View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

l i »

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

■v

:£ sm %

m - m

■ ■■■

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

- ^

3

m

... ,.... ......

m m \

NOVEMBER 1991
NUMBER 51

Chicago Fed Letter
Credit flows and the
credit crunch
The U.S. economy underwent a debt
explosion in the 1980s. Widespread
denunciations of the leveraging of
America have become grist for both
serious commentary and political
worry-mongering about the future of
the U.S. economy. However, recent
weakness in money and credit growth
combined with the continuing lacklus­
ter performance of the U.S. economy
have softened the general distrust of
debt growth and generated significant
pressures to ease monetary policy until
the rate of money and credit growth
returns to historically normal rates.
What is not well understood in this
debate is the degree to which the
changes in the make-up of U.S. credit
flows that began in the 1980s has ob­
scured the reality of the situation.
Innovative financing techniques and
tax related intermediation, in combi­
nation with the continuing fall-out of
the thrift bailout, have combined to
conceal the meaningful movements in
credit flows beneath a tidal wave of
substantially larger, but less meaning­
ful financial trends.
The credit crunch, as it is called, is the
outgrowth of changes in private sector
loan evaluation standards and in regu­
latory practices that occurred in the
late 1980s. Tighter capital require­
ments, higher deposit insurance pre­
miums and a substantial increase in
market discipline have all made it
harder for some types of borrowers to
qualify for credit, both in regulated
and non-regulated markets. Such
pressures have been cited regularly by
Chairman Greenspan and other se­
nior policy officials as part of the justi­
fication for a number of interest rate
reductions in the last two years. To­
day, even with short term interest rates

at thirteen year lows, credit growth
remains anemic, raising the question of
whether interest rates should be low­
ered until money and credit respond.
The seriousness of the situation posed
by the ongoing credit crunch is clear;
however, before too much weight is
placed on forcing money and credit

growth to historically “normal” rates, it
is important to understand just how
distorted these numbers have become.
The economy’s need for credit is un­
questioned, but those credit flows need
to reflect the reality of today’s financial
and economic environment, not histor­
ical averages.
Distortions run amok

Probably the most discussed develop
ment in the credit markets in the 1980s
was the massive build up of debt by
American corporations. Between 1984
and 1990, U.S. corporations added $1.1
trillion of debt to their balance sheets.

This helped generate an explosion not
only in corporate debt, but also in
total nonfinancial debt and total debt
for the U.S. as a whole. During this
same period, corporations were buy­
ing their own stock back at a rate of
$90 billion a year. As can be seen in
Figure la, these two phenomena were
actually mirror images of each other.

Essentially, corporations were just
crossing the word “stock” off their
stock certificates and penciling in the
word “debt.” Very little growth related
economic activity was involved in this
process, just a lot of very expensive
financial transactions. Nevertheless, it
caused debt aggregates to soar relative
to economic growth and destroyed
what up until then had been a solid
statistical relationship between nonfi­
nancial debt and real growth. Today,
the situation has normalized to some
extent. Debt growth is down and equi­
ty growth is actually positive again.
The reversal is causing debt aggregates
to seem depressed relative to the go-go

1980s and, to some extent, even to the
more normal periods in the 1960s and
1970s, as the excesses of the 1980s are
unwound.
The economic reality underneath all
the balance sheet gymnastics is star­
tling, especially given all the hype
about increased importance of the
financial markets in the 1980s. Figure
lb shows total net funds raised by
nonfinancial corporations from all
sources as a share of nominal GNP
(stock buy-backs are netted out of the
increase in debt instruments). This
shows that, relative to overall econom­
ic growth, external funding of corpo­
rations has actually been of declining
importance in the U.S. since the mid1970s. This process may have acceler­
ated somewhat beginning in 1986, but
has not shifted appreciably since then.
Thus, while corporate debt growth has
been declining, it has done so along a
6 year trend.
There are a number of likely reasons
for this trend. First, as corporations
have become larger and more diversi­
fied, they are better able to finance
investment out of current cash flow.
Second, the high speed, highly imita­
tive nature of modern international
business practice favors large firms
purchasing or licensing new technolo­
gies for rapid development over inno­
vators acquiring external funding to
build their own firms. Third, U.S. tax
policy has consistently favored internal
funding over debt and debt over equi­
ty, giving high cash flow firms that can
invest their own cash flows a major
competitive advantage, reinforcing the
trend away from external finance and
toward internal funding. The trend
toward internal corporate funding is
unmistakable and implies that corpo­
rate debt growth will in all likelihood
either continue to decline or, at least,
not grow as fast as historical averages
would indicate. In fact, if U.S. corpo­
rations are going to reverse the lever­
aging of the 1980s, current downward
trends may continue for some time,
regardless of the growth level in the
economy.
The path of government borrowing
over this period provides another, no

