View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Flexible Commitment
or Inflation Targeting for the U.S.?
Based on a speech given by President Santomero to the Money Marketeers, New York, NY, June 10, 2003

T

BY ANTHONY M. SANTOMERO

he idea of creating a framework for explicit
inflation targeting in the U.S. has recently
become a topic of considerable discussion.
The key question is: Could inflation targeting
improve on the U.S. economy’s performance? President
Santomero thinks inflation targeting makes sense for the
U.S., in principle. But he cautions that several important
issues must be worked out before an explicit targeting
regime is established. In this quarter’s message, he
discusses these issues — in particular, calibrating
the target and reconciling inflation targeting with the
Fed’s mandate to foster not just price stability but
also full employment.

Price stability is the primary
focus of central banks, as it should be.
Economic theory and recent experience show us that maintaining a
reasonably stable price level promotes
long-term growth, helps economies
run more efficiently, and enhances
their capacity to absorb exogenous
shocks in the short run. These benefits
arise partly because price stability
helps the marketplace infer changing
fundamentals and distinguish them
from transitory disturbances and partly
because it improves the central bank’s
ability to conduct effective monetary
policy.
Over the past decade or so, a
number of central banks around the
world have, to good effect, adopted
inflation targeting as a means of
www.phil.frb.org

achieving both price stability and
credibility as inflation fighters. The
monetary authorities of more than 20
countries, including New Zealand, the
United Kingdom, and Canada have
adopted explicit inflation targets.
Over roughly the same
period, the Fed has achieved price
stability in the U.S. without inflation
targeting. Rather, it has evolved a less
restrictive approach — an approach I
call “flexible commitment.” By flexible
commitment I mean that our current
policy’s commitment to low inflation
never precludes an active response to
economic disturbances. The Fed’s
approach has implicitly targeted low
inflation, though it does not embody a
numerical inflation target. Moreover, it
has been constructive in managing

inflation expectations. Indeed, it has
passed a crucial test of any good
monetary policy: It has established the
Fed’s credibility for maintaining low
inflation.
For over 20 years, the U.S.
economy has performed quite well
under this policy regime — dramatically better than it did in the high
inflation environment of the 1970s. In
fact, the Federal Reserve’s current
approach to monetary policy has done
a good job of meeting the Fed’s dual
goals of price stability and full employment — goals set by law.
Nonetheless, the idea of
creating a framework for explicit
inflation targeting in the U.S. has
recently become a topic of considerable discussion. Some have spoken for
it, some against it. The key question is:
Could inflation targeting improve on
the U.S. economy’s performance going
forward?
My position is that inflation
targeting makes sense in principle for

Anthony M. Santomero, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review Q3 2003 1

the U.S. It is the next logical step on the
path the Fed has been traveling for the
past two decades — a path toward
greater transparency and clarity. If
properly implemented, it would increase public confidence in the Fed’s
commitment to reasonable long-term
price stability in the U.S. It would also
strengthen monetary policy as a stabilization tool in a low-inflation environment. Moreover, while I do not think
the U.S. faces a serious risk of deflation,
inflation targeting would also help to
avoid this risk should it arise.
At the same time, I recognize
there are several important issues that
must be worked out before an explicit
inflation targeting regime could be
established. Two are particularly
important. One is calibrating the
inflation target — that is, choosing the
target price index, target inflation
range, and target horizon — so as to
reinforce, rather than undermine, the
credibility of the Fed’s commitment to
price stability. The second is properly
reconciling inflation targeting with the
Fed’s mandate to foster not only price
stability but also full employment.
As we shall see, these are
related issues. We need to move
carefully yet concretely on these two
fronts before we implement inflation
targeting, if we are to realize the
promise of better economic performance. With proper implementation,
inflation targeting makes sense for the
U.S. — in practice as well as in
principle — and I would support it.
THE CANADIAN EXPERIENCE
WITH INFLATION TARGETING
Our neighbors to the north
speak well of explicit inflation targeting. In Canada, the economic boom at
the end of the 1980s, together with an
oil-price shock and the introduction of a
goods and services tax, led to fears that
inflation would escalate. Against this
backdrop, the Canadian government

2 Q3 2003 Business Review

and the Bank of Canada agreed on
explicit targets for reducing inflation in
1991.
The first formal targets aimed
to bring inflation down to 2 percent by
December 1995. Inflation declined
more quickly than anticipated and was
already closing in on its target by
January 1992 — almost four years
ahead of schedule. Since then, with
year-over-year inflation almost always
in the 1 to 3 percent target range, the
policy has been widely regarded as a
success. Moreover, the Bank of Canada

The Canadian experience
points to the potential benefits of explicit
inflation targeting in the U.S. It suggests
that institutionalizing an explicit target,
by adding precision to inflation objectives and thus enhancing the transparency and accountability of central bank
policy, can both stabilize prices and
improve overall economic performance.
However, a U.S. shift to an
inflation targeting regime would entail
important implementation issues unique
to our environment. We would be
implementing inflation targeting after

Inflation targeting makes sense in principle
for the U.S. It is the next logical step on the
path the Fed has been traveling for the past
two decades — a path toward greater
transparency and clarity.
and many academics contend that
inflation targeting contributed to the
country’s improved economic performance.
Interestingly, the major lesson
drawn from the Canadian experience
with inflation targeting relates to
credibility and inflation expectations.
After inflation fell to 2 percent,
expectations began to closely track the
announced inflation target. With the
low inflation target becoming increasingly credible, the nature of inflation
in Canada began to change. During
the 1990s, inflation became less
responsive to short-run supply and
demand excesses as well as to relative
price shocks. Canada also enjoyed
increased stability in its real economy.
When compared with the preceding
decade, the first decade of inflation
targeting showed less volatility in both
output growth and the unemployment
rate. In short, inflation targeting worked
as an automatic stabilizer in response to
a whole range of economic disturbances.

having achieved price stability and
credibility. Other countries implement
inflation targeting as a means to achieve
those objectives. Moreover, inflation
targeting in the U.S. must recognize the
Fed’s dual goals of price stability and
maximum sustainable economic growth.
Unlike the Federal Reserve, many
inflation-targeting central banks have a
single mission of price stability.
These implementation issues
are more than technical. They lie at
the core of how such a system might
effectively work in the U.S. context.
Let me elaborate.
THE CURRENT U.S. POLICY
FRAMEWORK
While the Fed has not adopted
explicit inflation targeting, the policy
strategy it has followed over the past 20
years generated many of the benefits
inflation targeting offers. The Fed
greatly increased its credibility for
maintaining low and stable inflation and
achieved an enviable record of output

www.phil.frb.org

growth. It became more proactive in
heading off inflationary pressures, even
as it sought to ensure continued growth
by responding aggressively to financial
shocks and demand variations. At the
same time, the Fed has become
increasingly transparent — an important
component of maintaining a credible
commitment to low and stable inflation.
My colleague Ben Bernanke, a
Fed Governor, has described the current
policy framework as “constrained
discretion.” But, as I mentioned, I prefer
the term flexible commitment. Under
flexible commitment, the central bank
has been free to adjust monetary policy
to stabilize output and employment
during short-term disturbances, while
maintaining a strong commitment to
keeping inflation under control.
Flexible commitment incorporates the idea that low and stable
inflation is a key outcome of successful
monetary policy. Yet, it has not offered
an explicit inflation target, nor has it
reported quantitatively on our successes
or failures. Nonetheless, the Fed has
achieved what is essentially price
stability and also has stabilized inflation
expectations.
The Philadelphia Fed’s Survey
of Professional Forecasters clearly
confirms well-anchored long-term
inflation expectations. In 1991, we
began asking survey participants for
their 10-year inflation expectations.
The median forecast was that CPI
inflation would average 4 percent over
the next 10 years. As core inflation
declined, inflation expectations
declined along with it. Declining
inflation expectations are one reason
we were able to achieve remarkable
economic growth in the 1990s even as
trend inflation slowed to its lowest level
since the early 1960s. In 1999, our
survey’s 10-year CPI inflation expectation settled in at 2-1/2 percent. It has
stayed there ever since. The Fed’s
aggressive actions to lower the federal

www.phil.frb.org

funds rate in 2001 and 2002 did not
elevate survey participants’ long-run
inflation expectations. The recent dip in
core inflation did not diminish them. I
take this as a positive sign that the Fed’s
commitment to maintaining reasonable
price stability is a credible one in the
mind of the public.
This stabilization of expectations is crucially important. Indeed,
recent history suggests the commit-

In an environment
where we have
achieved credibility,
should we
institutionalize it?
ment to long-run price stability has
enhanced the Fed’s short-run flexibility
to respond to shocks, as well as monetary
policy’s effectiveness in offsetting
shocks. Because the Fed’s aggressive
actions to lower the federal funds rate in
2001 and 2002 did not elevate long-run
inflation expectations, long-term interest
rates came down with short-term rates.
Clearly, the decline of both long- and
short-term rates helped stabilize the
economy.
But we have not always been
successful. Recall the 1970s. Early in the
decade, inflation began to rise, and the
Fed failed to establish itself as a
champion of price stability. The
public’s inflation expectations became
unstable. Inflation and inflation
expectations spiraled upward. Economic performance deteriorated. The
Fed, concerned about the potential
impact on employment and economic
activity, initially avoided undertaking
the strong policy actions necessary to
break this destructive cycle. It was not
until Fed Chairman Paul Volcker led
the economy into disinflation in 1979-82

that the Fed began to regain credibility.
Unfortunately, regaining credibility was
costly. We suffered two recessions during
those years.
SHOULD WE MOVE TO
INFLATION TARGETING NOW?
Under both Chairman Volcker
and Chairman Greenspan, the Fed
worked hard to restore low and stable
inflation. Their efforts proved successful
in giving the Fed credibility as an
inflation fighter. This was done using
the strategy that I described as flexible
commitment — one with an implicit
objective of price stability rather than an
explicit inflation target. In the face of
well-anchored inflationary expectations,
the question now is whether this is the
time to adopt an explicit target. In an
environment where we have achieved
credibility, should we institutionalize it?
I believe a properly specified
inflation target can help ensure the
continuation of our recent success. It
can protect us from repeating the
mistakes of our past without unduly
constraining our ability to respond to
short-run shocks. An explicit inflation
target would place some check on Fed
actions, helping to lock in the Fed’s
hard-won credibility. But we must
recognize that inflation targeting in
the U.S. might differ from the systems
used abroad for two reasons: (1) the
U.S. has already achieved price stability,
and (2) the U.S. has the dual goals of
price stability and full employment.
Nonetheless, we can learn
from other countries’ successful
experience as well as from the academic
literature on this subject.
THE ACADEMIC LITERATURE
One key lesson of the academic literature is that, in theory,
inflation targeting is the best strategy for
achieving both Fed policy objectives:
low, stable inflation and full employment. Indeed, it is difficult to write

Business Review Q3 2003 3

down a macroeconomic model that does
not lead to some sort of inflation
targeting as the optimal monetary policy
approach for achieving these two goals
— not surprising, given that more-thantransitory deviations from full employment will, with a lag, mean changing
inflation.
Another idea theorists
emphasize is that of transparency. The
Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) recognizes that transparency
plays an important role in achieving
our policy objectives and goals. Any
policy action can have very different
effects, depending on what the private
sector infers about the information
that induced policymakers to act,
about policymakers’ objectives, and
about their likely future actions.
Accordingly, FOMC statements have
been made more explicit and more
direct, and votes are now released at
the end of meetings.
Greater transparency in
policymaking, along with a commitment to reasonable long-run price
stability, has enhanced Fed credibility.
As I mentioned earlier, credibility has
given the Fed greater flexibility to
respond to economic and financial
shocks. The benefit of transparency
and credibility is evident in the recent
movement of the fed funds rate to a
40-year low. A 525-basis-point
reduction in the funds rate with no
damaging rise in inflationary expectations would have been unimaginable
20 years ago.
The positive results of this
approach to monetary policy are
evident. The documented decline in
economic volatility in the mid-1980s
occurred at the time the Fed conquered inflation, started achieving
credibility for lower inflation, and
brought inflationary expectations under
control. While I do not believe better
monetary policy is the entire story, it
certainly played an important role.

4 Q3 2003 Business Review

If implemented carefully,
explicit inflation targeting can reinforce
the effectiveness of monetary policy. It
would enhance our transparency, make
it easier for the public to understand
monetary policy, and further improve
expectations dynamics.
We know that public perceptions about longer-run monetary policy
affect the effectiveness of short-run
policy actions. Specifically, the
effectiveness of current monetary
policy is influenced by expectations of
future policy actions and expectations of

generation and, most would agree, has
now achieved. The Fed would then
include in its regular testimony before
Congress a report on its success or failure
in achieving that numerical target.
These steps would move the Fed farther
along the path to greater transparency
and accountability — a path along
which it has already been moving.
But to say inflation targeting is
an evolutionary step is not to say it is an
easy one. Simply announcing a numerical target is not enough. A number of
important implementation issues are

An inflation target has to be calibrated in terms
of three components: an inflation measure, a
target range, and a time period over which
average inflation is to fall within that range.
long-term inflation. Inflation targeting
would anchor these expectations more
firmly, making price stability easier to
achieve in the long term and increasing
the central bank’s ability to stabilize
output and employment in the short
term. Explicit inflation targeting in the
U.S. might also deliver a more lucid
explanation of policy, reduced uncertainty in financial markets, and
increased popular support for the Fed.
The interaction between credibility and
policy actions is a key ingredient to
implementing effective monetary
policy. Proper implementation and
design are therefore crucial if explicit
targeting is to fulfill its promise.
INFLATION TARGETING AS
THE POTENTIAL NEXT STEP
Inflation targeting would be
an evolutionary, rather than a revolutionary, step in the Fed’s policy
strategy. Against the background of
flexible commitment, as I have described it, the Fed could simply quantify
what it means by price stability — a goal
it has been pursuing for almost a

essential to the success of inflation
targeting in the U.S. Given our nation’s
already low and stable inflation rate,
these issues are more substantive for us
than they would be for a country
experiencing high inflation. If we are to
coax additional gains from being
explicit, we must pay careful attention
to the design of the targeting framework.
An inflation target has to be
calibrated in terms of three components: an inflation measure, a target
range, and a time period over which
average inflation is to fall within that
range. Given the Fed’s dual mandate to
achieve price stability and full employment, we need to consider carefully
several issues relevant to the choice of
components for an inflation target.
The first issue is this: It is
widely accepted that pursuing policies
to stabilize output and employment in
the face of temporary shocks can
create greater short-run variance in
inflation. So how does the Fed set an
explicit range for an inflation target that
is firm enough to impart credibility to its

www.phil.frb.org

long-run price stability goal, yet flexible
enough to accommodate its short-run
stabilization goal?
Research suggests that central
banks face a quantifiable short-run
tradeoff between the variance in
inflation and the variance in economic
activity (output and employment).
Thus, to properly and optimally
implement inflation targeting, we must
allow for some variability in inflation.
This means that inflation
would equal its targeted value only on
average. The question arises: over what
time frame should we measure that
average? A second question is: how
much variability should we allow
around the average? Of course, the
answer will depend on the time frame.
A two-year average can be targeted
more precisely than a quarterly
average. Thus, implementation is
likely to require a target range and
time horizon pair.
The particular pair the
FOMC selects must hinge on practical
considerations, such as information
lags and the underlying volatility of
economic disturbances, along with our
understanding of how the economy
works. The target range/time horizon
pair may be subject to change, but only
infrequently. For explicit targeting to
improve on our current procedure, the
target horizon and target range must
be set in a way that enhances both
credibility and performance.
The second issue relevant to
the implementation of inflation
targeting is this: The target range/time
horizon pair, to some extent, will
influence the Fed’s flexibility in
reacting to shocks. In a perfect world
of full information and complete
credibility, everyone would be able to
discern the Fed’s optimal response and
observe whether it has followed through.
But this is not a perfect world. Maintaining credibility will require adherence to
the target range/time horizon specifica-

www.phil.frb.org

tion, which could impose some constraints on flexibility. Thus, a careful
consideration of how best to set our
targets is required to carry out our dual
mandate.
Similarly, the occurrence of an
improbably large shock could make
hitting the target range technically
impossible or extremely costly. In such
cases attempting to maintain the
targeting regime may not be socially
desirable.
At times, there may be a
temptation to re-contract by changing
the components of the inflation target or
by temporarily relaxing its parameters.
But such re-contracting would erode
credibility and leave us with less
effective monetary policy than we have

We must address
the implementation
concerns before
moving to an explicit
inflation target.
achieved thus far. So I believe that
careful design is important if explicit
inflation targeting is to prove effective.
Finally, there is a third issue
surrounding the implementation of
inflation targeting by the Fed. Again, it
emanates from the Fed’s dual mandate
to achieve price stability and full
employment. This time it is the issue of
symmetry. If the Fed sets an explicit
inflation target, will the public expect
the Fed to establish explicit targets for
other economic variables as well?
From an economist’s point of
view, this kind of symmetry would not
be reasonable. Long-run inflation is
under the control of the central bank.
Potential GDP growth and the natural
rate of unemployment are not. Further,
the central bank can target only one
variable and that variable is long-run

inflation. While we believe that
reasonable price stability, by which we
mean low and stable inflation, is a
necessary condition for achieving
maximum sustainable growth and full
employment, the central bank must
take the long-run values of other
variables as given.
Nonetheless, recognizing the
Fed’s capacity to conduct countercyclical monetary policy, we might
argue that the Fed should establish
near-term targets for real growth or
unemployment. However, in the real
world of daily ups and downs, it would
be difficult, if not impossible, for the Fed
to keep such variables within some
meaningful range.
I believe that establishing
dual numerical targets would be a
mistake, even though the Fed has dual
goals. Trying to establish numerical
targets for both inflation and real
growth or unemployment would
almost surely end up undermining,
rather than reinforcing, the Fed’s
ability to achieve price stability and
conduct effective countercyclical
policy. Accordingly, if inflation targeting
were deemed likely to fuel calls for
targeting other macroeconomic
variables, I would not endorse it.
In short, I am in favor of
inflation targeting in principle.
However, I strongly believe we must
address the implementation concerns I
set forth, before moving to an explicit
inflation target.
INFLATION TARGETING VS.
PRICE PATH TARGETING
Before closing, I want to
discuss an important difference
between two explicit price stabilization
strategies currently being debated in the
academic literature: inflation targeting
and price path targeting. The two terms
are often used interchangeably in the
popular press, but the distinction
between them is important.

Business Review Q3 2003 5

Stated simply, inflation
targeting targets the rate of inflation.
Under an inflation targeting regime, if
inflation rises temporarily above
target, it must then be brought back
down. However, the price level
remains permanently above its
targeted level. Price level targeting, by
contrast, means that any deviations
from the prescribed price level path
must be offset in the future so as to
return the price level to its target
value. Thus, price level stability is
more rigid and less forgiving than
inflation targeting.
Recent research has suggested
price path targeting may achieve better
economic outcomes in an environment of zero-inflation or deflation.
Indeed, Governor Bernanke recently
suggested that the Bank of Japan adopt
a price-level target.
It has been argued that when
inflation is very close to zero and
demand is weak, price path targeting is
more effective than inflation targeting
in staving off deflation. Suppose
inflation falls below target in the
current period. Under inflation
targeting, the price of goods and
services today does not change relative
to their expected future price. But
under price path targeting, the lower
price level today makes goods and
services cheaper today relative to their
expected future price. This encourages
consumption and increases demand
today. Also, firms — knowing that prices

6 Q3 2003 Business Review

will be a lot higher later — would be less
likely to cut prices. Both effects mitigate
the dangers of deflation.
By design, price path targeting
is much more constraining than inflation
targeting. Deviations in the price level
due to external shocks of any kind must
be offset in order to achieve the target
price level at some pre-determined point

that we may consolidate the gains made
by flexible commitment and increase
the efficacy of policy even further.
Some have suggested that our
recent success in achieving price
stability speaks against implementing
inflation targeting. The U.S. economy
has been able to realize price stability
and anchor inflation expectations under

I believe the FOMC should seriously consider
inflation targeting.
in the future. The costs of doing so are
not considered. But in actuality, such a
policy regime is likely to lead to more
pressure for relaxing the parameters of
the target than an inflation targeting
regime. This alone would undermine
stability of the policy regime and in the
long run reduce its credibility. For this
reason, I cannot advocate price path
targeting for the U.S. at this time.
Nonetheless, research on price
path targeting is still in its early stages.
And we have no empirical evidence on
how effective it would be in comparison
to inflation targeting. Accordingly, I do
find this research interesting and worth
pursuing, at least at a theoretical level.
CONCLUSION
In conclusion, I believe the
FOMC should seriously consider
inflation targeting. I would like to see
work on implementation issues begin so

a policy of flexible commitment. Why
change now?
I believe we have reached a
point where institutionalizing inflation
targeting simply makes good sense
from an economic perspective. In short,
it is a reasonable next step in the
evolution of U.S. monetary policy, and it
would help secure full and lasting
benefits from our current stable price
environment. Evolving to explicit
inflation targeting from our current
implicit target has significant potential
benefits, and the costs may be minimal if
we can implement it in a constructive
manner.
Clearly, proper implementation
of inflation targeting is crucial to its
success. That, in turn, requires more
research and analysis. It also requires
more public debate and discussion. BR

www.phil.frb.org

REFERENCES
Bernanke, Ben. Remarks at the Annual
Washington Policy Conference on the
National Association of Business Economists, Washington, D.C., March 25, 2003.
Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach,
Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S. Posen.
Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the
International Experience. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1999.
Broaddus, J. Alfred. “Monetary Policy in a
Low Inflation Environment,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly (Spring 2003), pp. 1-6.
Fischer, Stanley. Opening Remarks at the
International Monetary Fund Institute’s
High-Level Seminar on Implementing
Inflation Targets. Washington, D.C., March
20-21, 2000.
Freedman, Charles. “Inflation Targeting
and the Economy: Lessons from Canada’s
First Decade,” Presented at the Western
Economic Association International’s 75th
Annual Conference, Vancouver, Canada,
June 29-July 3, 2000.

www.phil.frb.org
w w w.phil.frb.org

Goodfriend, Marvin. “Monetary Policy
Comes of Age: A 20th Century Odyssey,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly (Winter 1997),
pp. 1-22.

