View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

Loretta J. Mester

What’s the Point of Credit Scoring?
Loretta J. Mester*

W

hen one banker asks another “What’s the
score?” shareholders needn’t worry that these
bankers are wasting time discussing the ball
game. More likely they’re doing their jobs and
discussing the credit score of one of their loan
applicants. Credit scoring is a statistical method
used to predict the probability that a loan applicant or existing borrower will default or be-

*Loretta Mester is a vice president and economist in the
Research Department of the Philadelphia Fed. She is also
the head of the department's Banking and Financial Markets section.

come delinquent. The method, introduced in
the 1950s, is now widely used for consumer
lending, especially credit cards, and is becoming more commonly used in mortgage lending. It has not been widely applied in business
lending, but this, too, is changing. One reason
for the delay is that business loans typically
differ substantially across borrowers, making
it harder to develop an accurate method of scoring. But the advent of new methodologies, enhanced computer power, and increased data
availability have helped to make such scoring
possible, and many banks are beginning to use
scoring to evaluate small-business loan applications.
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

Credit scoring is likely to change the nature
of small-business lending. It will make it less
necessary for a bank to have a presence, say,
via a branch, in the local market in which it
lends. This will change the relationship between the small-business borrower and his or
her lender. Credit scoring is already allowing
large banks to expand into small-business lending, a market in which they have tended to be
less active. Scoring is also an important step
in making the securitization of small-business
loans more feasible. The likely result would
be increased availability of funding to small
businesses, and at better terms, to the extent
that securitization allows better diversification
of risk.
WHAT IS CREDIT SCORING?
Credit scoring is a method of evaluating the
credit risk of loan applications. Using historical data and statistical techniques, credit scoring tries to isolate the effects of various applicant characteristics on delinquencies and defaults. The method produces a “score” that a
bank can use to rank its loan applicants or borrowers in terms of risk. To build a scoring
model, or “scorecard,” developers analyze historical data on the performance of previously
made loans to determine which borrower characteristics are useful in predicting whether the
loan performed well. A well-designed model
should give a higher percentage of high scores
to borrowers whose loans will perform well
and a higher percentage of low scores to borrowers whose loans won’t perform well. But
no model is perfect, and some bad accounts
will receive higher scores than some good accounts.
Information on borrowers is obtained from
their loan applications and from credit bureaus.
Data such as the applicant’s monthly income,
outstanding debt, financial assets, how long the
applicant has been in the same job, whether
the applicant has defaulted or was ever delinquent on a previous loan, whether the appli4

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

cant owns or rents a home, and the type of bank
account the applicant has are all potential factors that may relate to loan performance and
may end up being used in the scorecard.1 Regression analysis relating loan performance to
these variables is used to pick out which combination of factors best predicts delinquency
or default, and how much weight should be
given to each of the factors. (See Scoring Methods for a brief overview of the statistical methods being used.) Given the correlations between the factors, it is quite possible some of
the factors the model developer begins with
won’t make it into the final model, since they
have little value added given the other variables in the model. Indeed, according to Fair,
Isaac and Company, Inc., a leading developer
of scoring models, 50 or 60 variables might be
considered when developing a typical model,
but eight to 12 might end up in the final
scorecard as yielding the most predictive combination (Fair, Isaac). Anthony Saunders reports that First Data Resources, on the other
hand, uses 48 factors to evaluate the probability of credit card defaults.
In most (but not all) scoring systems, a
higher score indicates lower risk, and a lender
sets a cutoff score based on the amount of risk
it is willing to accept. Strictly adhering to the
model, the lender would approve applicants
with scores above the cutoff and deny applicants with scores below (although many lenders may take a closer look at applications near
the cutoff before making the final credit decision).
Even a good scoring system won’t predict
with certainty any individual loan’s performance, but it should give a fairly accurate prediction of the likelihood that a loan applicant
with certain characteristics will default. To
1

Some of the models used for mortgage applications also
take into account information about the property and the
loans, for example, the loan-to-value ratio, the loan type,
and real estate market conditions (DeZube).
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

