View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

JULY 2011
NUMBER 288

Chicag­o Fed Letter
How much of the decline in unemployment is due to the
exhaustion of unemployment benefits?
by Luojia Hu, senior economist, and Shani Schechter, associate economist

Prior studies have examined the impact of extended unemployment insurance (UI) benefits
on the rise in the unemployment rate in this recession and early recovery. We use real-time
microdata from the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ Current Population Survey (CPS) to examine
whether there has been a reverse effect recently as benefits have been exhausted. We find
that if UI benefits had lasted indefinitely, the unemployment rate would have been cumulatively
about 0.1 to 0.3 percentage points higher between October 2009 and January 2011, which
represents about 10% to 25% of the decline in the actual rate over that period.

During the most recent recession, the

unemployment rate—especially the
long-term unemploy1. Maximum potential weeks of UI benefits
ment rate1—rose to
historical highs. After
benefit weeks
percent of states
a surge following the
100
100
financial crisis in fall
2008, the unemploy80
80
ment rate peaked at
10.1% one year later in
60
60
October 2009. During
this period of unusually
high unemployment,
40
40
two federal programs—
Extended Benefits
20
20
(EB) and Emergency
Unemployment
0
0
Jul. Oct. Jan. Apr. Jul. Oct. Jan. Apr. Jul. Oct. Jan.
Compensation 2008
’09
’10
’11
2008
(EUC)—have extended
72 weeks
86 weeks
UI benefits substantially
39 weeks
93 weeks
73 weeks
46 weeks
beyond the normal
79 weeks
99 weeks
52 weeks
limit of 26 weeks, with
59 weeks
National maximum
eligible individuals in
(weighted average across states)
some states able to
Source: Data from U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration,
receive as many as 99
EB and EUC Trigger notices, available at http://workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/
weeks of unemployunemploy/claims_arch.asp.
ment compensation.
Extending UI benefits could raise the
unemployment rate in two ways. First, it
might create a disincentive in job search

efforts, leading to a lower job-finding
probability. Second, in order to qualify
for the benefits, unemployed individuals
might have a higher incentive to stay
unemployed rather than leave the labor
force. Both lead to a lower probability
of exiting unemployment, longer average
unemployment duration, and thus a
higher unemployment rate.2 Indeed,
several recent economic studies have
found that UI extensions can account
for 0.5 to 1.5 percentage points of the
increase in the unemployment rate
during the most recent recession and
early recovery.3
As of March 2011, the unemployment
rate had declined to 8.8%. Furthermore,
most of the people who entered unemployment two years ago have by now likely
reached the limit of their UI benefits.
If the UI extensions contributed to the
rise in the unemployment rate in this
recession and early recovery, will the
opposite now also be true? Are exhaustions of UI benefits now contributing to
the decline in the unemployment rate?
In this Chicago Fed Letter, we study the
evolution of UI benefit extensions and
the effect of their depletion on the

We then use reports
of unemployment
duration from the
thousands
800
CPS, available through
January 2011, to identify when individuals
600
reached their statespecific maximum.
Those reaching their
400
state’s maximum in
any given month are
henceforth known as
200
“exhausters.” Explicitly,
we define “exhausters”
0
as individuals reportJul.
Jul.
Jul.
Jul.
Jan.
Jan.
Jan.
Jan.
Jan.
ing an unemployment
2007
’08
’09
’10
’11
duration that is within
CPS count of “exhausters,” based on sampling weights and
a five-week interval
state-time-varying UI benefit week maximums, not accounting
containing the state
for the recipiency rate.
limit (e.g., an individNote: Counts are seasonally adjusted.
ual reporting 57 weeks
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey, basic monthly files, and U.S. Department of Labor,
unemployment and
Employment and Training Administration, EB and EUC Trigger notices.
living in a state where
the maximum at that
unemployment rate, in real time, between time was 59 weeks is an “exhauster,” since
October 2009 and January 2011. To
both values are in the 55- to 59-week
estimate this effect, we identify the UI
range).5 Figure 2 reveals a baseline
benefit “exhausters” and predict what they period of “exhaustions” as people hit the
would have done had they not exhausted regular benefits maximum (26 weeks),
their benefits. This analysis is complicated
a subsequent decline in November 2008
by the fact that maximum potential UI when second-tier EUC extensions began,
benefits weeks are state- and time-specific followed by a year of almost steadily inand that we do not actually observe what creasing exhaustions6 after the additional
“exhausters” would have done.
legislation in November 2009.7

