View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

How Useful Are Forecasts
Of Corporate Profits?
Dean Croushore*

I

nvestors’ forecasts of corporate profits affect
the prices of corporate stock. When a corporation announces that earnings won’t be as large
as expected, its stock price immediately drops.
Similarly, when investors think a firm will earn
higher profits than they previously thought, the
company’s stock rises in value. This positive relationship between forecasts of corporate profits and stock prices must be true for the stock

market as a whole. That is, if investors forecast
higher overall corporate earnings, that should
lead to higher overall stock prices. In the 1990s,
stock prices have grown substantially, in part
because of forecasts of higher levels of corporate
profits.1 But how accurate are those forecasts?
To investigate the accuracy of forecasts of overall U.S. corporate profits, we need to have a consistent set of forecasts. One such set comes from

*Dean Croushore is an assistant vice president and
economist in the Research Department of the Philadelphia Fed. He’s also head of the department’s macroeconomics section. Dean thanks John Duca of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas for comments on an earlier draft
of this article.

1
For a discussion of how stock prices are related to
corporate profitability in the 1990s, see the article by
John Cochrane and the article by John Carlson and Kevin
Sargent. U.S. data show strong correlations between stock
prices, corporate profits, and forecasts of corporate profits.

3

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF),
which has collected forecasts of corporate profits and many other macroeconomic variables for
over 30 years. The survey is widely respected by
academic researchers, and they often use it for
investigating the quality of forecasts of various
macroeconomic variables, especially inflation.2
In general, the forecasters who participate in the
survey are actively involved in forecasting as a
part of their jobs. The forecasters include many
Wall Street economists, along with chief economists at Fortune 500 companies, a number of
bank economists, and some economic consultants. It’s the type of group you’d expect to have a
pretty good idea about corporate profits as well
as the macroeconomic variables (such as inflation and output growth) they are asked to forecast.
DATA PROBLEMS
If we look at the raw data on the growth of
corporate profits in the U.S. economy, we see that
profits are very volatile over time (Figure 1).3 Notice that, on an annualized basis, corporate profits have occasionally risen from one quarter to
the next at a rate of over 100 percent. Data on
most macroeconomic variables, such as the

economy’s output or its industrial production,
aren’t nearly as volatile. To eliminate some of
the volatility, we’ll look at the growth in corporate profits over a year, not at quarterly data.4
The annual data series is a lot less volatile.
Unfortunately, attempts to analyze the forecasts of the growth of corporate profits are subject to a problem that’s also true of many other
variables — the data have been modified over
time. That is, the data a forecaster or stockholder
faced at a particular point in time look quite different from the data available today.
For example, let’s take a look at the reported
values for the growth of corporate profits from
1986 to 1987. If we look at the national income
data in May 1988, the growth rate of corporate
profits from 1986 to 1987 was reported as 8.5
percent. In July 1988, the numbers underwent a
minor revision, and the growth rate rose to 10.2
percent. But in July 1989, new IRS tabulations of
data from corporate tax returns led the Bureau
of Economic Analysis (BEA), the statistical

4
The variable we’ll use is the growth rate in the annual
average level of corporate profits from one year to the
next.

FIGURE 1
2

For a look at some of the details
of the survey and how it’s run, see
my 1993 article; to find out how accurate the inflation forecasts from the
survey are, see my 1996 article. I use
the SPF, rather than the Blue Chip
survey or the IBES survey, because it
began in 1968, much earlier than the
other surveys.

Quarterly Corporate-Profits Growth

3

The precise variable we’re examining is nominal (i.e., not adjusted
for inflation) after-tax corporate profits (without inventory valuation and
capital consumption adjustments)
as reported in the Survey of Current
Business from the national income
and product accounts.
4

Date
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

agency that compiles the national income ac- Survey of Professional Forecasters is taken. These
counts, to substantially reduce the value of cor- data sets show us what the official data looked
porate profits for both 1986 and 1987, but more like at the time. This real-time data set is a better
so for 1986. As a result, the growth rate of corpo- source for the numbers forecasters were trying
rate profits from 1986 to 1987 rose to 23.2 per- to predict than the data set available today, becent.
cause some of the changes in corporate-profits
An even bigger change came in December data involved redefinitions of the items included
1991, when the BEA, among other changes, re- in corporate profits; forecasters couldn’t have
classified the bad-debt losses of financial insti- foreseen those changes.
tutions as financial transactions; those losses
How well do the year-ahead forecasts comwere no longer included in the national income pare to the data, using the real-time data set? To
accounts and were not to be viewed as reducing find out, we’ll first plot the forecast for the growth
corporate profits. The result was a very large re- of corporate profits over a one-year period, then
calculation of corporate profits, especially for compare it to the actual value in the real-time
1987, when financial firms recorded very large data set (Figure 2).6 You can see that the forebad-debt losses. The impact was to increase the casts and actual growth rates move together
growth rate of corporate profits for 1987 to 44.4
percent. Minor revisions since then have re6
duced the growth rate to 43.5 percent.
The forecasts are taken from the November Survey
of
Professional
Forecasters each year, from 1968 to 1996.
So, occasionally the data for corporate profits
The
forecast
variable
is the growth rate of corporate profare revised quite extensively. Most of the time,
its from the year in which the survey was taken to the
the revisions aren’t as extensive as they were for
following year, based on annual average data. For ex1987, but they can still be substantial.
ample, the November 1968 survey forecasts how much
Getting around this problem of data revisions higher profits are expected to be in 1969 than they were
is not easy. We’re going to attempt to do so using in 1968.
the following technique: we’re
going to take data sets that
FIGURE 2
were created not long after the
Corporate Profits
forecasts were formulated, be(SPF
Forecasts
and Real-Time Actuals)
cause information available at
that time is what affected stock
prices. First, we’ve created a
special set of data, called a realtime data set.5 Based on data
published in the Survey of Current Business from 1965 to the
present, this data set contains
the data available to a forecaster in mid-November each
year, the same time at which the

