very high, there­
by enabling extraordinary levels of
school funding.5 Not all tax havens
have heavy concentrations of business
and industry. Some wealthy commu­
nities have very low property tax rates
because of the generally high average
value of the residential property. At
the same time, however, in communi­
ties such as Detroit, the heavy proper­
ty tax burden is sharply deterring
investment in the city (see figure 2).
Michigan’s revised tax structure may
help on two fronts. First, it will help
level the playing field for investments
inside the state. No longer will high
property tax rates for education deter
investment. Second, even with a 6%
sales tax, Michigan’s tax structure will
not be out of line with those of neigh­
boring states when the state competes
for economic development, since the
state sales tax throughout the Mid­
west is between 5% and 6%. With

greater balance in the state’s tax struc­
ture and lower property tax rates, the
state may improve its business climate
and enhance its development pros­
pects. W hether this new mix of taxes
will improve the business climate of
Michigan will ultimately depend on
how the modified tax structure plays
itself out for existing businesses as well
as for businesses Michigan hopes to
attract. Each business will find some
types of taxes more burdensome than
others, depending on its mix of pro­
duction inputs and the market for its
product. Further research and obser­
vation will be needed to determ ine the
ultimate impacts.

Education reform to reduce inequities
between school districts

Because Michigan relies so heavily on
local property taxes to fund education,
per pupil spending largely reflects the
combination of the relative property
wealth of the school’s community, and
that community’s willingness to fund
education. While the state’s average
per pupil expenditure is higher than
the U.S. average, the pattern of local
spending displays a high variation,
ranging from $3,000 to $11,000 per
pupil. Property-poor towns have been
unable to levy sufficient revenues to
provide adequate local education.
In support of greater equalization, it is
argued that education is a fundam en­
tal interest to both society and the
individual. For society, an educated
populace is essential to the economic
and social well-being of the country as

2. Homeowner’s tax rate, 1990
D e tro it, M l

4.4 0%

M ilw a u k e e , W l

3.7 8

N e w a rk , NJ

2.9 6

P h ila d e lp h ia , PA

2.6 4

B a ltim o r e , M D

2.4 6

H o u s to n , T X

2.19

J a c k s o n v ille , FL

2.1 8

A tla n ta , G A

2.0 8

C le v e la n d , OH

2.0 0

M e m p h is , T N

1.77

In d ia n a p o lis , IN

1.62

C h ic a g o , IL

1.59

U .S . a v e ra g e 3

1.67%

Note: Tax rates are expressed as percent
o f fu ll value.
aU nw eighted average effective pro p e rty
tax rate fo r the largest city in each state.
Source: O ffice of Econom ic and Tax
Policy, "Tax rates and tax burdens in the
D istrict o f C olum bia: A n a tio nw id e co m ­
parison, 1990," W ashington, June 1991.

igan will allow local interests to estab­
lish “charter schools” outside the
regular network of local school dis­
tricts. These will be specialty schools
emphasizing the development of par­
ticular skills such as math and science.
Over the long term, other features of
Michigan’s plan may facilitate addi­
tional school choice programs. In an
effort to boost school productivity and
match students with schools, other
Midwestern states such as Iowa and
Minnesota now allow students to
choose to attend any public school in
their respective states. This option is
intended to prom ote customization of
local school services to their clients
and to improve school performance
and accountability through competi­
tion. When students choose to attend
schools outside their home districts,
they carry state an d /o r local funding
with them to their chosen schools.
More equalized resources per pupil
would ensure that migrating students
carry along funds that are on par with
spending levels at the new schools.
Similarly, establishing a statewide
uniform core curriculum, as the Mich­
igan plan promises to do, will help
ensure that fundam ental education is
being provided in those schools that
otherwise choose to specialize in spe­
cial subject areas or innovative modes
of operation.