Loretta J. Mester

Scoring Methods
Several statistical methods are used to develop credit scoring systems, including linear probability models, logit models, probit models, and discriminant analysis models. (Saunders discusses
these methods.) The first three are standard statistical techniques for estimating the probability of
default based on historical data on loan performance and characteristics of the borrower. These
techniques differ in that the linear probability model assumes there is a linear relationship between
the probability of default and the factors; the logit model assumes that the probability of default is
logistically distributed; and the probit model assumes that the probability of default has a (cumulative) normal distribution. Discriminant analysis differs in that instead of estimating a borrower’s
probability of default, it divides borrowers into high and low default-risk classes.
Two newer methods beginning to be used in estimating default probabilities include optionspricing theory models and neural networks. These methods have the potential to be more useful in
developing models for commercial loans, which tend to be more heterogeneous than consumer or
mortgage loans, making the traditional statistical methods harder to apply. Options-pricing theory
models start with the observation that a borrower’s limited liability is comparable to a put option
written on the borrower’s assets, with strike price equal to the value of the debt outstanding. If, in
some future period, the value of the borrower’s assets falls below the value of its outstanding debt,
the borrower may default. The models infer the probability a firm will default from an estimate of
the firm’s asset-price volatility, which is usually based on the observed volatility of the firm’s equity
prices (although, as McAllister and Mingo point out, it has not been empirically verified that shortrun volatility of stock prices is related to volatility of asset values in a predictable way. Saunders
discusses other assumptions of the options-pricing approach that are likely to be violated in certain
applications.) Saunders reports that KMV Corporation has developed a credit monitoring model
based on options-pricing theory.
Neural networks are artificial intelligence algorithms that allow for some learning through experience to discern the relationship between borrower characteristics and the probability of default
and to determine which characteristics are most important in predicting default. (See the articles by
D.K. Malhotra and coauthors and by Edward Altman and coauthors for further discussion.) This
method is more flexible than the standard statistical techniques, since no assumptions have to be
made about the functional form of the relationship between characteristics and default probability
or about the distributions of the variables or errors of the model, and correlations among the characteristics are accounted for.
Some argue that neural networks show much promise in credit scoring for commercial loans,
but others have argued that the approach is more ad hoc than that of standard statistical methods.
(The article by Edward Altman and Anthony Saunders discusses the drawbacks.) A study by Edward Altman, Giancarlo Marco, and Franco Varetto analyzed over 1000 healthy, vulnerable, and
unsound Italian industrial firms from 1982-92 and found that performance models derived using
neural networks and those derived using the more standard statistical techniques yielded about the
same degree of accuracy. They concluded that neural networks were not clearly better than the
standard methods, but suggested using both types of methods in certain applications, especially
complex ones in which the flexibility of neural networks would be particularly valuable.

build a good scoring model, developers need
sufficient historical data, which reflect loan
performance in periods of both good and bad
economic conditions.2
WHERE IS CREDIT SCORING USED?
In the past, banks used credit reports, per-

sonal histories, and judgment to make credit
decisions. But over the past 25 years, credit
scoring has become widely used in issuing
2
Patrick McAllister and John Mingo estimate that to
develop a predictive model for commercial loans, some
20,000 to 30,000 applications would be needed.

5

BUSINESS REVIEW

credit cards and in other types of consumer
lending, such as auto loans and home equity
loans. The Federal Reserve’s November 1996
Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey of Bank
Lending Practices reported that 97 percent of
the responding banks that use credit scoring
in their credit card lending operations use it
for approving card applications and 82 percent
use it to determine from whom to solicit applications. About 20 percent said they used scoring for either setting terms or adjusting terms
on their credit cards.
Scoring is also becoming more widely used
in mortgage origination. Both the Federal
Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie
Mac) and the Federal National Mortgage Corporation (Fannie Mae) have encouraged mortgage lenders to use credit scoring, which
should encourage consistency across underwriters. Freddie Mac sent a letter to its lenders in July 1995 encouraging the use of credit
scoring in loans submitted for sale to the
agency. The agency suggested the scores could
be used to determine which mortgage applicants should be given a closer look and that
the score could be overridden if the underwriter determined the applicant was a good
credit risk. In a letter to its lenders in October
1995, Fannie Mae also reported it was depending more on credit scoring for assessing risk.
Both agencies have developed automatic underwriting systems that incorporate scoring so
that lenders can determine whether a loan is
clearly eligible for sale to these agencies or
whether the lender has to certify that the loan
is of low enough risk to qualify (Avery and coauthors).
Private mortgage insurance companies, such
as GE Capital Mortgage Corporation, are using scoring to help screen mortgage insurance
applications (Prakash, 1995). And it was recently reported that four mortgage companies—Chase Manhattan Mortgage Corp., First
Nationwide, First Tennessee, and HomeSide—
are involved in a test of the use of credit scor6

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

ing models for assessing mortgage performance, prepayments, collection, and foreclosure patterns (Talley). This test is being conducted by Mortgage Information Corp.
A growing number of banks are using credit
scoring models in their small-business lending
operations, most often for loans under
$100,000, although scoring is by no means universally used.3 It has taken longer for scoring
to be adopted for business loans, since these
loans are less homogeneous than credit card
loans and other types of consumer loans and
also because the volume of this type of lending
is smaller, so there is less information with
which to build a model.
The first banks to use scoring for small-business loans were larger banks that had enough
historical loan data to build a reliable model;
these banks include Hibernia Corporation,
Wells Fargo, BankAmerica, Citicorp,
NationsBank, Fleet, and Bank One.
BankAmerica’s model was developed based on
15,000 good and 15,000 bad loans, with face
values up to $50,000 (Oppenheim, 1996); Fleet
Financial Group uses scoring for loans under
$100,000 (Zuckerman). Bank One relies solely
on scores for loans up to $35,000 and approves
30 percent of its loans up to $1 million by
scorecard alone (Wantland). This spring, a regional bank in Pennsylvania began basing its
lending decision for small-business loans up

