View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

ESSAYS ON ISSUES
NOVEMBER 2021, NO. 464
https://doi.org/10.21033/cfl-2021-464

Chicago Fed Letter
What drives gold prices?
by Robert B. Barsky, senior economist and economic advisor, Craig Epstein, research assistant, Adrian Lafont-Mueller,
senior analyst, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, and Younggeun Yoo, PhD candidate in economics, University of Chicago

A half century after gold ceased to play a significant formal role in the international
monetary system, it still captures a great deal of attention in the financial press and the
popular imagination. Yet there has been very little scrutiny of the primary factors determining
the price of gold since its dollar price was first allowed to vary freely in 1971.1 In this article,
we attempt to fill in that gap by highlighting three considerations that are commonly cited
as drivers of gold prices: inflationary expectations, real interest rates, and pessimism
about future macroeconomic conditions.
Our empirical results in this Chicago Fed Letter are organized around three claims—namely, that
gold is a hedge against inflation, gold is sensitive to expected long-term real interest rates, and
gold is regarded as protective against “bad economic times.”
Gold is a hedge against inflation. A rise in inflation
or inflationary expectations increases investors’
interest in purchasing gold and, therefore, drives
real U.S. dollars per ounce, log scale
percent
up its price; in contrast, disinflation or a drop
8
1,600
in inflationary expectations does the opposite.
7
800
We will measure the “inflation hedge” motive for
6
holding gold with PTR—which is the mnemonic
400
5
for the survey-based ten-year inflation expectation
4
200
that is provided by the Board of Governors of
3
100
the Federal Reserve System; PTR has in recent
2
50
1
years coincided with the ten-year inflation projec1970 ’75 ’80 ’85 ’90 ’95 2000 ’05 ’10 ’15 ’20
tion of the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF)
Ten-year inflation expectation (left-hand scale)
conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Real price of gold (right-hand scale)
Philadelphia.2 The notion that gold can be
Notes: See the text for details on the measures of the ten-year
identified with an inflation protection motive is
inflation expectation and real gold price. All data are quarterly.
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
of course connected with the fact that, in contrast
Bullion Market Association and Board of Governors of the Federal
to fiat money, gold is in nearly fixed supply. But
Reserve System.
this property of gold is shared by many other
commodities. The special status accorded gold
may be a relic of the gold standard era, or it may even reflect a belief on the part of a subset of
investors that there is a positive probability that the world will at some point return to a gold standard.
Figure 1 shows how the real price of gold and the long-term inflation expectation have evolved
over time. The measure of the real gold price is the London PM fixing price for gold (from the
1. Real price of gold and ten-year inflation
expectation, 1971:Q1–2021:Q1

2. Real price of gold and real ten-year
U.S. Treasury yield, 1971:Q1–2021:Q1
real U.S. dollars per ounce, log scale

percent
10

1,600

8

800

6

400

4
200

2

100

0
–2
1970 ’75

’80

’85

’90

’95 2000 ’05

’10

’15

’20

50

Real ten-year U.S. Treasury yield (left-hand scale)
Real price of gold (right-hand scale)

Notes: See the text for details on the measures of the real ten-year
U.S. Treasury yield and real gold price. All data are quarterly.
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
Bullion Market Association and Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

3. Real price of gold and pessimistic
expectations for the U.S. macroeconomy,
1971:Q1–2021:Q1
percentage of
survey respondents

real U.S. dollars
per ounce, log scale

70

1,600

60

800

50

400

40

200

30

100

20
1970 ’75

’80

’85

’90

’95 2000 ’05

’10

’15

’20

50
Pessimistic expectations (left-hand scale)
Real price of gold (right-hand scale)

Notes: See the text for details on the survey measure of pessimistic
expectations and the measure of real gold price. All data are quarterly.
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
Bullion Market Association and University of Michigan, Surveys
of Consumers.

