View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

NOVEMBER 2004
NUMBER 208

Chicago Fed Letter
Rising interest rates, bank loans, and deposits
by Hesna Genay, economist, and Darrin R. Halcomb, associate economist

The authors show how the relationships between interest rate changes, deposit growth
rates, and loan growth rates have changed in the last ten years, discuss some possible
reasons, and assess the likely impact of rising interest rates on loans and deposits
going forward.

Historically, rising interest
rates have been associated
with slower growth of bank
loans and deposits.

Between January 2001 and June 2004,
the federal funds rate declined steadily to reach a historically low 1%. Between June and October, however, the
Federal Reserve raised the target fed
funds rate in three increments to 1.75%.
Moreover, based on recent economic
data and the statements of the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC),
market participants expect interest
rates to rise further: In early October,
the fed funds futures market predicted that the target rate will reach a little
over 2% by the end of 2004 and 2.5%
by May of 2005.
What is the likely impact of rising interest rates on bank loans and deposits? Historically, rising interest rates
have been associated with slower growth
of bank loans and deposits. Furthermore, the impact of rising interest rates
on bank loans has depended on bank
size, with small banks typically suffering greater declines in loan growth
during periods of rising interest rates
than large banks.
In this Chicago Fed Letter, we show that
these relationships between interest
rate changes, deposit growth rates, and
loan growth rates have weakened in the
last ten years. We discuss some possible
reasons and the likely impact of rising
interest rates on loans and deposits
going forward.

Theoretical implications

First, consider the effects of a contractionary monetary policy that raises shortterm interest rates. Changes in
monetary policy can be transmitted to
the real economy through various channels. In the “credit channel,” bank
loans and deposits play a central role
and interest rate changes are transmitted to aggregate spending through
the balance sheets of banks and nonfinancial firms.1
Under a contractionary monetar y policy, the Federal Reser ve raises the target fed funds rate and reduces the supply
of reserves in the banking system.2 Because certain deposit liabilities of banks
are subject to reserve requirements, a
higher fed funds rate and a smaller
supply of reserves can slow down growth
of bank deposits.
The effects of slower deposit growth on
bank loans are likely to depend on the
banks’ ability to substitute other forms
of funding for deposits. If banks can
easily access other sources of funding,
then they may be able to fund loan
growth at the same rate as before the
increase in interest rates. For instance,
banks with an extra capital cushion may
have greater access to financial markets,
allowing them to substitute other liabilities for core deposits.

1. Interest rate sensitivity of deposits and loans at small and large banks
B. 1976–2003

A. 1976–1993
percent

percent

4

10

2

8

0

6

-2

4

-4

2

-6

0

-8

-2

-10

Small
banks

Large
banks

Core deposits

Small
banks

Large
banks

Total loans

Small
banks

Large
banks

C&I loans

-4

Small
Large
banks
banks
Core deposits

Small
Large
banks
banks
Total loans

Small
Large
banks
banks
C&I loans

NOTES:

Large banks are in the top 1st percentile and small banks are in the bottom 75th percentile of the asset distribution in each quarter. Data are adjusted for mergers, entry, and exit
in each quarter. Core deposits are defined as total deposits minus time deposits in greater than $100,000 denominations. The figure reports the sum of coefficient estimates on four
lags of quarterly changes in the effective federal funds rate. The regression model also includes four lags of annualized quarterly growth rates of nominal gross domestic product, four
lags of quarterly growth rates of total Consumer Price Index, and four lags of the dependent variable. The dark blue bars indicate cumulative interest rate sensitivities that are significant at 5% or better; pale blue bars indicate estimates that are statistically insignificant.

SOURCE:

Authors’ calculations from banks’ Report of Condition and Income (call report).

On the other hand, if banks cannot
fully counteract the decline in deposits
by increasing other forms of funding,
they have to slow the growth rate of
their assets to match the slower deposit
growth. As a result, higher interest
rates can lead to slower loan growth
through their effect on deposits.
Are there impediments to the ability
of banks to substitute nondeposit liabilities for deposits? One potential impediment is imperfections in capital
markets, such as asymmetric information between investors and banks seeking funding. Information asymmetries
can raise the cost of external, nondeposit sources of funding or limit their
supply to banks. As a result, growth of
bank loans and other assets can be
limited by deposit growth.
Capital market imperfections and the
financial constraints they impose are
one potential source for differences in
the interest rate sensitivity of large
and small banks. Typically, information
on small banks is less readily available
to investors than information on large
banks. This information gap between
small banks and investors can potentially restrain their ability to fully substitute for deposits with other sources

of funding. As a result, small banks
may rely more on deposits.

growth rates of loans at small banks
than at large banks.