5
Details on this data set can be
found in my 1999 paper with Tom
Stark.

Date
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

pretty well in the 1970s, despite the oil-price
shocks in that period. Overall, the forecasts were
not too bad in the 1980s. The forecasters missed
the downturn in profits from 1980 to 1982, and
their forecasts didn’t capture the volatility in
profits in the late 1980s, but they did get the average about right. Forecasts in the 1990s haven’t
been too bad either; they were just a bit too pessimistic about the growth of profits from 1994 to
1997.
Another way to see the relationship between
the forecasts and the real-time actual data is to
use a scatter plot that compares the actual data
with the forecasts (Figure 3). If the forecasts are
accurate, the points in the scatter plot should lie
along the 45-degree line shown in the figure. A
data point close to that 45-degree line means that
the growth rate being forecast is close to the actual growth rate of corporate profits. The further
away a point is from the 45-degree line, the greater
the error and the poorer the forecast.
From the scatter plot, it looks like the forecasts for the growth rate of corporate profits are

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

pretty good. The data points are close to the 45degree line, with a few exceptions, which means
the forecast errors are usually fairly small.

STATISTICAL TESTS
FOR FORECAST QUALITY
Although examining figures that plot the forecasts along with the actual values is interesting
and graphically illustrates how good the forecasts are, we can also use statistical theory to
perform more formal tests of the quality of the
forecasts. Economists have developed a number
of tests that forecasts must pass to be considered
high quality.
All of the tests that follow look at the relationship between the forecasts and the actual values
and allow for the fact that no forecast is perfect.
After all, the economy is very difficult to predict,
and many things can cause a forecast to go awry.
We’re going to look at two different ideas about
forecast quality: (1) high-quality forecasts should
be rational, and (2) high-quality forecasts should
be better than simple alternatives.
A forecast is said to be rational when forecast errors are not
predictable in advance. If they
FIGURE 3
were, it would be possible to
Corporate Profits
create a better forecast. For ex(SPF Forecasts and Real-Time Actuals)
ample, if I knew that the forecasters, on average, predicted
a growth rate of corporate profits that was three percentage
points too high, I could make a
better forecast by taking the
survey’s prediction and subtracting three percentage
points. For a forecast to be considered rational, no such
method of changing a forecast
must lead to a better forecast.
The second test of forecast
quality is a forecast’s ability to
beat simple alternative forecasts. We should expect forecasts from our survey to be sig-

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

nificantly better (in the sense of having smaller result suggests that the forecasts are potentially
errors) than some simple alternative methods of useful and can’t be easily improved upon.
forecasting. For example, suppose we found that
If we look at a plot of the forecast errors (the
the forecast errors from the Survey of Professional actual value for the growth rate of corporate profForecasters were larger, on average, than the er- its minus the forecast at each date), we see they
rors from a forecast that assumes corporate profit are occasionally large (Figure 4). But the foregrowth will be 10 percent every year. Then we’d cast errors don’t show any predictable pattern,
think, with good reason, that the survey’s fore- which means it would be difficult for someone
cast was poor because it was worse than a naive to make a better forecast than the one provided
forecast.
by the survey forecasters.
We begin by testing to see if the survey forecasts are rational. We need statistical theory in
these tests because, as noted above, there will
7
To perform this test, we regress the actual value for
always be errors in forecasts. The statistical ques- corporate-profits growth each year on a constant and the
tion is: are the forecast errors unpredictable forecast value. If the forecast were perfect, the constant
enough that we should consider the forecasts term would be zero, and the coefficient on the forecast
rational? Or are they so predictable that we would be one. But, of course, there are certain to be some
should reject the notion of rationality for the fore- errors in the forecasts, which cause the coefficients to
differ from zero and one, so we must use statistical
casts? The average error in the forecasts for the theory to see how different from zero and one the coeffigrowth rate of corporate profits was one percent- cients are. Thus, we run a statistical test to see whether
age point. But in this case, the one-percentage- the constant term is significantly different from zero and
point average error is not statistically significant, the coefficient on the forecast is statistically different
because the growth rate of corporate profits is so from one. If they are significantly different from zero and
one, we say the forecast isn’t rational. Our tests show
variable from year to year that finding a one- they are not significantly different from zero and one.
percentage-point error isn’t surprising or un- Further details on the statistical tests in this article can be
usual. So one could not convincingly argue that found in the Appendix.
the forecasts aren’t rational
just because on average they
FIGURE 4
are slightly higher than acSPF Corporate Profit Forecast Errors
tual growth of profits.
(Real-Time Actuals)
A common statistical test
for rationality is a test for
unbiasedness, which uses a
technique known as regression analysis. The regression
analysis determines whether
the points lie along the 45degree line in the scatter plot
(Figure 3).7 In this case, the
test doesn’t reject the hypothesis that the forecasts are unbiased; visually, there is a
rough balance between the
points below the 45-degree
line and those above. This
7

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

If the value of the test statistic is less than the
critical value, the test supports the notion that
the forecasts are rational.9
In summary, all the tests support the view that
the forecasts of corporate-profits growth from the
Survey of Professional Forecasters are rational.
The second type of test for forecast quality
compares the forecasts from the survey to some
alternative forecasts. One alternative is to form
a naive forecast, in which the forecast for next
year’s growth rate of profits equals the value
from last year. Another possibility is to forecast
that corporate-profits growth equals its long-run
average. Yet another possibility is to assume that
corporate-profits growth simply equals its average over the last five years. When we try these
alternatives, however, the errors are always much
worse than the errors from the survey forecasts.
A good summary measure of overall forecast
accuracy is the root mean squared error of the
forecast.10 When we look at the root mean
squared error of the survey forecasts, compared
8
to the alternative forecasts, we see that the surThe first line of the table reports the test results that
vey has a lower root mean squared error than
show the forecast is unbiased. Additional information
about the other tests can be found in the Appendix.
any of the alternatives (Table 2).
Although the survey
forecasts pass all these
TABLE 1
statistical tests, we are left
wondering a bit about
Tests for Forecast Rationality
these results, because the
forecast errors are someTest
Value of Test Statistic
Critical Value
Rational?
A variety of statistical tests that examine the
forecasts show the forecast errors to be unpredictable and balanced, a sign of good-quality
forecasts. The various tests run on the forecasts
include the sign test, which examines whether
there are the same number of positive and negative forecast errors; the Wilcoxon signed-rank test,
which examines whether the magnitude of positive and negative forecast errors are the same;
the zero-mean test, which examines whether the
forecast errors are significantly different from
zero; and the Dufour test, which looks to see if
the forecast error for one year is independent of
the forecast error from the previous year. The
forecasts pass all these tests with flying colors
(Table 1).8 The table provides the value of the test
statistic, along with the critical value to which
that test statistic is to be compared, and whether
the test supports the rationality of the forecasts.

