View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CHICAGO

APRIL 2007
NUMBER 237

Chicago Fed Letter
The changing value of education
by Lisa Barrow, senior economist, and Cecilia Elena Rouse, professor of economics and public affairs, Princeton University,
and research associate, National Bureau of Economic Research

Why has the economic value of education stopped rising over the past ten years?
The most likely explanation seems to be that the booming economy of the late 1990s
helped to increase the average earnings of all workers, including those at the low end
of the skills distribution.

In the 1980s, education was an increasingly worthwhile investment. According
to data from the Current Population Survey
(CPS), in 1979, men and women with
a bachelor’s degree
or higher earned
1. Average annual income, by education group
$30,507 per year,
77% more than the
dollars (2003)
$17,283 per year
60,000
earned by workers
with only a high
school diploma. By
40,000
1989, annual earnings of those with a
college degree had
risen to $37,288,
20,000
nearly double the
$18,952 earned by
high school graduates (see figure 1).
0
Similarly, high school
1979 ’81 ’83 ’85 ’87 ’89 ’91 ’93 ’95 ’97 ’99 2001 ’03 ’05
graduates earned
High school dropout
Some college
47% more per year,
College graduate
High school graduate
on average, than high
school dropouts in
S OURCE: Authors’ calculations based on data from the March Current Population
Survey for individuals aged 25–65 years.
1979 ($17,283 versus
$11,737), and high
school graduates earned 80% more than
high school dropouts in 1989 ($18,952
versus $10,522).

Researchers identified a number of
likely causes of rising income inequality, including declines in unions and
the real value of the minimum wage,

as well as growing demand for more
highly skilled workers, likely due to
technological change. Policymakers
considered ways to increase earnings
among low-wage workers, such as raising the minimum wage, expanding the
earned income tax credit, and encouraging individuals to get more education. As former President Bill Clinton
wrote in 1997, “Today, more than ever
before in our history, education is the
fault line between those who will prosper in the new economy and those
who will not.”1
Changing labor markets in the 1990s

While the economic value of education remains high, its rate of increase
has slowed or even declined since the
early to mid-1990s.2 Economists measure the economic value of additional
schooling as the average percentage
increase in mean earnings for an additional year of schooling while controlling for other differences in individual
characteristics, such as years of potential work experience, geographic region,
sex, race, and marital status. Figure 2
shows that the increase in annual earnings associated with an additional year
of schooling was roughly 8.9% in 1979.
The value of an additional year of education peaked at 13.5% in 1993 and
has since fallen to 12.7% in 2005.

reasons. First, as figure 1 shows, there has
percentage increase in annual earnings
been a large increase
in the wages of col15
lege graduates. Similarly, Autor, Katz, and
13
Kearney document
that earnings at the
11
90th percentile of the
earnings distribu9
tion have been rising
steadily relative to median earnings since
7
the early 1970s.6 Second, the supply of
5
highly skilled workers
1979 ’81 ’83 ’85 ’87 ’89 ’91 ’93 ’95 ’97 ’99 2001 ’03 ’05
likely increased during
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations based on data from the March Current Population
this period because
Survey for individuals aged 25–65 years.
of increases in college
enrollment and more
immigration of high-skilled workers.
The stagnation in the growth of the
value of schooling occurred at the same Between 1996 and 2000, enrollment in
time as college tuition was rising; from two- and four-year degree-granting institutions increased by nearly 7%; also,
1993 to 2004, average tuition and fees
since 1999, 34% of immigrants entering
grew by nearly 46%.3 This led some to
the U.S. have had at least a bachelor’s deask whether a college education was
gree, compared with 28% of immigrants
still worth the money. Nevertheless, our
previous work suggests that even when arriving in the 1990s and 24% of immigrants arriving in the 1980s.7 Overall, the
the increased cost of college tuition has
percentage of the population aged 25–65
been taken into account, a four-year
with at least a bachelor’s degree rose
college degree is worth at least $300,000
more than a high school diploma over from 26% in 1996 to 30% in 2004 (our
calculations based on March CPS data).
an average working lifetime in net
Autor, Katz, and Kearney also find that
present value terms.4 However, as with
the relative supply of college-equivalent
many investments, today’s performance
is no guarantee of future performance. labor continued to increase throughout the late 1990s and early 2000s.8 The
So why has the economic value of edufact that the wages of college graduates
cation declined or stagnated over the
increased so dramatically in spite of the
past ten years? A large literature in the
likely increase in the relative supply of
1990s hypothesized that the major source
college graduates is consistent with inof increasing wage inequality of the
creasing—not decreasing—demand.
1980s was an increase in “skill-biased
technological change.”5 Namely, changes The average earnings of workers with
in technology increased the productivity lower levels of education have also increased since 1993. It is this increase
of high-skilled workers relative to lowthat accounts for the slowing growth
skilled workers, leading to a shift in demand toward more highly skilled labor. in the value of education. Given the
As a result, wages for high-skilled workers growth in the average earnings of collegeeducated workers, the value of education
rose, while wages for low-skilled workers fell. It would seem reasonable, there- would have risen at a faster rate since
1993 than it did between 1980 and 1990
fore, that an explanation for the leveling
off of the return to education might be if the earnings of those with less educaa slowdown in the increase in demand tion had either decreased or remained
constant. And so, we might ask why the
for such highly skilled labor. While this
earnings of these less educated workis certainly possible, we do not consider
ers have increased.
it the most likely explanation for two
2. Economic value of an additional year of education