At the end of 2003, insured deposits
funded 61.7% of total assets at small
banks (banks with total assets less than
$1 billion), almost twice the 31% at large
banks (banks with total assets greater
than $1 billion). On the other hand,
fed funds and brokered deposits purchased in capital markets financed only
2.3% and 2.0%, respectively, of total
assets at small banks. In contrast, fed
funds financed 7.8%, and brokered
deposits financed 4.0%, of total assets
at large banks.

In figure 1, panel A, we replicate the
type of response documented in these
studies. Using the same methodology
as in Kashyap and Stein (1995), we sort
banks according to their size for ever y
quarter in the 1976–93 period.4 We form
two portfolios: Banks in the top 1st percentile of the size distribution in any
quarter are classified as “large,” and
banks in the bottom 75th percentile
are “small.” For each portfolio, we calculate annualized quarterly growth rates
of core deposits (total deposits minus
time deposits greater than $100,000),
total loans, and commercial and industrial (C&I) loans. We regress these
growth rates on four lags of changes
in the effective fed funds rate and a
set of control variables. The sum of coefficients on the interest rate changes
provides us with a measure of interest
rate sensitivity of core deposits, total
loans, and C&I loans for large and
small banks (see figure 1, panel A).

If small banks are subject to greater capital market imperfections than large
banks, then we would expect rising interest rates and slower deposit growth
to have a greater adverse effect on loan
growth at small banks.
Empirical evidence

A number of studies compare the sensitivity of loan growth at large and small
banks to changes in interest rates and
deposit growth.3 These studies, which
use data through the mid-1990s, show
that either a 1% increase in interest
rates or a 1% decline in deposit growth
is associated with a greater decline in

During the 1976–93 period, rising interest rates are associated with slower
growth of core deposits at both large
and small banks. A 1% increase in the
fed funds rate over four quarters is

associated with a 2.96% decline in the
growth of core deposits at small banks
and a 3.66% decline at large banks. The
interest rate sensitivity of core deposits is statistically significant for each
size category, and the sensitivities of
the two portfolios are not statistically
different from each other.

total loans and a 7.7% rise in the
growth rate of C&I loans.

However, loan growth rates (both total
and C&I loans) at large banks and small
banks respond differently to rising interest rates. At small banks, a 1% rise
in the fed funds rate over four quarters
is associated with a 2.32% decline in
total loan growth and a 9.5% decline
in C&I loans (these sensitivities are statistically significant). In contrast, rising
interest rates are associated with positive, but statistically insignificant, changes in loan growth rates at large banks.
In other words, during the 1976–93
period, rising interest rates are associated with slower loan growth at small
banks, but have no discernible effect
on loan growth at large banks.

Developments since the mid-1990s

These results are consistent with small
banks facing greater capital market
imperfections and financial constraints
in funding their loan growth. They
also provide evidence consistent with
the credit channel of monetary policy
transmission.
In figure 1, panel B, we extend our sample period to the end of 2003 and reestimate our models. Clearly, the results
for the entire 1976–2003 period are
very different from the earlier period.
Over the 1976–2003 period, a cumulative 1% increase in interest rates over
four quarters is still associated with declines in the growth rates of core deposits at large and small banks: a 1.27%
decline at small banks and a 2.2%
decline at large banks. However, the
estimates are no longer statistically
significant. Moreover, rising interest
rates are no longer associated with
statistically significant declines in the
growth rates of total and C&I loans at
small banks. And, surprisingly, rising
interest rates are associated with statistically significant increases in the growth
rates of loans at large banks: A 1% rise
in interest rates is associated with a
3.48% increase in the growth rate of

Our results suggest that the relationship between interest rate changes,
deposit growth, and loan growth
changed significantly sometime during
the mid-1990s.

Although pinpointing the exact source
of the change in the relationships between interest rates, deposits, and loans
is beyond the scope of this article, we
can point to some developments since
the mid-1990s that might have played
a role.
One of the distinguishing features of the
period since 1993 has been the strength
and stability of the U.S. economy. The
U.S. emerged from a recession in 1991
to enjoy the longest business cycle expansion in its history. During this period, economic growth has been rapid,
yet remarkably stable. We have also enjoyed a low and stable inflationary environment, accompanied by similarly
low and stable short-run interest rates.
Macroeconomic stability, deregulation,
and technological advances have allowed
both financial and nonfinancial firms
to improve their balance sheets and
offered them new financing options.
These developments could have altered
demand for loans and deposits in ways
that are not captured by our model.
Today, firms are able to meet their funding needs from a much wider array of
financial instruments and institutions
than before. Deregulation has allowed
banks to move into insurance and investment banking, but it has also allowed
investment banks, finance companies,
and other intermediaries to provide
traditional banking services.
In addition, technological innovation
has allowed better management and
transfer of risk in financial markets.
Firms that were previously too small
or opaque to borrow in the bond markets are now able to access these markets. Consequently, at the end of 2003,
corporate bonds comprised 27.6% of
total liabilities of nonfinancial corporate businesses, up from 22.8% at the