3

A survey reported in the American Banker in May 1995
with responses from 150 U.S. banks indicated that only 8
percent of banks with up to $5 billion in assets used scoring
for small-business loans, while 23 percent of larger banks
did (Racine). The smaller banks were less inclined to adopt
scoring, citing small loan volumes. Fifty-five percent of
banks with more than $5 billion in assets reported they
planned to implement scoring in the next two years. In a
more recent survey of larger banks—the Federal Reserve’s
January 1997 Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices—70 percent of the respondents, that is,
38 banks, indicated that they use credit scoring in their
small-business lending, and 22 of these banks said that they
usually or always do so.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

to $35,000 exclusively on a credit score. 4 Other
banks have loan officers review the decisions
based on credit scores: at First National Bank
of Chicago it’s been reported that about a quarter of the small-business loan applications rejected by credit scoring are approved after review, and an equal number that pass the scoring model are rejected. First Union looks at
credit scores as a supplement to more traditional analyses of businesses’ financial statements (Hansell).
Credit scoring is now available to lenders
who do not have sufficient volumes to build
their own small-business loan scoring models.
In March 1995, Fair, Isaac introduced its “Small
Business Scoring Service (SBSS),” a scoring
model that was developed with RMA, a trade
association of commercial lenders. The model
was built using five years’ worth of data on
small-business loans from 17 banks in the
United States, a sample of more than 5000 loan
applications from businesses with gross sales
of less than $5 million and loan face values up
to $250,000; banks provided data on good and
bad accounts and on declined applications, as
well as credit reports on at least two of a
business’s principals and on the business (Asch;
Hansell; and Neill and Danforth). 5 Separate
scorecards were created for loans under $35,000
and for loans between $35,000 and $250,000.
The models found that the most important indicators of small-business loan performance
were characteristics of the business owner
rather than the business itself. For example,
the owner’s credit history was more predic-

4
For its small-business loans between $35,000 and
$250,000, a lender makes the decision, but a credit score is
also calculated as a guideline. At this bank, a small-business borrower is one with annual sales of $2 million or less.
5

A good account was defined as one that had not been
30 days delinquent more than twice during the first four
years of account history, while a bad account was one that
at least once had been 60 days or more delinquent (Asch).

Loretta J. Mester

tive than the net worth or profitability of the
business. While this might seem surprising at
first, it’s worth remembering that small businesses’ financial statements are less sophisticated than those of larger businesses and that
the owners’ and businesses’ finances are often
commingled (Hansell). Other companies such
as CCN-MDS, Dun & Bradstreet, and Experian
(formerly TRW) are developing or already have
competitive products. These standardized
products make scoring available to lenders
with smaller loan volumes, but the models may
not be as predictive for these lenders to the
extent that their applicant pool differs from that
used to create the scorecard.6
Despite its growing use for evaluating smallbusiness lending, credit scoring is not being
used to evaluate larger commercial loans.
While the loan performance of a small business is closely related to the credit history of
its owners, this is much less likely to be the
case for larger businesses. Although some
models have been developed to estimate the
default probabilities of large firms, they have
been based on the performance of corporate
bonds of publicly traded companies. It is not
at all clear that these models would accurately
predict the default performance of bank loans
to these or other companies. (See McAllister
and Mingo for more discussion on this point.)
To develop a more accurate loan scoring model
for larger businesses, a necessary first step
would be the collection of a vast array of data
on many different types of businesses along
with the performance of loans made to these
businesses; the data would have to include a
large number of bad, as well as good, loans.

6

In personal conversation, the manager of the small-business lending department of a regional bank in Pennsylvania reported that it was because of this concern that the bank
does not rely on the credit score from a standardized model
to make the approval decision for loans between $35,000 to
$250,000.
7

BUSINESS REVIEW

Since the typical default rate on business loans
is in the range of 1 percent to 3 percent annually, banks would have to pool their data. Such
data-collection efforts are currently under way.7
But the fact that loans to large businesses vary
in so many dimensions will make the development of a credit scoring model for these types
of loans very difficult.
BENEFITS OF CREDIT SCORING:
QUICKER, CHEAPER, MORE OBJECTIVE
Credit scoring has some obvious benefits
that have led to its increasing use in loan evaluation. First, scoring greatly reduces the time
needed in the loan approval process. A study
by the Business Banking Board found that the
traditional loan approval process averages
about 12-1/2 hours per small-business loan,
and in the past, lenders have taken up to two
weeks to process a loan (Allen). Credit scoring
can reduce this time to well under an hour, although the time savings will vary depending
on whether the bank adheres strictly to the
credit score cutoff or whether it reevaluates
applications with scores near the cutoff. For
example, Kevin Leonard’s study of a Canadian
bank found that the approval time for consumer loan applications averaged nine days
before the bank started using scoring, but three
days after scoring had been in use for 18
months. Barnett Bank reports a decrease from
three or four weeks’ processing time for a
small-business loan application before scoring
to a few hours with scoring (Lawson).
This time savings means cost savings to the
bank and benefits the customer as well. Customers need to provide only the information

7
Loan Pricing Corporation and several of its clients are
pooling their data on commercial loans so that in several
years there may be information on a sufficiently large number of good and bad loans to begin building a scoring model
for commercial loans to larger businesses (correspondence
from John Mingo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System staff).