Unbiasedness test

0.23

3.37

yes

Sign test

0.56

1.96

yes

Wilcoxon
signed-rank test

0.07

1.96

yes

Zero-mean test

0.64

2.04

yes

Dufour test

1.32

1.96

yes

Note: The test is consistent with rationality of the forecast when the value of
the test statistic is less than its critical value.

8

9
To see how the forecasts
would fare in these tests using today’s data, as opposed
to the real-time data set, see
Corporate Profits Data Today.
10
The root mean squared
error is calculated by taking
the forecast errors at each
date, squaring them, adding
them together, dividing by the
number of data points, and
taking the square root.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

Corporate Profits Data Today
How much difference would it make to use today’s data on corporate profits, instead of the realtime data set used in this article? The choice of which data to use makes a difference, especially at
particular dates. If we plot the data from today over time and compare it to the real-time data, we see
that the new definitions and recalculations of the data are important, especially at certain dates, such
as 1987 (Figure). The figure shows that
the difference in the growth rate of
Corporate Profits
corporate profits between the differ(SPF Forecasts and Actuals)
ent data sets is as much as 33 percentage points!
How much difference would this
have made to our statistical tests?
Using the latest vintage of the data
would increase the average forecast
error to three percentage points
(higher than the one-percentagepoint average error based on the realtime data). Despite that, when we run
all the statistical tests reported in Table
1 and the alternative forecasts reported in Table 2, using the latest data,
the forecasts still pass all the tests, but
not by as large a margin.
Date

times large. It’s not clear why that should be the
case. But a close look at the data reveals a good
reason why the forecasts pass the tests despite
the occasional large errors: corporate profits are
very volatile, as we saw in Figure 1. Forecasting
TABLE 2

Tests for Improving Forecasts
Alternative

Root Mean
Squared Error

Survey

8.9

Naive

15.8

Constant Average Value

11.9

Five-Year Moving Average Value

13.5

a variable this volatile is bound to lead to large
forecast errors, as we’ve seen. However, large
forecast errors don’t indicate that the forecasts
are bad, just that the variable itself is inherently
volatile.
WHY ARE CORPORATE PROFITS
SO VOLATILE?
The main source of volatility in corporate profits seems to be the business cycle. Recessions
cause corporate profits to decline substantially
(Figure 5). As you can see from the figure, the
recessions (the shaded periods in the figure) that
began in 1969, 1973, 1980, 1981, and 1990 led to
significant declines in the growth rate of corporate profits.
Other sources of volatility in corporate profits include: (1) changes in the value of the dollar
against other currencies; (2) changes in the in9

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

porate profits until the
economy came out of the recession in late 1982 and began growing strongly in
1983.12

FIGURE 5

Corporate Profits
(Real-Time Actuals)

Date

flation rate; and (3) changes in tax laws.
Changes in the value of the dollar against
other currencies can influence corporate profits,
since large corporations depend heavily on profits from foreign operations, which are affected
by the exchange rate. When the dollar rises
against foreign currencies, profits earned abroad
in foreign currencies convert to fewer dollars, so
the dollar profits of international corporations
decline.
Uncertainty about profits can also stem from
changes in the inflation rate. Inflation introduces
a number of distortions into our accounting systems, and those systems can’t deal with inflation perfectly. For example, the manner in which
accounting methods handle the value of inventories can make a significant difference in nominal profits. As a result of problems like this,
changes in the inflation rate make profits hard
to predict.11
Changes in tax law obviously influence aftertax corporate profits, though sometimes the effects aren’t apparent for several years. Corporate taxes were cut in 1981, in the middle of a
recession, but the effects didn’t show up in cor10

SUMMARY
Corporate profits are
quite volatile. Even so, forecasts of corporate profits
from the Survey of Professional Forecasters pass a variety of statistical tests that
show they’re rational and
better than simple alternative
forecasting methods. The
forecasts line up reasonably
well with actual values.
The value of the stock
market may have risen over
the past few years partly because of forecasts of
high corporate profits. The results reported here,
concerning the forecasts of corporate profits from
the Survey of Professional Forecasters, suggest
that such forecasts have been fairly accurate,
though certainly not perfect, over the last 30
years.
What is the forecast for corporate profits for
this year? In the Survey of Professional Forecasters from the fourth quarter of 1998, the forecasters projected that corporate profits would rise
just 0.8 percent in 1999, after declining in 1998.
This represents a significant slowdown from the
growth rate of corporate profits throughout the
earlier part of the 1990s.