Changes in compensation

One possibility is that the changing earnings trends are an “illusion” driven by
changes in compensation practices and/
or changes in labor force composition.
For example, if highly educated workers increasingly receive compensation
in the form of benefits, such as health
insurance, while less educated workers
are less likely to receive health insurance,
the value of education in terms of total
compensation may be increasing at a
faster rate than the value measured by
wages and salaries alone. Pierce finds
that compensation inequality was increasing faster than wage inequality
through the mid-1990s and that it was
driven largely by declines in the health
insurance coverage rate for workers at
the bottom of the distribution.9 Data
from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics’
Employer Costs for Employee Compensation
indicate that employer benefits costs
have been rising faster than wage and
salary costs since 2000, which, depending on the distribution of the benefits,
could mean that the value of education
in terms of total compensation may have
continued to rise at a high rate. In contrast, we think there is less support for
labor force composition changes that
contribute to the slowing of the growth
in the value of education. Over the past
ten years, labor force participation
among high school dropouts has been
increasing (even when assuming all incarcerated people are high school dropouts), while participation rates for those
with more education have been falling.
These changes in participation would
more likely lead to an increase in the
estimates of the value of education if
we assume that within the completed
education category, the expected earnings of the individuals who are not participating in the labor market are lower
than the observed earnings of the individuals who are participating in the labor
market. Of course, there may be other
changes in the composition of the labor
force that might explain these trends.
Minimum wage increases in the late
1990s may also have helped increase
the wages of the least skilled workers.
However, minimum wage increases are
unlikely to fully explain the trends for

at the low end of the skills distribution.
Studies of labor market cyclicality show
that earnings and (especially) employment are procyclical and that less educated individuals experience greater
cyclical variation than more educated
individuals.13

5

For example, see John Bound and George
Johnson, 1992, “Changes in the structure
of wages in the 1980s: An evaluation of alternative explanations,” American Economic
Review, Vol. 82, No. 3, June, pp. 371–392;
and Lawrence F. Katz and Kevin M. Murphy,
1992, “Changes in relative wages, 1963–
1987: Supply and demand factors,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 1,
February, pp. 35–78.

6

two reasons. First, the latest increase
in the federal minimum wage was in
late 1997, two years after average wages
of the least skilled workers began to
increase. And, the federal minimum
wage has not been changed since then,
such that it cannot account for further

David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and
Melissa S. Kearney, 2006, “The polarization of the U.S. labor market,” American
Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 2, May,
pp. 189–194. They further document that
since the late 1980s, both high- and lowskilled jobs have grown relative to “middleskilled” jobs (routine cognitive and manual
tasks, e.g., bookkeeping and repetitive production labor). This “polarization” of the
labor market, they argue, is driven by computers directly substituting for middleskilled tasks, complementing high-skilled
labor, and having no direct effect on lowskilled jobs.

7

For data on college enrollment, see T. D.
Snyder, A. G. Tan, and C. M. Hoffman,
2004, Digest of Education Statistics, 2003, U.S.
Department of Education and Institute of
Education Sciences, National Center for
Education Statistics, Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, No. NCES2005-025, table 174, available at www.nces.
ed.gov/programs/digest/d03/tables/xls/
tab174.xls, accessed on April 1, 2005. For
the educational attainment of immigrants,
see U.S. Census Bureau, 2004, Current
Population Survey, Foreign-Born Population