8

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

used in the scoring system, so applications can
be shorter. And the scoring systems themselves
are not prohibitively expensive: the price per
loan of a commercially available credit scoring
model averages about $1.50 to $10 per loan,
depending on volume (Muolo). Even if a bank
does not want to depend solely on credit scoring for making its credit decisions, scoring can
increase efficiency by allowing loan officers to
concentrate on the less clear-cut cases.8
Another benefit of credit scoring is improved objectivity in the loan approval process.
This objectivity helps lenders ensure they are
applying the same underwriting criteria to all
borrowers regardless of race, gender, or other
factors prohibited by law from being used in
credit decisions (see Credit Scoring and Regulation B). Bank regulators require that the factors in a scoring model have some fundamental relationship with creditworthiness. Even if
a factor is not explicitly banned, if it has a disparate impact on borrowers of a certain race
or gender or with respect to some other prohibited characteristic, the lender needs to show
there is a business reason for using the factor
and there is no equally effective way of making the credit decision that has less of a disparate impact. A credit scoring model makes it
easier for a lender to document the business
reason for using a factor that might have a disproportionately negative effect on certain
groups of applicants protected by law from
discrimination. The weights in the model give
a measure of the relative strength of each
factor’s correlation with credit performance

8
Scoring is one part of an automated loan system, which
permits banks to offer loans over the phone or via direct
mail, so that a costly branch network can be avoided. It’s
worth mentioning, however, that the costs of a fully automated lending operation at a large bank could be quite high,
since reliability would be essential. As one lender has
pointed out, when an automated loan system goes down,
the bank’s lending operation is out of business. Hence,
backup systems are necessary.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

Loretta J. Mester

Credit Scoring and Regulation B
The Equal Credit Opportunity Act (implemented by the Federal Reserve Board’s Regulation B) prohibits creditors from discriminating in any aspect of a credit transaction because of an
applicant’s race, color, religion, national origin, gender, marital
status, or age (provided the applicant has the capacity to contract),
because all or part of an applicant’s income derives from public
assistance, or because the applicant has in good faith exercised
any right under the Consumer Credit Protection Act.
Scoring models cannot include information on race, gender, or
marital status. Recently, the Board amended its commentary on
Reg B to clarify the use of age in credit scoring models. Reg B
defines an “empirically derived, demonstrably and statistically
sound, credit scoring system” as one that is: (i) based on data that
are derived from an empirical comparison of sample groups or
the population of creditworthy and noncreditworthy applicants
who applied for credit within a reasonable preceding period of
time; (ii) developed for the purpose of evaluating the creditworthiness of applicants with respect to the legitimate business interest of the creditor; (iii) developed and validated using accepted
statistical principles and methodology; and (iv) periodically reevaluated by the use of appropriate statistical principles and methodology and adjusted as necessary to maintain predictive ability.
Reg B classifies any other system as a judgmental system, and such
systems cannot use age directly as a predictive variable in the
model. However, if the model does qualify as an empirically derived, demonstrably and statistically sound system, the Board has
determined that it can use age directly in the model as long as the
weight assigned to an applicant 62 years or older is not lower than
that assigned to any other age category. And if a system assigns
points to some other variable based on the applicant’s age, applicants who are 62 years and older must receive at least the same
number of points as the most favored class of nonelderly applicants. (Any system of evaluating creditworthiness may favor a
credit applicant aged 62 years or older.)

(given the other factors contained in the model).
Also, a well-built model will include all allowable factors that produce the most accurate prediction of credit performance, so a lender using such a model might be able to argue that a
similarly effective alternative was not available.9

subsample had

But not everyone
agrees that the objectivity in scoring will benefit
minorities or low-income individuals, who
may have had limited
access to credit in the
past. Some argue that
since these potential borrowers are not well represented in the loan data
on which the scoring
models have been built,
the models are less accurate predictors of their
loan performance. (See,
for example, the discussion in “Mortgage Credit
Partnership Project:
1996-1997.”) This is a legitimate concern. But it
need not be the case that
the models are less accurate, since the factors and
their weights identified
in the model could also
be those that determine
creditworthiness of the
underrepresented
groups. One study by
Fair, Isaac indicated that
their scoring model for
installment loans was as
predictive for low- to
moderate-income loan
applicants as for the entire sample of applicants,
although the low-income
lower scores. (With a cutoff

9
But banks that override the model for certain borrowers need to be particularly careful in documenting the reasons for the override to avoid violating fair lending laws.
Similarly, borrowers right at the margin of cutoff for approval must be handled carefully.

9

BUSINESS REVIEW

score of 200, the acceptance rate for low- to
moderate-income applicants was 46 percent,
while for higher income applicants it was 67
percent. See Fair, Isaac.)10 Freddie Mac also
says its system, called Loan Prospector, is
equally predictive of loan performance, regardless of borrower race or income (Prakash, 1997).
LIMITATIONS OF CREDIT SCORING
The accuracy of the scoring systems for
underrepresented groups is still an open question. Accuracy is a very important consideration in using credit scoring. Even if the lender
can lower its costs of evaluating loan applications by using scoring, if the models are not
accurate, these cost savings would be eaten
away by poorly performing loans.
The accuracy of a credit scoring system will
depend on the care with which it is developed.
The data on which the system is based need to
be a rich sample of both well-performing and
poorly performing loans. The data should be
up to date, and the models should be reestimated frequently to ensure that changes in the
relationships between potential factors and
loan performance are captured. If the bank
using scoring increases its applicant pool by
mass marketing, it must ensure that the new
pool of applicants behaves similarly to the pool
on which the model was built; otherwise, the
model may not accurately predict the behavior of these new applicants. The use of credit
scoring itself may change a bank’s applicant
pool in unpredictable ways, since it changes
the cost of lending to certain types of borrowers. Again, this change in applicant pool may
hurt the accuracy of a model that was built

10
Fair, Isaac’s study used data on direct installment loan
applicants from July 1992 to December 1994. Low- and
moderate-income applicants were defined as those having
gross monthly incomes of less then $1750. By this definition, one-third of their sample and one-fifth to one-half of
the applicants of each of the individual lenders were
deemed low- to moderate-income applicants.