11

There is some controversy about this issue, since the
biggest increases in inflation were accompanied by large
increases in oil prices and economic recession. As a result, it’s hard to tell whether corporate profits really fall
because of inflation alone.
12

For more on the sources of volatility in corporate
profits, see the article by John Duca.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

REFERENCES
Carlson, John B., and Kevin H. Sargent. “The Recent Ascent of Stock Prices: Can It Be Explained by
Earnings Growth or Other Fundamentals?” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review
(1997 Quarter 2), pp. 2-12.
Cochrane, John H. “Where Is the Market Going? Uncertain Facts and Novel Theories,” Working
Paper 6207, National Bureau of Economic Research (1997).
Croushore, Dean. “Introducing: The Survey of Professional Forecasters,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Business Review, November/December 1993.
Croushore, Dean. “Inflation Forecasts: How Good Are They?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review, May/June 1996.
Croushore, Dean, and Tom Stark. “A Real-Time Data Set for Macroeconomists,” Working Paper 994, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, June 1999.
Diebold, Francis X., and Jose A. Lopez. “Forecast Evaluation and Combination,” in G.S. Maddala and
C.R. Rao, eds., Handbook of Statistics. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1996, pp. 241-68.
Duca, John V. “Has Long-Run Profitability Risen in the 1990s?” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Economic Review, Fourth Quarter 1997.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

APPENDIX
For the interested reader, this appendix explains the tests discussed in this article in more detail (see
Table 1 in the text). More information about all these tests can be found in the 1996 article by Diebold
and Lopez.
BIAS TESTS
The first test discussed in the paper is a test for unbiasedness. A set of forecasts over time is unbiased
if a regression of the actual values (the dependent variable) on a constant term and the forecasted
values (the independent variable) yields coefficients that are not significantly different from 0 for the
constant term and 1 for the forecast term. That is, the regression is:

pt = a + b ptf + et,
where pt is actual profits and ptf is the forecast at each date t. The bias test is simple and sensible: over
a long sample period, you’d expect ^
a to be close to zero and ^
b to be close to one. When we estimate
this equation, we get the following results:
_

pt = 1.380 + 0.949 p tf,
(2.15) (0.216)

R2 = 0.21, D.W. = 0.17, F = .23, F* = 3.37,

_
where R2 is the adjusted R2 statistic, D.W. is the Durbin-Watson statistic, numbers in parentheses are
standard errors, F is the value of the test statistic for the joint hypothesis that a is zero and b is one, and
F* is the critical value of that statistic. Since F < F*, we don’t reject the null hypothesis.
Sign Test. If a forecast is optimal, the forecast errors should be independent with a zero median.
The sign test examines this null hypothesis by examining the number of positive forecast errors in the
sample, which has a binomial distribution. Since the studentized version of the statistic is standard
normal, we assess its significance with the normal distribution. The test statistic has a value of 0.56,
less than the critical value of 1.96, so we don’t reject the null hypothesis that the forecast errors have
zero median.
Wilcoxon Signed-Rank Test. The Wilcoxon signed-rank test is related to the sign test, since it has
the same null hypothesis, but requires distributional symmetry. It accounts for the relative sizes of
the forecast errors, not just their sign. The test statistic is the sum of the ranks of the absolute values
of the positive forecast errors, where the forecast errors are ranked in increasing order. The studentized
value of the statistic is normally distributed. The test statistic has a value of 0.07, while the critical value
is 1.96, so we don’t reject the null hypothesis.
Zero-Mean Test. Optimal forecasts should pass a simple test: the mean of the forecast errors
should be zero. The mean of the forecast errors divided by its standard error is 0.64, which is less than
the critical value of 2.04, so we don’t reject the null hypothesis that the mean of the forecast errors is
zero.
Dufour Test. Dufour adapts the Wilcoxon signed-rank test and applies it to the product of successive forecast errors. This is a stringent test of the hypothesis that the forecast errors are white noise
and serially independent, in particular that they are symmetric about zero. The value of the test
statistic is 1.32, less than the critical value of 1.96, thus we don’t reject the null hypothesis that forecast
errors are white noise.

12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Useful Are Forecasts of Corporate Profits?

Dean Croushore

The Philadelphia Story:
A New Forecasting Model
For the Region
Theodore M. Crone and Michael P. McLaughlin*

F

orecasts of the national economy have long
been a staple of the planning and budgeting process for large corporations and the federal government. But for small firms and state and local
governments, a forecast of the regional economy
may be more important to their planning process. This demand for regional forecasts challenges the professional forecaster to develop
models that produce accurate predictions of the
major economic variables for states and metro-

politan areas. Several years ago, the Philadelphia Fed developed a small forecasting model
for each of the three states in the Third Federal
Reserve District — Pennsylvania, New Jersey,
and Delaware.1 This article introduces a similar
model that forecasts major economic variables
for the Philadelphia metropolitan area and the
city of Philadelphia.
For the metro area as a whole, the model suggests continued job growth through mid-year

*Ted Crone is a vice president and economist and
Mike McLaughlin is a research associate at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

1
Theodore M. Crone, “A Slow Recovery in the Third
District,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Business
Review (July/August 1992).

13

BUSINESS REVIEW

2000. For the city of Philadelphia, the outlook is
not so bright. The model predicts that the city
will lose a significant number of jobs between
the second quarter of 1999 and the second quarter of 2000.

GOOD REASONS TO FORECAST THE
PHILADELPHIA ECONOMY
The Philadelphia metropolitan area is a natural choice as a region for developing an economic
forecast. It is one of the nation’s largest metro
areas, and it has a diverse economy. Moreover,
the area’s business cycle is similar, though not
identical, to the national cycle.
Metropolitan areas in general represent logical geographic divisions for forecasting economic activity because “the general concept
adopted for the determination of a standard
metropolitan area was that each area should represent an integrated economic unit with a large
volume of daily travel and communication between a central city and the outlying parts of the
area.”2 The Philadelphia metropolitan area is
the fourth largest in the United States and still
conforms to the classic description of a metropolitan area — an integrated economy with a
densely populated central city to which a large
number of workers commute from surrounding
suburbs. In 1990, almost a quarter of a million
people commuted to the city of Philadelphia to
work — about one-third of the wage and salaried workers in the city. The Philadelphia metro
area has a population of almost 5 million and
supplies more than 2.25 million nonfarm jobs,
slightly less than 2 percent of the national totals

2
U.S. Bureau of the Census, County and City Data
Book, 1949. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Office, p. iv. The Philadelphia metropolitan area includes
five counties in Pennsylvania (Philadelphia, Bucks,
Chester, Delaware, and Montgomery) and four counties
in New Jersey (Burlington, Camden, Gloucester, and Salem).

