View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SPECIAL ISSUE

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

NOVEMBER 2001
NUMBER 171a

Chicag
Chicago Fed Letter
tte
The financial safety net:
Costs, benefits, and
implications
by Oscar Cerda, Elijah Brewer III, and
Douglas D. Evanoff
On May 9–11, 2001, the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago hosted its 37th annual
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition. This year’s theme, “The Financial Safety Net: Costs, Benefits, and
Implications for Regulation,” focused
on the implications of the various explicit and implicit financial safety nets, ranging from deposit insurance and subsidies
to government sponsored enterprises
(GSEs) to the notion that some financial
institutions are “too big to fail.” The timing of the conference was opportune in
light of the reform measures to the deposit insurance program introduced by
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation in April 2001, the legislative undercurrents concerning the proposed
new regulatory structures for the GSEs,
and the slowdown in economic activity
coupled with greater financial consolidation resulting from the Gramm–Leach–
Bliley Act of 1999. This Chicago Fed Letter
summarizes some of the issues discussed
at the conference.
In his opening remarks to the conference
on Thursday, May 10, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago President Michael
Moskow set the stage when he stated
that the “general public has a better understanding of the benefits than the costs”
of the financial safety net because of the
positive connotations the term conjures.
But, he suggested that “any thorough
discussion of the financial safety net
should include an analysis of both the
implicit and explicit guarantees, the
means by which those guarantees are
delivered, and the changes in behavior
resulting from those guarantees.”
Key questions that were addressed during the conference include:

· Has the safety net expanded in recent

years? And how has market behavior
been altered as a result?
· How should we reform the deposit
insurance program to better protect
taxpayers from losses and to provide
equitable treatment among insured
depository institutions?
· What are the financial market distortions emanating from a perceived or
actual too-big-to-fail doctrine?
· What are the implicit and explicit subsidies to GSEs, and how should regulatory oversight be handled?
A special theme panel was selected to
address these issues, featuring Arthur J.
Murton, director, Division of Insurance,
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC); Laurence H. Meyer, governor,
Federal Reserve System; Robert E. Litan,
vice president and director, economic
studies and Cabot Family Chair in Economics, Brookings Institution; Kenneth
A. Guenther, president and CEO, Independent Community Bankers of America; and Thomas H. Stanton, fellow,
Center for the Study of American Government, Johns Hopkins University. In
addition to the conference theme panel,
several other sessions provided presentations on GSEs and federal deposit insurance reform.
In his keynote address to the conference,
Federal Reserve System Chairman Alan
Greenspan discussed the central issue
behind the explicit and implicit features of the financial safety net. Although
the financial safety net has succeeded
in “eliminating bank runs, in assuaging
financial crises, and arguably in reducing the number and amplitude of economic contractions in the past 60 years
… these benefits have come with a cost:
distortions in the price signals that are
used to allocate resources, induced excessive risk-taking, and, to limit the resultant moral hazard, greater government
supervision and regulation.” To minimize the marginal costs of the financial

safety net, Chairman Greenspan warned
that policymakers must be “very cautious
about purposefully or inadvertently extending the scope and reach of the safety net.”
Deposit insurance
The federal deposit insurance program
is clearly the most recognized component
of the financial safety net and has undoubtedly helped sustain the general
public’s confidence in the banking system. Since its inception in 1933, it has
deterred liquidity panics, forestalled
bank runs, and avoided instability in
the economy.
This confidence, however, has not been
obtained without cost. It has long been
known that this feature of the safety net
induces moral hazard. Because of the
reality and perception that bank deposits are fully protected, banks are willing
to engage in riskier activities, insured
depositors are less willing and able to
monitor the activities of banks, and creditors are less sensitive to the risks incurred
by banks. Therefore, it is imperative to
develop a system that appropriately prices
this insurance and the risks associated
with providing it.
Murton presented a brief overview of
the history of the FDIC insurance fund,
focusing on how insurance premiums
have changed over the years. The Federal Deposit Insurance Improvement
Act (FDICIA) of 1991 required the FDIC
to maintain the insurance fund at 1.25%
of all insured deposits. It also directed
the FDIC to charge risk-based insurance
premiums. Many researchers believe that
the present system consistently underprices risk by restricting the FDIC’s flexibility in setting premiums. The FDIC is
prohibited from charging premiums on
well-capitalized banks when the insurance
fund increases above the 1.25% reserve
ratio. The end result is that today, only
one bank in 20 pays deposit insurance
premiums.