Mishkin, Frederic S., and Klaus SchmidtHebbel. “One Decade of Inflation
Targeting in the World: What Do We
Know and What Do We Need to Know?”
NBER Working Paper 8397, 2001.

King, Mervyn. “The Inflation Target Ten
Years On,” Remarks to the London School
of Economics, London, England, November
19, 2002.

Orphanides, Athanasios, and John C.
Williams. “Imperfect Knowledge, Inflation
Expectations, and Monetary Policy,”
Working Papers in Applied Economic
Theory 2002-04, Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco (2002).

King, Mervyn. “How Should Central Banks
Reduce Inflation? Conceptual Issues,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Economic Review (December 1996),
pp. 25-52.
Kohn, Donald L. Remarks at the National
Bureau of Economic Research Conference
on Inflation Targeting, Bal Harbour,
Florida, January 25, 2003.
Meyer, Laurence H. “Inflation Targets and
Inflation Targeting,” Remarks at the
University of California at San Diego
Economics Roundtable. San Diego,
California, July 17, 2001.

Orphanides, Athanasios. “Monetary Policy
Rules, Macroeconomic Stability and
Inflation: A View from the Trenches,”
Finance and Economics Discussion Series.
Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, Division of
Monetary Affairs (December 2001).
Siklos, Pierre L. “Inflation Target Design:
Changing Inflation Performance and
Persistence in Industrial Countries,”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
(March/April 1999), pp. 47-58.

Business
Business Review
Review Q3
Q3 2003
2003 77

Crises, Contagion, and Coordination:
A Summary of the 2002 Philadelphia Fed Policy Forum
BY LORETTA J. MESTER

John Murray, Urban Bäckstrom, Robert Parry, and Anthony Santomero

On November 22, 2002, the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
held its second annual Philadelphia
Fed Policy Forum, "Crises, Contagion,
and Coordination: Issues for
Policymakers in the Global Economy."
This event, sponsored by the Bank's
Research Department, brought
together a group of highly respected
academics, policymakers, and market
economists, for discussion and debate

Loretta Mester
is senior vice
president and
director of
research at the
Federal Reserve
Bank of
Philadelphia.
8 Q3 2003 Business Review

about issues monetary policymakers
must grapple with in our increasingly
global economy. The Policy Forum
was not intended to be a traditional
academic conference on monetary
policy, nor was it intended to be a
discussion of issues relevant to the
next FOMC meeting. Rather, we took
a longer-term perspective and tried to
engage the right people in a discussion
of current economic research and its
implications for monetary policy. Our
hope is that the 2002 Policy Forum is
a catalyst for both greater understanding of today's global economy and
more critical thinking about the role
of policymakers in that global world.
National economies are
linked through trade in goods and
services, cross-border flows of finan-

cial assets, and labor migration. Economic integration strengthens these ties.
Reduction of trade barriers, financial
innovations, and advances in communications and information flows have
increased integration. Participants at the
Policy Forum discussed a number of
issues that policymakers must confront in
our increasingly interdependent world:
the importance of institutional arrangements in maximizing the benefits of
economic and financial linkages, the
factors that foment crises and foster
contagion, the actions policymakers can
take to prevent and contain crises, and
the question of whether policy should
be coordinated (or not). We were
reminded that policymakers' actions
affect incentives: the actions a policymaker takes to ameliorate a crisis may
set up conditions that raise the likelihood
or the cost of the next crisis. We were
also reminded that while globalization
has increased the level of interrelationship among economies and markets,
financial crises and contagion are not
new: they have characterized economies
far into the past.
Anthony M. Santomero,
president of the Philadelphia Fed,
began the day by pointing out that as
economies and financial systems
around the globe have become more
closely integrated, political and
economic events abroad can have
important economic implications at
home. Policymakers must learn to
cope with the challenges faced by
globalization because it is here to stay.
Economists recognize the benefits to
national economies that globalization
offers: the promise of higher returns and
a lower variance in economic perforwww.phil.frb.org

mance than any one country could
achieve on its own, the promise of more
rapid output growth and higher living
standards via greater exploitation of
specialization and comparative advantage, and the promise of better diversification of financial risks. But at the same
time, globalization has its shortcomings:
greater potential for contagion and
spread of economic and financial
problems and reduced potency of
domestic policy.
In Santomero's view, on
balance, globalization is a strong
positive for national economies.
Policymakers can maximize the
benefits and minimize the costs of
global integration by creating infrastructures that allow markets to
function efficiently, to contain the
system in times of crisis, and to control
the impact of cyclical fluctuations.
Efficiency is fostered by having a legal
system that establishes property rights
and enforces contracts, and regulation
that provides the basis for a wellfunctioning financial system.
Policymakers should act to stabilize
cyclical fluctuations and take actions
that not only stabilize financial systems
in time of crisis but are time consistent, so that they do not create
expectations that deepen or even
precipitate a crisis tomorrow.
Santomero emphasized that the
overarching question for policymakers
as they act to strengthen markets,
avoid and contain crises, and dampen
business-cycle fluctuations is the
degree to which effective performance
requires international coordination of
activities. This issue was taken up
later in the day.
FINANCIAL CRISES1
I had the pleasure of moderating the first session, which addressed
several questions that emerged throughout the rest of the day as well. Are
crises the inevitable consequence of

www.phil.frb.org

globalization? If so, what, if anything,
can policymakers do to lower the
probability that a crisis will occur? What
can policymakers do to limit the extent
and lower the costs of a crisis once it
occurs? The session's papers underscored the importance of recognizing
that institutional arrangements can lead
to actions that exacerbate moral hazard
problems and the need to focus on
policies that are time consistent.
Indeed, the design of the institution,
including its objective function, has
important effects on feasible outcomes.
For me, the session underscored the fact that policymakers often
face a tradeoff between the short-run
benefits of their action — namely,
stemming the crisis and avoiding lost
output — versus its longer run cost that
could arise if the institution distorts the
incentives of financial markets. An
important issue is whether institutions
can be designed to give policymakers
the incentive to avoid the temptation of
going for the short-run benefits despite
their long-run cost. Another important
issue is the measurement of these costs
and benefits. In the midst of a crisis,
how can the policymaker be sure what
that tradeoff is? If intervention succeeds
in stemming a crisis, it is difficult to
measure the long-run costs implicit in
taking the action — the cost of
incentive distortion. Crisis situations are
often characterized by coordination
failures. What determines whether
such a coordinator will emerge?
V.V. Chari of the University
of Minnesota began his presentation
by reviewing some of the recent
research on financial crises. In Chari's
view, the central feature of the data on
financial crises in emerging markets is
that when a crisis hits there are substan-

Many of the presentations reviewed here are
available on our web site at www.phil.frb.org/
conf/policyforum2002.html.
1

tial swings in capital and output. When
times are good, capital flows strongly
into the country. During a crisis, capital
starts flowing out dramatically, so that
there is a sharp swing in the current
account. Similarly, output growth turns
into contraction at the time of the crisis.
One theory consistent with the
data is coordination failure among
debtors: if a debtholder fears that the
government will default on its debt if
other debtholders choose to not roll
over the country's debt, then it's
rational for the first debtholder not to
roll over the debt either. Even though
all debtholders would be better off if
they agreed to the rollover (since
default would be avoided), the fact
that they cannot coordinate leads to a
worse outcome for all.
Another theory consistent
with the data involves herd behavior.
There are a number of players that
might contemplate investing in an
emerging market, for example,
investment banks or mutual funds, and
each has its own information on which
to base its decision. If one small group
decides not to invest or withdraws its
investment, the others might be
deterred from investing too, reasoning
that the first group might have some
important, negative information. That
is, the investors move in herds, which
can result in capital flight. Note that
this can happen even if the inference
is incorrect: it could be that if the
information of all the players was
aggregated, it would show that
investing in the country is profitable.
These theories share some
common elements: there is the
possibility the government will default;
debtholders may fear they may be
expropriated; and debtholders'
property rights are insecure. Chari
draws three conclusions. (1) Crises are
here to stay, since these common
elements are inherent in the process of
emerging markets striving to become

Business Review Q3 2003 9

more developed. (2) Some mechanism
for restructuring and renegotiating
sovereign debt in the event of a default
or a threatened default, a so-called
international bankruptcy court, can
serve a useful social role, since it
reduces the possibility of expropriation
of some debtors by others. (3) Current
direct lending policies of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) that
involve lending to countries when they
are threatened with a crisis are socially
harmful because they mean debtholders don't monitor the debt as much
as they would if there were no possibility
for a bailout.
Chari explains why, in his
view, the logic for having a domestic
lender of last resort does not carry
through to the international context.
The logic for a domestic lender of last
resort depends on the inherent fragility
of the banking system: banks lend long
but borrow short. This mismatch of
maturities on their balance sheets
creates a coordination problem: if
enough depositors start to withdraw
their funds, others find it in their
interest to withdraw as well, causing
the bank to fail. If that failure is
contagious, other banks might fail, too.
The lender of last resort can stem the
systemic failures of banks that would
be healthy if they were not experiencing heavy withdrawals.
In the international context,
governments do not have to have
mismatched assets and liabilities to
carry on their functions; hence, in
Chari's view, an international lender of
last resort that would choose which
countries to bail out is not necessary.
Rather, in the event of a threatened
financial crisis, it would be important
to provide liquidity to the entire
financial system. Chari argues that the
appropriate institutions for providing this
liquidity already exist: central banks.
Moreover, the central banks have
already shown they are able to coordi-

10 Q3 2003 Business Review

nate in this fashion as evidenced by
their response during the Russian debt
default, when the central banks of the
major powers coordinated on interest
rate cuts.2
Hyun Song Shin of the
London School of Economics continued the discussion by drawing some
analogies between a seldom-described
crisis that occurred in Europe in 1763
and the LTCM crisis of 1998 for the
purpose of extracting some policy
lessons. Many commentators have
emphasized the failure of sophisticated
risk-management methods in precipitating the 1998 financial crisis, but as
Shin points out, many of the themes
are actually very old and already
present in the crisis of 1763 — namely,
liquidity risk and aggregate risk.
He used London's Millennium Bridge to illustrate the problem
of aggregate risk. On opening day,
thousands of people were walking
across the bridge to christen it when a
gust of wind started the bridge
swaying. As the people tried to
balance themselves, this caused the
bridge to sway even more, which
caused the people to rebalance
themselves, which caused more
swaying, and so on, and a bad feedback
loop was created. The bridge had to
be shut down for 18 months for
repairs. The engineers discovered that
the bridge swayed violently if people
all walked at the same cadence, and
the rebalancing mimicked this
cadence. Should the designers have
taken this into account? The odds of a
thousand random people walking in
step are extremely small, but once the

In the question-and-answer period, Charles
Goodhart of the London School of Economics
said he believes Chari overstates the extent of
possible central bank coordination to handle
crises. Goodhart, who was on the British
monetary policy committee in 1998, said that to
his knowledge, there was no policy coordination in 1998.
2

wind started, the people were not
walking at random. Their steps were
no longer random events.
The analogy to the LTCM
crisis is apparent. The hedge fund
LTCM matched a long position with a
short position in a very similar asset
and made a gain on the very slight
difference in returns. By leveraging
this many, many times, the fund could
make a high return. Other firms
copied very similar trading strategies.
When a shock hit, the funds had to
unwind leveraged positions to meet
margin calls, which moved prices
against everyone that had a very
similar trading position, which caused
more distress, which led to more
margin calls, and so on. In Shin's view,
it is incorrect to think that LTCM was
just unlucky. Far from a probability of
zero, collapse was a near certainty,
given the right conditions. When
there is aggregate risk, it is not possible
for everyone to hedge away their risk;
someone has to be holding the residual
risk.
In the 1700s, the Netherlands
was a preeminent trading nation in
Europe. It was capital rich but had
very few investment opportunities.
Prussia was an emerging market
hungry for capital. Trade was facilitated using bills of exchange, which
enabled a string of interconnected
obligations that mimicked a loan from
Amsterdam to Berlin. But these linked
the balance sheets of the merchants
and bankers involved. Everyone's
liability was exactly matched by a
claim on someone else; that is, everyone
had a perfectly hedged book. But this
meant there was substantial liquidity
risk: when a shock hit one claimant, it
affected all.
Such a shock hit in 1763 when
the Seven Years War ended, causing the
price of war goods to decline. As
collateral values fell, banks became
distressed. Merchants' asset values fell.

www.phil.frb.org

They needed to sell more of their assets
to meet their obligations, and this
caused prices to fall even more, creating
a negative feedback effect. Banks
began to fail in Amsterdam, then in
Hamburg. Because of the web of
linkages, the crisis spread to Berlin,
Stockholm, and Russia, resulting in a
massive number of bank failures. The
crisis of 1763 involved aggregate risk:
counterparty risk was correlated with
credit risk. The crisis of 1763 also
involved liquidity risk. Instead of the
usual banking story in which distress is
transmitted across banks via their
liabilities (deposit withdrawals), here
there was asset-side contagion: as asset
prices fell, other traders got into
distress.
In Shin's view, one lesson
from the crises of 1763 and LTCM is
that we need to take endogenous risk
seriously. While we need to refine our
mathematical methods and statistical
techniques to extract the most
information we can from past data, we
also have to think about how all the
interested parties are interlinked.
Relying on past data, no matter how
sophisticated the statistical methods, is
not going to capture the correct
prediction. When push comes to
shove, historic correlations break
down and credit risk and counterparty
risk will suddenly strike together. Risk
is inherent in the system as a whole, so
we need to take aggregate risk seriously: it is not possible for everyone to
hedge themselves perfectly. When the
economy itself has risk, someone has
to bear that risk somewhere; the
question then becomes, who should
bear that risk? Shin also underscored
the importance of coordination, a
theme in Chari's work and an important
difference between the LTCM crisis and
the crisis of 1763. The New York Fed
acted as a coordinator of the creditors in
the LTCM crisis. In contrast, no entity
played the role of coordinator in the

www.phil.frb.org

crisis of 1763, and there were dire
consequences.
FINANCIAL CONTAGION
AND BUSINESS-CYCLE
CORRELATION
The next session focused on
the causes of contagion and how crises
spread across regions of the world.
Franklin Allen of the Wharton
School, University of Pennsylvania,
discussed how different institutional
arrangements, in particular central
bank and financial system arrangements, can affect the probability of
contagion when financial systems are
not fully integrated. Allen pointed out
that most central banks today have a
dual mandate of price stability and
financial system stability. An exception is the European Central Bank
(ECB), whose single goal is price
stability. Financial stability is the
responsibility of the national central
banks in Europe. In Allen's view, this
arrangement poses several problems. It
precludes using monetary policy for
financial stability aims. It makes it
difficult to coordinate responses to a
problem that starts in the banks in one
European country but that could
potentially spread to other countries.
It makes it more difficult to handle
contagion, since a national central
bank may not internalize the problems
contagion causes in other countries.
Allen's paper demonstrates
the tradeoff between price stability and
financial stability. Consider a world
without contagion. Banks generally
lend long and borrow short. If asset
values fall, banks may find they have
to liquidate assets early and take firesale losses in order to meet their
obligations. A central bank can stave
off the need for costly liquidations if it
lends to the banking system. The
money injection allows banks to meet
their nominal obligations, and it also
lowers the price level. In this case,

financial stability and monetary stability
are inconsistent. An alternative way to
stem the panic is through fiscal policy:
increase taxes on individuals and give
the proceeds to the banks. In this case,
financial stability and monetary stability
are consistent.
But now consider a world
with many regions whose banking
systems are interlinked, and there is
the possibility of contagion. Interbank
markets and flexible exchange rates
allow for risks — both asset risk and
liquidity risk — to be shared across
countries. But they also allow for the
propagation of problems from one
country's banking system to others if
there is aggregate risk. If the central
bank has the right incentives, it can
correctly estimate the costs and benefits
of intervening to stem the contagion. In
Allen's view, the Euroland system does
not have those correct incentives
because: (1) the ECB, having responsibility only for price stability and not
financial stability, cannot use monetary
policy to ensure financial stability, and
(2) the national central banks will
pursue policies in their own national
interests rather than in the interests of
the whole group of nations; the costbenefit calculation for intervening will
be different from that for the whole
group, which will lead to inefficient
decision making.
Allen proposes that one way to
solve this problem is to give the ECB the
dual mandate of price stability and
financial stability. In his view, at the
present low levels of inflation that
prevail in Europe, the cost of the
inflation that would result from using
monetary policy to stem a financial crisis
would be less than the cost of a financial
crisis. He also notes that the fixed
exchange rate in Europe causes a large
part of the problem. Flexible exchange
rates would help stem contagion as long
as domestic banks' liabilities are in
domestic currency. A devaluation of

Business Review Q3 2003 11

data on stock market returns in
the 1990s to measure turmoil as
stock market returns in the tail of
the distribution. Thus, very large
decreases or declines in stock
returns that occur in countries on
the same day are evidence of
spillovers. Kaminsky's results
suggest that spillovers have
regional characteristics. There
was spillover across the countries
of Asia in 1997, but not later in
the 1990s. There was no spillover
Kenneth Rogoff
of turmoil from Asia to Europe in
1997, but in 1998, the sharp
movements in the stock markets
the currency would allow banks to meet
of Europe occurred on the same days.
their liabilities and avoid costly liquidaIn Latin America, there were spillovers
tion of assets. Fiscal intervention could
across countries in early 1999. Somealso solve the problem, but only if a
times spillovers are worldwide, as they
single tax to bail out banks is levied
were in the fall of 1998. Often, when a
across all the countries; this would entail
financial-center country, for example,
coordination problems.
the U.S. or Germany, experiences
In Allen's view, a single
turmoil, it is transmitted to the rest of
currency area, such as the Euroland,
the world. Problems occur synchrothat has separation of fiscal and
nously in many emerging markets but
monetary responsibilities has the
generally only when a shock in one of
potential problem of contagion: a small
them first influences a financial center.
shock in one place can become a big
In looking at crises over the
problem everywhere. He urged that the
past 200 years, Kaminsky noted (as
creation of an integrated financial
had Chari earlier) that crises that entail
system in the Euro area be hastened,
contagion generally are preceded by a
since that would ensure risk sharing
surge in capital flows. Once the shock
across countries and financial stability
hits, there is a sudden reversal of capital
from monetary policy or fiscal interflows, then the crisis spreads through the
vention in the same way as when there
world. Contagion does not occur when
is a single country.
there is no activity in international
If we are to devise policies
financial markets or when there is a
and institutions to try to prevent this
small amount of international lending.
type of contagion and systemic crises,
Kaminsky distinguishes crises
it is important to know the causes of
that are anticipated from those that
contagion and the channels through
are a surprise. The damage is much
which a shock in one country can spill
larger from an unanticipated crisis
over and be transmitted to others.
because there is no time for lenders to
Graciela Kaminsky of George Washrebalance their portfolios ahead of the
ington University reviewed some of her
crisis. The crises in Mexico, Thailand,
recent work in this area, examining
and Russia were not anticipated: these
spillovers that occur in a matter of days
countries' sovereign debt had not been
or hours in countries with established
downgraded by Standard and Poor's in
financial systems. Kaminsky used daily
the 12 months before the crisis, and