14

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

in both cases. The area has more people and jobs
than 30 states, and the city of Philadelphia alone
has a larger population and more jobs than 12
states. The Philadelphia metro area contains
more than 40 percent of the population in the
Third Federal Reserve District and about 50 percent of the jobs.
The Philadelphia economy is not only large,
it’s also diverse. We would expect the distribution of jobs in few, if any, metropolitan areas to
exactly mirror the distribution in the nation as a
whole, but the distribution in Philadelphia
comes close. Jobs in the Philadelphia area are
somewhat more concentrated in financial and
nonfinancial services than in the nation as a
whole, and the other major job categories (construction, manufacturing, transportation and
utilities, trade, and government) are somewhat
underrepresented in the Philadelphia economy.3
Despite these differences, the distribution of jobs
in the Philadelphia area mirrors the national
distribution fairly closely when compared to the
other nine largest metropolitan areas in the country. (See Measuring the Relative Importance of Industries Across Metropolitan Areas.)
Even though the structure of the Philadelphia
economy has closely resembled the national
economy in recent decades, significant shifts
have occurred in the last 30 years. Prior to the
1980s, the Philadelphia area had a larger proportion of its jobs in the manufacturing sector
than the nation. But Philadelphia has been losing manufacturing jobs at a much faster pace
than the nation, so the region’s economy is now
less manufacturing oriented than the U.S.

3
The Philadelphia area has about 6.8 percent more of
its jobs in nonfinancial services and about 1.1 percent
more in financial services than the nation. The area has
an especially high concentration of jobs in the insurance
industry, legal services, health services, social services,
and private education. The underrepresentation in Philadelphia ranges from 0.5 percent for transportation and
public utilities to 3.1 percent for government (federal,
state, and local).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

HowPhiladelphia
Useful Are Forecasts
of Corporate
Profits?
The
Story: A New
Forecasting
Model for the Region

Croushore
Theodore M. Crone and MichaelDean
P. McLaughlin

Measuring the Relative Importance
Of Industries Across Metropolitan Areas
One measure of a metro area’s relative specialization in a given industry is the “location quotient.”
This quotient is calculated as the proportion of an area’s employment (or output) in a given industry
divided by the proportion of the nation’s employment (or output) in that industry. A location quotient
equal to one indicates that the industry in question is neither over- nor underrepresented in the
region relative to the nation. Industries with location quotients greater than one have relatively more
importance in the region than in the nation. The reverse is true for industries with location quotients
less than one. The table presents location quotients for the major industry divisions in the 10 largest
metropolitan areas. Since output measures are not available at the metropolitan level, these location
quotients are based on nonfarm employment.
Philadelphia’s location quotients range from 0.75 for construction and mining to 1.23 for nonfinancial business and personal services.* This means that the proportion of jobs in construction and
mining in the Philadelphia metro area is 25 percent less than the proportion nationwide. Similarly, the
proportion of jobs in nonfinancial services in Philadelphia is 23 percent higher than the proportion in
the United States. Three of the other top 10 metro areas (Los Angeles, New York, and Boston) have a
lower percentage of their jobs in construction and mining than does Philadelphia. And New York,
Washington, and Boston have a higher percentage of jobs in nonfinancial services than Philadelphia.
Every one of the other nine metro areas in the table except Chicago has at least one location quotient
that is lower than Philadelphia’s lowest, and every one has at least one location quotient that is higher
than Philadelphia’s highest. For each of the major industry divisions, Philadelphia’s location quotient
ranks between fourth and seventh among the top 10 metropolitan areas. None of Philadelphia’s
location quotients are at the extremes among the nation’s largest metro areas.

TABLE
Location Quotients for Major Industries in the 10 Largest Metropolitan Areas
Metro Area

Construction and
Mining*

Los Angeles
New York
Chicago
Philadelphia
Washington
Detroit
San Francisco/
Oakland
Houston
Atlanta
Boston

Manufacturing

Transportation and
Public
Utilities

Trade

Finance,
Insurance
and
Real Estate

Nonfinancial
Services

Government

0.59
0.61
0.77
0.75
1.00
0.77

1.14
0.52
1.07
0.89
0.27
1.39

1.09
1.11
1.19
0.91
0.89
0.87

0.95
0.75
0.96
0.94
0.80
1.01

0.98
2.19
1.31
1.20
0.94
0.92

1.10
1.25
1.07
1.23
1.32
1.04

0.87
1.00
0.76
0.80
1.45
0.70

0.90
2.00
0.98
0.61

0.68
0.74
0.73
0.77

1.38
1.36
1.64
0.83

0.93
0.97
1.14
0.92

1.41
0.91
1.14
1.43

1.12
1.03
1.00
1.32

0.93
0.82
0.80
0.75

*Because there are so few jobs in the mining and extractive industries in the Philadelphia area, the Bureau
of Labor Statistics combines the employment data for this sector with data for the construction industry.

15

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

economy.4 The loss of manufacturing jobs has
been a major factor in keeping Philadelphia’s
overall job growth below the U.S. average.5 Nonfarm job growth in the metro area has averaged
less than 1 percent a year since 1967, compared
with 2 percent a year for the nation.
Although trend growth in the Philadelphia
area has been slower than the national average,
the business cycles have been similar. Since the
late 1960s, both the nation and the metro area
have suffered five periods of sustained job losses
(losses lasting two consecutive quarters or more).
The national and regional downturns have occurred at approximately the same time, but
downturns in the Philadelphia area have tended
to begin a bit earlier and last a bit longer. In most
cases, the differences in timing have been narrow. At all but two of the 10 turning points, the
cyclical high or low employment levels in the
metro area were within one quarter of the cyclical highs and lows in the nation (Figure 1).6 Job
growth in the metro area is also much more vola-

tile than job growth in the nation, and there have
been isolated quarters in some expansions when
the metro area has lost jobs.
USING NATIONAL AND REGIONAL
DATA TO FORECAST
THE PHILADELPHIA ECONOMY
Since the cyclical patterns of the national and
regional economies are similar, one way to forecast the metro area’s economy would be to take a
national forecast and assume that the Philadelphia economy would follow the same pattern,
6
The history of job growth in the city of Philadelphia
has been somewhat different. For most of the past 30
years, the city has been losing jobs. Nevertheless, the
national and metro area patterns are reflected in the city
data. When national job growth has been strong, losses
in the city have been less severe, and when the nation was
losing jobs, losses in the city were even larger. The city’s
tax structure sets its economy apart as a distinct segment of the metro area’s economy. For evidence of how
the city’s tax structure affects its job growth relative to
the nation’s, see Robert P. Inman, “Can Philadelphia Escape Its Fiscal Crisis With Another Tax Increase?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Business Review (September/October, 1992).