London Bullion Market Association) in U.S. dollars per ounce deflated by the U.S. Consumer
Price Index, or CPI (from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics), plotted on a log scale; and the
measure of expected inflation over the next ten years is PTR. From 1971 to around 2000, the real
gold price and the long-term inflation expectation tend to move together. A sharp uptick in inflation
expectations during the period 1971–80 coincides with a dramatic run-up in gold prices. Gold
prices fell dramatically during the Volcker disinflation of 1980–83.3 Over the period 1983–2000,
the steady downward march of expected long-term inflation following the Volcker disinflation
period coincides with the decrease in the real gold price. Since 2000, however, the long-term inflation
expectation has deviated relatively little from 2%, whereas the real gold price has increased more
than fivefold. The role of expected inflation in this later period seems to have given way to that of
the real interest rate—our second key driver of the gold price—which we discuss next.
Gold is sensitive to expected long-term real interest rates. Given that gold is a long-duration durable asset
with a relatively stable dividend yield, its price is expected to have a strong inverse relationship
with the long-term real interest rate. A rise in expected real rates, all else being equal, should
drive down the price of gold.4 Figure 2 shows the real gold price (the U.S. dollar price per ounce
deflated by the CPI, once again on a log scale), along with the real ten-year U.S. Treasury yield (the
nominal yield on ten-year Treasury securities minus PTR). The predicted negative co-movement
of the real interest rate and the real gold price does not show up in these data before 2001.5 By
contrast, between 2001 and 2012, the long-term real interest rate fell some 400 basis points,
accompanied by an over fivefold rise in the real gold price.
Gold is regarded as protective against “bad economic times.” We test for this factor’s importance by using
the Surveys of Consumers conducted by the University of Michigan (Michigan survey); one of the
key survey questions is the following: “Looking ahead, which would you say is more likely—that in
the country as a whole we’ll have continuous good times during the next 5 years or so, or that we
will have periods of widespread unemployment or depression, or what?”6 We use as our measure
the fraction of pessimistic responses to this question, and refer to it as “pessimistic expectations”
in our analysis. Figure 3 shows the log real gold price along with the fraction of respondents to
the Michigan survey who expect the next five years to be characterized by mostly bad times; there
is considerable positive correlation between these two variables over our sample period.

Multiple regressions
Comparing figures 1–3 reveals that the key factors driving gold price variation often move together.
For example, the rather steady rise in pessimistic expectations (figure 3) between 2001 and 2012
matches a persistently falling real interest rate over the same period (figure 2). To disentangle the
roles of the various factors over time, we perform multiple regressions.7 Our regressions provide a
simple econometric evaluation of the contribution of our three key factors to the time-series variation
in the real gold price over the period 1971–2021. In addition, we show that one additional factor
proxied by real world or U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) plays an important role in accounting
for the long-run trend in gold prices.
We begin with regressions that explain the association between the average annual log level of real
gold prices and four variables, also at the average annual level: 1) the real U.S. dollar value of
world GDP provided by the World Bank, 2) the expected ten-year real interest rate computed as
the nominal ten-year U.S. Treasury yield minus the Federal Reserve Board’s PTR, 3) PTR itself,
and 4) the fraction of the Michigan survey’s participants expecting largely bad economic times
over the next five years (i.e., the pessimistic expectations variable). These regressions highlight
the sources of longer-term variation in the level of real gold prices over the past half century (see
figure 4). Although we find this exercise to be the most revealing about the basic historical movements
of gold prices, the sample is not large and, more importantly, the degree of persistence in the
error term is substantial, as indicated by the relatively low Durbin–Watson statistic of 0.98.8 The
second regression exercise (whose results are reported in figure 5) uses essentially the same variables;
but instead of looking at levels, it looks at the relationship between the log change in the real gold
price and news about the explanatory variables using quarterly data. Finally, we conduct a limited
investigation using daily data (whose regression results are reported in figure 6). The precise
variables discussed here are not available at the daily frequency. However, we can investigate the
roles of expected real rates and expected inflation using daily data on Treasury Inflation-Protected
4. Factors influencing annual real gold prices,
1971–2019

5. Factors influencing changes in quarterly
real gold prices, 1971:Q1–2021:Q1

Log
(real gold price)