The first concern with the current approach is that premiums tend to be procyclical. Banks are required to pay high
premiums when the insurance fund experiences losses in times of economic
distress. By diverting earnings to the insurance fund, these premiums would
reduce bank earnings at the worst time
and potentially restrain economic recovery. Another deficiency in today’s deposit insurance system is that it does not
allow for a meaningful risk-based pricing
system. In good economic times most
banks do not pay premiums, while in
times of economic crisis, the FDIC will
not be able to differentiate between premiums on distressed banks and well-performing banks. Finally, the current
system provides an opportunity for
newly chartered banks to insure deposits without contributing to the insurance
fund. Yet, in times of economic crisis,
newly chartered banks are more likely
to fail.
Guenther argued that large financial
institutions such as Merrill Lynch and
Citigroup, are also “free riding” off of
the current insurance program. Because
Merrill Lynch owns two banks and
Citigroup’s Salomon Smith Barney owns
six banks, their brokerage units are able
to shift funds into accounts of federally
insured banks. He argued that in the
spring of this year, these financial institutions had moved about $85 billion
from their brokerage affiliates into their
bank subsidiaries without paying premiums for the coverage.
Deposit insurance reform
Murton discussed the FDIC’s recommendations for reforming the Deposit Insurance Fund. First, he suggested that the
two funds, the Bank Insurance Fund
and the Savings Association Insurance
Fund, should merge. Although the two
funds provide the same product, they
set their insurance premiums separately. This dual insurance fund system increases the possibility that banks and
savings institutions with the same level
and characteristics of risk may pay different insurance premiums, potentially
creating a misallocation of resources.
Second, the FDIC proposes indexing
insurance coverage to account for inflation. It further proposes that every bank
be required to pay a premium every
year, while the FDIC would institute a
system of rebates and surcharges to

ensure that the insurance fund would
not become too large or small. The
FDIC’s ultimate goal is to reduce the
volatility of the insurance premiums by
spreading them “more evenly and equitably across institutions.”
George Pennacchi, professor of finance
at the University of Illinois at Urbana–
Champaign, spoke in one of the Thursday afternoon sessions in support of
the FDIC’s proposal to make deposit insurance premiums more equitable and
stable.1 The key to accomplishing this,
according to Pennacchi, is to view a
bank’s insurance coverage as “multiple
long-term contracts whose contract intervals partially overlap.” The overlapping feature of the agreement allows
the costs of insurance to be smoothed
out over time.
Of the proposed reforms, indexing insurance coverage to inflation appeared
to draw the greatest differences of opinion. Coverage levels have not been increased since 1980, while the overall price
level in the economy has approximately
doubled since that time. Guenther argued that neglecting to adjust for inflation essentially “kills” a program that
has been essential to the stability of the
banking system. In his view, by refusing
to increase deposit insurance coverage,
policymakers discourage individuals
and corporations from using community financial institutions and encourage
them to use large financial institutions,
thereby increasing systemic risk.
Opponents of increasing insurance coverage argue that raising the ceiling from
$40,000 to $100,000 in 1980 contributed to the savings and loan crisis, due to
moral hazard. Litan noted that there is
no political support for such a change,
and from a consumer’s point of view, it
is unnecessary. He argued that people
have access to accounts at other banks
and, therefore, effectively have access
to unlimited deposit insurance. In addition, he argued that an increase is unnecessary given the fact that the average
size of a bank account is around $10,000.
Too big to fail?
In his opening remarks to the conference, President Moskow said that “perhaps the most controversial feature of
the safety net is the expectation that
large banks may be ‘too big to fail’.”
In order to avoid financial crises,

governments may be willing to bail out
financial institutions even without explicit guarantees.
The central question here is whether
uninsured depositors and non-deposit
creditors of large failed banks should
be required to incur losses. When
deemed necessary, uninsured depositors and creditors may be made whole
in order to prevent a mass flight by uninsured depositors from a large troubled
bank. On that issue, Chairman Greenspan
stated, “If the government protects all
creditors, or is generally believed to
protect all creditors, the other efforts
to reduce the costs of the safety net will
be of little benefit.” Most analysts would
agree that government should strive to
avoid creating the perception that it
will bail out large financial institutions
so that uninsured bank creditors would
not have the expectation that some financial institutions are too big to fail.
Guenther argued that the Federal Reserve, FDIC, and the Treasury have all
contributed to the notion that there is
an unspoken policy of “too big to fail”
and it is up to them to eliminate this
perception. As evidence, Guenther noted that depositors at all major failing
banks have never been forced to incur
a loss on uninsured deposits. Many critics also point to the “systemic risk exception” embedded in FDICIA. For
example, under the “least cost requirement,” bank failure resolutions must be
made in such a manner that insured
depositors are made whole in a way that
is least costly to the insurance fund.
This provision puts uninsured depositors and other creditors at greater risk,
thereby encouraging them to monitor
the activities of banks. While this has
served to reduce moral hazard, least
cost resolution may be circumvented in
the event that such a resolution would
“have serious adverse effects on economic conditions or financial stability.”
Critics maintain that this exemption
formally reinforces the notion of too
big to fail and undermines efforts to
reduce moral hazard.
Meyer, on the other hand, argued that
the effects of this exemption are overstated. In his view, the restrictions and
limitations on the use of this exemption
are adequate. In addition, the exemption does not require that uninsured
depositors or creditors be made whole.
He also pointed to the fact that of the