12 Q3 2003 Business Review

some were even upgraded. In contrast,
the crises in Brazil, Turkey, and
Argentina were anticipated: their debt
was downgraded consistently in the
months going into the crisis. This
allowed investors and creditors to
hedge some of their risk and scale back
their exposure, thereby limiting the
damage.
In Kaminsky's view, there is
no clear solution to contagion and
spillovers that happen very quickly.
One can impose controls on capital
mobility, but it is impossible to avoid
capital flight.
POLICY COORDINATION
AND MONETARY POLICY
DURING A CRISIS
Our third session concerned
policy coordination and appropriate
monetary policy in a crisis, a theme
that ran through the first two sessions.
In a world in which goods and
financial markets are becoming
increasingly interlinked, are problems
created when each country sets its own
monetary policy? Are stabilization
gains from having separate currencies
dissipated if monetary policies are not
coordinated? According to Kenneth
Rogoff of the International Monetary
Fund and Harvard University, the
answer is no. Rogoff's research suggests
that, in most cases, the gains from
monetary policy coordination are
relatively small compared with the
gains obtained if each central bank
pursues an optimal monetary policy for
macroeconomic stabilization in its
respective country. That is, typically, the
biggest gains are from getting your own
house in order. Although the gains to
international policy coordination would
not be that large among the U.S.,
Europe, and Japan, little research has
been done on the spillover effects to the
rest of the world. For example, exchange rate volatility does not have firstorder effects on these three areas, but it

www.phil.frb.org

could be significant to the rest of the
world.
Rogoff emphasized that one
cannot meaningfully discuss international monetary coordination in the
absence of the underlying fiscal policy
framework in the countries in question. Monetary policy cannot cure all
the problems caused by poor fiscal
policy, and a poor fiscal situation can
limit the effectiveness of monetary
policy. He notes that the welfare
effects of alternative policies will differ,
depending on the underlying distortions in the economy, for example,
wage rigidities or nonoptimal tax
systems. In closing, Rogoff pointed out
that the exchange of ideas among
central bankers, which one might
characterize as a type of coordination,
is valuable, since countries often face
similar economic problems and issues.
Martin Eichenbaum of
Northwestern University continued
the discussion of the links between
monetary and fiscal policy, focusing on
the fiscal implications of banking and
currency crises, the so-called twin
crises. According to the classical view,
currency crises arise when the government prints money to finance ongoing
or prospective government deficits.
These prospective government deficits
might be caused by the costs of
resolving a banking crisis, which can
be very large. For example, the
resolution costs of the Indonesian
banking crisis have been estimated at
over 60 percent of Indonesia's GDP.
Indeed, three effects can raise the costs
of resolving a banking crisis. A currency
crisis that results in a devaluation of the
country's currency raises the cost of
resolving a banking crisis by reducing
the residual value of banks, which
typically have dollar liabilities and local
currency assets and are unhedged. In
addition, twin crises are typically
followed by recessions in which tax
revenues fall, exacerbating the fiscal

www.phil.frb.org

implications of twin crises. Finally, there
is a relative price effect. When the local
currency depreciates, the dollar value of
tax receipts falls. If this drop outweighs
the drop in value of government
spending on nontradable goods, this
worsens the government's fiscal
situation.
But there are two problems
with the classical view of currency
crises. First, it implies that inflation
rates would be high after a currency
crisis, but in reality, many crises are
followed by moderate inflation rates.
Second, it emphasizes the role of
seignorage as an important source of
government finance, but in reality,
seignorage provides a limited amount
of revenue.
A key insight from
Eichenbaum is that printing money to
generate seignorage is only one of the
ways a government can pay for the
fiscal costs of a twin crisis, and the
method chosen will have implications
for the post-crisis inflation rate. This
recognition allows models of twin crises
to be reconciled with the data. In
addition to seignorage, the government
could finance a banking system bailout
by using explicit fiscal reform of raising
taxes or cutting spending; deflating the
real value of outstanding nonindexed
nominal debt; using implicit fiscal
reform of reducing the real value of
government transfer commitments (for
example, social security payments) that
aren't fully indexed to foreign
currency; defaulting on outstanding
debt; and/or receiving an international bailout.
All of the methods of
paying for the crisis, except for
explicit default or explicit fiscal
reform, require a depreciation of the
currency — the government would
need to abandon a fixed exchange
rate regime to gain access to these
revenues — and they involve some
inflation. But the exact amounts

depend on the mix of financing
strategies used. If there is a significant
depreciation of the country's currency to
pay for the crisis, the post-crisis inflation
rate need not be as high as when the
country prints money to finance the
costs of resolution. Eichenbaum
concluded with a case study of the
Korean twin crisis, showing that an
extension of the model to include
various methods of financing allows it to
fit the data. It remains for future
research to determine what leads
different countries to adopt different
financing strategies and what the
welfare implications of those alternatives
are.
Lawrence Christiano of
Northwestern University turned the
discussion to how a central bank should
manage a financial crisis, such as the
Asian crisis of 1997-98, in which the
value of the country's currency is
collapsing, there's a sharp reversal from
capital inflows to outflows, and the
domestic economy is falling into a
recession. Consider a country that is
borrowing in domestic currency to pay
for labor and in international markets for
foreign currency to purchase a foreign
intermediate input. A crisis is triggered
by collateral constraints suddenly
becoming binding: firms need to borrow
but the value of their assets does not
permit them to borrow more. What's a
central bank to do?

Martin Eichenbaum

Business Review Q3 2003 13

One view, which Christiano
characterized as the Krugman-Stiglitz
view, advocates that the central bank
cut interest rates, since the economy is
falling into a recession. The interest-rate
cut causes a reduction in the real
interest rate used to discount future
flows, so asset prices rise. If asset prices
rise enough, the collateral constraint
becomes less binding, firms can finance
more of the intermediate input, and
output can expand. An alternative
view, which Christiano characterized as
the IMF view, advocates against cutting
interest rates in order to help stem
capital flight. If the country cuts its
domestic interest rate, its currency will
depreciate and the value of a firm's
assets in foreign currency will fall;
hence, its purchases of the intermediate
input must fall. Production contracts,
and the economy may enter a recession.
Which is correct? The key is
how asset prices respond to a cut in
interest rates. Christiano's research
suggests that that depends on how open
the country's economy is, that is, how
flexible its prices and factors of production are. Any relaxation in the collateral
constraint makes it easier to bring in the
foreign input, and if it is easy to move
factors around, the foreign input can be
combined with capital and labor and
immediately be put to productive use.
This, in turn, raises asset prices and the
marginal product of capital. In this type
of flexible economy, cutting the
domestic interest rate in the face of a
crisis is the better thing to do. But if the
economy is inflexible, it cannot move its
factors of production around very much,
so the increase in the foreign input,
which occurs when the collateral
constraint is relaxed, cannot be put to
productive use, so asset prices do not
rise. In this case, cutting rates would be
counterproductive; it would intensify
the capital outflow but not raise asset
values. Christiano's latest research
suggests that in an economy in which

14 Q3 2003 Business Review

resources are inflexible in the short run
but flexible in the long run, the optimal
strategy in the face of a crisis is to raise
interest rates in the short run to stem
capital flight but to lower rates in the
long run. This appears to be what
happens in crisis economies.
POLICYMAKING IN A GLOBAL
CONTEXT
Our final session brought
together a panel of international
policymakers to discuss the practical
aspects of implementing monetary
policy in a global context. Robert
Parry, president of the Federal Reserve

Graciela Kaminsky

Bank of San Francisco, made the point
that in setting monetary policy, the
Federal Reserve's primary focus is on the
U.S. economy and its goals remain
maximum sustainable output and
employment and price stability. The
integration of goods and financial
markets has made conditions in other
countries more prominent in the Fed's
deliberations, but for the most part,
the effects on policymaking are at the
margin; globalization has not severed
the connections between monetary
policy and the U.S. economy.
In Parry's view, globalization
has not changed the goals or conduct
of U.S. monetary policy to any great
extent. This is because foreign events

rarely have a large effect on the U.S.
economy, since: (1) our economy is
large so shocks in foreign economies
matter less for us than for smaller
countries, (2) there is still a substantial
home bias in our demand for goods,
services, and assets, so changes in
foreign demand have only a small effect
on aggregate demand in the U.S., and
(3) our flexible exchange rate regime
allows us to use interest rates to conduct
monetary policy. But there have been a
few instances when U.S. monetary
policy has responded to foreign developments, for example, during the global
financial crises of the late 1990s.
Parry also made the point that
growing interdependence of national
economies makes it increasingly
important to pay attention to the actions
of foreign policymakers, and he agreed
with Rogoff that there is value in the
formal and informal meetings that
Federal Reserve staff members have
with the staffs of other central banks
around the world. Such information
exchange enables the Fed to better
forecast global economic conditions that
affect the U.S. economy. The meetings
also allow officials to get to know one
another so that if an event occurs in
which cooperation is needed, it is easier
to effect. Parry said that agreements to
coordinate monetary policy actions do
not typically occur at such meetings.
On the other hand, there is a great deal
of coordination of regulatory policy in
financial markets in recognition of the
fact that problems in one country's
financial sector can be quickly transmitted to other countries' financial systems
through debt defaults or contagion.
John Murray, adviser to the
governor of the Bank of Canada,
concurred that running independent
monetary policies across countries has
benefits. According to Murray, the
Bank of Canada has a skeptical
attitude toward policy coordination,
even though economies have become

www.phil.frb.org

more integrated and there have been a
series of crises. He agreed with Rogoff
that policy coordination may be good
in concept, but that in practice, it is
better for central bank policymakers to
focus on their own domestic objectives. This, despite that fact that in
contrast to the U.S., Canada is a small,
open economy.
Canadian monetary policy
operations are guided by three
precepts: the importance of keeping
your own house in order with respect
to price stability and full-employment
growth; the importance of transparency and credibility to eliminate
unnecessary uncertainty and doubt;
and the importance of a flexible
exchange rate, which helps insulate
the economy from external shocks. In
periods of extreme instability, international coordination may offer some
gain, but in Murray's view, good
domestic policies should help keep
these occurrences to a minimum.
Urban Bäckstrom, governor
of the Central Bank of Sweden,
endorsed Murray's statements and
went on to discuss how central bankers
can go about putting their houses in
order. He believes that central bankers
have made much progress in focusing on
price stability and increasing transparency and that their next major issue will
be financial stability. What can
policymakers do to mitigate financial
cycles? As Bäckstrom explained it,
financial cycles would seem to evolve
from excessive optimism: credit
expansion feeds into asset prices,
lowering the cost of capital, which
stimulates investment and leads to an
economic boom. Eventually, the

www.phil.frb.org

investments are found not to be
sustainable, since they do not generate
profits, and the structure collapses. The
economy moves from boom to bust, and
there may be banking and/or currency
crises.
Bäckstrom said two conventional pieces of policy advice for central
bankers in preventing financial cycles
are moral suasion and prudential
regulation. Central bank policymakers
might warn market participants they are
becoming overly optimistic in their
expectations about future cash flows.
While such moral suasion may be worth
a try, Bäckstrom is skeptical that a
market can be talked down when it is
rushing to new heights. There are also
problems with prudential regulation. In
Bäckstrom's view, most financial crises
stem not from individual banks' getting
into difficulties and affecting others by
contagion but from many institutions'
acting similarly. Also, prudential
regulation is based on perceptions of
risk, which are not independent of the
credit and asset-price cycle itself.
Apparent risk declines as collateral
values rise during the upturn in the
cycle, even though actual risk builds
up as the expansion and leverage
continues. Bank supervisors are aware
of this problem and are trying to
address it, but for Bäckstrom, whether
improved prudential regulation,
supervisory practices, and riskmanagement techniques will be
enough to avoid financial cycles in the
future is an open question.
Bäckstrom would like
researchers to explore the possible use
of monetary policy in preventing large
financial cycles, noting that price

stability is not, by itself, sufficient to
ensure financial stability. There is little
to prevent the emergence of cycles in
the prices of real and financial assets
that are not included in the measure of
inflation. He acknowledged that there
are arguments against a central bank's
trying to respond to changes in asset
prices that do not lead to inflation in the
prices of goods and services (for
example, how does the central bank
know that a bubble is a bubble and not a
reflection of fundamentals?) and that a
central bank should not target asset
prices per se. But he proposed that the
central bank be observant when notable
increases in assets prices are one of
several imbalances building up in the
economy, even when inflation is
contained. Bäckstrom said he considers the use of monetary policy in trying
to prevent financial cycles to be
consistent with the central bank's
mandate to achieve long-run price
stability.
SUMMARY
The 2002 Policy Forum
generated lively discussion among the
program speakers and audience
participants on a number of issues that
policymakers must confront in this
increasingly interdependent world.
Our hope is that the ideas raised will
spur further research and foster a
greater understanding of today's global
economy.
We will hold our third annual
Philadelphia Fed Policy Forum,
"Managing the Recovery in Uncertain
Times," on November 14, 2003. You
will find the agenda on page 17. BR

Business Review Q3 2003 15

Changes in the Use of Electronic Means of Payment: 1995-2004
Loretta J. Mester
April 14, 2006
In “The Changing Nature of the Payments System: Should New Players Mean New Rules?”
(Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, March/April 2000), I presented some data from
the 1995 Federal Reserve Survey of Consumer Finances on the use of electronic banking. This survey of
more than 4,000 households, which is designed to be representative of all households in the U.S., is
redone every three years. Attached are updates of the statistics indicating how the usages of various
means of electronic payment have changed between 1995 and 2004.
As seen in Exhibit 1, usage of electronic forms of payment, including ATMs, debit cards,
automatic bill paying, and smart cards, has risen from about 78 percent of households in 1995 to about 90
percent of households in 2004. Debit card use, which doubled between 1995 and 1998, continued to
increase rapidly and now stands at nearly 60 percent of all households. Increases were seen in all
categories by age, income, and education. Use of direct deposit and automatic bill paying showed
somewhat smaller increases, with the percentage of households now using automatic bill paying over
double what it was in 1995. Nearly 75 percent of households have an ATM card. The question on smart
cards was dropped from the survey in 2004; usage remained low in 2001, with less than 3 percent of
households having a smart card they could use for purchases. There was a small increase in the
percentage of households that use some type of computer software to manage their money: from 18
percent in 2001 (the first year this question was asked) to about 19 percent in 2004. Respondents under
60 years old, those with higher income, and those with college degrees are more likely to use a computer
for money management.
As seen in Exhibit 2, households that do business with at least one financial institution have
continued to shift from paper-based methods of conducting this business to automated methods. A
sizable fraction of households, over 75 percent, still report that one of the main ways they deal with at
least one of their financial institutions is in person; this percentage held steady between 2001 and 2004
but is down from 1995. Overall use of electronic means of doing business – either ATM, phone, fax,
direct deposit and payment, other electronic transfer, and/or computer – continued to increase between
2001 and 2004, but not as sharply as the sizable rise seen between 1995 and 1998. In 2004, 89 percent of
households used an electronic method as one of their main ways of conducting business, and differences
by income and education have become less pronounced. There remains, however, a large difference in
the popularity of ATMs across age groups: over 79 percent of those under 30 years old use ATMs as one
of their main ways of conducting business, while less than 40 percent of those over 60 years old use them.
Still, the usage by those over 60 has more than doubled since 1995.
The largest increase was seen in the percentage of households that use a computer, the Internet, or
an online service to do business. In 2004, over 33 percent of households used these methods, up from
less than 4 percent in 1995. Youth, high income, and a college degree continue to be associated with a
higher incidence of computer banking, but the computer remains a less popular means of doing business
with financial institutions compared with other methods.

Loretta J. Mester
April 14, 2006

Exhibit 1, Part 1
Percent of U.S. Households That Use Each Instrument: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004a
ATMb

Smart Cardb

Debit Card

1995

1998

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

62.5%

67.4%

69.8%

74.4%

17.6%

33.8%

47.0%

59.3%

1.2%

1.9%

2.9%

Under 30 years old

72.3%

75.6%

78.1%

83.0%

24.4%

45.0%

60.6%

74.4%

1.8%

2.6%

2.6%

Between 30 and 60 years old

68.6%

76.1%

76.8%

82.3%

19.7%

38.6%

53.4%

67.6%

1.5%

2.3%

3.3%

Over 60 years old

44.2%

41.9%

48.9%

51.6%

9.6%

16.0%

24.6%

32.5%

0.3%

0.5%

2.1%

Low income

38.5%

45.9%

46.8%

53.0%

7.0%

19.7%

29.2%

41.2%

0.7%

1.5%

1.9%

Moderate income

61.5%

64.4%

67.4%

73.4%

16.0%

31.6%

46.3%

57.4%

0.6%

3.1%

3.0%

Middle income

70.9%

72.0%

75.2%

78.3%

20.5%

36.6%

50.0%

64.3%

1.3%

2.0%

2.4%

Upper income

77.2%

82.3%

83.7%

86.5%

25.1%

43.8%

57.8%

69.3%

1.8%

1.7%

3.7%

No college degree

54.7%

60.1%

63.7%

67.4%

14.3%

29.2%

42.3%

54.9%

0.8%

1.8%

2.4%

College degree

80.4%

82.1%

81.6%

86.4%

25.2%

43.1%

56.2%

67.0%

2.1%

2.0%

3.8%

All Households

1995

1998

2001

By Age:

By Incomec:

By Education

a

The percentages reported are based on the population-weighted figures using the revised Kennickell-Woodburn consistent weights for each year. (For further discussion see the Survey of
Consumer Finances codebooks at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/oss/oss2/scfindex.html.) This exhibit reports percentages for all households.
b
The questions on ATMs and smart cards asked whether any member of the household had an ATM card or a smart card, not whether the member used it. The other questions asked about
usage. The question on smart cards was dropped from the 2004 survey.
c
Low income is defined as less than 50 percent of the median household income; moderate income is 50 to 80 percent of the median; middle income is 80 to 120 percent of the median; and
upper income is greater than 120 percent of the median. Each survey refers to income in the previous year. Median income was $32,264 in 1994; $37,005 in 1997; $41,990 in
2000; and $43,318 in 2003.
Source: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances data as of March 31, 2006, Federal Reserve System, and author’s calculations.

Loretta J. Mester
April 14, 2006

Exhibit 1, Part 2
Percent of U.S. Households That Use Each Instrument: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004a
Direct Deposit

Automatic Bill Paying

Software

b

Any of the Methods:
ATM, Debit Card, Smart Card,
Direct Deposit, Automatic Bill
Paying, or Software

1995

1998

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

46.7%

60.5%

67.3%

71.2%

21.8%

36.0%

40.3%

47.4%

18.0%

19.3%

77.7%

85.5%

88.4%

90.4%

Under 30 years old

31.0%

45.2%

48.8%

54.0%

17.7%

30.5%

32.1%

36.5%

17.0%

20.4%

76.3%

80.2%

83.0%

87.3%

Between 30 and 60 years old

42.8%

58.0%

64.8%

68.2%

24.4%

38.6%

44.1%

50.3%

22.0%

21.9%

78.7%

87.5%

89.3%

90.3%

Over 60 years old

63.3%

74.8%

83.2%

87.0%

18.2%

33.0%

35.9%

46.5%

9.0%

12.8%

76.1%

83.7%

89.2%

91.9%

Low income

32.5%

44.3%

51.9%

54.8%

9.7%

17.1%

18.2%

24.6%

6.1%

6.8%

56.7%

69.3%

73.6%

77.4%

Moderate income

42.9%

58.8%

63.1%

64.0%

17.5%

30.5%

35.1%

40.5%

10.7%

11.1%

78.4%

87.2%

88.5%

88.6%

Middle income

48.3%

66.1%

65.7%

73.2%

23.4%

42.8%

45.1%

52.8%

16.3%

17.8%

85.1%

89.4%

92.3%

95.1%

Upper income

58.3%

70.4%

80.2%

83.6%

32.1%

49.3%

55.2%

62.4%

29.9%

31.4%

89.6%

94.9%

96.5%

97.1%

No college degree

40.3%

54.4%

61.8%

64.3%

18.1%

30.2%

33.7%

39.5%

10.9%

12.4%

71.4%

80.7%

84.7%

86.2%

College degree

61.0%

72.6%

78.0%

83.2%

30.1%

47.7%

53.2%

61.1%

31.8%

31.3%

91.8%

95.1%

95.6%

97.5%

All Households
By Age:

By Incomec:

By Education

a

The percentages reported are based on the population-weighted figures using the revised Kennickell-Woodburn consistent weights for each year. (For further discussion see the Survey of
Consumer Finances codebooks at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/oss/oss2/scfindex.html.)
b
The question on software asked whether the respondent or spouse/partner uses any type of computer software to help in managing their money.
c
Low income is defined as less than 50 percent of the median household income; moderate income is 50 to 80 percent of the median; middle income is 80 to 120 percent of the median; and
upper income is greater than 120 percent of the median. Each survey refers to income in the previous year. Median income was $32,264 in 1994; $37,005 in 1997; $41,990 in
2000; and $43,318 in 2003.
Source: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances data as of March 31, 2006, Federal Reserve System, and author’s calculations.