Going forward, the recent push to increase the minimum wage
will likely help keep the value of education from increasing
rapidly in the near future.
increases in the wages of low-skilled
workers. Although 17 states and the
District of Columbia have raised their
minimum wages above the 1997 federal
minimum, several large states—including
Florida, New Jersey, and New York—did
not enact minimum wages above the
federal minimum until 2005.10 Thus,
only 30% of payroll employment was
in states with minimum wages above the
federal minimum as of January 1, 2004,
making it unlikely that these state minimum wages fully account for changes in
average wages across the entire country.11 Second, although Lee finds that
the fall in the real value of the minimum wage can explain much of the
increase in inequality at the bottom of
the wage distribution over the 1980s
(implying that the minimum wage increases of the mid-1990s also propped
up wages at the bottom of the wage
distribution), Autor, Katz, and Kearney
question this interpretation.12 They highlight that much of the decline in the real
value of the minimum wage during the
1980s occurred during an economic
downturn, whereas the minimum wage
increases in the 1990s were legislated
during economic expansions. As a result,
the time series relationship between inequality and the minimum wage may
be spurious. Further, both studies note
the anomaly that the minimum wage
seems to be related to inequality at
both the bottom and the top of the
wage distribution.

The puzzle associated with this explanation, however, is why wages of the least
educated continued to rise or at least
did not fall relative to those of the more
educated during the 2001 recession.
Any explanation for the changes in
the economic value of education over
the past 15 years will likely involve a
combination of the many factors discussed in this article. Going forward,
the recent push to increase the minimum wage will likely help keep the value
of education from increasing rapidly
in the near future. That said, large shifts
in the relative demand for, or supply of,
more educated or less educated labor
could change that. For now, at least, the
value of education in terms of earnings remains near its peak, providing
much incentive for young people to
pursue a college education.
1

William J. Clinton, 1997, Call to Action for
American Education in the 21st Century, special report prepared by U.S. Department of
Education, Washington, DC, February 14,
available at www.ed.gov/updates/
PresEDPlan, accessed on April 4, 2005.

2

This discussion draws heavily on Lisa Barrow
and Cecilia Elena Rouse, 2005, “Does college
still pay?,” The Economists’ Voice, Vol. 2, No. 4,
article 3, available at www.bepress.com/
ev/vol2/iss4/art3. Material used with permission from the publisher, The Berkeley
Electronic Press, ©2005.

3

Authors’ calculations based on data for
undergraduates from the U.S. Department
of Education and Institute of Education
Sciences, National Center for Education
Statistics, 2005, National Postsecondary Student
Aid Study, Data Analysis System (DAS)
online application.

4

Barrow and Rouse (2005).

Conclusion

The booming economy of the late 1990s
appears to have increased the average
earnings of all workers, including those

Michael H. Moskow, President; Charles L. Evans,
Senior Vice President and Director of Research; Douglas
Evanoff, Vice President, financial studies; Jonas Fisher,
Economic Advisor and Team Leader, macroeconomic
policy research; Richard Porter, Vice President, payment
studies; Daniel Sullivan, Vice President, microeconomic
policy research; William Testa, Vice President, regional
programs and Economics Editor; Helen O’D. Koshy,
Kathryn Moran, and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita
Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors.
Chicago Fed Letter is published monthly by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the
authors’ and are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
Reserve System.
© 2007 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
Letter and other Bank publications are available
on the Bank’s website at www.chicagofed.org.
ISSN 0895-0164

Illinois, Maine, Massachusetts, Minnesota,
New Jersey, New York, Oregon, Rhode
Island, Vermont, Washington, and
Wisconsin, along with the District of
Columbia. See John J. Fitzpatrick, Jr., 2006,
“State labor legislation enacted in 2005,”
Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 129, No. 1, January,
pp. 3–29.

in the United States, March, annual data tables
(PPL-176), table 2.5, available at www.
census.gov/population/www/socdemo/
foreign/datatbls.html, accessed on
January 16, 2007.
8

David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and
Melissa S. Kearney, 2005, “Trends in U.S.
wage inequality: Re-assessing the revisionists,”
National Bureau of Economics Research,
working paper, No. 11627, September.

9

Brooks Pierce, 2001, “Compensation inequality,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 116, No. 4, November, pp. 1493–1525.

10

The 17 states are Alaska, California,
Connecticut, Delaware, Florida, Hawaii,

11

Authors’ calculations using payroll employment data from the CPS as of January 2006.

12

David S. Lee, 1999, “Wage inequality in the
United States during the 1980s: Rising
dispersion or falling minimum wage?,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114,
No. 3, August, pp. 977–1023.

13

Hilary W. Hoynes, 2000, “The employment
and earnings of less skilled workers over
the business cycle,” in Finding Jobs: Work and
Welfare Reform, Rebecca Blank and David
Card (eds.), New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 23–71; and James R. Hines, Jr.,
Hilary W. Hoynes, and Alan B. Krueger,
2001, “Another look at whether a rising
tide lifts all boats,” in The Roaring Nineties:
Can Full Employment Be Sustained?, Alan B.
Krueger and Robert M. Solow (eds.), New
York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 493–537.