∆ Log
(real gold price)

Log (real world GDP)

1.125*
(0.105)

Innovations in log real U.S. GDP

0.395
(0.625)

Ten-year Treasury yield – PTR

–0.131*
(0.022)

–0.034*
(0.011)

PTR

0.365*
(0.033)

Innovations in (ten-year Treasury
yield – PTR)
Innovations in PTR

Pessimistic expectations

0.012*
(0.004)

Innovations in pessimistic
expectations

0.005*
(0.001)

Constant

0.010
(0.006)

Constant

–35.588*
(3.329)

0.010
(0.044)

R-squared

0.87

R-squared

0.12

Durbin–Watson statistic

0.98

Durbin–Watson statistic

1.91

*Significant at the 1% level.
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. The standard errors
have been corrected for serial correlation using the Newey–West
method. See the text for details on the real gold price, real world
gross domestic product (GDP), real ten-year Treasury yield, PTR
(a measure of the ten-year inflation expectation), and pessimistic
expectations (based on University of Michigan survey results).
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
Bullion Market Association, World Bank, Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, and University of Michigan, Surveys
of Consumers.

*Significant at the 1% level.
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. See the text for details
on the real gold price, as well as the VAR (vector autoregression)
innovations in log real U.S. gross domestic product (GDP), real
ten-year Treasury yield, PTR (a measure of the ten-year inflation
expectation), and pessimistic expectations (based on University
of Michigan survey results).
Sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
Bullion Market Association, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and University
of Michigan, Surveys of Consumers.

6. Factors influencing changes in
daily nominal gold prices,
January 7, 2003–February 12, 2021
∆ Log
(nominal gold price)
∆ TIPS yield

–0.011*
(0.004)

∆ Break-even inflation rate

0.027*
(0.005)

Constant

–1.71E-05
(2E-04)

Securities (TIPS) and break-even inflation rates9
relative to nominal Treasury yields. In these three
exercises, as in all regressions on nonexperimental
data, it is important to repeat the usual caveat
that the statistical analysis reveals correlations in
the data, but does not in itself establish causality.
The extent to which such regressions go beyond
mere association depends on the “reasonableness” of the coefficients (see note 7) and, in
short, the ability to “tell the story” that goes with
the regressions.

Figure 4 shows the annual regression results.
The real world GDP measure, which comes in
Durbin–Watson statistic
2.11
highly significantly, reflects the fact that the
*Significant at the 1% level.
demand for the services of gold and the demand
Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. TIPS means Treasury
Inflation-Protected Securities. See the text for details on the
for other goods increase together, approximately
break-even inflation rate.
one-for-one in percentage terms. The estimated
sources: Authors’ calculations based on data from the London
Buillon Market Association and Board of Governors of the Federal
coefficient on the ten-year Treasury yield minus
Reserve System.
PTR indicates that a percentage point rise in the
long-term real interest rate lowers the real gold
price by 13.1%. PTR has an additional effect over and above its presence as a component of the
real rate—and indeed this is far stronger quantitatively. Given the long-term real interest rate, an
extra percentage point of ten-year expected inflation raises the real gold price by a hefty 37%—
well in line with the long-held “inflation hedge” view. Finally, evaluated at the mean of 0.46, a one
standard deviation increase in the fraction of pessimistic survey respondents (8.1 percentage
points) raises the gold price by 9.7%.
R-squared