less cautionary, tale
about the easy interpre­
tation of credit num­
bers. The large run-up
in government borrow­
ing in the late 1970s
and early 1980s shown
in Figure 2 and the
resulting increase in
total borrowing in U.S.
credit markets is well
known. The recent
trends and their impli­
cations are less well
understood. Govern­
ment borrowing began
to fall as a percent of
GNP beginning in 1986
and by 1989 had fallen
to 3% of nominal GNP. While still
sizable, this level of government bor­
rowing was not large by international
standards, putting less strain on the
markets as well as damping the rate of
overall credit growth relative to eco­
nomic growth.
More recently, in large part due to the
need to finance the thrift industry
bailout, government borrowing has
again exploded. This run-up, howev­
er, is very different from the earlier
one. In this case, the government is
assuming debts already in the econo­
my. Very little in the way of resource
allocation, the real meat and potatoes
of economic growth, is actually hap­
pening. All that is really going on is
that a large number of S&L liabilities
are becoming (officially) liabilities of
the U.S. government, damping finan­
cial debt growth and swelling nonfi­
nancial debt. While this has significant
consequences for taxpayers, it does
not put any additional stress on the
credit markets. Before the bailout, the
S&Ls owed the money, now the gov­
ernm ent does. No new funds other
than working capital for the Resolu­
tion Trust Corporation are actually
required. In fact, as the government is
not making the types of questionable
loans that got many of the now de­
funct S&Ls in trouble, more funds
rather than less may well be available
for productive investment. Thus, non­
financial debt growth has been pushed
up relative to economic growth while
financial aggregates and the savings

component of the money supply are
depressed. As before, much of what
we observe in the credit numbers is
not related to economic activity, but
to large scale changes in labeling of
assets.
It’s not all bookkeeping

Not all of the large movement in the
credit aggregates are labeling changes.
The 1981 and 1982 tax bills, building
on previous tax laws, heavily favored
certain types of offsetting financial
transactions. Under these tax laws, it
often paid to borrow money on which
the interest was deductible and invest
in some other, often complicated,
financial shelter arrangement that
paid tax free returns or produced tax
write-offs. This often generated a host
of offsetting financial transactions for
one (and sometimes no) economic
investment. The simplest examples
are individuals who borrowed cash
from banks to invest in IRAs in order
to take advantage of the IRA tax de­
duction and the deductibility of inter­
est on the bank loan. Some of the
fastest growth in tax generated inter­
mediation was in complicated Sub­
chapter S corporations and limited
partnerships arrangements that often,
though not always, involved complicat­
ed real estate deals and leasebacks that
could generate large numbers of off­
setting financial transactions.
These tax laws generated a massive
increase in purely financial credit

activity that had little, if anything, to
do with economic activity. This can be
seen in Figure 3a, which shows as a
percent of GNP the net funds flows
into the nonfarm, noncorporate sec­
tor, which includes all the Subchapter
S corporations and other tax shelter
activity. Figure 3b shows the growth in
commercial real estate mortgages, a
particularly favored recipient of special
tax treatments, and Figure 3c shows
nonmortgage consumer debt, which
includes all of the individual efforts to
take advantage of the tax laws. As can
be seen, intermediation activity ex-

p ercent of nom inal G N P (4 quarter moving average)

a. Nonfarm, noncorporate borrowing

b. Commercial mortgages

c. Consumer nonmortgage debt

1959 '61

’63

'65 ’67

’69 71

73

75

77

79

'81

ploded in all of these sectors from
1981 to 1986, reaching historical
highs. At their peak, the funding go­
ing into these sectors was immense.
The nonfarm, noncorporate sector
absorbed $129 billion in 1985. Com­
mercial mortgages peaked at $74 bil­
lion in 1986. Consumer nonmortgage
debt peaked at $83 billion in 1985, for
a total in the three sectors of $286
billion.
The Tax Reform Act of 1986 removed
many of the incentives for purely fi­
nancial transactions. Tax shelters were
in large part eliminated.
The special treatment
of commercial real
estate was severely re­
duced, and many of the
individual incentives,
such as the interest
deductibility of non­
mortgage consumer
debt, were eliminated
or phased out. The
effect was enormous.
By 1990, the flows into
nonfarm, noncorporate
credit, commercial
mortgages, and consum­
er nonmortgage debt
had dropped to $14
billion, $9 billion, and
$14 billion a year, re­
spectively, all historical
lows. This means that
these sectors are absorb­
ing $249 billion a year
less in credit than they
did in 1985. Further, as
can be seen in Figures
3a, 3b, and 3c, these
changes did not occur
overnight but rather
constitute a continuing
restructuring of credit
flows. These shifts in
basic trends clearly
make detecting recent
movements in credit
creation virtually impos­
sible.
One way to see this in
terms of the overall
market is shown in
Figure 4, which shows
net credit raised in all