Loretta J. Mester
April 14, 2006

Exhibit 2, Part 1
Percent of U.S. Households with at Least One Financial Institution Using Each Method
Among the Main Ways of Conducting Business with at Least One of Their Financial Institutionsa
In Person

Mail

ATM

1995

1998

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

85.5%

79.5%

77.2%

77.3%

56.5%

54.1%

50.4%

50.2%

33.8%

52.6%

56.7%

64.4%

Under 30 years old

77.0%

73.7%

71.5%

72.9%

58.2%

51.9%

50.5%

44.2%

53.0%

68.8%

72.6%

79.3%

Between 30 and 60 years old

86.8%

81.8%

78.6%

77.3%

62.1%

60.4%

56.6%

56.3%

37.7%

61.5%

65.0%

72.0%

Over 60 years old

86.7%

77.2%

76.8%

79.5%

44.0%

39.9%

36.0%

39.1%

16.2%

22.3%

29.8%

39.8%

Low income

81.2%

70.3%

68.2%

71.2%

32.8%

33.4%

24.7%

28.9%

19.6%

34.7%

35.6%

46.6%

Moderate income

85.9%

80.4%

76.9%

75.0%

48.5%

46.9%

42.0%

42.6%

29.6%

47.8%

50.5%

62.3%

Middle income

85.7%

81.4%

78.6%

77.7%

56.9%

56.4%

58.4%

56.0%

37.7%

54.1%

60.7%

65.7%

Upper income

87.7%

84.1%

81.8%

81.4%

74.3%

69.1%

64.9%

62.4%

42.3%

65.2%

69.6%

74.4%

No college degree

85.8%

79.2%

75.1%

76.9%

49.4%

48.2%

43.5%

44.1%

27.4%

45.1%

50.1%

59.1%

College degree

84.8%

80.2%

81.1%

78.0%

71.2%

65.2%

63.0%

60.1%

46.7%

66.7%

68.8%

72.9%

All Households
By Age:

By Incomeb

By Education

a

The percentages reported are based on the population-weighted figures using the revised Kennickell-Woodburn consistent weights for each year. (For further discussion see the Survey of
Consumer Finances codebooks at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/oss/oss2/scfindex.html.) Referring to each financial institution with which the household does business, the survey
asked: “How do you mainly do business with this institution?” Respondents could list multiple methods, with the main method listed first. This exhibit reports for all households
with at least one financial institution all the methods a respondent listed for each of the household’s financial institutions. Note, the percentages do not add up to 100 percent
across columns, since households could list more than one method and more than one financial institution. Previous versions of this chart reported for 1998 and 2001 on the main
ways respondents did business with their depository financial institutions (i.e., commercial banks, trust companies, thrifts, and credit unions) rather than with any of their financial
institutions.
b
Low income is defined as less than 50 percent of the median household income; moderate income is 50 to 80 percent of the median; middle income is 80 to 120 percent of the median; and
upper income is greater than 120 percent of the median. Each survey refers to income in the previous year. Median income was $32,264 in 1994; $37,005 in 1997; $41,990 in
2000; and $43,318 in 2003.
Source: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances data as of March 31, 2006, Federal Reserve System, and author’s calculations.

Loretta J. Mester
April 14, 2006

Exhibit 2, Part 2
Percent of U.S. Households with at Least One Financial Institution Using Each Method
Among the Main Ways of Conducting Business with at Least One of Their Financial Institutionsa
Phone

Electronicb

Computer

1995

1998

2001

2004

2001

2004

1995

1998

2001

2004

25.7%

49.7%

48.9%

48.8%

3.7%

6.2%

19.6%

33.6%

56.2%

81.7%

87.0%

89.2%

Under 30 years old

20.8%

45.4%

45.9%

43.2%

5.2%

8.3%

22.9%

42.2%

66.7%

81.0%

85.2%

89.2%

Between 30 and 60 years old

28.1%

54.3%

52.4%

51.4%

4.5%

7.6%

24.2%

39.8%

59.9%

85.1%

89.4%

90.9%

Over 60 years old

23.0%

40.6%

42.4%

45.7%

1.2%

1.6%

7.3%

15.4%

43.4%

73.9%

82.4%

85.4%

Low income

13.5%

28.8%

29.2%

30.0%

1.3%

1.5%

4.8%

14.0%

35.3%

65.4%

73.8%

78.7%

Moderate income

18.6%

42.5%

42.8%

44.8%

1.8%

2.7%

11.2%

22.5%

48.5%

80.1%

84.2%

84.8%

Middle income

22.6%

51.7%

51.7%

50.7%

4.0%

4.3%

17.8%

32.4%

59.2%

85.2%

89.7%

92.1%

Upper income

37.9%

64.9%

61.4%

60.0%

5.9%

11.5%

32.5%

49.4%

70.8%

91.0%

94.5%

95.6%

No college degree

19.7%

41.9%

41.7%

43.4%

2.8%

2.7%

11.3%

23.9%

47.8%

76.5%

83.2%

85.7%

College degree

38.1%

64.3%

61.9%

57.7%

5.6%

12.8%

34.8%

49.3%

73.5%

91.4%

94.0%

94.9%

All Households

1995

1998

By Age:

By Incomec:

By Education

a

The percentages reported are based on the population-weighted figures using the revised Kennickell-Woodburn consistent weights for each year. (For further discussion see the Survey
of Consumer Finances codebooks at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/oss/oss2/scfindex.html.) Referring to each financial institution with which the household does business, the
survey asked: “How do you mainly do business with this institution?” Respondents could list multiple methods, with the main method listed first. This exhibit reports for all
households with at least one financial institution all the methods a respondent listed for each of the household’s financial institutions. Note, the percentages do not add up to
100 percent across columns, since households could list more than one method and more than one financial institution. Previous versions of this chart reported for 1998 and
2001 on the main ways respondents did business with their depository financial institutions (i.e., commercial banks, trust companies, thrifts, and credit unions) rather than with
any of their financial institutions.
b
In 1995, electronic refers to ATM, phone, payroll deduction and direct deposit, electronic transfer, or computer. In 1998, 2001, and 2004, electronic refers to ATM, phone (via voice or
touchtone), direct deposit, direct withdrawal/payment, other electronic transfer, computer/Internet/online service, or fax machine.
c
Low income is defined as less than 50 percent of the median household income; moderate income is 50 to 80 percent of the median; middle income is 80 to 120 percent of the median; and
upper income is greater than 120 percent of the median. Each survey refers to income in the previous year. Median income was $32,264 in 1994; $37,005 in 1997; $41,990 in
2000; and $43,318 in 2003.
Source: 1995, 1998, 2001, and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances data as of March 31, 2006, Federal Reserve System, and author’s calculations.

Trade Credit:
Why Do Production Firms Act as Financial Intermediaries?
BY MITCHELL BERLIN

T

rade credit remains the single largest source
of short-term business credit in the United
States and other nations around the world.
Why do production firms act as financial
intermediaries—a role usually reserved for banks?
Mitchell Berlin focuses on explanations that view trade
credit as a method of monitoring and enforcing loan
contracts to relatively risky firms. He also examines
explanations in which a firm’s long-term supply
relationship helps it to make better credit decisions
than a bank would.

The United States has the
most highly developed financial
markets in the world. Yet, trade credit
— credit granted by a selling firm to
finance another firm’s purchase of the
seller’s goods — remains the single
largest source of short-term business
credit. Despite its importance as a
mechanism for financing inter-firm
trade, trade credit receives less attention in the business press than developments in bank lending markets or
corporate debt markets. But the key
role of trade credit asserts itself whenever a well-known firm suffers severe

financial problems. When a firm’s
suppliers begin to demand cash on
delivery, the business press begins to
speculate on whether the firm is headed
for bankruptcy.
The numbers attest that trade
credit plays a large role in firms’ finance.
One way to measure this is to look at
firms as borrowers. Mitchell Petersen
and Raghuram Rajan’s 1997 article
shows that accounts payable — funds
owed by the firms in their sample to
trade creditors — average 4.4 percent of
sales for a sample of small U.S. firms and
11.6 percent of sales for a sample of large
U.S. firms.1 Another way to measure
The small firm sample is from the Fed’s
National Survey of Small Business Finance,
conducted in 1988-1990, while the large firm
sample is from Compustat. The median firm
in the small business survey has sales of
$300,000. Although Petersen and Rajan don’t
report which vintage of the Compustat database they use, the median sales figure for
all Compustat firms in 1989 was just over
$52 million.
1

Mitchell Berlin is
an economist and
research officer in
the Research
Department of the
Philadelphia Fed.

www.phil.frb.org

this is to look at firms as lenders, that is,
to look at accounts receivable — funds
owed to the firms in the sample by their
customers. Accounts receivable
represent nearly 7.3 percent of sales for
small firms and 18.5 percent of sales for
large firms.2
Firms in most other industrialized nations are comparably reliant on
trade credit. Raghuram Rajan and Luigi
Zingales report that in the G-7 nations,3
accounts payable of a sample of large
firms range from 17 percent of assets in
France to 11.5 percent of assets in
Germany — compared with 15 percent
of assets for U.S. firms.4 Accounts
receivable range from 13.0 percent of
assets in Canada to 29 percent of assets
in France and Italy — compared with
17.8 percent in the U.S.5 Data from the
less developed world suggest that trade
credit may be even more important for
such nations.
Remarkably, until Petersen and
Rajan’s empirical work in the 1990s,
economists could offer only sketchy,
As Petersen and Rajan note in their 1997
article, trade credit is not a source of net
credit for firms, since receivables exceed
payables. The difference is the amount of
receivables financed by other sources, e.g.,
bank loans.
2

The Group of Seven (G-7) nations are
Canada, France, Germany, Great Britain,
Italy, Japan, and the United States.
Established in 1985, this organization fosters
economic cooperation among the largest
industrial nations.
3

The remaining nations are Japan (15.4
percent), Italy (14.7 percent), the U.K. (13.7
percent), and Canada (13.3 percent).
4

The remaining nations are Japan (22.5
percent), Germany (26.9 percent), and the
U.K. (22.1 percent).
5

Business Review Q3 2003 21

anecdotal answers to the most elementary questions about trade credit: Who
offers trade credit? Who takes trade
credit? While their work made a giant
step forward, getting some of the facts
straight is only the first, necessary step in
answering a basic question that occurs
to any economist who thinks about
trade credit: Why should a firm that
specializes in production or sales act as a
financial intermediary when specialized
intermediaries like banks can (and do)
provide working capital finance? Most
puzzling, why should a firm borrow short
term from a bank, then provide shortterm credit to its customers? Why not
cut out the middleman? 6
While financial economists
have proposed a number of explanations,
I focus on those explanations that view
trade credit as a method of monitoring
and enforcing loan contracts to
relatively risky firms. I also examine the
explanations that hinge on the benefits
of long-term supply relationships as an
underpinning for flexible and differentiated credit decisions.
HOW TRADE CREDIT WORKS
Consider Stocking Out, a
fast-growing retail hosiery emporium
with six outlets in the Philadelphia
suburbs, and one of its major input
suppliers Run/Don’t Run (R/DR), a
manufacturer of top-of-the-line athletic
socks. R/DR makes a large monthly
delivery of socks, and it may take
anywhere from a few hours to a few
weeks to sell the socks once they are on
the shelves. Until the socks are sold,
Stocking Out counts them as inventory
on its books. How might Stocking Out
pay for the unsold goods until the

Rajan and Petersen are not, of course, the
first economists to examine trade credit
empirically. Notable early contributions that
explicitly view bank loans and trade credit as
substitutes include Alan Meltzer’s article
and Dwight Jaffee’s book.

revenues from selling them arrive? The
main possibilities are illustrated in the
figure.
Banks Offer Working
Capital Loans. One possibility is
that Stocking Out takes out a working
capital loan — a loan to finance
inventories — from a bank and pays
R/DR directly. The most typical

Stocking Out could still borrow up to
$400,000, the unused balance of the
loan commitment.
Unlike credit card agreements,
loan commitments must be renewed or
renegotiated at fixed intervals. For
example, a common arrangement for
risky borrowers is a loan commitment
with a one-year maturity, and in many

Why should a firm borrow short term from
a bank, then provide short-term credit to
its customers?
arrangement is a revolving loan
commitment, in which the bank sets a
credit limit and the firm draws down
and repays loans at prearranged terms,
much like a credit card. For example,
the loan commitment might stipulate a
credit limit of $500,000 and a loan rate
of prime plus 2 — that is, the prevailing
prime rate plus 2 percent — when the
borrower draws down $100,000 for three
months. Until this loan is repaid,

cases, the inventories purchased with
the bank loan serve as collateral for the
borrowings. The most notable feature of
a loan commitment is its flexibility; the
borrower has substantial discretion over
the amount it borrows, the maturity of
its borrowings, and how to use the funds
it borrows.
Supplier Trade Credit Is
Expensive If Not Repaid Quickly. A
second possibility is that R/DR provides

FIGURE
Direct Bank Finance vs. Indirect Bank
Finance of Trade Credit

Bank

Loan Commitment to
Stocking Out

Loan Commitment
to R/DR

Stocking
Out

Trade Credit

6

22 Q3 2003 Business Review

R/DR

www.phil.frb.org

trade credit to Stocking Out. On
R/DR’s balance sheet, the dollars owed
by Stocking Out are an asset called
accounts receivable, while the trade
credit appears on Stocking Out’s
balance sheet as a liability called
accounts payable. Trade credit comes
in a wide variety of terms, but there are
two broad types of agreements.7
Under a net contract, Stocking
Out promises to repay R/DR after a
fixed period of time; 30 days is the most
common maturity, according to Chee
Ng, Janet Smith, and Richard Smith’s
survey results. This contract would be
described as “net 30.” Although the
price Stocking Out pays for the goods
will clearly be affected by R/DR’s cost of
providing credit to its customer, the net
contract doesn’t include an explicit loan
rate.
Alternatively, Stocking Out
and R/DR may use a more complicated
two-part contract, in which Stocking
Out receives a discount for paying
within a fixed period, but then must pay
the full price for the remaining term of
the contract. For example, if the terms
of the trade credit are “2/10 net 30” —
the most common two-part contract in
Ng, Smith, and Smith’s survey —
Stocking Out receives a 2 percent
discount if it pays within 10 days of
delivery (the discount period) but pays
full price between days 11 and 30 (the
net period).
This sounds like a good deal
for Stocking Out, and it is if the credit is
repaid within the first 10 days. But this is
a very expensive form of borrowing if the
firm takes longer than 10 days to repay.

The implicit annual interest rate for
such borrowings is nearly 45 percent. To
see this, think about Stocking Out’s cost
of missing its payment on the 10th day
and paying 20 days later. It has effectively chosen to pay 2 percent for 20
days. Thought about differently, if
Stocking Out had paid on the 10th day,
it could have invested the 2 percent
discount on the pricing of goods for 20
days.8 For the sake of comparison, the
annualized interest rate on my credit
card is 16.25 percent if I don’t pay off
the loan balance before the 15th of the
month. We might also make a comparison with the rate on a bank loan to a
firm without broad access to financial
markets. At a time when the prime rate
was 4.25 percent, a collateralized loan
with a face value of less than $100,000
carried a loan rate of 5.35 percent per
year.9
Thus, trade credit is expensive
compared with a bank loan for any
borrower who doesn’t pay within the
discount period. Not surprisingly, the
evidence indicates that firms strongly
prefer to borrow from a bank if bank
credit is available. For example, in their
1997 article, Mitchell Petersen and
Raghuram Rajan show that firms with
unused bank credit lines have significantly lower accounts payable — that is,
they use less trade credit. Also, firms
with long-term relationships with a bank
use less trade credit.
Suppliers Are Financial
Intermediaries. How does R/DR
finance its provision of credit to

The formula for the annual interest rate is
[1/(1-discount rate)](days in the year/days borrowed) -1 =
(1.02) (365/20) -1.
7

www.phil.frb.org

See Loretta Mester, Leonard Nakamura,
and Micheline Renault’s paper for an account
of banks’ comparative advantage in providing
financing for accounts receivable.
10

See Aubhik Khan’s article for a summary of
the evidence from the manufacturing sector
that a firm’s probability of survival increases
with age and size.

11

Bank financing is not the sole external
funding source through which R/DR might
finance this credit. Large firms also bypass
the banking system altogether by selling
securities backed by the cash flows from their
receivables; that is, they also act as
intermediaries between financial markets and
the firms to which they grant trade credit.
In some industries, providers of trade credit
also sell their receivables at a discount to
firms known as factors, which specialize in
enforcing repayment. See Shehzad Mian and
Clifford Smith’s article about the variety of
institutions involved in financing trade
credit.

12

8

Ng, Smith, and Smith’s article documents
the wide variety of trade credit terms.
Interestingly, their survey data indicate that
trade credit terms are much more standardized within industry groups than across
industry groups. However, they don’t make
much progress in explaining cross-industry
variation in contract terms.

Stocking Out? To a significant extent,
R/DR’s bank actually finances this
credit.10
Petersen and Rajan report that
larger and older firms typically have
larger accounts receivable; that is, they
are large suppliers of trade credit. It is
reasonable to view a firm’s age and size
as indicators of its creditworthiness.11
One interpretation of Petersen and
Rajan’s results is that larger and older
firms have easier access to external
finance; they, in turn, act as intermediaries and extend trade credit to other,
riskier firms. An even more explicit link
between R/DR’s access to bank credit
and its provision of trade credit is
Petersen and Rajan’s finding that firms
with larger credit lines also have larger
accounts receivable. In particular, firms
that have drawn down a larger share of
their credit lines have even larger
accounts receivable, consistent with the
view that creditworthy firms effectively
finance their provision of trade credit
with bank loans. 12
Jeffrey Nilsen’s article examines different firms’ use of trade credit
during periods of monetary contraction,

Survey of Terms of Business Lending, March
20, 2003. A small “prime plus” loan is a
relevant basis for comparison because firms
that borrow above prime don’t have access to
broader financial markets and view a
commercial bank as their cheapest source of
funds.
9

Business Review Q3 2003 23

when banks become stingy and bond
markets dry up for all but the most
creditworthy firms. William Lang and
Leonard Nakamura’s article shows that
monetary tightness leads to a “flight to
quality,” in which banks reduce their
lending to risky firms. Nilsen demonstrates that in such tight conditions,
trade credit usage increases for small
firms but not for large firms that have
credit ratings from agencies such as
Moody’s — firms that have the greatest
access to bank loans and other sources
of outside finance. Firms with access to
outside sources of funds continue to tap
these sources when credit is tight; they,
in turn, provide credit to firms unable to
borrow from a bank or sell bonds. That
is, firms’ role as intermediaries increases
during tight financial conditions.
But this account raises a
serious question: Why not cut out the
middleman? Think about R/DR’s bank.
As a specialist in collecting funds from
savers, the bank almost certainly has a
lower cost of funds than the sock
manufacturer. Also, banks are specialists
in evaluating borrowers’ credit risk.
Why doesn’t the bank simply use its
funding advantage to lend directly to
Stocking Out?
TRADE CREDIT IMPROVES
MONITORING AND
ENFORCEMENT
In normal times, R/DR’s
managers don’t lose much sleep over the
possibility that Stocking Out will not pay
for socks already delivered. But many
contracts and institutions are best
understood if we think about how well
they deal with the stresses and strains of
abnormal times. During the last year,
Sam’s Socks, which offers an entire line
of hosiery and socks at discount prices,
has placed an outlet within a mile of
each of Stocking Out’s locations. The
Philadelphia economy has entered a
downturn as the Christmas season
approaches, and the combination of

24 Q3 2003 Business Review

hard economic times and bare-knuckles
competition has shrunk Stocking Out’s
revenues to the point where it is having
difficulties meeting its payroll.
It’s Hard to Control How a
Borrower Uses Money. Assume first
that Stocking Out has signed a loan
commitment with a bank. The
flexibility of a loan commitment is one of
its main attractions to the borrower.
Although the firm must establish that it

buy lots of festive socks in the Philadelphia region this Christmas.
Of course, it is the bank’s
business to attempt to foresee situations
like these when the initial commitment
is signed and to design the commitment
accordingly. Had Stocking Out and its
banker foreseen Sam’s take-no-prisoners
business plan before the loan commitment was negotiated, the loan commitment would have been smaller, its

Itís hard to control how a borrower uses
money...Diverting goods is harder than
diverting money.
is creditworthy when the loan commitment is signed — and the loan contract
usually contains covenants that require
the firm to maintain evidence of
financial stability to stay in compliance
— the firm has a lot of discretion about
how to use the borrowed funds. It can
respond quickly and efficiently to
opportunities that require funds as they
arise.
In normal times, this flexibility
is beneficial to the firm and to the bank
— notably because the firm is willing to
pay for it through the commitment fee
and the loan rate. But under mounting
financial pressure, Stocking Out might
be tempted to exploit this flexibility to
avoid cost cutting that may be necessary
for the firm to cover its debts. For
example, Stocking Out might be
tempted to draw down the unused
balance of its loan commitment to cover
payroll costs when it should be laying off
workers and shutting its worst performing stores.
This illustrates a problem
stressed by Mike Burkart and Tore
Ellingsen in their discussion paper. Cash
is relatively easy to divert from its
intended purpose. 13 Stocking Out’s
bank may find itself with an uncollectible loan unless lots of mothers-in-law

covenants would have been tighter, and
it would have had a shorter maturity.
All of these would have limited
Stocking Out’s discretion to misuse
funds. But the bank can’t foresee every
contingency. And if the bank had
foreseen Stocking Out’s troubles, it
might simply have decided that the risks
were too large to make a loan at all.
Diverting Goods Is Harder
Than Diverting Money. Now assume
that, in place of signing a bank loan
commitment, Stocking Out finances its
purchases from R/DR using trade credit
provided at 2/10 net 30. Instead of
lending money, R/DR provides credit in
the form of goods, which are harder to
divert than money, according to Burkart
and Ellingsen. For example, most
employees would refuse to accept
hosiery in place of a paycheck, so
Stocking Out could not use trade credit
to meet payroll costs, and its ability to
keep unprofitable stores operating is
more limited than it would be with a
loan commitment.