4
Since their peak in 1967, manufacturing jobs in the
Philadelphia metro area have declined almost 50 percent, while the nation has lost
about 4 percent of its manufacFIGURE 1
turing jobs. Manufacturing jobs
in the nation did not peak until
1979. Some of the reasons for the
(Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate)
decline of manufacturing jobs in
the Third District states are outlined in Theodore M. Crone,
“Where Have All the Factory Jobs
Gone—and Why?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Business Review (May/June 1997).

Quarterly Job Growth

5

The loss of manufacturing
jobs is not the only factor, however. Nonmanufacturing jobs
have been increasing in the area,
but not nearly as fast as in the
nation. Nonmanufacturing jobs
in the Philadelphia area have increased almost 80 percent since
1967, but nationally they have
risen more than 130 percent.
16

Shaded areas represent national recessions.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

HowPhiladelphia
Useful Are Forecasts
of Corporate
Profits?
The
Story: A New
Forecasting
Model for the Region

but at a somewhat slower pace. For example, we
might assume that in expansions, job growth in
the Philadelphia area would be half as strong as
growth at the national level, and that in economic downturns, job losses would be half again
as great in Philadelphia as in the nation. But
this type of forecast would ignore the relationship between job growth in the Philadelphia area
and other measures of the national economy,
such as industrial production and housing construction. Job growth in the Philadelphia area
may be systematically related not only to overall
job growth in the nation but also to which segments of the national economy are growing.
Moreover, growth in the Philadelphia area
has its own momentum. In the 1970s, annual job
growth in the Philadelphia metropolitan area
was almost 2 percent below the national average; in the 1980s, it was only one-third of 1 percent below the national average; and in the
1990s, it has been somewhere in between. To
capture as many of these relationships as possible, forecasters build models that relate several national and regional variables to one another, then estimate the strength of the relationships from historical data. We have built such a
model using variables for the nation, the metro
area, and the city.
Our Focus Is the Region. We are most interested in a forecast of nonfarm employment and
the unemployment rate for the metropolitan area
and the city. Nonfarm employment is the most
comprehensive, timely measure of economic activity available for the metro area or the city.7
And economic analysts regularly point to
changes in nonfarm employment and the level

7

We would like to have a broad measure of regional
output such as “gross regional product” that would be
analogous to gross domestic product — the most comprehensive measure of output for the nation. Unfortunately, we do not have such a measure. Personal income
data are available for the metropolitan area, but they are
published with a considerable lag and only on an annual
basis, so we cannot use them in our quarterly model.

Croushore
Theodore M. Crone and MichaelDean
P. McLaughlin

of the unemployment rate as indicators of the
strength or weakness of regional economies, and
not without justification. At the national level,
changes in these two variables are important
factors in determining official business cycles.8
At the metropolitan level, there are no official
business cycles, and changes in employment
and the unemployment rate are the best indicators of the cycle.
Our forecast model includes two other regional variables: housing permits and initial
unemployment claims, both for the metro area.9
Housing permits and initial unemployment
claims follow a cyclical pattern, but they tend to
lead the general business cycle at the national
level. That is, housing permits tend to decline
and initial unemployment claims tend to rise
before the onset of a downturn or recession. For
this reason, changes in permits and initial unemployment claims are useful in forecasting
more comprehensive measures of the economy,
such as employment and the unemployment
rate.10
Thus, our Philadelphia model contains six
regional variables: four for the metropolitan area
and two for the city of Philadelphia. These six
variables are the ones we are most interested in
forecasting. We supplement these with eight
national variables, which are mainly used to

8

Geoffrey H. Moore, Business Cycles, Inflation, and Forecasting, NBER Studies in Business Cycles No. 24, Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, 1983. Peaks and troughs in nonfarm employment and the unemployment rate do not
always coincide with the official beginning or end of national business cycles, however.
9
Housing permits are also available for the city of
Philadelphia, but the numbers are very small and the
pattern is erratic, so we did not use the city housing
permits in our model.
10

There is independent interest in forecasts of housing
permits because they are the best regional measure of
residential construction, and our model produces a forecast of housing permits for the Philadelphia area.
17

BUSINESS REVIEW

help forecast the metro-area and city variables.11
We include all the national counterparts to the
regional variables in the model. We also include
some national variables, such as real gross domestic product, because they are comprehensive
measures of the U.S. economy. Finally, we include some financial variables, such as the difference between the yield on 10-year Treasury
bonds and the federal funds rate (the overnight
interbank loan rate) because they have been
found useful in forecasting the national economy
and are valuable in forecasting some of the
metro-area and city variables in our model.12
A Small Time-Series Model. Our Philadelphia model differs from the large structural models used by most major consulting firms to predict the nation’s economy. These structural models attempt to specify a full range of economic
relationships among many variables, and economic theory plays a critical role in how the variables are allowed to interact. Good structural
models of this type require a large number of
variables.13 Since few regional variables are available on a quarterly basis, these large structural
models are not a practical option for forecasting
the Philadelphia economy.
In the late 1970s and early 1980s, researchers
at the Minneapolis Fed developed small time11

The national variables in the model are real gross
domestic product, nonfarm employment, the unemployment rate, industrial production, housing permits, initial unemployment claims, the difference between the
yield on 10-year Treasury bonds and the federal funds
rate, and the inflation rate. All the variables in the model
except the unemployment rates, the inflation rate, and
the spread in interest rates are included as logarithms of
the quarterly levels.
12

See Ben S. Bernanke, “On the Predictive Power of
Interest Rates and Interest Rate Spreads,” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, New England Economic Review (November/December 1990).
13
The national models produced by DRI and Macroeconomic Advisers, for example, consist of more than
250 variables.