82 banks that failed between 1993 and
2000, uninsured depositors did indeed
suffer losses in almost three-quarters of
the resolutions.
Meyer added that policymakers can do
little to reduce the perception of too
big to fail other than to set the market’s
expectations by continuously reiterating
that there are no financial institutions
that can not be allowed to fail, regardless of size. But he conceded that, ultimately, regulators and policymakers have
to perform in a manner that is consistent with these assertions.
Managing banking failures
The nation’s last banking crisis during
the 1980s brought about reforms aimed
at addressing the unintended consequences of the financial safety net. Most
adjustments tended to increase reliance
on market discipline. Chairman
Greenspan stressed the advantage of
the reforms as they attempt “to simulate
what markets alone might do, or at least
create market-type incentives.” He discussed the advantages of having banks
managed as if there were no safety net
present. The reforms, however, have
not been tested during a period of economic distress.
Many of the participants agreed that one
approach to avoid a bail out is to ensure
a greater cushion of capital in financial
institutions through revised capital standards. As institutions encounter difficulties, their losses would be absorbed
first by bank capital. Therefore, a strong
capital position is needed to deal with
unexpected losses and to provide a
countervailing force to moral hazard.
Currently, capital standards are being
revised under the Basel Committee, a
committee of regulators from 13 nations.
Litan argued that many flaws exist with
the proposed revisions. He noted that
they are incredibly and needlessly complex, arbitrary, and do not rely sufficiently on market discipline. Of particular
concern in the revisions, Litan said, was
the fact that they effectively lower the
largest banking organizations’ required
capital ratios. Responding to Litan’s comments, Meyer acknowledged the complexity of the proposed reforms, but
insisted that they reflect the reality that
large banking organizations engage in
a wide range of banking activities.

In Meyer’s view, the new Basel Accord
“should strike a better balance of requirements versus recommendations.”
Although he agreed that certain items
such as capital ratios should be required
to be disclosed, he also supported efforts to increase voluntary disclosure
of credit management, credit risk, and
trading positions at the largest and
more complex financial institutions.
Government sponsored enterprises
GSEs are special purpose corporations
chartered by Congress to carry out a
specific mission. Because many GSEs
are large, complex, and some would
argue, risky organizations, many observers believe that they should have
increased disclosure requirements and
additional regulatory oversight. Although six GSEs exist, the conference
theme panel focused on the two largest housing finance GSEs, Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac. Both of these institutions, along with the Federal Home
Loan Banks (FHLB), were created to
provide liquidity for the secondary mortgage market, thereby helping to enhance
the flow of funds to finance mortgages.
Because of their government sponsorship and the perception among investors that the federal government will
not allow them to fail, Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac are able to borrow
money at lower cost than fully private
enterprises. They also benefit from tax
exemptions, security registration and
fee exemptions, and the ability to hold
emergency credit lines with the U.S.
Treasury. Stanton commented on the
lower capital required of GSEs compared
with the requirements for other institutions operating in the same market.
In his view, “the problem is that this systems rewards the firm with the most
favorable government charter, rather
than necessarily the most efficient firm.”
Stanton mentioned several factors that
make supervision of the GSEs difficult.
GSEs utilize their government subsidies
to grow rapidly, they wield strong political influence, and government
policymakers do not necessarily understand the complexities of the GSEs
or their charters.
While acknowledging that the two
housing GSEs benefit from their ability to borrow funds at a lower cost than
comparably situated private sector