10

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

using information from the past pool of applicants.
Account should be taken not only of the
characteristics of borrowers who were granted
credit but also of those who were denied. Otherwise, a “selection bias” in the loan approval
process could lead to bias in the estimated
weights in the scoring model.11 A model’s accuracy should be tested. A good model needs
to make accurate predictions in good economic
times and bad, so the data on which the model
is based should cover both expansions and recessions. And the testing should be done using loan samples that were not used to develop
the model in the first place.
It is probably too soon to determine the accuracy of small-business loan scoring models
because they are fairly new and we have not
been through an economic downturn since
their implementation. Studies of the mortgage
scoring systems suggest that they are fairly
accurate in predicting loan performance. In its
November 11, 1995, industry letter, Freddie
Mac reported some of its own research on the
predictive power of mortgage credit scores by
Fair, Isaac and CCN-MDS. The agency studied hundreds of thousands of Freddie Mac
loans originated over several years and selected
from a wide distribution of lenders, product
and loan types, and geographic areas; it found
a high correlation between the scores and loan
performance. The agency also had its underwriters review thousands of loans and found
a strong correlation between the underwriters’

11

For example, suppose owning a home means a person
is less likely to default on a loan. Then if the majority of
applicants that a bank approves are home owners, the distribution of home ownership in the approved applicant pool
will differ from that in the total applicant pool. If this fact
is ignored in estimating the model, the model could not accurately uncover the relationship between home ownership
and loan default. The model would show that home ownership is less predictive of good performance than it actually is.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

judgments and the Fair, Isaac credit scores.
Avery and coauthors also found that credit
scores based on the credit history of mortgage
applicants generally were predictive of mortgage loan performance.12
Not all the news on accuracy is good, however. In the November 1996 Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey, 56 percent of the 33 banks
that used credit scoring in their credit card operations reported that their models failed to accurately predict loan-quality problems by being too optimistic. The bankers attributed part
of the problem to a new willingness by consumers to declare bankruptcy. This is a reasonable supposition: this type of “regime shift” (to
a world in which there’s less stigma attached
to declaring bankruptcy) would not be picked
up in a scoring model if it was not reflected in
the historical data on which the model was
based. In response, 54 percent of the banks
have redefined or reestimated their models,
and 80 percent have raised the cutoff score an
applicant needs to qualify for credit.
It’s important to remember, though, that a
credit scoring model is not going to tell a lender
with certainty what the future performance of

12
Avery and coauthors examined data from Equifax on
all mortgages that were outstanding and whose payments
were current as of September 1994 at three of the largest
lenders in the United States. Each loan had a mortgage
credit history score and measures of performance over the
subsequent 12 months, to September 1995. For each loan
type (conventional fixed rate, conventional variable rate,
or government-backed fixed rate), regardless of seasoning
status (newly originated or seasoned), borrowers with low
scores had substantially higher delinquency rates than those
with medium or higher scores, although most borrowers
with low scores were not delinquent. They also examined
data from Freddie Mac on loans for single-family owneroccupied properties purchased by Freddie Mac in the first
six months of 1994, which showed that borrowers with low
scores had higher foreclosure rates (by the end of 1995), and
that loans with both low credit scores and higher loan-tovalue ratios had particularly high foreclosure rates. In addition, credit scores were much stronger predictors of foreclosure than was income.

Loretta J. Mester

an individual loan will be. When loan approval
decisions are based solely on credit scores,
some borrowers will be granted credit but will
ultimately default, which visibly hurts the
lender’s bottom line. Other borrowers won’t
be granted credit even though they would have
repaid, which, though less visible, also hurts
the lender’s profitability. No scoring model can
prevent these types of errors, but a good model
should be able to accurately predict the average performance of loans made to groups of
individuals who share similar values of the factors identified as being relevant to credit quality.
Many considered the well-publicized denial
of then Federal Reserve System Governor
Lawrence Lindsey’s application for a Toys ‘R’
Us credit card a failure of a credit scoring
model. But the denial does not necessarily
mean the model was faulty. The denial was
based on the fact that his credit report showed
too many voluntary credit bureau inquiries,
and research by Fair, Isaac shows that as a group,
applicants with seven to eight such inquiries
are three times riskier than the average applicant and six times riskier than applicants with
no such inquiries (McCorkell).13
IMPLICATIONS FOR THE
BANKING INDUSTRY
The spread of credit scoring, especially its
growing use in small-business lending, should
lead to increased competition among providers of this type of credit and increased availability of credit for small businesses. Traditionally, lenders to small businesses have been
smaller banks that have had a physical presence, usually in the form of a branch, in the
13