well as a necessary ingredient to the
proper functioning of a democracy.
For the individual, education is a re­
quirem ent for successful participation
in the economy. This reasoning holds
that at a minimum, the state’s respon­
sibility is to insure or provide a foun­
dation level of educational services.
Investing in the education of lowerincome children may be particularly
im portant to the state’s economic
development efforts, since globally
competitive industries require a pro­
Conclusion
ductive labor force.
The Michigan plan is a dramatic at­
While the movement to boost and
tempt to combine tax reform with
equalize education funding may be
education reform. O ther states will
laudable from the perspectives of
closely evaluate this combination as a
both equity and social investment,
way of achieving tax reform and re­
there is nonetheless some concern
ducing disparities in school funding,
that shifting more of the responsibility while increasing the effectiveness of
for education funding onto the state
education spending.
will diminish local control and the
—Paul D. Ballew,
ability to customize school programs
Richard H. Mattoon, and
to fit local conditions. At times, cen­
William A. Testa
tralization of educational funding in
the U.S. has been accompanied by
centralized or bureaucratic control of
According to the Michigan Fiscal Agen­
how the money is spent. This hap­
cy, the distribution of school district per
pened to some extent in the 1970s
expenditures prior to the passage
and early 1980s throughout the nation pupil
of
the
new law was as follows: 119 dis­
as states took on more of the financial tricts (including
13 K-6 districts) serving
responsibility for education. To ad­
approximately
181,000
students spent
dress such concerns, the state of Mich­ less than $4,200 per pupil.
397 districts

with 1,245,000 students spent between
$4,200 and $6,500 per pupil. 41 districts
with 166,400 students spent in excess of
$6,500 per pupil.
2$20,114 for the U.S. versus $19,680 for
Michigan. (U.S. Department of Com­
merce, Bureau of Economic Analysis,
“Survey of current business,” September
1993, Vol. 75, No. 9, p. 74.)
3National “business climate” surveys such
as the GrantThornton Manufacturing
Climates Study have ranked Michigan at
or near the bottom in a number of costof-doing-business categories including
hourly wages (50), unemployment com­
pensation benefits (49), worker compen­
sation cost per case (49), and overall
state tax effort (47). For more details,
see GrantThornton Accountants and
Management Consultants, Manufacturing
Climates Study, No. 11, Chicago: Grant­
Thornton, August 1990.
4Funding in fiscal year 1994-95 will be
4% higher than in 1993-94. This ex­
cludes possible revenue enhancements
that local school districts may decide
to fund.
5There will be clear winners and losers
and certain inequities in any changes
that do away with the current system of
tax havens. For example, some inequi­
ties will result to those who have recently
purchased property in tax havens. These
property owners presumably will now
have to pay for the previous fiscal surplus
attendant to the community in which
they purchased property; i.e., the lower
tax rate was reflected in a higher pur­
chase price.

Karl A. Scheld, Senior Vice President and
Director of Research; David R. Allardice, Vice
President and Assistant Director of Research;
Janice Weiss, Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are
the authors’ and are not necessarily those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the
Federal Reserve System. Articles may be
reprinted if the source is credited and the
Research Department is provided with copies
of the reprints.
Chicago Fed Letter 'll available without charge
from the Public Information Center, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834,
Chicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.
ISSN 0895-0164

Midwest m anufacturing output continued to climb in January and February
after surging in the fourth quarter. The early 1994 gains were also impressive
for having overcome the direct and indirect effects of unusually harsh winter
weather. Growth was centered in cyclically sensitive industries im portant to
the region, including primary metals, industrial machinery, and m otor
vehicles and parts.
Production of cars and light trucks slipped in March, but only after surging to
the highest level in 15 years in February. Purchasing m anagers’ surveys indi­
cate that expansion in Midwest m anufacturing activity changed little in March.

Sources: The Midwest Manufacturing Index
(MMI) is a composite index of 15 industries,
based on monthly hours worked and kilowatt
hours. IP represents the Federal Reserve Board
industrial production index for the U.S. manu­
facturing sector. Autos and light trucks are
measured in annualized physical units, using
seasonal adjustments developed by the Board.
The purchasing managers’ survey production
index for the Midwest is a weighted average of
the production components from the Chicago,
Detroit, and Milwaukee Purchasing Managers’
Association survey, with assistance from Bishop
Associates and Comerica.

llie-SSg (2I£)

FF80-06909 S1°«HII (oSvoii&
j ,)hi,»3

F£8 xog O d

uopEuuojuj 3i[C|nj

OOVOIH3 3 0 MMVH 3A*I3S3y TVH3CI3i

joypq poq chum p)