the “discontinuity” around the UI benefits time limit and focus on exhausters
relative to a group of “nonexhausters”
who also have relatively long unemployment spells but are just short of reaching
their state’s limit.9 The idea is that the
two groups would likely behave similarly
had there been no limit on UI benefits.
We argue that any differences between
these two groups’ transitions into employment and out of the labor force are thus
more likely to be due to the effects of UI.

Measuring exhaustions

Effects of exhaustions

First, we compile a database of maximum
potential benefit weeks. Due to a multitier benefit system that relies on nationaland state-level labor market triggers, as
well as some differences in laws across
states (e.g., which EB triggers will be recognized), there has been considerable
variation by state and over time in the
number of maximum weeks of UI benefits individuals could receive.4 Figure 1
shows this heterogeneity explicitly by
plotting the fraction of states, plus
Washington, DC, with a given level of
maximum potential benefit weeks over
time. The variation began in September–
November 2008 with the triggering of
EB and introduction of the EUC tier
system, and potential weeks peaked in
November 2009 with the addition of
two more tiers to EUC and continued
worsening of the labor market.

To assess whether exhausting one’s UI
benefits has an effect on one’s labor market status, we track individuals over time8
and look at the fractions of exhausters
transitioning in the next period to employment (this is the unemployment to
employment rate, or UE, for exhausters),
out of the labor force (UO), and to continued unemployment (UU). Since
changes in these rates might merely
reflect changing economic conditions
rather than responses to UI policy, we
compare exhausters’ transitions with
those of unemployed individuals who
have not yet exhausted their benefits (a
control group). However, people with
much shorter unemployment spells may
generally differ from exhausters in many
other observed and unobserved traits
that could also affect their transition rates.
To deal with this problem, we explore

With information on both the number
of exhausters and the differences in transition rates, we can find out what the
unemployment rate would have been
(“the counterfactual”) if UI benefits were
indefinite and nobody had exhausted
their benefits, so that exhausters, too,
exhibited the transition rates of nonexhausters.11 We find that between
October 2009 and January 2011, the exhaustion of UI benefits can explain a
cumulative change of 0.28 percentage
points in the unemployment rate, which
means that the headline January unemployment rate, 9.0%, would have been
9.3% without the effect of UI exhaustions.

2. Number of exhausters

Figure 3 presents the transition rates of
UU, UE, and UO for exhausters and
nonexhausters over the last three years.
Panel A shows that from 2008 onward,
nonexhausters became increasingly likely
to stay unemployed (UU rate rose from
approximately 60% to 80%). In contrast,
the corresponding UU probability for
exhausters also increased at first, but in
mid-2009 it started falling to its early 2008
level. Panels B and C indicate that this
visible split between the two groups’ tendencies to leave unemployment, especially
from September to December 2010, is
not so much due to exhausters being
more likely to find a job (UE rates did
not differ much) but due to exhausters’
higher likelihood of leaving the labor
force (UO rates averaged 16 percentage
points higher in the four-month period).10
Counterfactual unemployment rate

Our estimates might be biased upward for
various reasons. In particular, we might
have classified too many people as exhausters because of heaping (rounding)
in the unemployment duration responses
at 104 weeks.12 To partly offset this, we

3. Labor market transition rates
A. Unemployment to unemployment (UU)

B. Unemployment to employment (UE)

percent

percent

90

40

Nonexhausters
80

30

70

20

Exhausters

60
50
Jan.
2007

Jan.
’08

Jan.
’09

Jan.
’10

Nonexhausters

Exhausters

10
0
Jan.
2007

Jan.
’11

Jan.
’08

Jan.
’09

Jan.
’10

Jan.
’11

C. Unemployment to out-of-labor-force (UO)
percent
40

30

Exhausters

1 The long-term unemployment rate is the

20

share of the labor force unemployed more
than 26 weeks.