0.012

For figure 5, we shift our focus to quarterly data. Here the conceptual experiment is to ask how
news about the explanatory variables is reflected in contemporaneous changes in the log real gold
price. In addition to the markedly reduced concern about serially correlated errors, this has somewhat more of a causal feel than the levels regression in figure 4, although the coherent story told
by the levels regression gives it more economic credibility than it would have on its purely econometric merits alone. For the exercise whose results are reported in figure 5, we replace the world
output series with real U.S. GDP, in logs, given that our world GDP series is only available annually.
The news variables are constructed by running four predictive regressions—collectively called a
vector autoregression (VAR)—on the explanatory variables; the innovations from this VAR constitute the news (or surprise) component of the key explanatory variables.10 A 1% innovation in log
real U.S. GDP is associated with a rise in the real gold price of 0.4%, substantially lower than the
1.1% value in the first row in figure 4, although in figure 5 the coefficient is very imprecisely estimated
(indeed not statistically significant). A 1 percentage point innovation in the expected ten-year real
interest rate (the nominal yield on ten-year Treasury securities minus PTR) is associated with a
3.4% reduction in real gold prices. In striking contrast with the result in figure 4, after accounting
for the real interest rate, innovations in PTR play no significant role in the gold price. The coefficient
on innovations in the pessimistic expectations variable appears small, but this is deceptive because
of the large units in which the pessimistic expectations variable is measured, as well as the large
variation in this variable over time. A 10 percentage point innovation in the fraction of survey
participants who expect the next five years to constitute mostly bad times raises the real gold
price by 5%. Because the pessimistic expectations variable repeatedly reaches lows of about 30%
and highs of 60%, over the entire sample it drives substantial fluctuations in the real gold price.
Finally, we do a limited exercise using daily data and report the results in figure 6. Because the CPI
is published only monthly, the dependent variable is the daily change in the nominal gold price.

This is less problematic than it may at first appear because if we could observe daily changes in the
overall price index, they would be at least two orders of magnitude less than the corresponding
changes in the highly volatile nominal gold price. Of the independent variables we study in this
article, only measures of the real yield on long-term Treasury securities and expected long-term
inflation—in this case taken from the TIPS market—are available at a daily frequency. However,
we regard this as useful for two reasons. First, the regression is run on the daily differences in the
log nominal gold price; innovations in real GDP or pessimistic views on the next five years are
likely to be essentially constant at this frequency. Second, the roles of expected real interest rates
and inflation have been our most central theme (as evidenced by the coefficients in figures 4 and 5),
and we have the data to obtain at least some evidence on these at the daily frequency. Since the
variables are in differences, which are quite noisy, the R-squared, which measures the fraction of
the variance of the dependent variable that is explained by the regression, is only 0.012. Yet, there
are valuable lessons in this exercise. First, the negative effect of the real interest rate on the gold
price—the proposition that comes most directly from economic theory—is once again confirmed.
Hence, it has been shown to hold in annual levels, quarterly innovations, and daily differences.
Second, the observation that the inflation effect is quantitatively much larger than the real interest
rate effect holds here, as was the case in the levels regression of figure 4, though contrary to the
innovations regression of figure 5.

Conclusion
We have investigated several hypotheses about the determinants of gold prices—in annual levels
data, quarterly data in innovations form, and daily data in differences. The negative effect of real
interest rates on gold prices predicted by theory holds in all three contexts. Two of the three
specifications (the quarterly innovations specification being the exception) support the notion that
gold is an inflation hedge and that this effect is quantitatively larger than the real interest rate effect.
The two specifications that can be used to evaluate the proposition that gold prices also reflect
protection against bad economic times are highly supportive of it. In the early part of the sample,
variation in inflation or inflationary expectations was the single most important consideration for
the real price of gold. From 2001 on, however, long-term real interest rates and pessimism about
future economic activity appear as the dominant factors. While disinflation since 2001 might have
been expected to result in low gold prices, any effect of low inflation was more than compensated for
by unprecedentedly low long-term real interest rates and by pessimism about future economic activity.
Notes
1
The Bretton Woods system—which pegged the U.S. dollar price of gold and, for the most part, fixed ratios between
gold and the other main currencies—collapsed in stages because of inherent contradictions in the design of the system.
In 1971, the U.S. Gold Window was closed and the fixed price of gold vis-à-vis the dollar ended. We thus begin our
sample in 1971. For a full explanation, see Michael Bordo, 2017, “The operation and demise of the Bretton Woods
system: 1958 to 1971,” VoxEU.org, April 23, available online.
2

PTR is from the Federal Reserve Board’s FRB/US model’s database; see note 4 of John M. Roberts, 2018, “An estimate
of the long-term neutral rate of interest,” FEDS Notes, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 5.
Crossref

3

Further details on the U.S. disinflation period of the early 1980s associated with former Federal Reserve Chair Paul
Volcker are in Michael D. Bordo and Athanasios Orphanides, 2013, “Introduction,” in The Great Inflation: The Rebirth
of Modern Central Banking, Michael D. Bordo and Athanasios Orphanides (eds.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
pp. 1–22, available online.