borrowers, Alden Toevs, executive vicepresident of First Manhattan Consulting
Group, who spoke in a session on the impact of GSEs on the underlying markets,
indicated that GSEs actually pass through
more benefits to mortgage borrowers
than they retain. That is, the average
homeowner receives substantial interest
savings through GSEs’ activities versus
the benefits that GSEs receive from their
government sponsorship. In this same
session, Wayne Passmore, an economist
at the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, presented a model suggesting that, under certain conditions,
GSEs can lower mortgage rates for some
classes of borrowers. However, he questioned whether this is enough to justify
the existence of housing GSEs.
Later in the same session, Mark Vaughan,
an economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Saint Louis, suggested that the
FHLB’s advances (loans) to depository
institutions provide benefits by enhancing the flow of funds to the mortgage
market, but these benefits may come at
a cost. He expressed some concern about
the recent increase in the reliance of commercial banks on FHLB funding. According to Vaughan, “access to advances
reduces the effectiveness of market discipline in constraining bank risk-taking, and
deposit insurance premiums do not adjust
adequately to price the added risk.”
Some concern was also expressed that
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have

Michael H. Moskow, President; William C. Hunter,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; Charles
Evans, Vice President, macroeconomic policy research;
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President, microeconomic policy
research; William Testa, Vice President, regional
programs and Economics Editor; Helen O’D. Koshy,
Editor; Kathryn Moran, Associate Editor.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System. Articles may be reprinted if the
source is credited and the Research Department is
provided with copies of the reprints.
Chicago Fed Letter is available without charge from
the Public Information Center, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690-0834, tel. 312-322-5111 or fax 312-322-5515.
Chicago Fed Letter and other Bank publications are
available on the World Wide Web at http://
www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

grown so large that they may pose systemic risk to the economy. “Whenever
large financial institutions become as
large as that, it’s reasonable that there
ought to be concern,“ said Meyer. But
many, including Meyer, are more concerned about the “resource allocation
that comes from the subsidy… and how
it is growing over time.” As an example
of this resource misallocation, Stanton
pointed out that, “if we require a commercial bank to back its residential mortgages with 4% capital, while requiring
much less capital for a GSE to hold the
same mortgage, we create a system of
regulatory arbitrage where it’s to the
advantage of both institutions to shift
mortgages to GSEs for funding.” Because banks tend to have greater product diversification than mortgage GSEs,
this shift of residential mortgages could
potentially increase systemic risk. Stanton concluded that as a result of the
differing charters between GSEs and
other financial institutions, “risk will
migrate to the place where the government is least equipped to deal with it.”
Reform measures for GSEs
Because the government, in Stanton’s
view, has shown an inability to adequately regulate the GSEs, he concluded that
it needs an exit strategy. “We have created a government sponsored monopoly
in the secondary mortgage market …
and the government does not display

significant ability to regulate either the
public costs or the public benefits.” The
main difficulty in any reform strategy is
convincing decision-making parties of
the costs and benefits of GSEs.

also seeks to enhance transparency and
market discipline as the growth and sophistication of the two largest GSEs increase.

During his luncheon presentation on
Friday, May 11, Armando Falcon, Jr., director of the Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight, the agency responsible for regulating mortgage
GSEs, indicated that market discipline
of GSEs’ risk-taking propensity should
not be seen as an adequate substitute
for formal government regulation. The
perceived implicit government guarantee would impede the effectiveness of
relying on market discipline alone. In
addition, oversight is necessary because
the government has a stake in ensuring
that GSEs, created to support affordable housing, do not disrupt U.S. housing markets.

Conclusion

In his address to the conference, Congressman Richard Baker, chairman of
the U.S. House Financial Services Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored
Enterprises, discussed pending legislation that would transfer regulatory authority over Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac to the Federal Reserve System. Although Congressman Baker recognized
that his proposal would need modifications, he explained that its main goal is
to create a regulatory structure that will
be credible in the eyes of the market. It

Continual reevaluation of the safety net
is important in a marketplace that is becoming increasingly complex through
technological innovation, globalization,
and increased financial sophistication.
Policymakers must recognize that safety
net reforms that extend its reach have
both benefits from increased industry
stability and costs from increased moral
hazard induced risk-taking and possible
resource misallocation. This delicate
trade-off must be given serious consideration before introducing reforms.
This year’s Bank Structure Conference
brought out many different opinions
on how best to balance this trade-off
and how to move forward.
1
In addition to the theme panel discussion,
the conference had several other presentations highlighting the need to reform
federal deposit insurance. See Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, 2001, The Financial Safety Net: Costs, Benefits, and Implications for Regulation, proceedings of the 37th
Annual Conference on Bank Structure
and Competition, forthcoming.

Return service requested
Public Information Center
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834
(312) 322-5111

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

Chicago Fed Letter

PRESORTED
FIRST CLASS MAIL
US POSTAGE PAID
CHICAGO, IL
PERMIT 1942