The problem of diversion of funds is more
pervasive than this extreme example suggests.
Diversion can refer to any use of funds that
would reduce a lender’s expected repayments.
13

www.phil.frb.org

Stocking Out may actually
increase its access to credit by borrowing
from its supplier rather than its bank,
because borrowing goods instead of
money permits the firm to make a
credible commitment not to divert the
loan for unprofitable purposes. So, trade
credit may be the lowest cost way for
Stocking Out to borrow, even though its
bank has a lower cost of funds than
R/DR. If a firm’s temptation to divert
funds for unprofitable purposes is
greatest when it faces financial difficulties, Burkart and Ellingsen’s model may
help explain the empirical evidence that
less creditworthy firms rely on trade
credit and that trade credit usage
increases when economic conditions are

difficult and financial markets are
tight.14
The structure of the two-part
contract may also facilitate monitoring.
The sharp rise in the cost of borrowing at
10 days acts as a tripwire: R/DR will
notice immediately if payment isn’t
made by the 10th day, especially if
Stocking Out seldom borrows into the
net period. This view finds support in
suppliers’ responses to a survey conducted by Ng, Smith, and Smith. They

report that one-half of the respondents
from firms that offer two-part trade
credit view payments beyond the
discount period as a sign of financial
difficulty.15
I’ve been comparing a
standard bank lending arrangement to
supplier-provided trade credit. See Why
Can’t a Bank Duplicate Supplier-Provided
Trade Credit? for a discussion of why the

The usefulness of payment beyond the
discount period as a tripwire assumes that
firms do not routinely make payments beyond
the discount period. Petersen and Rajan’s
1994 article shows that, in most industries, a
significant majority of firms take advantage of
the early payment discounts over 90 percent
of the time.
15

In Burkart and Ellingsen’s model, firms can
also borrow using a mixture of bank loans and
trade credit when potential diversion
problems are moderate.
14

WHY CAN’T A BANK DUPLICATE SUPPLIER-PROVIDED TRADE CREDIT?
Consider the following
imaginary “bank loan.” The bank
gives Stocking Out a check written
out to R/DR, and the retailer must
repay the bank the face value of the
check within 30 days. If Stocking
Out pays back the bank within 10
days, it receives a 2 percent discount
on the amount of the loan.
Note, this arrangement is
essentially identical to the 2/10 net
30 credit described in the text,
except that the bank provides the
credit rather than R/DR. Providing
the loan in the form of a check
payable to R/DR ensures that the
loan can’t be used for anything but
purchasing goods from the manufacturer. This overcomes the problem
that money is easier to divert than
goods. The two-part structure of the
contract provides identical incentives

to Stocking Out for early payment, and
the 10-day tripwire provides the bank
with identical information about the
retailer’s financial health. Finally, since
Stocking Out must get a new check to
pay for the next delivery of goods, R/DR
would have the same incentive to
continue making shipments — or to
refuse to make further shipments — in
the event Stocking Out can’t repay the
bank within 30 days.
This contract won’t work for
two main reasons. The more important
reason is that a single firm will have
many different suppliers; that is, for each
borrower the bank must monitor a
portfolio of contracts, rather than a
single contract. Supply arrangements
differ across different types of suppliers:
Some typically use a net 30 contract,
others use 2/10 net 30, and yet others
use 2/10 net 20. Firms also change

suppliers. The amount of information
required for the bank to appropriately
design and monitor a constantly
shifting portfolio of contracts for each
firm in its loan portfolio would be
prohibitive.
The second reason is that
the firm and its suppliers will have
incentives to collude against the
bank. For example, a supplier may be
willing to provide inputs to a firm —
perhaps at an artificially high price —
knowing the firm has a large risk of
not repaying. The risk of default is
shifted to the bank, while the
supplier gains the benefits of the sale.
Again, the bank would need a
prohibitive amount of knowledge
about each transaction to prevent
collusion.*

*This argument is slightly misleading because any three-party interaction can generate incentives for two parties to shift risks to a third. In
particular, a variant of this problem arises any time a firm uses both bank loans and trade credit. Bruno Biais and Christian Gollier’s article
examines the incentives for a firm and its trade creditors to act collusively against the firm’s bank or for a firm and its bank to act collusively
against trade creditors.

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q3 2003 25

bank can’t profitably duplicate R/DR’s
contract.
Empirical Evidence. To a
large extent, the enforcement advantage of trade credit flows from the
supplier-customer relationship, rather
than from formal recourse to legal
institutions and debtor-creditor law. For
this reason, some researchers call trade
credit a type of informal finance, in
contrast to bank loans. Some of the most
interesting empirical evidence that
monitoring and enforcement concerns
are central to understanding trade
credit comes from recent cross-national
studies of firms’ borrowing patterns.
Asli Demirguc-Kunt and
Vojislav Maksimovic’s working paper
finds that firms are more likely to rely on
trade credit in countries where legal
institutions are less efficient. So, in a
country where judges are easily paid off
or where the police powers of the state
are weak, firms can’t rely on the state to
enforce loan contracts. Thus, they tend
to rely more heavily on trade credit.
Raymond Fisman and Inessa Love’s
article finds that industries that tend to
depend on trade credit grow faster than
other industries in nations with weak
financial institutions.16 The authors
interpret this to mean that in the
absence of factors associated with welldeveloped financial institutions — for
example, transparent accounting
standards and incorruptible legal
institutions — industries less dependent

The authors use the financial structure of
firms in the U.S. as the standard for ranking
industries according to their reliance on
trade credit, arguing that firms in the U.S.
secure funds in the most highly developed
financial markets in the world. The view that
the financial structure of U.S. firms is a
reasonable standard for ranking firms relies
on empirical evidence that industry group is
the most important determinant of a firm’s
capital structure. That is, a textile manufacturer in one country tends to have a capital
structure similar to that of a textile
manufacturer in another country with very
different financial laws and institutions.
16

26 Q3 2003 Business Review

on bonds or bank loans face fewer
barriers to growth.
Nilsen’s finding that small,
unrated firms in the U.S. increase their
use of trade credit during a monetary
contraction also supports the view that
enforcement concerns are important for
explaining the use of trade credit. One
reason that large, creditworthy firms
take over a greater share of the job of
providing credit to small, riskier firms is
that they have an advantage in
monitoring these firms when incentive

A study of Vietnamese
firms shows that
firms are more likely
to provide trade credit
to customers with
whom they have
exclusive buyer-seller
relationships.
problems are greatest. In effect, banks
delegate the task of monitoring the
riskiest firms. When financial conditions
are less difficult, close monitoring is less
important, and banks increase their
share of the financing of working capital
for riskier firms.
LONG-TERM SUPPLY
RELATIONSHIPS ARE
IMPORTANT
The option to cut off shipments for nonpayment is a potentially
powerful means for a trade creditor to
force repayment, especially if a supplier
provides its customer with a product that
has no close substitutes. Even if a firm
could find ready substitutes, the threat
to withhold shipments will carry weight,
since other suppliers may not provide
credit if word gets out that the retailer’s
troubles are serious enough to affect its
payments to trade creditors.

But a firm with a long-term
supply relationship with its customer will
not carry out this threat lightly because
it has a natural interest in the long-term
health of its customers. While R/DR
doesn’t want to throw money down the
drain in a hopeless attempt to keep the
retailer afloat, it also knows that
Stocking Out provides R/DR more
prominent shelf-space than it could ever
hope for with Sam’s. Its own profits are
likely to be larger if Stocking Out
retrenches to cut costs but stays in
business and continues to purchase
R/DR’s goods in the future. In these
circumstances, a supplier’s interest in the
long-term profitability of its important
customers can be compared with
owning shares of stock in a customer’s
firm.
R/DR may rationally continue
to draw on its own sources of credit and
provide trade credit when Stocking
Out’s bank wouldn’t. Along with its
long-run interest in the retailer’s
survival, R/DR may also have better
information than a bank about some of
Stocking Out’s problems. For example,
the producer will know better whether a
decline in demand for R/DR’s socks is
an independent cause of the retailer’s
problems, since it sells through outlets
other than Stocking Out.17
Empirical Evidence.
Petersen and Rajan’s article provides
evidence that suppliers of trade credit
are willing to continue to provide credit
even to firms with negative profits, but
only if their customers’sales are increasing. This is consistent with the view that

It should be noted that Stocking Out gains
bargaining power to the extent that R/DR
sees no ready substitute for Stocking Out as
an outlet for its goods. I emphasize the
potential gains to both firms from a close
bilateral relationship. But with no ready
substitute, R/DR may find it difficult to
credibly threaten to withhold future
deliveries. Benjamin Wilner’s article
emphasizes this aspect of trade credit.
17

www.phil.frb.org

suppliers are willing to provide credit to
financially troubled borrowers, but only
if the customer is likely to provide a
continuing and growing demand for the
supplier’s goods. Similarly, a significant
number of the firms surveyed by Ng,
Smith, and Smith report that they are
willing to extend the discount period,
especially for long-term customers. A
study of Vietnamese firms by John
McMillan and Christopher Woodruff
shows that firms are more likely to
provide trade credit to customers with
whom they have exclusive buyer-seller
relationships. This supports the view that
it is helpful to think of the supply
relationship as being similar to owning
shares in a customer’s firm.
I have concentrated on two
explanations for the use of trade credit:
monitoring and enforcement advantages and the potential gains from longterm supply relationships. But trade
credit is widely used across a range of
industries; thus, in practice, there are
likely to be multiple reasons for its use.
(See Other Theories of Trade Credit.)
SUMMARY
When a firm provides trade
credit to a customer, it is acting as an
intermediary. The firm is using its own
funds or funds provided by a specialized
financial intermediary — for example, a
bank line of credit — and passing the
credit on to its customers. This raises a
fundamental puzzle: Why shouldn’t the
bank and the firm receiving the trade
credit cut out the middleman altogether? Why not leave financing to the
financing specialists and leave production and selling to the producers and
sellers of goods?
Actually, there are good
reasons for creditworthy firms to
combine the supply of credit and goods

www.phil.frb.org

to some of their less creditworthy
customers. Suppliers may have advantages in monitoring and enforcing loan
contracts. They may also be more
flexible than banks when their customers face financial troubles because of the
long-term nature of many supply
relationships. These advantages may be
particularly important in nations where
creditors have difficulties collecting on
debts because the rule of law is weak or
the courts are easily corrupted. Recent
cross-national studies — and a limited
number of case studies — have shown
that supplier-provided credit works
comparatively well, even in countries
where bank loans or other sources of
finance are not easily available.
Since it is hard to transform a

country’s legal environment or banking
system over any time horizon—much
less in the short run—it is very tempting
to draw policy prescriptions from these
cross-national studies. Some policymakers view the empirical evidence as
support for public policies to encourage
trade credit in developing countries
where it is not already prevalent. They
hope that trade credit may offer a short
cut to expand firms’ access to finance in
nations with weak legal institutions. But
the evidence is only suggestive and
offers no clear policy prescription. To
address policy-related questions like
these, researchers will have to understand in much more detail how and why
trade credit works in those nations
where it already flourishes. BR

OTHER THEORIES OF TRADE CREDIT

Michael Brennan, Vojislav
Maksimovic, and Josef Zechner’s
article explains trade credit as a
method for firms to engage in price
discrimination by combining the
good along with credit. By law, firms
are precluded from offering identical
goods at different prices; offering the
product along with subsidized credit
may permit a firm to lower its price to
firms whose goods are sensitive to
changes in price.
Bruno Biais and Christian
Gollier’s article suggests that firms
and banks have different types of
information about firms that can be
aggregated. In their model, firms are

unable to secure a bank loan unless the
bank lender sees that suppliers are
willing to provide credit, because it
needs the assurance the suppliers’
information about the firm is favorable.
Murray Frank and Vojislav
Maksimovic’s working paper argues that
trade creditors may have a comparative
advantage over banks or other creditors
in liquidating certain types of inventories. J. Stephen Ferris’s article emphasizes that trade creditors can reduce
transaction costs in the presence of
uncertainties about delivery times and
production needs. In particular, the use
of trade credit reduces a firm’s need to
hold precautionary money balances.*

*See Petersen and Rajan’s 1997 article for a discussion of some other theories.

Business Review Q3 2003 27

REFERENCES
Biais, Bruno, and Christian Gollier. “Trade
Credit and Credit Rationing,” Review of
Financial Studies,” 10, 1997, pp. 903-37.
Brennan, Michael, Vojislav Maksimovic,
and Josef Zechner. “Vendor Financing,”
Journal of Finance, 43, 1988, pp. 1127-41.
Burkart, Mike, and Tore Ellingsen. “In-Kind
Finance,” Discussion Paper 421, Financial
Markets Group, London School
of Economics (2002).
Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav
Maksimovic. “Firms as Financial
Intermediaries: Evidence from Trade Credit
Data,” Working Paper, World Bank, 2001.
Ferris, J. Stephen. “A Transactions Theory of
Trade Credit Use,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 96, 1981, pp. 243-70.
Fisman, Raymond, and Inessa Love.
“Trade Credit, Financial Intermediary
Development, and Industry Growth,”
Journal of Finance, 58, 2003, pp. 353-74.
Frank, Murray, and Vojislav Maksimovic.
“Trade Credit, Collateral, and Adverse
Selection,” Working Paper, University of
Maryland (1998).
Jaffee, Dwight. Credit Rationing and the
Commercial Loan Market. Wiley Press,
1971.

28 Q3 2003 Business Review

Khan, Aubhik. “Understanding the Life
Cycle of a Manufacturing Plant,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review (Second Quarter 2002), pp. 25-33.

Nilsen, Jeffrey. “Trade Credit and the Bank
Lending Channel,” Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, 34, 2002, pp. 226-53.

Lang, William, and Leonard Nakamura.
“The Flight to Quality,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 1995, pp. 145-64.

Petersen, Mitchell, and Raghuram Rajan.
“The Benefits of Lending Relationships:
Evidence from Small Business Data,”
Journal of Finance, 49,1994, pp. 3-37.

McMillan, John, and Christopher Woodruff.
“Interfirm Relationships and Informal
Credit in Vietnam,” Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 114, 1999, pp. 1285-1320.

Petersen, Mitchell, and Raghuram Rajan.
“Trade Credit: Theories and Evidence,”
Review of Financial Studies, 10,1997, pp.
661-91.

Meltzer, Alan. “Mercantile Credit,
Monetary Policy, and the Size of Firms,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 1960,
pp. 429-37.

Rajan, Raghuram, and Luigi Zingales.
“What Do We Know About Capital
Structure? Some Evidence from International Data,” Journal of Finance, 50, 1995,
pp.1421-60.

Mester, Loretta, Leonard Nakamura, and
Micheline Renault. “Checking Accounts
and Bank Monitoring,” Working Paper
01-3/R, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia (January 2003).

Wilner, Benjamin. “The Exploitation of
Relationships in Financial Distress: The
Case of Trade Credit,” Journal of Finance,
55, 2000, pp. 153-78.

Mian, Shehzad, and Clifford Smith.
“Accounts Receivable Management Policy:
Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Finance,
1992, pp. 169-200.
Ng., Chee K., Janet Kiholm Smith,
and Richard Smith. “Evidence on the
Determinants of Credit Terms Used in
Interfirm Trade,” Journal of Finance,
54,1999, pp. 1109-29.

www.phil.frb.org

The Long and the Short of It:
Recent Trends and Cycles in the Third District States
BY THEODORE M. CRONE

M

ost discussions of business cycles focus on
the national economy. But regional cycles
are also important, and they can vary
significantly from one region to another.
Analysis of regional cycles can help businesses plan
investments, project sales, decide whether to enter new
markets, or identify trend growth in current ones. A
look at the economies of the Third District states—
Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Delaware—illustrates
how trends and cycles can differ even among
neighboring states. In this article, Ted Crone traces
the historical patterns of the three states’ economies
but warns that noting such patterns is not a substitute
for detailed current analysis.

In early 2001, the longest
economic expansion in U.S. history
came to an end. The recession that
followed served to remind us that even
the most advanced economies continue
to experience cycles of expansion and
contraction. Most discussions of business
cycles focus on the national economy.
But regional cycles are important as
well, and they can vary significantly
from one region to another. For busi-

Ted Crone is a
vice president
and economist in
the Research
Department of the
Philadelphia Fed.

www.phil.frb.org

nesses whose markets are concentrated
in one state or a few neighboring states,
regional trends and cycles are crucial for
projecting sales, planning production,
and making capital investments.
Businesses that want to diversify across
states or regions seek to serve markets
whose cycles do not always coincide
with one another. Firms also need to
identify trend growth in the markets
they serve to make rational investment
decisions.
An analysis of the economies
of the three states in the Third Federal
Reserve District (Pennsylvania, New
Jersey, and Delaware) illustrates how
trends — long-run growth of economic
output — and cycles — fluctuations
around the trend — can differ even
among neighboring states. Among the

three District states, economic growth
over the past two decades has been
stronger in Delaware and New Jersey
than in the nation; Pennsylvania's
growth, however, has been weaker than
the national average. But for each of the
three states, trend growth has varied
considerably over the past 20-some
years. Also, economic downturns have
generally been more severe in Pennsylvania than in the U.S. or in the neighboring states of New Jersey and
Delaware, but this has not been true for
each downturn. While historic patterns
are helpful in analyzing state economies,
trends can change and every business
cycle is different; therefore, an understanding of historic patterns is important
but only as a guide not as a substitute for
detailed current analysis.
MEASURING
A STATE'S ECONOMY
Business writers and financial
commentators often refer to "the U.S.
economy," "the regional economy," or
"the local economy." To what are they
referring? It's not just the stock market;
it's not just the banking industry; it's not
just manufacturing. It is all of these and
more. "The economy" in this sense
includes all the activity that goes into
providing the goods and services that a
nation, a region, or a locality produces
and distributes over a given period of
time. At the national level, we measure
economic activity every quarter by
adding up the monetary value of all
those goods and services; we call this
measure gross domestic product (GDP).
But how do we measure a
state's economy and calculate its
growth? State governments and the
Business Review Q3 2003 29

federal government produce a number
of measures, and each has its advantages and disadvantages.
Gross state product (GSP),
published by the national Bureau of
Economic Analysis, is the state counterpart to gross domestic product for the
nation. As such, it is the most comprehensive measure of output in a state. If
GSP were available monthly or quarterly, it would be the ideal measure for
establishing the trend and the cycles in
a state's economy. Unfortunately, GSP is
available only on an annual basis, and it
is published with a considerable lag.1
Since economic downturns are measured in months rather than years,
changes in annual GSP are not a good
measure of the length and depth of
these downturns. Moreover, because
GSP data are released with a lag, they
are not useful for current analysis of the
business cycle. But other state data are
published more frequently and without
such a long lag.
The Bureau of Economic
Analysis also publishes personal income
at the state level on a quarterly basis.
Most components of personal income
(for example, wages, proprietors' income,
interest, and rent) represent payments to
the workers, owners, or lenders who
contribute in some way to production.
These payments are measures of the
value added in the economy.
But personal income also has
some drawbacks as a measure of
economic activity in the state. For
example, transfer payments such as
social security benefits and government
pensions are included in personal
income, but they do not represent
payment for current production. Other
components of personal income in a
state, such as dividends, interest, and

rents, may reflect production that took
place outside the state and should not
be included in a measure of the state's
economic activity. Also, state personal
income is published quarterly and with
some lag. Quarterly data are better than

troughs of U.S. business cycles. But
employment, or the total number of
nonfarm jobs, is an imperfect measure of
the output of a state's economy for a
couple of reasons. First, the total number
of jobs does not account for the number

Personal income also has some drawbacks as
a measure of economic activity in the state.
annual data for analyzing business
cycles, but monthly data would be
preferable. Moreover, state personal
income data are normally released about
four months after the end of a quarter,
so they are not as current as other data
on the state's economy.
Monthly employment and
unemployment data are published at the
state level, and they are available before
the end of the following month. Most
analysts view the monthly nonfarm
employment number, derived from a
survey of establishments in the state, as
the best current measure of a
state's economic activity.2 At
the national level, the cyclical
changes in nonfarm employment are highly correlated with
changes in GDP with a slight
lag,3 and the monthly change in
nonfarm employment is a major
factor in dating the peaks and

of hours worked. Second, a change in
productivity — output per hour worked
— can affect output without any
change in employment.
The lack of a timely monthly
indicator of output at the national or
regional level has led to the search for a
composite monthly index of economic
activity that combines information from
several indicators. Perhaps the best
known composite index for the U.S.
economy is the coincident index
published by the Conference Board.4 It
combines data on

This index was
previously
published by the
Department of
Commerce.