Nonexhausters

2 Nevertheless, extended benefits can be

10
0
Jan.
2007

September 2010 and December 2010.15
If there is no further change in the current programs, the same analysis would
indicate that UI exhaustions will have a
limited and diminishing effect on the
unemployment rate in coming months.16
However, if as labor market conditions
improve in the coming years, the UI programs return to normal (no EUC or EB),
we would expect to see bigger effects on
the unemployment rate (as many recently
unemployed hit the 26-week limit). Thus,
the cumulative effect of UI exhaustions
on the decline of the unemployment
rate since late 2009 could be larger than
0.3 percentage points and would thus
gradually reverse the effect of UI extensions on the rise in the unemployment
rate, estimated in prior studies to be in
the neighborhood of 1 percentage point.

Jan.
’08

Jan.
’09

Jan.
’10

Jan.
’11

Note: Rates are seasonally adjusted, three-month moving averages.
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey, basic monthly
files, and U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration, EB and EUC Trigger notices.

derived an alternative estimate, applying
a lower recipiency adjustment factor13
to the CPS count of exhausters. We also
applied the Department of Labor’s
Employment and Training Administration
data on final payments of EB as another
alternative for the count of exhausters,
since typically EB benefits are paid out
after all regular and four tiers of EUC
benefits have been exhausted. The resulting estimates of the cumulative change
in the unemployment rate were reduced to 0.2 and 0.1 percentage points,
respectively, with the latter likely being
a lower bound.14
Conclusion

In this article, we were able to use realtime CPS microdata on people counts and
labor market transitions, rather than a set
of strong assumptions (e.g., assuming all
exhausters leave the labor force or using
historical averages of transition rates for
all unemployed) to estimate the magnitude of the change in the unemployment

rate resulting from UI exhaustions. Our
main findings are as follows. 1) The
number of people hitting their state’s
maximum UI benefits weeks rose sharply
after November 2009. 2) While, on average, the job-finding probabilities are
similar between exhausters and nonexhausters, exhausters appear to be more
likely to leave the labor force. 3) If UI
benefits had been extended indefinitely
and exhausters had thus behaved like
nonexhausters, the unemployment rate
would have been cumulatively 0.1 to
0.3 percentage points higher between
October 2009 and January 2011, representing about 10% to 25% of the decline
in the actual unemployment rate over
the same period.
Overall, our estimates suggest that UI
exhaustions contributed modestly to the
decline in the unemployment rate between October 2009 and January 2011.
Our alternative unemployment rate path
(not shown here) indicates that the effect
of UI exhaustions was largest between

welfare enhancing for many with low savings
by reducing their need to take low-paying
jobs that do not match well with their skills.
See Raj Chetty, 2008, “Moral hazard versus
liquidity constraint and optimal unemployment insurance,” Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 116, No. 2, April, pp. 173–234.

Charles L. Evans, President ; Daniel G. Sullivan,
Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
markets group ; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
Heckinger, Assistant Vice President, markets team;
Anna L. Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A.
Testa, Vice President, regional programs, and Economics
Editor ; Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors ;
Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2011 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

3 For a summary, see Bhashkar Mazumder,

2011, “How did unemployment insurance
extensions affect the unemployment rate in
2008–10?,” Chicago Fed Letter, No. 285, April.
With the exception of Daniel Aaronson,
Bhashkar Mazumder, and Shani Schechter,
2010, “What is behind the rise in long-term
unemployment?,” Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 34,
Second Quarter, pp. 28–51, these studies
typically derive their estimates from comparing the unemployment rate in two steady
states: pre- and post-UI extensions. They
are silent about how the effect evolves in
real time.