4

This idea manifests itself in at least two ways. First, for the owner of a gold mine to be indifferent between keeping gold in
the ground on the one hand and mining it and investing the proceeds in financial assets on the other, the price must
be expected to rise at the rate of interest. Given an appropriate terminal condition, the higher the expected real interest
rate, the lower the initial price would have to be. A second approach would be to imagine that gold provides some service
flow (e.g., its value as jewelry). The present value of that “dividend stream” depends inversely on the real interest rate.

5

This is in contradiction with Barsky and Summers (1988), who found a strong negative correlation between the real gold
price and their measure of the real interest rate, particularly over the period 1973–82; rather than using survey-based
inflation expectations, they used a statistical model of inflation that was more sensitive to current inflation and thus
provided a quite different series for expected long-term inflation. See Robert B. Barsky and Lawrence H. Summers,
1988, “Gibson’s paradox and the gold standard,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, No. 3, pp. 528–550. Crossref

6

The full Michigan survey questionnaire is available online.

7

Multiple regressions are statistical exercises estimating the effects of several independent variables on a dependent
variable. Each regression coefficient represents the mean change in the dependent variable for a one-unit change in
the independent variable while holding constant the other independent variables.

8

The Durbin–Watson statistic—which measures the degree of persistence or serial correlation in the residuals (differences
between the observed values and the values predicted by the regression model)—takes on a value close to 2 in the ideal
case where the residuals are serially uncorrelated. A value close to zero indicates that the errors are so persistent that
the regression is “spurious” (uninterpretable and effectively meaningless). The Durbin–Watson statistic of 0.98 in the current
regression exceeds the level at which the regression would be regarded as spurious, but raises some questions about
how well specified the regression is—an issue largely addressed by the innovations formulation in figure 5. In addition,
the standard errors of the coefficients in figure 4 have been corrected for serial correlation as indicated in that figure.

9

The TIPS yield, as noted on the Federal Reserve Board’s website, is a real rate. The break-even inflation rate is the
one that would in principle make a risk-neutral investor indifferent between holding a nominal Treasury security and
a TIPS of the same duration. It is often regarded as a measure of inflationary expectations at the relevant horizon.
A VAR is a statistical model used to capture the dynamic relationship between two or more time-series variables; in a
VAR, each variable is a linear function of past lags of itself and past lags of the other variable(s). In a VAR context, an
innovation is the difference between the observed value of a variable at a particular point in time and the optimal
forecast of that value based on information available before that point in time.

10

Charles L. Evans, President; Anna L. Paulson, Executive
Vice President and Director of Research; Daniel G. Sullivan,
Executive Vice President and Director, Economic Mobility
Initiative; Daniel Aaronson, Senior Vice President, Associate
Director of Research, and Director, Microeconomics; Spencer
Krane, Senior Vice President and Senior Research Advisor ;
Sam Schulhofer-Wohl, Senior Vice President and Director
of Financial Policy and Outreach; Gene Amromin, Vice
President, Finance; Alessandro Cocco, Vice President, Markets;
Jane Dokko, Vice President, Community Development and Policy
Studies; Jonas D. M. Fisher, Vice President, Macroeconomics;
Leslie McGranahan, Vice President, Regional Analysis; Helen
Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Julia Baker, Senior Production
Editor ; Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

The views expressed are the authors’ and do not
necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.
© 2021 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in whole
or in part, provided the articles are not reproduced or
distributed for commercial gain and provided the source
is appropriately credited. Prior written permission must
be obtained for any other reproduction, distribution,
republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago
Fed Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, managing editor, at 312-322-5830 or email
Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed Letter and other Bank
publications are available at https://www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164