4

There is a second statewide employment
measure, residential employment, based on a
household survey and supplemented by data
from the establishment survey. This estimate
of employment is less precise than the
estimate from the establishment survey, and it
includes residents whose jobs may be in
neighboring states. These jobs would not
contribute to production in the person’s home
state.
2

See James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson,
“Business Cycle Fluctuations in U.S.
Macroeconomic Time Series,” in John B.
Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds.,
Handbook of Macroeconomics, V.I-A.
(Elsevier, 1999), pp. 3-64.
3

When this article was completed in early
2003, the latest available GSP data were for
the year 2000.
1

30 Q3 2003 Business Review

www.phil.frb.org

nonfarm employment, personal income
minus transfer payments, the Federal
Reserve Board's index of industrial
production, and manufacturing and
trade sales.5
In the late 1980s, James Stock
and Mark Watson developed an
alternative index of monthly activity for
the U.S. economy using essentially the
same indicators but based on a statistical
model to estimate the "underlying state
of the economy."6 Recently, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia published
coincident indexes for each of the 50
states based on a Stock and Watsontype model.7 Most of the data series that
Stock and Watson and the Conference
Board use for their indexes, however, are
not available at the state level. The state
indexes are based on monthly nonfarm
employment, the unemployment rate,
average hours worked in manufacturing, and quarterly wage and salary
disbursements, adjusted for inflation.8
For comparison purposes, I have also

The data for personal income and trade sales
are adjusted for inflation.
5

See James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson,
“New Indexes of Coincident and Leading
Economic Indicators,” NBER Macroeconomics
Annual (1989), pp. 351-94; James H. Stock and
Mark W. Watson, “ A Probability Model of
the Coincident Economic Indicators,” in
Geoffrey Moore and K. Lahiri, eds., The
Leading Economic Indicators: New Approaches
and Forecasting Records (Cambridge University
Press, 1990,) pp. 63-89. For a less technical
description of this model, see Theodore M.
Crone, “New Indexes Track the State of the
States,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review, January/February, 1994, pp.
19-31. Stock and Watson use the same
monthly series as the Conference Board with
one exception: They use total hours worked
in nonagricultural establishments rather than
nonfarm employment.
6

estimated a U.S. index using the same
variables as in the state indexes.9 The
analysis of trends and cycles in the three
states in the Third District is based on
these indexes for the states and the
comparable national index (Figure 1).
DISTINGUISHING TRENDS
FROM CYCLES
A classic recession is characterized by an absolute decline in output
and other measures of economic
activity. In the United States, the
National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER) determines the official dates for

Since the indexes are meant to reflect
output at the state level, each state’s index is
adjusted so that the long-run growth in the
index is equal to the long-run growth in the
state’s GSP.
8

To make this national index comparable to
the state indexes, the national wage and
salary data are taken from the quarterly
personal income report for the states, and the
average increase in the U.S. index is set to
the average for the combined GSP for all 50
states.
9

the beginning and end of these
recessions. The four official recessions
since 1980 were marked by a decline in
the U.S. economic activity index that I
have constructed (Figure 1). Official
recessions are indicated by the shaded
bars in the figure. Besides official
recessions, however, there are other
periods when jobs become more difficult
to find, growth in output slows even if
output does not decline, and the
unemployment rate rises slightly. We
sometimes hear the refrain: "It may not
be a recession, but it sure feels like one."
In the midst of each of the last two
expansions, the U.S. economy experienced a period of slow growth.10 These

In the long expansion of the 1980s, a period
of slow growth occurred in 1985-86; in the
expansion of the 1990s, a period of slow
growth occurred in 1995. See Victor
Zarnowitz and Ataman Ozyildirim, “Time
Series Decomposition and Measurement of
Business Cycles,” The Conference Board,
Economics Program Working Paper Series 0104 (December 2001).
10

FIGURE 1
Economic Activity Indexes

Theodore M. Crone, “Consistent Economic
Indexes for the 50 States,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, Working Paper 02-7/R
(June 2003). Sufficient data are not available
to calculate these indexes prior to 1979.
These indexes can be found at
www.phil.frb.org/econ/stateindexes/
index.html.
7

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q3 2003 31

periods are often called growth recessions because economic growth dips
below its current trend.
To identify these growth
recessions, we need to distinguish the
current trend from the cyclical movement in economic activity. The simplest
definition of trend growth is some longrun average, for example, the average
growth of real GDP in the post-World
War II period. This understanding of
trend growth was common in the 1960s
and 1970s. But it is not difficult to
imagine that structural changes in the
economy, such as a reduction of trade
barriers, or changes in the rate of
innovation and productivity growth
could change trend growth. So in the
1980s some economists began to look for
evidence of identifiable breaks in trend
growth in the U.S. economy. Others
thought of the trend as changing from
one period to the next. This debate
about how to characterize trend growth
has not been settled.11 It seems
reasonable to assume, however, that
trend growth can and does change over
time. Marianne Baxter and Robert King
have developed a commonly used
statistical technique to separate a slowly
evolving trend from the cyclical
movements in any data series that
exhibits trends and cycles.12 I use their
technique to separate trend from cycle

in the economic activity indexes for the
states and the nation.
SIGNIFICANT DIFFERENCES
IN TREND GROWTH AMONG
THIRD DISTRICT STATES
A cursory glance at some
common measures of economic activity
illustrates how widely total growth has
varied among Pennsylvania, New Jersey,
and Delaware over the past 20-some
years (Table 1). The table shows total
growth for real GSP, real personal

Labor force growth varies more at the state
level than at the national level.
income, and nonfarm employment for
each of the three states and the U.S.
between 1979 and 2000.13 By these
measures, New Jersey and Delaware
generally outperformed the nation while
Pennsylvania lagged far behind. For
example, real output (GSP) more than
doubled in New Jersey and Delaware,
but it increased at only about half that
rate in Pennsylvania. There is only one
exception to this pattern of slower than
average growth in Pennsylvania and
faster than average growth in Delaware

We chose this time span because the
economic activity indexes we use in this
article begin in 1979 and GSP is not available
after 2000.
13

See Francis X. Diebold and Glenn D.
Rudebusch, “Five Questions about Business
Cycles,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, 2001, pp. 1-15.
11

See Marianne Baxter and Robert G. King,
“Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate
Band-Pass Filters for Economic Times Series,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(1999), pp.
575-93. Business cycles are represented by
periods of slower-than-average growth
followed by faster-than-average growth that
last 18 months to eight years. Longer run
movements in the data represent the trend.
This technique also filters out short-term
irregular movements in a series (less than 18
months).

and New Jersey. New Jersey's output
and income grew faster than the
nation's, but jobs grew more slowly. In
effect, New Jersey's economy has shifted
toward jobs with higher productivity and
earnings.
Since trends can vary over
time, the total growth reported in Table
1 does not indicate what trend growth
would be for a state at any point in time.
Figure 2 shows the trend components of
the state and national indexes derived
using Baxter and King's technique.

Trend growth varies over time for all
three states and the U.S., and it varies
more for the states than for the nation.14
It's not surprising that trends change
more at the state level than at the
national level. Growth in the labor force

Monthly trend growth for the U.S. ranges
from 0.29 percent to 0.02 percent, with a
standard deviation of 0.08 percent. For
Pennsylvania, the range of monthly trend
growth is 0.35 percent to -0.11 percent, and
the standard deviation is 0.13 percent. For
New Jersey, the range is 0.32 percent to 0.04
percent, and the standard deviation is 0.08
percent. For Delaware, the range is 0.41
percent to zero percent, and the standard
deviation is 0.12 percent. Figure 2 plots the
trend of the log of each index, so that the
slope of the line is approximately the growth
rate.
14

12

32 Q3 2003 Business Review

TABLE 1
Total Growth for Measures of Economic Activity 1979-2000 (Percent)
Real GSP
US
PA
NJ
DE

89.5
55.3
102.2
107.8

Real Personal Income

Nonfarm Employment

70.8
40.7
73.8
80.3

45.7
18.4
32.0
63.6
www.phil.frb.org

is a major factor in how fast an economy
can grow, and at the state level, growth
of the labor force is affected not only by
international migration but also by
migration between the states. Therefore,
labor force growth varies more at the
state level than at the national level.15
Also, firms can move more easily from
state to state than they can from one
country to another. These relocations
can change the structure of a state's
economy and its trend growth.
The most obvious feature in
Figure 2 is the gap between the trend
component in Pennsylvania's economy
and the trends in the U.S. and the
neighboring states.16 The slower trend
growth in Pennsylvania in part reflects
very slow labor force growth in the state.
On average, Pennsylvania's labor force
increased only about 0.7 percent a year
between 1979 and 2002. Moreover, the
state's economy was traditionally
dominated by manufacturing industries
that were in decline in the last two
decades of the 20th century, and in
Pennsylvania, other industries did not
expand to take the place of those that
were on the wane.17 Although

Pennsylvania's trend growth has
generally been slower than the nation's,
it did surpass the national average for a
four-year period in the mid-1980s and a
two-year period in the late 1990s.18
These episodes illustrate that even states
like Pennsylvania with low overall trend
growth can have spurts of growth that
push them temporarily above the
national average.
Among the three states in the
Third District, New Jersey has had the
most consistent trend growth over the

The state had higher trend growth than the
nation from December 1984 to November 1988
and from June 1997 to October 1999. Since
1979, Pennsylvania has generally had slower
trend growth than New Jersey; however, for a
five-year period (August 1985 to November
1991), Pennsylvania had faster trend growth
than New Jersey. In two short periods since
1979 (December 1990 to December 1992 and
December 1999 to October 2002), Pennsylvania also had faster trend growth than
Delaware.
18

past 22 years.19 Higher productivity
rather than increased employment
generated most of the growth in New
Jersey. However, in the period between
January 1987 and November 1996, New
Jersey's trend dropped below the
national trend. It is difficult to pinpoint
the causes of the lower trend in New
Jersey during this period, but changes in
federal and state tax laws may have
played a role. Changes in the federal
income tax law in 1986 lengthened the
depreciation schedule for incomeproducing property. This change seems
to have had a greater impact in New
Jersey than in other states. The value of
both residential and nonresidential
construction contracts declined 60
percent or more in New Jersey after the
1986 tax changes. These declines were

See footnote 14 for the ranges and standard
deviations of monthly trend growth in the
three states.
19

FIGURE 2
Trend Component of the Economic
Activity Indexes

The standard deviation of the annual
change in the labor force in Pennsylvania from
1979 to 2002 was almost twice the standard
deviation of the change in the nation. In New
Jersey, the standard deviation in the annual
change in the labor force was almost two and
a half times the standard deviation of the
change in the nation, and in Delaware, the
standard deviation of labor force growth was
more than three and a half times the
standard deviation of the national growth.
15

Because the trend is a moving average, a
large negative decline in the economy can
result in a slower trend around that period.
The two severe downturns in the early 1980s
probably contributed to the lower trend for
Pennsylvania in the early 1980s.
16

For a discussion of some of the economic
forces behind this decline in the state’s
manufacturing sector, see Theodore M.
Crone, “Where Have All the Factory Jobs
Gone—and Why?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Business Review (May/June 1997).
17

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q3 2003 33

much greater than the declines at the
national level. New Jersey state income
taxes were also raised significantly in
1990 to cover a state budget deficit. This
too may have slowed growth in the
state's economy.
Trend growth has varied more
in Delaware than in either of the other
two states in the Third District.
Delaware's faster overall growth is
primarily due to very rapid trend growth
in the mid- to late 1980s. In 1981
Delaware passed the Financial Center
Development Act, which encouraged
banks, especially credit card banks, to
locate in the state.20 This act had a
profound effect on the structure of the
state's economy. Jobs in the finance,
insurance, and real estate sector
increased between 8 percent and 18
percent every year between 1982 and
1988.21 These high rates of growth were
not sustained in the 1990s, but growth in
the broad financial services sector in
Delaware still outpaced growth at the
national level. Jobs in finance, insurance, and real estate comprised only 5
percent of Delaware's jobs in 1981 but
more than 12 percent in 2002.
Trend growth has varied not
only among the three states in the Third
District but within each state over time.
But certain patterns stand out.
Pennsylvania's trend has been significantly lower than that of the other two
states, and Delaware's trend has varied
more over time than the trends in the
other two states.

See Janice M. Moulton, “Delaware Moves
Toward Interstate Banking: A Look at the
FCDA,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (July/August 1983).

BUSINESS CYCLES IN THE
THREE STATES: DIFFERENCES
IN TIMING AND DEPTH
The classic understanding of a
business cycle includes an expansion of
economic activity followed by a
recession or contraction and a revival of
activity that leads to the next expansion.22 In the classic definition of a
business cycle, a recession is a period of
sustained absolute decline in economic

In the classic definition of a business cycle, a
recession is a period of sustained absolute
decline in economic activity, and an expansion
is a period of increasing levels of activity.
activity, and an expansion is a period of
increasing levels of activity. The ability
to distinguish between trends and cycles
allows us to apply business-cycle analysis
to those periods in which the cyclical
component of the national or state
economy is rising or declining. Figure 3
shows the cyclical components of the
economic activity indexes for the
United States and the three states in the
Third District. Those periods in which
the economy falls below its trend — i.e.,
when the line goes below zero — are
called growth recessions. According to
Figure 3 there have been two growth
recessions in the national economy since
1979 that were not associated with
classic recessions — one in the mid1980s and one in mid-1990s.23 However,
since the economy tends to grow more

20

This compares with growth rates between
1.5 percent and 5.5 percent for the U.S. in
those years. Employment data on the
components of the finance, insurance, and
real estate sector in Delaware are not
available prior to 1984.

slowly for some months before a classic
or a growth recession, the cyclical
component of the economy begins to
decline before the beginning of the
recession. We will refer to periods when
the cyclical component is declining as
cyclical downturns, and since the late
1970s, they have always been longer
than the official recessions. We will refer
to periods in which the cyclical component is rising as cyclical expansions.

The classic description is found in Arthur F.
Burns and Wesley C. Mitchell, Measuring
Business Cycles, NY: National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1946.
22

After recessions end and the overall
economy begins to expand, the cyclical
component may remain negative for
several months even as it rises from its
low point.
Cyclical Downturns in the
Tri-State Region. How do the cyclical
downturns in the three states compare
to the national downturns? We can look
at the peaks and troughs of the cyclical
component of the state and national
economic indexes as well as the total
decline in the cyclical component in
each downturn (Table 2). Pennsylvania
has suffered the same number of
cyclical downturns since 1979 as the
U.S., and Pennsylvania's downturns
have generally been the same length as
or shorter than the corresponding
national downturns.24 But the timing of
Pennsylvania's downturns differed
somewhat from the timing of national
downturns. Five of the six downturns
since 1979 began earlier in Pennsylvania
than in the U.S. And Pennsylvania's

21

34 Q3 2003 Business Review

In their decomposition of trends and cycles
in the U.S. economy, Zarnowitz and
Ozyildirim (2001) find growth recessions in
the U.S. economy during the same two
periods.
23

The exceptions are the downturn in 197980, which lasted two months longer in
Pennsylvania than in the U.S., and the most
recent cyclical downturn that began in 2000.
24

www.phil.frb.org

FIGURE 3
Cyclical Component of the Economic
Activity Indexes

TABLE 2
Changes in the Cyclical Components of Economic Activity Indexes
During Cyclical Downturns
PA
NJ
DE
US
Peak
Sep-79
Sep-79
Aug-79
Nov-79
Trough
Sep-80
Oct-80
Sep-80
Total % Change Peak to Trough
-2.2
-0.6
-0.7
Peak
Trough
Total % Change Peak to Trough

Jul-81
Feb-83
-6.9

May-81
Nov-82
-2.5

Aug-82
-3.6

Jul-81
Feb-83
-4.2

Peak
Trough
Total % Change Peak to Trough

Nov-84
Jun-86
-0.8

Sep-84
Mar-86
-0.9

Feb-85
Apr-86
-0.9

Feb-85
Dec-86
-1.2

Peak
Trough
Total % Change Peak to Trough

Oct-89
Dec-91
-4.6

Feb-89
Feb-92
-4.1

Apr-89
May-92
-4.4

Mar-90
Aug-92
-3.2

Peak
Trough
Total % Change Peak to Trough

Nov-94
Jan-96
-1.5

Dec-94
Apr-96
-1.2

Mar-95
Aug-96
-0.5

Feb-95
Jun-96
-0.9

cyclical downturns have generally been
more severe than the corresponding
national ones; that is, the percentage
decline in the cyclical component of the
state's economy has been greater than
the decline in the nation's economy.25
Like Pennsylvania, New Jersey
has suffered the same number of
cyclical downturns as the U.S. since
1979. Also, all New Jersey's downturns
have begun earlier than their U.S.
counterparts, and most have been
shorter. New Jersey experienced less
severe downturns than the nation
through most of the 1980s. The two
cyclical downturns between 1989 and
1996, however, were more severe in
New Jersey than in the nation. This is
the same period in which trend growth
in New Jersey dipped below the national
average, so the state's economic growth
suffered on both counts.
The cyclical pattern in
Delaware's economy has differed in a
significant way from the patterns in the
nation and the other two states in the
Third District. Delaware suffered one
long cyclical downturn between August
1979 and August 1982 — a period that
spanned two downturns for the nation
and for the other two states in the
region. Despite the length of the
cyclical downturn in Delaware in the
early 1980s, the cyclical decline in
Delaware was less severe than the
decline at the national level between
1981 and 1983. From 1989 to 1992,
however, the cyclical component of
Delaware's economic activity index had
a much larger percentage loss than the
nation's. This downturn was also longer
in Delaware than in the nation. But the
length of the cyclical downturns in the
three states has not always corresponded
to their relative severity.