A credit bureau inquiry refers to an inquiry into
someone’s credit history at a credit bureau. A so-called
voluntary inquiry is initiated when a person seeks credit.
An involuntary inquiry can occur without a person’s knowledge as part of a routine review of existing accounts or a
prescreening for a promotional mailing, for example.
11

BUSINESS REVIEW

borrower’s neighborhood. The local presence
gives the banker a good knowledge of the area,
which is thought to be useful in the credit decision. Small businesses are likely to have deposit accounts at the small bank in town, and
the information the bank can gain by observing the firm’s cash flows can give the bank an
information advantage in lending to these businesses. (Leonard Nakamura’s article discusses
the advantages small banks have had in smallbusiness lending.)
However, credit scoring is changing the way
banks make small-business loans, and large
banks are entering the market using credit scoring and processing applications using automated and centralized systems. These banks
are able to generate large volumes of smallbusiness loans even in areas where they do not
have extensive branch networks. Applications
are being accepted over the phone, and some
banks are soliciting customers via direct mail,
as credit card lenders do. For example, Wells
Fargo uses centralized processing for loans
under $100,000, soliciting these loans nationwide, and uses credit scores not only in the
approval process but also for loan pricing. For
loans over $100,000, it still uses traditional underwriting, soliciting in areas where it has
branches (Zuckerman).
Out west, in the 12th Federal Reserve District, the largest banks have increased their
commercial loans of less than $100,000 and
have taken market share from smaller banks,
while they have reduced their commercial
loans in the $100,000 to $1 million size range,
which are less easy to automate (Levonian).14
Many of the larger banks are finding that auto-

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

mated small-business lending allows them to
profitably make loans of a smaller size than
they could using traditional methods. For example, at Hibernia Corp., the break-even loan
size was about $200,000 before automation, but
now Hibernia has a large portfolio of loans
under $50,000 (Zuckerman). At Wells Fargo,
the average size of a small-business loan is
$18,242 (Oppenheim, January 1997).
This spring, a regional bank in Pennsylvania planned to solicit small-business loan applications with a direct mail campaign to 50,000
current and prospective customers who will be
prescreened using the bank’s scoring model.
The bank will exclude certain lines of business
and businesses less than three years old. A
simple application form will be used, with no
financial statements required, and loans up to
$35,000 will be approved based solely on the
credit score. Also this spring, PNC Bank Corp.
opened an automated loan center in suburban
Philadelphia through which it plans to process
25,000 small-business loan applications from
across the nation in the next year. While much
of the application process is automated and
credit scores are used, a lender makes the final
approval decision on a loan application
(Oppenheim, May 1997).
For many creditworthy small-business borrowers, the entry of the larger banks into the
market means more potential sources for credit.
Some banks have found they’ve been able to
extend more loans under credit scoring than
under their judgmental credit approval systems without increasing their default rates
(Asch). Credit scoring may also encourage
more lending because it gives banks a tool for
more accurately pricing risk.15 However, the
relationship that a borrower has with its large

14

Mark Levonian reports that between June 1995 and
June 1996, the largest banks in the 12th District increased
their holdings of loans under $100,000 by over 26 percent,
while other banks increased their holdings of these loans
by a little over 3 percent. (These figures are adjusted for
bank mergers.)
12

15

Banks that use scoring to develop risk-related loan
pricing need to keep in mind fair lending rules and should
avoid selectively overriding the model for some borrowers
and not others.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

creditor is likely to be very different from the
one it has traditionally had with its small bank.
The typical bank-borrower relationship, which
is built up over years of lending, allows for
substantial flexibility in loan terms. A longterm relationship allows the bank to offer concessionary rates to a borrower facing temporary credit problems, which the bank can later
make up for when the firm returns to health.
(Mitchell Berlin’s article discusses relationship
lending.)
But automated small-business loans are
likely to be more like credit card loans than traditional business loans, with the terms being
less flexible and set to maximize a bank’s profits period-by-period rather than over the life
of a relationship. Monitoring these borrowers
would likely be more expensive for the bank,
since the borrowers may come from outside
the bank’s traditional lending markets. This
would tend to make the bank less flexible on
its loan terms. Small businesses that value the
flexibility of the traditional relationship loan
will have to seek banks that make loans on this
basis, most likely smaller banks, as has been
the case in the past. These smaller banks will
maintain their advantage over larger banks in
monitoring loans, since they have a good
knowledge of the local markets in which they
and their borrowers operate. Businesses that
find it hard to qualify for loans based solely on
their credit scores but that, nevertheless, are
creditworthy on closer inspection will need to
seek funding from these relationship lenders
as well.
Another way credit scoring may encourage
lending to small businesses is by making
securitization of these loans more feasible.
Securitization involves pooling together a
group of loans and then using the cash flows
of the loan pool to back publicly traded securities; the loans in the pool serve as collateral for
the securities. The loan pool will typically have
more predictable cash flows than any individual loan, since the failure of one borrower