18

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

series models that overcame the need for such a
large number of economic variables and that
were useful for forecasting state and regional
economies.14 Our Philadelphia model is a variant of those models.
Time-series models emphasize the statistical
regularities among economic variables over time
rather than the underlying theoretical relationships, but they are not totally divorced from
theory. For example, theory suggests which variables should be included in the models. Moreover, some basic assumptions can help solve the
problem of “overfitting,” which occurs when we
try to forecast a particular variable, say, the
metro-area unemployment rate, using a relatively
large number of other variables.15 If we use too
many variables, the model we estimate based on
past relationships may explain the historical data
well but may not produce a very good forecast.
In other words, we can overfit the model by estimating influences of one variable on another that
reflect not only the stable relationships among
the variables but also those relationships that
were peculiar to the period from which the data
were drawn. When the model is used to forecast,
these temporary patterns will be projected into
the future, diminishing the accuracy of the forecast.
A common way to limit the number of explanatory variables in time-series models is to
allow the national variables to affect the regional

14

See Paul A. Anderson, “Help for the Regional Economic Forecaster: Vector Autoregression,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review (Summer
1979).
15
In our Philadelphia model we have 92 observations
for each variable (quarterly data from 1976 to 1998).
Our explanatory variables include four lagged values
for each of the 14 variables in the model, so there are 56
potential explanatory variables in each equation. If we
allow all the potential explanatory variables to help account for the historical pattern of a particular variable,
we may end up overfitting the model for forecasting
purposes.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

HowPhiladelphia
Useful Are Forecasts
of Corporate
Profits?
The
Story: A New
Forecasting
Model for the Region

ones, but not vice versa. In effect, this assumes
that the regional variables, such as the unemployment rate for the metro area or the city, have
no independent effect on the national economy.
We apply the same principle to the metro-area
and city variables. The metro-area variables are
allowed to affect the city variables, but not vice
versa.16
Researchers at the Minneapolis Fed made
some other major assumptions that helped address the overfitting problem. Most important,
they assumed that the best predictor of a given
variable, say, this quarter’s unemployment rate,
is its value in the most recent past.17 So, the first
stage in developing a model is to forecast each
variable using only its own past values. Past
values of other variables are added to the equation only if including them lowers the forecast
error for the time beyond the period in which the
model is estimated. For example, using data up
to the fourth quarter of 1988, we would estimate
a model in which the equation for the unemployment rate contains only past values of the
unemployment rate. We would then estimate a
model in which the equation for the unemployment rate also contains the past values of another variable, such as initial unemployment

16
In technical language, the model is “block recursive.” Any national variable can be affected only by its
past values and the past values of the other national
variables. Any metro-area variable can be affected by its
past values and the past values of the national or other
metro-area variables. And each of the city variables can
be affected by the past values of any variable in the
model.
17

In the literature, this is known as one of the Minnesota priors. Another Minnesota prior is that recent values of a variable are more important than distant values
in determining its current level. Because of the role of
prior beliefs in developing these time-series models, they
are called Bayesian vector autoregression models. For a
full technical description of the models, see Thomas Doan,
Robert Litterman, and Christopher Sims, “Forecasting
and Conditional Projection Using Realistic Prior Distributions,” Econometric Reviews, 3 (1984), pp. 1-100.

Croushore
Theodore M. Crone and MichaelDean
P. McLaughlin

claims. If the model that includes unemployment
claims results in a smaller forecast error in the
period after 1988, initial unemployment claims
are included in the final equation for the unemployment rate.18 This process limits the number
of variables that influence each of the regional
variables in our model (Table 1).
We decided on which variables to include in
the Philadelphia model and how much influence they would have on the regional forecast in
this way: We included any variable that reduced
the out-of-sample forecast errors over the past
10 years. Thus, we assumed that the pattern of
relationships among the variables in the near
term would follow this recent historical pattern
more closely than the pattern over the entire period for which we have data.19
THE NEAR-TERM FORECAST
FOR THE METRO AREA AND THE CITY
Even though we have included many national
variables in our forecast model, our primary interest is in the variables for the metropolitan area
18

We also restrict the degree to which a variable such
as initial unemployment claims influences the unemployment rate to provide the best “out-of-sample” forecast of the unemployment rate. For each equation in our
model, we test the forecast value of each of the variables
one by one. We add a variable and re-estimate the model
using data through the end of 1988; we then calculate
the root mean squared errors of the forecasts after that
date. We then re-estimate the model through the first
quarter of 1989, and so on quarter by quarter, producing
forecasts and calculating the out-of-sample forecast errors from those models. In our final model, we incorporate those variables that result in the lowest root mean
squared error based on the four-quarter-ahead forecasts
over a 10-year period.
19

We also experimented with a model in which the
parameters would change over time to pick up any
change in the relationship among the variables. This
model with time-varying parameters lowered the outof-sample forecast errors for some of our regional variables but increased the errors for others. Therefore, we
did not incorporate time-varying parameters in our
model.
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

TABLE 1

National and Other Regional Variables That Affect
Each of the Regional Variables in the Philadelphia Model*

National Variables
Used in Forming the Forecast

Variable Being Forecast
Metro-area
nonfarm
jobs

Metro-area
unemployment
rate

Metro-area
housing
permits

Gross
domestic
product

Unemployment
rate

Unemployment
rate

Housing
permits

Gross
domestic
product

Unemployment
rate

Nonfarm
employment

Housing
permits

Housing
permits

Inflation
rate

Housing
permits

Housing
permits

Unemployment
Initial
rate
unemployment
claims
Industrial
production

Inflation rate

Metro-area
City nonfarm
City
initial
jobs
unemployment
unemployment
rate
claims

Spread between
10-yr Treasuries
and fed
funds rate

Inflation rate

Housing
permits
Initial
unemployment
claims
Spread between
10-yr Treasuries
and fed
funds rate

Metro- Area Variables
Used in Forming the Forecast

Inflation rate

Unemployment
Initial
rate
unemployment
claims
Housing
permits

Unemployment
rate

Housing
permits

Housing
permits

Initial
unemployment
claims

Initial
unemployment
claims

*Each equation also contains four lags of the variable being forecast.