The one exception is the downturn in
Pennsylvania between November 1984 and
June 1986. The decline in Pennsylvania was
less than the decline at the national level.
25

Peak
Trough

www.phil.frb.org

Sep-00
—

Aug-00
—

Nov-99
—

Oct-00
—

Business Review Q3 2003 35

Cyclical Expansions in the
Tri-State Region. Just as Pennsylvania's
cyclical downturns have been more
severe than the national downturns,
cyclical expansions in the state have also
been stronger (Table 3). In short,
Pennsylvania's economy is more sensitive
to the business cycle than the U.S.
economy. Part of the explanation for the
more pronounced business cycles in
Pennsylvania is that the state's economy
is more heavily weighted toward the
manufacturing sector than is the
nation's.26 And manufacturing
industries are more cyclically sensitive
than other industries. Just as economic
downturns have tended to begin earlier
in Pennsylvania than in the nation,
three of the last five cyclical expansions
have begun earlier in the state than in
the nation, and the other two have
begun at the same time.
New Jersey's cyclical patterns
differed somewhat between the 1980s
and the 1990s. In the 1980s, the state's
cyclical expansions were shorter than
the national expansions, and they were
also weaker in terms of total growth
(Table 3). That pattern was reversed in
the 1990s: New Jersey's cyclical growth
in expansion periods surpassed the
nation's cyclical growth, and the state's
expansions were the same length as or
longer than the nation's. In both
decades, however, New Jersey's
expansions tended to begin earlier than
the corresponding expansions at the
national level, just as cyclical downturns
tended to begin earlier in New Jersey.27
The pattern of cyclical
expansions is more difficult to characterize in Delaware than in the other two

In 2002, 15.1 percent of Pennsylvania’s
nonfarm employment was in manufacturing
compared to 12.8 percent for the nation. In
1979, the gap was even wider—28.9 percent
for Pennsylvania and 23.4 percent for the U.S.
26

The one exception was the 1980-81
expansion that began later in New Jersey.
27

36 Q3 2003 Business Review

states in the Third District. Delaware
had fewer cycles than the nation in the
1980s. In two of Delaware's cyclical
expansions — the one in the second half
of the 1980s and the one in the second
half of the 1990s — cyclical growth at
the state level was greater than the
national average. In the other expansion, cyclical growth at the state level
lagged growth at the national level
(Table 3). Finally, while most cyclical
expansions have begun several months
earlier in Delaware than in the nation,
there is one exception. The expansion in
the late 1990s began slightly later in
Delaware.
Timing of Cyclical Movements in the Region. We have seen
that cyclical downturns in Pennsylvania
and New Jersey generally begin before
the corresponding national downturns;
the same is true of cyclical expansions in
all three states in the region. But there
are exceptions. So can we say that

movements throughout the entire cycle
for any of the states lead or lag movements at the national level?
Table 4 presents correlations
between changes in the cyclical
component of each state's index and
changes in the nation's cyclical component during both downturns and
expansions. The column marked "t"
shows the correlation between changes
in the same month for both the state
and the nation. The columns to the left
of "t" show correlations between changes
at the national level and previous
months' changes in the states. The
columns to the right of "t" show
correlations between the changes at the
national level and future months'
changes for the states. For example, the
correlation between the change in the
national cyclical component and the
change in Pennsylvania's cyclical
component six months earlier is 0.619
while the correlation between the

TABLE 3
Changes in the Cyclical Components of Economic Activity Indexes
During Cyclical Expansions
PA

NJ

DE

US

Trough
Peak
Total % Change Trough to Peak

Sep-80
Jul-81
1.0

Oct-80
May-81
0.2

Trough
Peak
Total % Change Trough to Peak

Feb-83
Nov-84
5.9

Nov-82
Sep-84
3.3

Aug-82
Feb-85
2.8

Feb-83
Feb-85
4.1

Trough
Peak
Total % Change Trough to Peak

Jun-86
Oct-89
3.4

Mar-86
Feb-89
2.0

Apr-86
Apr-89
3.6

Dec-86
Mar-90
2.2

Trough
Peak
Total % Change Trough to Peak

Dec-91
Nov-94
2.6

Feb-92
Dec-94
2.6

May-92
Mar-95
1.3

Aug-92
Feb-95
2.3

Trough
Peak
Total % Change Trough to Peak

Jan-96
Sep-00
3.4

Apr-96
Aug-00
2.5

Aug-96
Nov-99
2.9

Jun-96
Oct-00
2.2

Sep-80
Jul-81
0.7

www.phil.frb.org

TABLE 4
Correlations Between Changes in Cyclical Component of U.S. Index
and State Indexes at Various Leads and Lags of the State Index
t-6

t-5

t-4

t-3

t-2

t-1

t

t+1

t+2

t+3

t+4

t+5

t+6

PA

0.619

0.725

0.816

0.887

0.933

0.952

0.944

0.908

0.848

0.764

0.663

0.549

0.426

NJ

0.770

0.835

0.883

0.911

0.919

0.904

0.867

0.811

0.736

0.645

0.542

0.430

0.313

DE

0.673

0.683

0.685

0.680

0.666

0.644

0.615

0.578

0.534

0.486

0.434

0.378

0.320

change in the national cyclical component and the change in Pennsylvania's
cyclical component one month earlier is
0.952. The current national change is
more closely associated with the onemonth earlier change in Pennsylvania
than with the six-month earlier change.
All the correlations in Table 4
are positive, but the highest correlations
are with state changes in months
preceding the national change. In
general, cyclical movements in the
region precede cyclical movements at
the national level — by one month for
Pennsylvania, two months for New
Jersey, and four months for Delaware.
Moreover, changes in Pennsylvania have
the highest correlations with changes at
the national level, and changes in
Delaware have the lowest correlations.
Delaware may give us the earliest signal
of a cyclical change at the national level
but the signal is weak.
Business-Cycle Patterns in
the Three States: Opportunity to
Diversify? Table 5 shows correlations
between changes in the cyclical
components of the three state indexes.
Cyclical movements in Pennsylvania
and New Jersey are very similar; they
are highly correlated. The correlation is
not as strong, however, between New
Jersey and Delaware, and it is weakest
between Pennsylvania and Delaware.
The weaker correlations between
Delaware and the other two states

www.phil.frb.org

suggest that there is some room for firms
to diversify their markets within the tristate region. This assumes, of course,
that a firm's business is dependent on
the local economy, such as might be the
case for a small chain of restaurants or
fitness centers. A manufacturing firm
that sells its products nationwide could
not protect itself from downturns in
manufacturing by locating some of its
facilities in Delaware.
WHAT CAN WE LEARN FROM
THIS ANALYSIS?
Most economic series show
that Pennsylvania has had the weakest
economy among the three states in the
Third District in the last two decades.
An analysis of trends and cycles shows
that Pennsylvania's poor performance
has been due not only to its lower trend
growth but also to more severe cyclical
downturns. The state's economy has
been more volatile than the national
economy. Both New Jersey and
Delaware have had higher trend growth
and, in general, less severe cycles than
the nation. But this did not preclude
them from having a much more serious
downturn than the nation between 1989
and 1992.
Delaware's trend growth has
been less consistent than that of the
other two states, and cycles in Delaware
have been considerably different from
those in the other two states and the

U.S. These differences may make it
difficult to predict cyclical movements
in Delaware, but differences in the
cyclical components of the state indexes
suggest that firms can find diverse
markets in the tri-state region.
Finally, a careful reading of
cyclical conditions in the region may
provide an indication of what lies ahead
for the national business cycle. In all
three states, cyclical movements
precede movements at the national
level. The signals are strongest in
Pennsylvania and weakest in Delaware.
The patterns illustrated in this
breakdown of the states' economies into
trends and cycles should only be a guide
and not a substitute for careful analysis
of current data. None of the three states
has always had a higher or lower trend
than the national average, and none of
the states has been a safe haven in every
economic downturn. BR

TABLE 5
Correlations Between
Contemporaneous Changes
in the Cyclical Component
of the State Indexes
PA-NJ
PA-DE
NJ-DE

Correlation
0.88
0.61
0.76

Business Review Q3 2003 37

The Role of Inventories
In the Business Cycle
BY AUBHIK KHAN

C

hanges in the stock of firms’ inventories are
an important component of the business
cycle. In fact, discussion about the timing
of a recovery following economic recessions
often focuses on inventories. Aubhik Khan surveys the
facts about inventory investment over the business
cycle, then discusses two leading theories that may
explain these observations.

Changes in the stock of firms’
inventories are an important component
of the business cycle. Alan Blinder, a
former Governor of the Federal Reserve
System, famously remarked that “the
business cycle, to a surprisingly large
degree, is an inventory cycle.” Consistent with this perspective, much of the
discussion about the timing of a
recovery following economic recessions
focuses on firms’ stocks of inventories.
Pundits suggest that production and
employment cannot recover until firms’
inventories fall, relative to their sales.
This article surveys the facts
about inventory investment over the
business cycle, then discusses two
leading theories of inventory investment

Aubhik Khan is a
senior economist in
the Research
Department of the
Philadelphia Fed.

38 Q3 2003 Business Review

that may explain these observations.
Theory that passes the test of observation may allow us, with some confidence, to predict future movements in
the data. Theories that have sought to
explain macroeconomic changes in
inventory investment have generally
focused on firms’ attempts to (1) reduce
the costs of adjusting their production
level or (2) reduce the costs of placing
orders for intermediate goods. While
much of the research on inventories in
the past 50 years has emphasized the
cost of adjusting production, this
approach has had well-known difficulties when confronted with the data.
Recent work that has focused on
reducing the fixed costs of ordering
goods may provide a framework that is
more consistent with the facts. At the
same time, this recent work may
produce new insights about the
interaction between inventories and the
macroeconomy. These two theories
predict different behavior for aggregate
production, sales, and inventory
investment.

INVENTORIES SEEM
TO BE IMPORTANT IN THE
BUSINESS CYCLE
Figure 1 shows the businesscycle component of real gross domestic
product (GDP) in the United States
over most of the postwar period. We can
think of movements in GDP as the sum
of two components: the trend and the
business cycle. The trend represents the
average growth rate of the economy
across surrounding years. The business
cycle reflects short-term deviations from
this trend: the expansions and contractions that make up the business cycle.1,2
For comparison, recessions, as dated by
the National Bureau of Economic
Research, are shaded in the figure.
The figure also includes
changes in the stock of private nonfarm
inventories (private refers to nongovernment). The difference between GDP,
the sum of all goods and services
produced in the economy over a given
period, and final sales, the sum of all
goods and services sold, is known as net
inventory investment. Net inventory

Actually, any type of expenditure or output
may be broken down into a business-cycle
component and a trend. The process of
isolating the business-cycle component is
known as “detrending” or “filtering.” The
real quarterly series in the figure have been
detrended with the Hodrick-Prescott filter
using a smoothing parameter of 1600. For
additional details, see Edward C. Prescott’s
paper.
1

It then follows that a recession, in this
approach to business cycles, is a period in
which the economy is growing at rates that
are lower than its trend. This contrasts with
the conventional use of the term recession to
describe a period of negative growth.
2

www.phil.frb.org

investment is a measure of goods that
have been made but not sold to
consumers nor used by a firm as an
intermediate input into production.
A car made by Honda in Ohio,
completed but retained unused in the
factory, adds to Honda’s stock of
inventories. Steel bought by the same
manufacturer but left unused is a raw
material that also adds to Honda’s stock
of inventories. Nonfarm private
inventories are essentially stocks of these
final goods, intermediate inputs,
materials, or supplies held by businesses.
Changes in this component of total
inventory investment account for most
of the change in total inventories over
the business cycle.
Cyclicality and Volatility. In
organizing their thinking about the role
of an economic variable such as
inventory investment over the business
cycle, economists focus on the cyclicality
and volatility of the variable. A
variable’s cyclicality — formally, its
correlation with real GDP — is a
measure of how the variable changes
over the business cycle. For example, net
exports — that is, exports minus imports
— are countercyclical: they fall as GDP
rises during an expansion, and they rise
as GDP declines in a recession.
In contrast, consumption and
investment are pro-cyclical: they rise
during expansions and fall, alongside
GDP, in recessions. A significant
correlation, whether positive or negative,
between any economic variable and
GDP suggests that the variable is
cyclical in that it varies in a systematic
way with GDP over the business cycle.
This is not true of all economic variables.
For example, government spending is
acyclical: it shows no significant
correlation with economy activity over
the business cycle, neither rising nor
falling systematically.
While the cyclicality of a
variable measures the extent to which it
rises or falls with GDP, volatility mea-

www.phil.frb.org

sures the size of the variable’s total
fluctuation over the business cycle.3
Economic variables differ considerably
in their volatility. For example, consumption of nondurable goods and services is
far less volatile than GDP, while business
investment and consumption of
consumer durable goods are more
volatile — i.e., they have bigger swings.
Thus, investment fluctuates a lot more
than does the consumption of nondurables and services as output rises and
falls.
Net inventory investment is
pro-cyclical (Figure 1). It moves along
with GDP, rising during expansions and
falling during recessions. This is a very
important observation because it means

Formally, we define volatility as the
standard deviation of the business-cycle
component of the quarterly data.
3

that a common view of inventories —
that they are goods that firms were
unable to sell — can’t explain most of
the movements in inventories. In an
expansion, inventories grow as consumption and investment grow. That is, when
sales rise, inventories also rise. If
inventories were mainly goods that firms
couldn’t sell, they would tend to rise
when sales fell.
By definition GDP = Final
Sales + Net Inventory Investment.
Thus, any change in GDP must be
attributable to either a change in final
sales or a change in net inventory
investment. Let’s look at the fraction of
the change in GDP that can be
accounted for by changes in net
inventory investment. To accomplish
this, we divide the change in inventories
during recessions by the corresponding
change in GDP. The result is a number
around one-half. Almost half of the fall

FIGURE 1
GDP, Final Sales, and Changes in Nonfarm Inventories

Business Review Q3 2003 39

in production experienced by the U.S.
economy during a recession may be
explained by a reduction in net
inventory investment. This is a
surprisingly large fraction when one
considers that net inventory investment
is, on average, only around 0.5 percent
of GDP. It indicates that inventory
investment is extremely volatile.
Adding to the Volatility of
Output. The pro-cyclicality and
extreme volatility of inventory investment have led researchers to suggest
that inventories are a destabilizing force.
At its simplest, their argument is as
follows. Inventory investment and final
sales tend to move together: both rise
during expansions, and both fall during
recessions. Consequently, GDP varies
by more than it would if inventory
investment were constant or negatively
correlated with final sales.
To understand this better,
consider the following simple example. If
final sales rise during odd years and fall
during even years, while inventory
investment rises (by the same amount)
during even years and falls during odd
years, there’s no effect on GDP.
Inventory investment and final sales
move in opposite directions; they are
negatively correlated. As a result, each
offsets the change in the other. Production is smoothed.
Now, consider an alternative
case in which both series rise during odd
years. Since inventory investment moves
with output, and since it’s highly
volatile, inventories substantially raise
the volatility of GDP. Since final sales
and inventory investment are indeed
positively correlated, typically rising and
falling at the same time, researchers
have concluded that inventories are a
destabilizing force in the economy. (See
Are Inventories Becoming Less Prominent?) Changes in inventories magnify
the effect of a change in final sales on
domestic production.

40 Q3 2003 Business Review

THE MYSTERY
OF INVENTORIES
Economists are not satisfied
merely to uncover the facts about
inventories and the business cycle.
Their primary goal is to explain these
findings. Before we may begin to
understand why firms change their
holdings of inventories over the business
cycle, we must have an understanding
of why firms hold inventories at all. For
economic theory, this has been more of a
mystery than you might suppose.
Why would a firm produce
goods but not sell them? Sales completed today give the firm income that it
may invest. For example, even if the
firm has no other immediate use for the
funds, it might deposit them in an
interest-earning account. A firm would
forgo this interest income if it chooses
not to sell its goods immediately.
But perhaps it isn’t voluntary.
You may think firms hold inventories
only of finished goods they have been
unable to sell. While firms do sometimes
accumulate inventories of unsold goods
because of weaker-than-expected
demand, this can’t be the central
explanation of inventory holdings. First,
remember that inventories rise when
sales do. Second, goods that have been
produced but not yet sold are only a
fraction of the total stock of inventories.
Firms also hold inventories of inputs they
use to produce their goods, buying them
before they need them.
The answer to the question of
why firms forgo interest income must
involve benefits derived from holding
inventories. Holding stocks of inventories must somehow reduce a firm’s cost
of production, and these cost savings
must exceed the forgone interest.
There are two theories of how
production costs induce firms to hold
stocks of inventories. The first, known
as the production-smoothing model of
inventories, emphasizes the costs of
adjusting production. The second,

known as the (S, s) model of inventories,
emphasizes the costs of accepting
deliveries. While each of these theories
can explain why firms hold inventories,
they are commonly applied to different
types of inventories. Thus, the two
theories are not mutually exclusive; both
may be relevant to an understanding of
the overall stock of inventories.
However, as with all science,
the empirical relevance of these
alternative theories can be assessed by
evaluating their predictions against the
data. The production-smoothing model
and the (S, s) model generally have
distinct predictions about the joint
behavior of production, sales, and
inventory investment.
THE PRODUCTIONSMOOTHING MODEL
The production-smoothing
model explains why a manufacturing
firm holds stocks of goods produced but
unsold. The model assumes that it is
costly for the manufacturing firm to
adjust production.
It is costly to buy and install
new equipment or to uninstall and sell
off previously installed equipment.
Workers are costly to hire and train, and
layoffs are also expensive. Since changing levels of output often involve
changing the size of the labor force and
purchasing new capital equipment,
these adjustment costs are inevitable for a
firm that changes its level of output over
time. It’s reasonable to assume that these
costs of changing production levels
actually increase with the size of the
change. For example, a large increase in
production requires hiring more workers
and, thus, involves higher training costs.
In any case, given these costs of adjusting production, if sales are volatile, a
firm may prefer not to vary production
to match the variation in sales. Instead,
it may use inventories of already
produced goods to offset the difference
between production and sales.

www.phil.frb.org

ARE INVENTORIES BECOMING LESS PROMINENT?
If inventories are indeed a destabilizing element
intermediate inputs and materials and supplies, both
of aggregate economic activity, perhaps the much heralded
components of the overall stock of inventories but not part
improvements in technology that have led to sharp declines
of final sales, must account for the divergence between the
in the inventory to sales ratio will eventually yield a less
real and nominal ratios of inventories to sales.
severe business cycle. Since inventories seem to explain so
While I cannot suggest which ratio is more
much of the decline in output during recessions, and since
sensible, Figure 2 casts some doubt on some of the discusthey amplify the effect of changes in final sales on GDP, as
sion of technological improvements’ role in reducing
inventory levels decline, perhaps GDP will be subject to less
demand for inventories. While both the financial press and
severe fluctuations.
policymakers have repeatedly mentioned the important
Arguments such as this have led economists to
role of improved management techniques, such as just-inemphasize the decline in the inventory to sales ratio. In
time production methods, in reducing firms’ dependence
Figure 2, we see the nominal stock of inventories as a ratio
on inventories, the real inventory to sales ratio in Figure 2
of final sales. Clearly, it has declined sharply since the early
suggests caution before making sweeping generalizations.
1980s. Many observers have regarded this decline as the
When examining the nominal inventory to sales ratio, we
result of improvements in technology and management
see that it rose before it fell, something that is hard to
methods that have allowed firms to reduce their holdings
explain using technological improvement. The real ratio
of inventories relative to their sales. This is less clear from
has not declined consistently over the past 20 years.
the figure. First, we see that the
inventory to sales ratio rose sharply
in the 1970s. If technological
FIGURE 2
innovation has reduced the ratio
since the 1980s, what was the sharp
Quarterly Nominal and Real Inventory
technological regress in the 1970s?
to Sales Ratios
Second, and related, is the finding
that the inventory to sales ratio was
as low in the late 1960s as it was in
the mid 1980s.
Even the decline in the
importance of inventories is less clear
than is commonly acknowledged.
The figure also plots the real
inventory to sales ratio, that is, the
ratio when both inventories and
sales figures have been divided by
their price indexes. While the
nominal inventory to sales ratio
shows a clear negative trend over
the past 20 to 25 years, the real
inventory to sales ratio displays no
corresponding decline! This implies
that the price index for inventories
has fallen more slowly than that for
final sales. It would seem that
changes in the relative price of

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q3 2003 41

For example, a toy maker
knows that sales are always higher
during the Christmas season. However,
since it is expensive to hire a large
number of workers in the last quarter of
the year, the toy company may produce
more toys than it sells over the first nine
months. During these nine months,
production exceeds sales, and the toy
company accumulates inventories. At
the end of the year, when demand rises,
the toy factory has fewer workers than it
needs to satisfy sales. But even though
production is lower than Christmas sales,
the company can sell off its accumulated inventories to meet the increased
demand. Accumulating inventories
from January through September lets
the toy maker smooth production
relative to sales; that is, production is less
volatile than sales, and when sales rise,
inventories fall.
The defining assumption of
the production-smoothing model is that
there are costs of adjusting the level of
production in a firm and that these costs
rise in proportion to the extent of the
adjustment. The central prediction of
the production-smoothing model is that,
at least to the extent that there are
fluctuations in the demand for a firm’s
products, its production will vary less
than its sales, and when its sales are
high, inventories will be reduced. If all
firms behave this way, we should see, for
the economy as a whole: (1) GDP less
volatile than final sales and (2) a
negative correlation between final sales
and inventory investment.
The Dilemma with Inventories as a Buffer Against Changes in
Sales. There are two difficulties with
the production-smoothing model (Table
1). The first row of the first column
shows a measure of the volatility — the
standard deviation — of the businesscycle component of GDP. The first rows
of the next two columns report the
relative volatility of final sales and net
inventory investment. The relative
42 Q3 2003 Business Review

volatility of final sales is the ratio of the
standard deviation of final sales divided
by that of GDP itself. This gives us a
measure of how much sales fluctuate
relative to GDP. For example, we see
that the relative volatility of final sales is
82 percent of that of GDP. At least at
the aggregate level, production is more
volatile than sales.
In the third row of the second
column, we also find that the correlation
between final sales and inventory
investment is actually positive. Both the
higher variability of production and this
correlation contradict the predictions of
the basic production-smoothing model
described above. If production is more
volatile than sales, inventories are not
effective in smoothing production. This
evidence — which also holds for
countries other than the U.S. and for
individual industries and even for firms
— offers no support for the view that
smoothing production is an important
motive for holding inventories.
Attempts to Adapt the
Model to Fit the Facts. By adjusting
the production- smoothing model to fit
the data, both Valerie Ramey and
Martin Eichenbaum have developed
solutions to the problems with the basic
production-smoothing model.