Loretta J. Mester

to make a payment can be offset by another
borrower who does make a payment. The expected cash flows from the loan pool determine
the prices of the securities, which are sold to
investors. Securitization can reduce the costs
of bank lending, since typically the loan pool
is moved off the bank’s books to a third-party
trustee so that the bank need not hold capital
against the loans and the securities provide
what is often a cheaper source of funding than
deposits. (See Christine Pavel’s article for an
overview of securitization.)
Securitization has occurred with mortgage
loans, credit card receivables, and auto loans,
all of which tend to be homogeneous with regard to collateral, the loan terms, and the underwriting standards used. This homogeneity
is important, since a crucial aspect of
securitization is being able to accurately predict the cash flows from the pool of loans so
that the securities can be accurately priced.
There have not been many securitizations of
small-business loans, partly because of their
heterogeneous nature.16 But credit scoring will
tend to standardize these loans and make default risk more predictable, steps that should
make securitization more feasible.17 As was
true in the mortgage market, securitization
would probably lead to an increase in small-

16

In his 1995 article, Ron Feldman indicates that less than
$900 million in small-business loans had been securitized,
while $155 billion of these types of loans were outstanding
at year-end 1994. He also provides descriptions of some of
these securitizations.
17

The difficulty that the borrower’s option to prepay a
mortgage poses for pricing mortgaged-backed securities is
not an issue for small-business loan securitizations, since
small-business loans have short maturities. For example,
the November 1996 Survey of Terms of Bank Lending indicated that 85 percent of loans made in the survey period
either had no stated maturity or a stated maturity of less
than one year. The average maturity, weighted by loan size,
of loans with stated maturities of longer than one day but
less than a year was 64 days (Federal Reserve Bulletin).
13

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

business lending, with nonbank lenders playing a larger role. The market would become
more liquid, since unlike loans, the securities
are easily bought and sold; thus, diversification would be easier to achieve. Since diversification lowers risk, loan rates could be lower.
CONCLUSION
Widespread securitizations of small-business loans are still in the future. But credit scor-

ing is increasingly being used to evaluate smallbusiness loan applications, something that was
not widely anticipated a decade ago. Credit
scoring will never be able to predict with certainty the performance of an individual loan,
but it does provide a method of quantifying
the relative risks of different groups of borrowers. Scoring has the potential to be one of the
factors that change small-business banking as
we know it.

BIBLIOGRAPHY
Allen, James C. “A Promise of Approvals in Minutes, Not Hours,” American Banker (February 28,
1995), p. 23.
Altman, Edward I., Giancarlo Marco, and Franco Varetto. “Corporate Distress Diagnosis: Comparisons Using Linear Discriminant Analysis and Neural Networks (The Italian Experience),”
Journal of Banking and Finance 18 (1994), pp. 505-29.
Altman, Edward I. and Anthony Saunders. “Credit Risk Measurement: Developments Over the
Last 20 Years,” Journal of Banking and Finance, forthcoming 1997 (New York University Salomon
Center Working Paper S-96-40).
Asch, Latimer. “How the RMA/Fair, Isaac Credit-Scoring Model Was Built,” Journal of Commercial
Lending (June 1995), pp. 10-16.
Avery, Robert B., Raphael W. Bostic, Paul S. Calem, and Glenn B. Canner. “Credit Risk, Credit Scoring and the Performance of Home Mortgages,” Federal Reserve Bulletin 82 (July 1996), pp. 62148.
Berlin, Mitchell. “For Better and For Worse: Three Lending Relationships,” Business Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (November/December 1996), pp. 3-12.
DeZube, Dona. “Mortgage Scoring: Rules of Thumb,” Mortgage Banking (August 1996), pp. 51-57.
Fair, Isaac. “Low to Moderate Income and High Minority Area Case Studies,” Fair, Isaac and Company, Inc. Discussion Paper (October 4, 1996).
Federal Reserve Bulletin, Table 4.23 Terms of Lending at Commercial Banks (February 1997), p. A68.
Feldman, Ron. “Will the Securitization Revolution Spread?” The Region, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis (September 1995), pp. 23-30.
Freddie Mac Industry Letter (July 11, 1995).
Hansell, Saul. “Need a Loan? Ask the Computer: ‘Credit Scoring’ Changes Small-Business Lending,” New York Times (April 18, 1995), p. D1.
14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