4

5

6

For 2008–10, we compile a database of
triggers for EB and all four tiers of EUC
using data from the Department of Labor
website, http://workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/
unemploy/claims_arch.asp. We adjust thirdand fourth-tier triggers in April, June, July,
and December 2010 to account for the fact
that although the EUC law expired in these
months, individuals already collecting benefits were allowed to finish out their tier.
The exception is 99 weeks. Since answers
are heaped (i.e., people tend to round their
responses) at two years or 104 weeks, very
few people actually report 95–99 weeks of
unemployment duration. Thus, in states
where the maximum is 99, “exhausters” are
those reporting unemployment durations
between 100 and 104 (rather than 95 and
99) weeks.
For figure 2, we adjusted our maximum
potential weeks database for the temporary
turnoffs of EB benefits in June, July, and
December 2010, which is not an entirely
unrealistic adjustment since the EB turnoffs
did not affect individuals who had already
collected EB benefits. These turnoffs
were probably due to the temporary expiration of 100% federal funding for EB.

7

To verify that our CPS data on unemployment duration are reliable, we compare our
exhaustion series to the official Regular
Benefits final payments series from the
Department of Labor’s Employment and
Training Administration website, http://
www.ows.doleta.gov/unemploy/euc.asp.
We find that over the period of 1978–2007
(not shown here), our CPS data line up
reasonably well in periods without extensions (with a regression R2 of 0.45).

8

That is, we use a matched CPS sample.

9

Henceforth, we define nonexhausters as
individuals reporting an unemployment
duration that is short of their state’s maximum by 8–12 weeks.

10

In general, exhausters are more likely to
leave unemployment than nonexhausters,
both before and after the recession (see
the dotted bars in figure 3), suggesting
that the UI benefit limit (26 weeks before
July 2008 and as many as 99 weeks after)
has had a behavioral impact. The observation that the two groups’ behaviors line
up for some interval before they diverge
possibly reflects that exhausters at the
time were anticipating further extensions
to maximum potential weeks, so they acted
like nonexhausters.

11 Specifically, if the actual unemployment

rate is URt = Ut /LFt, we compute the counterfactual unemployment rate as URt =
[U t + .65 ∗ Exhausterst−1 ∗ ( D _ ue t + D _ uot )]/
[ LFt + .65 ∗ Exhausterst−1 ∗ D _ uot ] , where
D _ ue t = UEtExhauster − UEtNonexhauster ,
D _ uot = UOtExhauster − UOtNonexhauster .
The exhauster count comes from figure 2,
and the transition rate differentials are
derived from figure 3. We scale down our
exhauster count by .65, the average UI
benefit recipiency rate from October 2009
to January 2011.

12 Other factors, such as workers not being

eligible to receive the full number of weeks
possible (in which case, exhaustion of benefits would happen sooner) or exhaustions
not being feasible in the same period as an
increase in the maximum (in which case,
exhaustion would happen later), affect the
timing but may net each other out.

13 See note 11. We try 40% instead of 65%.
14

The size of final payments by category is
much smaller for EB than for the regular
benefits and EUC tiers. The lower count
could be because many people do not actually receive the maximum weeks of benefits
(EB, for example, has different eligibility
rules than EUC). Alternatively, it could be
that some people had already collected EB
before the final two tiers were added. Thus,
the EB final payments series likely underestimates the number of exhausters.

15

This conclusion is consistent with the findings in Lisa Barrow, 2011, “Explaining the
recent decline in the unemployment rate,”
Chicago Fed Letter, No. 287, June, suggesting
that changes in aggregate UO rates (for all
unemployed, not just insured unemployed)
explain a substantial part of the decline in
the unemployment rate from November to
December 2010, but not from January to
March 2011.

16

DOL ETA data confirm that final payments
for the regular 26-week program peaked in
August 2009; even if all 26-week exhausters
qualified for the maximum additional 73
weeks, they would have exhausted benefits
around January 2011.