In her paper, Ramey suggests
that firms may actually prefer to bunch
their production because unit costs fall
as they produce more. This is known as
increasing returns. Ramey and Daniel
Vine studied an interesting example of
increasing returns in the automobile
industry that is a result of contracts
between manufacturers and labor
unions. They argued that these
contracts broadly imply that if an
automobile manufacturer employs
workers for less than 40 hours in any
given week, it must also pay them 85
percent of the earnings lost in working
less than a full week, but only if the
workers work at all.4
Consider the following
example, which highlights the implications of such a wage contract. Assume
that an automobile manufacturer sells
75 cars a week. If its workers work a full
week (40 hours), they produce 100 cars.

Thus, if a worker is paid $10 an hour and is
employed full time for 40 hours, he is paid
$400 for the week. However, if he is employed
for 35 hours, he is paid $350 for the time he
worked and 85 percent of the $50 he would
have earned for the five hours he did not
work or $392.50 in total. Finally, if he does
not work at all in a week, he is not paid at all.
4

TABLE 1
GDP, Final Sales, and Inventory Investment

GDP

Final Sales

Net Inventory
Investment

Percent Standard Deviation
Relative to GDP

1.675

0.824

0.282

Correlation with GDP

1.000

0.951

0.653

Correlation with NII

0.653

0.410

1.000

Data are quarterly U.S., 1954.1 – 2002.4, seasonally adjusted and chained in 1996 dollars. GDP
and final sales are reported as percentage standard deviations, detrended using a HodrickPrescott filter with a weight of 1600. Net inventory investment in private nonfarm inventories
xt, is detrended relative to GDP; the detrended series is (xt -xt) / yt, where xt is the HP-trend
of the series and yt is the trend for GDP.

www.phil.frb.org

One possible production plan would be
to employ all workers for only 30 hours
a week. But if, instead, they are
employed full time for three weeks,
then laid off every fourth week, the
manufacturer will have lower labor
costs. Moreover, this second option
implies that production varies across
weeks, while sales do not. Production
has become more variable than sales
because of increasing returns.5
Martin Eichenbaum considers
an alternative: the effect of random
changes in unit costs that are independent of the quantity produced. This
theory is different from the assumption
of increasing returns; it does not assume
that unit costs fall with quantity
produced but that they rise and fall
unexpectedly over time. Examples of
such unexpected changes in firms’
production costs include, but are not
limited to, changes in input prices, such

If the firm chooses to employ its workers for
four weeks, having them work just 30 hours
each week, it will have to pay them for 38.5
hours a week, or 154 hours in total, for a
total cost of $1540. If, instead, the firm has
them work full time for 40 hours during the
first three weeks, then lays them off during
the fourth week, it has to pay them for only
120 hours, or $1200 in total.
5

as a rise in oil prices, and poor weather.
A sudden rise in oil prices that is not
expected to last very long may give a
transportation company an incentive to
temporarily reduce its shipments. An
unexpectedly cold winter will lead
construction companies to defer as
much building as they can. Such
random changes in costs lead to random
changes in production and do so
independently of fluctuations in sales.
Thus, production becomes more volatile,
and if these cost shocks are sufficiently
large, it may become more volatile than
sales.
Both Ramey’s increasing
returns model and Eichenbaum’s cost
shocks model modify the productionsmoothing model, making it more
consistent with the data. In each
instance, the positive co-movement
between final sales and inventory
investment is restored, and production
becomes more variable than sales.
Regardless of whether the
production-smoothing model can be
reconciled to observation, a second
difficulty remains. This model may
apply to a relatively small fraction of the
firms that hold inventories because the
model is based on a manufacturing firm
that produces, then stores as inventories,

finished goods that it will sell later.
Inventories of finished manufactured goods are only 13 percent of
the total stock of inventories in the
economy (Table 2). The remaining
two-thirds of inventories held in the
manufacturing sector are intermediate
inputs into production. The inventories
held in the wholesale and retail sectors
are largely finished goods, but production smoothing may not be best suited
to explain the inventories held in these
sectors. One reason is that firms in
these sectors do not produce the goods
they sell.6
THE (S,s) MODEL OF
INVENTORY ACCUMULATION
Surprisingly, given its widespread use by macroeconomists studying
inventory accumulation, the original
model developed by economists to

However, V.V. Chari of the University of
Minnesota and the Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis and Mitchell Berlin of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia have
independently noted, in separate discussions
with me, that long-term relationships between
sellers and manufacturers may imply that the
production-smoothing model is applicable to
retail and wholesale inventories. In such
settings, manufacturers may store their
finished goods with sellers.
6

TABLE 2
Sectoral Distribution of Private Nonfarm Inventories

Manufacturing
finished goods
work in process
materials & supplies

Percentage of Total
Stock of Inventories

STD
(Inventory Investment)

Correlation (Inventory
Investment, GDP)

37
13
12
12

0.14

0.65

26
26
11

0.12
0.09

0.32
0.35

Trade
retail
wholesale
Other

Column 3, the percentages of the total stock of inventories, is taken from Ramey and West, 869, Table 4.

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q3 2003 43

explain firms’ holdings of inventories was
not the production-smoothing model. It
was the (S, s) model first formulated by
Herbert Scarf of Yale University. While
macroeconomists do not commonly use
this model, Alan Blinder and Louis
Maccini have argued that the (S, s)
model provides a natural resolution to
the empirical inconsistencies of the basic
production-smoothing model without
relying on increasing returns or cost
shocks.
The (S,s) model obtains very
different predictions because adjustment costs operate differently. Instead of
assuming that adjustment costs increase
smoothly with changes in production, in
the (S, s) model, adjustments lead to
fixed costs. Moreover, instead of arising
during production, these costs are
incurred when a firm either orders or
undertakes delivery of goods.
A firm facing such costs will
tend to order the relevant goods in large
quantities but infrequently. By ordering
more than is needed at any one time,
the firm can hold stocks of the goods,
thereby avoiding fixed order costs
because the firm orders less frequently.
By holding these stocks of goods, the
firm reduces the overall cost of ordering.
For example, consider Honda
again. In deciding the size of the
quarterly steel order for Honda’s Ohio
plant, a manager must go over last
quarter’s production and forecast future
sales. This takes a certain amount of
managerial time that is largely independent of the size of the steel order. As
such, the costs of ordering steel, which
include the labor costs associated with
the manager’s efforts, are fixed costs.
These costs are reduced when the firm
orders infrequently — that is, when it
places orders of sufficient size so as to
not have to order again for some time. In
other words, Honda will hold inventories
of steel to reduce the fixed costs of
ordering. As Herbert Scarf proved, a
firm facing such fixed costs will allow its

44 Q3 2003 Business Review

inventories to fluctuate between an
upper level labeled S and a lower level
labeled s — hence, the conventional
label (S, s). S represents the level of
inventories held by the firm after it has
restocked. It then allows its stock to fall
over time until it reaches the threshold s.
At that time, another order is placed.
Sometimes, the order costs are called
adjustment costs.
The (S, s) model is flexible
enough to be consistent with either
positive or negative correlations between
sales and inventories. To see this, assume
there’s a short-term increase in sales
across a large number of firms selling the
same product. Firms will reduce their
inventories to meet the rise in sales. For
some firms, the net effect is to reduce
inventories. For firms with already low

words, inventories will tend to move
with sales when the change in sales itself
is large. Smaller increases in sales may be
associated with a net reduction in total
inventory holdings. Thus, the model
predicts an interesting nonlinearity: we
should expect inventories and sales to
rise together when sales rise by a large
amount, but the correlation may be
negative for a small rise in sales.
In a formal analysis of (S, s)
retail inventories, Andrew Caplin
proved a positive correlation between
final sales and inventory investment. For
the reasons described above, this positive
correlation raised the variability of
production above that of sales. Caplin
concluded, “The (S, s) theory thus
contradicts the widely held notion that
retail sector inventories act as a buffer,
protecting manufacturers from fluctuat-

Overall, some firms will increase inventories
when sales increase, while others will
reduce them.
levels of inventories, this initial reduction means they reach their order
threshold, s. As a result, they will adjust
their inventories upward, raising them to
S. Overall, some firms will increase
inventories when sales increase, while
others will reduce them. On average,
the rise in sales could be associated with
either an increase or a decrease in net
inventory investment, depending on the
size of the demand shock and different
firms’ current levels of inventories.
There is an interesting subtlety
to the reasoning outlined above. A rise
in the typical firm’s inventories along
with a rise in sales is more likely if many
firms hit their re-ordering level. This is
more likely to be the case when the
increase in sales itself is large. Such
large increases in sales move most firms
to their lower threshold for inventories,
causing them to readjust. In other

ing sales.”7 Caplin’s work suggests that
inventories may indeed destabilize the
economy. However, his seminal analysis
of retail sector inventories took final
sales as given, rather than allowing them
to be determined along with inventories,
in general equilibrium. In general
equilibrium, a complete assessment of
the role of inventories would have to
allow for feedback effects from the rest
of the economy, which may change the
behavior of final sales.
(S, s) Inventories in a Model
of the Business Cycle. The (S, s)
model of inventories provides us with a
framework, broadly consistent with
observation, to study the role of
inventories over the business cycle. For

See page 1396, paragraph 2, of Caplin’s
article.
7

www.phil.frb.org

example, it allows us to examine the
central question of whether inventories
destabilize the economy and exacerbate
the movements in GDP. In a recent
paper, Julia Thomas and I did just that.
Our approach, in common
with other modern macroeconomic
analysis, relied on building a model of
the macroeconomy in which aggregate
economic variables, such as production,
consumption, investment, and employment, are the result of interactions
between households and firms, much as
in the actual economy. The essential
feature of our model is that, in keeping
with modern practice, we model the
decisions of individual households and
firms, summing these decisions to arrive
at aggregate variables for the economy
as a whole.
Our model included an (S, s)
model of a firm’s inventory investment.
Simulating our model to produce
artificial business cycles, we were able to
explain roughly one-half of the observed
volatility of inventory investment. More
important, inventory investment and
final sales moved together, as in the
data, and production, as a result, was
more volatile than sales. We also found
that the relationship between inventories and GDP is not as straightforward as
you might expect.
We compared two model
economies, identical in most fundamentals, but with one difference. Firms in
one economy had no adjustment costs
and, thus, no need to hold inventories.
Firms in the second economy faced the
costs of purchasing inputs and, thus, had
an incentive to hold inventories using an

www.phil.frb.org

(S, s) rule, as described above. In this
setting, we asked the question: If an
economist were to observe two economies with firms and consumers that
were essentially identical, but firms in
one economy held higher inventory
levels than firms in another economy,
should we expect to observe more
volatile sales in the economy with
inventories?
Our answer is that there are
really two effects. The first is straightforward. Remember the relationship
GDP = Final Sales + Net Inventory
Investment. As we discussed above, net
inventory investment in the data is
procyclical and volatile. It is also
positively correlated with final sales.
This tends to raise the variability of GDP
above that of final sales. Increases in
final sales are associated with increases
in inventory investment, and given that
both rise simultaneously, GDP rises more
than final sales. This effect is in our
model.
However, our model identified
a second effect: the introduction of
inventories reduces the volatility of final
sales. Firms facing adjustment costs —
the reason for the inventories in the first
place — change production levels less
frequently. This tends to offset the
increase in the variability of GDP.
Certainly, the introduction of inventories raised the variability of GDP
directly, but there was an offsetting
change in the volatility of final sales.
When the first effect dominates, more inventories lead to more
volatile sales and increases in the
variability of GDP. In contrast, when the

second effect dominates, higher levels of
inventories actually reduce the volatility
of sales and, thus, GDP. Which effect
dominates depends on how the many
parameters of our model interact;
however, we often found cases where
increases in the level of inventories
reduced the variability of GDP.
CONCLUSION
Economics is full of puzzles,
some of which take the form of
disparities between the best available
models and macroeconomic data. The
production-smoothing model of
inventory investment is an example of
such a puzzle.
Inventory investment is procyclical and very volatile. Furthermore,
it is positively correlated with final sales.
As a result, the sum of these two objects,
GDP, is more volatile than sales. The
production-smoothing model assumes
that since production is costly to adjust,
firms hold inventories to smooth
fluctuations in sales. The result is that
simple versions of the model predict that
production is less volatile than sales.
Some recent research has
focused on alternative explanations of
why firms hold inventories, and this has
led to a renewed emphasis on the (S, s)
model of inventory investment. The
(S, s) model, which replaces the
assumption that production is costly to
adjust with the alternative assumption
that there are costs of ordering goods,
may overturn our thinking of inventories
as existing to buffer changes in sales. BR

Business Review Q3 2003 45

REFERENCES

Blinder, Alan S. and Louis J. Maccini.
“Taking Stock: A Critical Assessment of
Recent Research on Inventories,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 5, 1991, pp. 73-96.

Prescott, Edward C. “Theory Ahead of
Business Cycle Measurement,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review, 10, 1986, pp. 9-22.

Caplin, Andrew S. “The Variability of
Aggregate Demand with (S, s) Inventory
Policies,” Econometrica, 53, 1985, pp.
1395-1410.

Ramey, Valerie A. “Nonconvex Costs and
the Behavior of Inventories,”
Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1991,
pp. 306-34.

Eichenbaum, Martin S. “Rational Expectations and the Smoothing Properties of
Inventories and Finished Goods,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 14, 1984, pp. 71-96.

Ramey, Valerie A., and Daniel J. Vine.
“Tracking the Source of the Decline in GDP
Volatility: An Analysis of the Automobile
Industry,” University of California, San
Diego Economics Department Working
Paper, 2001.

Khan, Aubhik, and Julia K. Thomas.
“Inventories and the Business Cycle: An
Equilibrium Analysis of (S, s) Policies,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Working Paper 02-20 (2002).

46 Q3 2003 Business Review

Ramey, Valerie A., and K.D. West.
“Inventories,” in M. Woodford and J. Taylor,
eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics IB.
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1999, pp.
863-927.
Scarf, Herbert E. “The Optimality of
(S, s) Policies in the Dynamic Inventory
Problem,” In Mathematical Methods in the
Social Sciences 1959. Proceedings of the First
Stanford Symposium. Stanford, Calif.:
Stanford University Press, 1959.

www.phil.frb.org

RESEARCH RAP

Summaries of
research
produced by the
economists at
the Philadelphia
Fed

You can find more Research Rap summaries on our web site at: www.phil.frb.org/econ/resrap/index.html.
Or view our Working Papers at: www.phil.frb.org/econ/wps/index.html.

DATA REVISIONS AND THE
IDENTIFICATION OF MONETARY
POLICY SHOCKS
Monetary policy research using
time-series methods has been criticized
for using revised data that were not
known to anyone during the actual period
of empirical analysis. The Philadelphia
Fed’s real-time data set, developed by
Dean Croushore and Tom Stark, however,
gives researchers access to the original
data releases that would have been used
by analysts and policymakers in a given
time period. How much of a difference
does this information make to empirical
analyses of monetary policy shocks?
This paper considers two
approaches to addressing the fact that
the macroeconomic data sets of econometricians are changing over time
because of data revisions. The first
approach is to assess the sensitivity of
vector autoregression (VAR) estimates
across different data vintages. The second
approach considers a statistical model of
data revisions and implements an alternative, real-time estimation strategy to
overcome errors-in-variables biases. The
authors conclude that the use of revised
data in VAR analyses of monetary policy
shocks may not be a serious limitation.
Working Paper 03-1, “Data
Revisions and the Identification of Monetary
Policy Shocks,” Dean Croushore,
www.phil.frb.org
w w w.phil.frb.org

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, and
Charles L. Evans, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago
THE EFFECTS OF A BABY BOOM
ON STOCK PRICES AND CAPITAL
ACCUMULATION IN THE
PRESENCE OF SOCIAL SECURITY
Is the stock market boom a result
of the baby boom? In this paper Andrew B.
Abel examines the long-term sustained
increase in the value of the stock market
over the period since 1980. He develops
an overlapping generations model in
which a baby boom is modeled as a high
realization of a random birth rate and the
price of capital is determined endogenously. A baby boom increases national
saving and investment and thus causes an
increase in the price of capital. The price
of capital is mean-reverting, so the initial
increase in the price of capital is followed
by a decrease.
Social Security, according to the
author, can potentially affect national
saving and investment, though in the long
run, it does not affect the price of capital.
Working Paper 03-2, “The Effects of
a Baby Boom on Stock Prices and Capital
Accumulation in the Presence of Social
Security,” Andrew B. Abel, The Wharton
School of the University of Pennsylvania;
NBER; and Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia
BusinessBusiness
Review Q3
Review
2003 Q3
47 2003 47

NON-EXCLUSIVE CONTRACTS, COLLATERALIZED TRADE, AND A THEORY OF AN
EXCHANGE
Liquid markets in which agents have limited
capacity to sign exclusive contracts, as well as
imperfect knowledge of previous transactions by
others, raise the risk of an agent promising the same
asset to multiple counterparties and subsequently
defaulting. In this paper, Yaron Leitner shows that in
such markets an exchange can arise as a very simple
type of intermediary whose only role is to set limits on
the number of contracts that agents can report. In
addition, reporting can be voluntary. In some cases,
these limits must be nonbinding in equilibrium, and
reported trades must not be made public. A costly
alternative to an exchange is collateralized trade,
and the gains from an exchange increase when
agents have more intangible capital or when markets
are more liquid.
Working Paper 03-3, “Non-Exclusive Contracts, Collateralized Trade, and a Theory of an Exchange,” Yaron Leitner, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
HOW STRONG IS CO-MOVEMENT IN
EMPLOYMENT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE?
In this paper, the authors measure the degree
of business-cycle co-movement in quarterly industry
employment at state and regional levels. The analysis
covers the years 1942 to 1995, a period that includes
10 national business cycles as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The data
indicate that there is co-movement in the business
cycle across industries and across states but the
degree of co-movement is relatively weak. The
results suggest that the degree of co-movement
across business cycles has risen over time and as

w w 48
w.pQ3
hil2003
.frb.Business
org
Review

regions have grown in geographic size. The authors
present evidence that the measured degree of comovement is sensitive to the chosen periodicity of
the data and that there is much greater cohesion
across states for a given industry than across different
industries within a state.
An investigation into the sources of crossstate variation in the level of business-cycle comovements reveals that important determinants
include the strength of input-output linkages within
each state, the different effects of monetary policy
actions on each state’s employment, and the degree
of industrial diversity within a state.
Working Paper 03-5, “How Strong Is CoMovement in Employment Over the Business Cycle?
Evidence from State/Industry Data,” Gerald A. Carlino,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, and Robert H.
DeFina, Villanova University
A SHORT-TERM MODEL OF THE FED’S
PORTFOLIO CHOICE
What would happen if the Federal Reserve
were to change the assets in its portfolio? In this
paper, Dean Croushore creates a model in which the
Fed, instead of using open-market operations in
Treasury securities to increase the monetary base,
engages in open-market operations in private securities or uses discount loans via a mechanism that
allows banks to borrow as much as they would like at
a fixed discount rate. The model demonstrates how a
change in the Fed’s portfolio would affect the
economy’s general equilibrium at a given point in
time.
Working Paper 03-8, “A Short-Term Model of
the Fed’s Portfolio Choice,” Dean Croushore, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

www.phil.frb.org
Business Review
Q3 2003 48