20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

HowPhiladelphia
Useful Are Forecasts
of Corporate
Profits?
The
Story: A New
Forecasting
Model for the Region

and the city of Philadelphia, especially nonfarm
employment and the unemployment rate. From
the second quarter of 1998 to the second quarter
of 1999, nonfarm jobs increased 1.3 percent in
the Philadelphia metro area and 1.2 percent in
the city, the first meaningful job growth in the
city since 1987. By the second quarter of 1999,
the unemployment rate in the city had fallen to
5.4 percent, its lowest level in almost a decade,
and the unemployment rate in the metropolitan
area was just 4.0 percent.

Croushore
Theodore M. Crone and MichaelDean
P. McLaughlin

What does our forecast model predict for the
second half of 1999 and the first half of 2000?
For the metropolitan area, our new Philadelphia
model is predicting job growth of 1.6 percent between the second quarter of 1999 and the second quarter of 2000, and the unemployment rate
is predicted to fall slightly to 3.8 percent (Table
2).20 The model forecasts that total housing per20
For the national variables, our model predicts real
GDP growth of 2.0 percent from 1999:II to 2000:II, and

TABLE 2

Forecasts from the Philadelphia Model
Variable

Previous period
1998:II-1999:II

Forecast
1999:II-2000:II

Root mean squared error
of four-quarters-ahead
forecast 1989-1998*
Percentage points

Metro-area nonfarm
job growth

1.3%

1.6%

1.2

City nonfarm job growth

1.2%

-1.5%

1.3

Previous period
1999:II

Forecast
2000:II

Metro-area
unemployment rate

4.0%

3.8%

0.6

City unemployment rate

5.4%

5.3%

0.8

Previous period
1998:III to 1999:II
over
1997:III to 1998:II

Forecast
1999:III to 2000:II
over
1998:III to 1999:II

1.0%

-2.6%

Metro-area housing
permits**

*The square root of the average of the squared values of the errors in the forecasts for four quarters ahead
for the years 1989 to 1998.
**Since housing permits at the metropolitan area level are so volatile from quarter to quarter, we report
growth on a four-quarter-average basis.
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1999

mits issued in the metro area from the third quarter of 1999 through the second quarter of 2000
will be 2.6 percent lower than in the previous
four quarters. The forecast for the city of Philadelphia is not as rosy. Our model predicts that
job losses will resume, and the city will give up
most of the jobs it has gained since the end of
1997. The unemployment rate in the city, however, is expected to be just 5.3 percent in the second quarter of 2000. Unlike the situation with
most published forecasts from large structural
models, no forecaster’s independent judgment
was used to alter the forecasts generated by our
model.
How accurate are these forecasts likely to be?
No forecasting model is 100 percent accurate,
and our Philadelphia model is no exception.
Moreover, forecasts of smaller segments of the
economy tend to be less accurate than forecasts
of the national economy as a whole. One way to
gauge the accuracy of a forecast is to look at the
forecast errors from the model over the recent
past. In Table 2, we have reported the root mean
squared errors over the past 10 years of the forecasts produced by our model.21 Using the root

mean squared errors as a guide, we can say that
about two-thirds of the time, metro-area job
growth will be within 1.2 percentage points of
what we report in Table 2.22 The dashed line in
Figure 2 shows the four-quarter-ahead forecast
for metropolitan employment from 1989 to 1998,
with a band of 1.2 percent (shaded area) on either side of the forecast. The solid line shows the
actual level of employment in this period; it was
within the band around the forecast more than
75 percent of the time. Based on the root mean
squared error, city job growth will likely be within
1.3 percentage points of what we report in Table
2. For example, our model is forecasting a substantial decline in city jobs (1.5 percent), but
based on the forecast errors over the past 10 years,

squared errors, dividing by the total number of forecast
errors (40), and then taking the square root. This measure of accuracy puts more emphasis on large errors
than on small ones.
22
This assumes that the recent forecast errors are a
good estimate of future ones and that the errors are
normally distributed.

FIGURE 2
DRI and Macroeconomic Advisors are forecasting growth of 2.3
percent. Our model’s predicted
unemployment rate for 2000:II
is within 0.2 percentage point of
their forecasts. Our time-series
model is predicting considerably
faster job growth than these large
macro models (about 230,000
new jobs per month versus
130,000 new jobs for the two
commercial forecasters).

Four-Quarter-Ahead Forecasts and Actual
Employment Levels
(Philadelphia Metropolitan Area)

21

We concentrated on the root
mean squared errors of the forecasts for the period four quarters ahead of the actual data. This
statistic is calculated by squaring the four-quarter-ahead forecast error for each quarter from
1989:I to 1998:IV, adding these
22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

HowPhiladelphia
Useful Are Forecasts
of Corporate
Profits?
The
Story: A New
Forecasting
Model for the Region

there is some chance (about 15 percent) that job
losses will be negligible or that the number of
jobs in the city will increase, not decline, over
the next four quarters.
CONCLUSION
It remains difficult to accurately forecast the
economy for metro areas and individual cities,
23

Technical details about the model are available in
Theodore M. Crone and Michael P. McLaughlin, "A Bayesian VAR Forecasting Model for the Philadelphia Metropolitan Area," Working Paper 99-7, Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia.

Croushore
Theodore M. Crone and MichaelDean
P. McLaughlin

but the development of time-series models has
made the process easier and, in many cases, well
worth the effort. The size and diversity of the
Philadelphia metropolitan area make it a natural candidate for which to develop a forecasting
model. For many local businesses, organizations,
and governments, a reasonable forecast for the
area’s economy can be helpful to the planning
process. The time-series model we have developed provides an additional tool to the economist in charting the course of the Philadelphia
economy. The historical errors in the forecast are
a reminder, however, that this tool should not be
used alone.

23