sectors, thus illustrating the full force
of the explosion in purely financial
transactions. The rapid rise from the
1981 tax bill and the equally dramatic
reversal of trend that begins with the
1986 tax bill stand out in sharp relief.
Credit flows peak in the fourth quarter
of 1985 at an unbelievable 34% of
GNP or $1,387 trillion and then de­
scend steadily to a current level of 9%
of GNP or $505 billion. It is equally
apparent from this graph that detect­
ing whether or not there has, in fact,
been a decline in credit creation due
to the credit crunch is much like trying
to measure the effects of an electric
fan in the midst of a hurricane.
Nor does it help, as some have suggest­
ed, to concentrate on the banking
sector as a provider of business loans

Karl A. Scheld, S enior Vice P re sid en t a n d
D irecto r o f R esearch; David R. A llardice, Vice
P re sid en t a n d A ssistant D irecto r o f R esearch;
C arolyn M cM ullen, E ditor.
Chicago Fed Letter is p u b lish ed m o n th ly by th e
R esearch D e p a rtm e n t o f th e F ed eral Reserve
B ank o f C hicago. T h e views ex p ressed are th e
a u th o rs ’ a n d are n o t necessarily th o se o f th e
F ederal Reserve B ank o f C hicago o r th e F ederal
Reserve System. A rticles m ay b e re p rin te d if
th e source is c re d ite d a n d th e R esearch
D e p a rtm e n t is p rovided w ith copies o f th e
rep rin ts.
Chicago Fed Letter is available w ith o u t ch arg e
fro m th e Public In fo rm atio n C e n te r, F ederal
Reserve B ank o f Chicago, P.O. Box 834,
C hicago, Illinois, 60690, (312) 322-5111.

ISSN 0895-0164

to measure the potential effects of the
credit crunch. As Figure 5 shows,
bank loans not elsewhere classified
(where the bulk of business lending
done by banks is counted) has been
declining steadily as a percent of GNP
since the 1970s. While the recent
drop may be a bit faster, it is no more
dramatic than other declines over this
period, only some of which were in

any way associated with economic slow­
downs. This conclusion is further rein­
forced by the observation that banks
were also engaged in the tax generated
lending of the early 1980s as well as the
subsequent decline. Consequently,
bank loan numbers are subject to all of
the same problems of interpretation as
the numbers presented above. The fact
is that, as worrisome as recent trends in
money and credit
growth have been in
light of sluggish overall
economic performance,
they are, in terms of the
credit numbers, at most
a modest backwash in
the midst of the fero­
cious riptides of finan­
cial restructuring.
Conclusion

This article has exam­
ined recent trends in
credit creation and
suggested that these
trends are in large part
the results of major
shifts in intermediation

patterns in the U.S. economy as well as
the unwinding of the effects of the tax
policies of the 1980s. These trends are
so large that any evaluation of current
credit numbers to determine the di­
rection of current policy are subject to
substantial uncertainty and should be
treated as such. When there are major
changes in financial structure, as so
often been the case in the 1970s and
1980s, policymakers must rely heavily
on real economic numbers and exer­
cise careful judgm ent concerning what
constitutes reasonable economic per­
formance. In such an environment,
policymakers cannot rely on simple
rules, or on limited sets of financial
indicators. Given recent economic
performance and known changes in
the financial environment, concerns
about the availability of credit are in
all likelihood well-founded. Neverthe­
less, as this article has argued, we
should examine the overall perfor­
mance of the economy and the terms
of credit availability rather than the
credit flows for information to guide
the future course of policy.
—Steven Strongin

(Z Ig )

06909 s io u in i ‘o S e d i io

K8 xoa

O d

j a i l o r u o iiE im o ju i o q q n j
O O V 3 IH 3 3 0 3N V H 3 A ^ 3 S 3 H 3V ^3< 333