end of 1993. At the same time, the share
of bank loans in total liabilities declined
from 8.9% in 1993 to 5.9% in 2003.5
These changes were particularly pronounced during the most recent
recession. Over the last three years,
corporations have increased the share
of bonds in their liabilities from 23%
to 27%, while decreasing their reliance on bank loans.
Moreover, changes in technology and
improvements in productivity allowed
firms to trim costs even as consumer
demand remained strong during this
most recent recession. The resulting
record profits and lower expenses
have led to an unprecedented increase
in the rate at which firms generate internal funds.
Overall, these developments might
have changed the demand for loans
by businesses significantly. The relatively simple model we estimate may
not be able to fully capture changes in
loan demand and instead may attribute
them to changes in the interest-rate
sensitivity of loan growth.
The market forces that increased the
sources of funding for nonfinancial
businesses have also brought significant
changes to the banking industry. Banks
recovered from the 1991 recession in
Michael H. Moskow, President; Charles L. Evans,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research;
Douglas Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies;
David Marshall, Vice President, macroeconomic policy
research; Richard Porter, Senior Policy Advisor,
payment studies; Daniel Sullivan, Vice President,
microeconomic policy research; William Testa, Vice
President, regional programs and Economics Editor;
Helen O’D. Koshy, Editor; Kathryn Moran,
Associate Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2004 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
on the Bank’s website at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

a remarkable fashion, with capital levels
becoming stable yet substantial by the
mid-1990s. As we noted before, strong
profits and higher capital levels can
provide a cushion against the impact
of lower deposit growth on loan volume by permitting greater access to
financial markets.
In recent years, consolidation has been
the byword in the banking sector. Today,
banks with assets greater than $1 billion
account for over 85% of total banking
sector assets, up from 73% at the end of
1993. If larger size allows banks greater
access to capital markets, then the relationship between deposit and loan growth
for all banks would be closer to that observed for large banks in the past. Indeed,
evidence suggests that banks of all sizes
now rely more on market (nondeposit)
sources. Today, deposits fund a smaller
share of total assets (66.2% at the end
of 2003) than a decade ago (74.3% at
the end of 1993). As a result, a decline
in deposit growth is likely to have a
1

2

3

See Ben S. Bernanke and Alan S. Blinder,
1992, “The federal funds rate and the channels of monetary transmission,” American
Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4, pp. 901–921.
See Cheryl L. Edwards, 1997, “Open market operations in the 1990s,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, November, pp. 859–874.
See Anil K Kashyap and Jeremy C. Stein,
1995, “The impact of monetary policy on
bank balance sheets,” Carnegie-Rochester

smaller impact on loan growth today,
irrespective of bank size.
Conclusion

These and more recent developments
may also alter our expectations about
how interest rate increases will affect
bank loans and deposits going forward.
The business caution that has characterized the economy in recent years
has eased some, with firms boosting
investment and increasing payrolls.
As a result, demand for bank borrowing may continue to increase, though
this rise could be tempered by the availability of alternative funding sources.
However, the earlier caution has left
businesses with greater financial slack
than they had at similar points in previous economic recoveries, reducing
the demand for bank loans. Since the
last recession, firms have been allocating
a smaller portion of their internal funds
to capital investment and a greater

Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 42,
pp. 151–195; Ruby P. Kishan and Timothy
P. Opiela, 2000, “Bank size, bank capital,
and the bank lending channel,” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 32, No. 1,
pp. 121–141; Jith Jayaratne and Donald P.
Morgan, 2000, “Capital market frictions
and deposit constraints at banks, “Journal
of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 32, No. 1,
pp. 74–92; and Hesna Genay, 2000, “Recent trends in deposit and loan growth:

fraction to purchasing financial assets.
Over the eight quarters since the end
of the last recession, 88% of internally
generated funds, on average, were used
to fund capital investment. In contrast,
over the eight quarters following the
previous five recessions, capital spending
averaged 109% of internally generated funds, with the gap being financed
with external funds. As a result, nonfinancial firms have only very recently
begun to increase their bank borrowing.
On balance, it would not be surprising
to see C&I lending increase in the short
run, despite the presence of higher
short-term interest rates. In the longer
term, the historical economic trends
and cycles are more likely to return, so
that higher interest rates are associated
with slower loan and deposit growth.
Still, the strength of this effect in the
future may be mitigated by the financial market changes that have occurred over the last 15 years.

4

5

Implications for small and large banks,”
Chicago Fed Letter, December, No. 160.
As in Kashyap and Stein, we adjust our
sample for mergers, entry, and exit. The
results do not change if the period extends
to 1994 or 1995.
Part of the shift away from bank loans
toward bonds may be due to firms lengthening the maturity structure of their liabilities in a low interest-rate environment.