Loretta J. Mester

Lawson, James C. “Knowing the Score,” US Banker (September 1995), pp. 61-65.
Leonard, Kevin J. “The Development of Credit Scoring Quality Measures for Consumer Credit
Applications,” International Journal of Quality and Reliability Management, 12 (1995), pp. 79-85.
Levonian, Mark E. “Changes in Small Business Lending in the West,” Economic Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Number 97-02 (January 24, 1997).
Malhotra, D.K., Rashmi Malhotra, and Robert W. McLeod. “Artificial Neural Systems in Commercial Lending,” The Bankers Magazine (November/December 1994), pp. 40-44.
McAllister, Patrick H., and John J. Mingo. “Commercial Loan Risk Management, Credit-Scoring,
and Pricing: The Need for a New Shared Database,” Journal of Commercial Lending (May 1994),
pp. 6-22.
McCorkell, Peter L. “Comment: Managing Credit Risk Means Getting the Right Mix,” American
Banker (March 20, 1996), p. 14.
“Mortgage Credit Partnership Project: 1996-1997,” Final Report, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, March 5, 1997.
Muolo, Paul. “Building a Credit Scoring Bridge,” US Banker (May 1995), pp. 71-73.
Nakamura, Leonard I. “Small Borrowers and the Survival of the Small Bank: Is Mouse Bank Mighty
or Mickey?” Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (November/December
1994), pp. 3-15.
Neill, David S., and John P. Danforth. “Bank Merger Impact on Small Business Services Is Changing,” Banking Policy Report, The Secura Group, 18 (April 15, 1996), pp. 1 & 13-19.
Oppenheim, Sara. “Would Credit Scoring Backfire in a Recession?” American Banker (November 18,
1996), p. 16.
Oppenheim, Sara. “Wider Rate Gap Between Small and ‘Small’,” American Banker (January 21, 1997),
p. 10.
Oppenheim, Sara. “Gearing Up for Small-Business Push, PNC Building an Assembly Line,” American Banker (May 27, 1997), p. 1.
Pavel, Christine. “Securitization,” Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (July/
August 1986), pp. 16-31.
Prakash, Snigdha. “Mortgage Lenders See Credit Scoring as Key to Hacking Through Red Tape,”
American Banker (August 22, 1995), p. 1.
Prakash, Snigdha. “Freddie Mac Exec Details Evolution of Credit Scoring,” American Banker (March
6, 1997), p. 12A.
Racine, John. “Community Banks Reject Credit Scoring for the Human Touch,” American Banker
(May 22, 1995), p. 12.

15

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

BIBLIOGRAPHY (continued)
Saunders, Anthony. Financial Institutions Management: A Modern Perspective, 2nd edition, Chapter
10, Boston: Irwin: Boston, 1997.
Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices, Federal Reserve System, November
1996 and January 1997.
Talley, Karen. “Four-Lender Test Could Advance the Status of Credit Scoring,” American Banker
(March 24, 1997), p. 12.
Wantland, Robin. “Best Practices in Small Business Lending for Any Delivery System,” Journal of
Lending and Credit Risk Management (December 1996), p. 16-25.
Zuckerman, Sam. “Taking Small Business Competition Nationwide,” US Banker (August 1996), pp.
24-28, 72.

16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring?

Loretta J. Mester

What Determines the Exchange Rate:
Economic Factors or
Market Sentiment?

R

eaders of the financial press are familiar
with the gyrations of the currency market. No
matter which way currencies zig or zag, it
seems there is always an analyst with a quotable, ready explanation. Either interest rates are
rising faster than expected in some country, or
the trade balance is up or down, or central
banks are tightening or loosening their monetary policies. Whatever the explanations, the

*When this article was written, Greg Hopper was a senior economist in the Research Department of the Philadelphia Fed. He is now in the Credit Analytics Group at Morgan Stanley, Co., Inc., New York.

Gregory P. Hopper*
underlying belief is that exchange rates are affected by fundamental economic forces, such
as money supplies, interest rates, real output
levels, or the trade balance, which, if well forecasted, give the forecaster an advantage in predicting the exchange rate.
What is not so well known outside academia
is that exchange rates don’t seem to be affected
by economic fundamentals in the short run.
Being able to predict money supplies, central
bank policies, or other supposed influences
doesn’t help forecast the exchange rate. Economists have found instead that the best forecast
of the exchange rate, at least in the short run,
is whatever it happens to be today.
17

BUSINESS REVIEW

In this article, we’ll review exchange-rate
economics, focusing on what is predictable and
what isn’t. We’ll see that exchange rates seem
to be influenced by market sentiment rather
than by economic fundamentals, and we’ll examine the practical implications of this fact.
Sometimes, there are situations in which market participants may be able to forecast the direction but not the timing of the movement.
We’ll also see that volatility of exchange rates
and correlations between exchange rates are
predictable, and we’ll examine the implications
for currency option pricing, risk management,
and portfolio selection.
THE EXCHANGE RATE AND
ECONOMIC FUNDAMENTALS
The earliest model of the exchange rate, the
monetary model, assumes that the current exchange rate is determined by current fundamental economic variables: money supplies
and output levels of the countries. When the
fundamentals are combined with market expectations of future exchange rates, the model
yields the value of the current exchange rate.
The monetary model might also be dubbed the
“newspaper model.” When analyzing movements in the exchange rate, journalists often
use the results of the monetary model. Similarly, when Wall Street analysts are asked to
justify their exchange-rate predictions, they will
typically resort to some variant of the monetary
model. This model is popular because it provides intuitive relationships between the economic fundamentals and it’s based on standard
macroeconomic reasoning.
The reasoning behind the monetary model
is simple: the exchange rate is determined by
the relative price levels of the two countries. If
goods and services cost twice as much, on average, in U.S. dollars as they do in a foreign
currency, $2 will fetch one unit of the foreign
currency. That way, the same goods and services will cost the same whether they are
bought in the U.S. or in the foreign country.1
18

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

But what determines the relative price levels of the two countries? The monetary model
focuses on the demand and supply of money.
If the money supply in the United States rises,
but nothing else changes, the average level of
prices in the United States will tend to rise.
Since the price level in the foreign country remains fixed, more dollars will be needed to get
one unit of foreign currency. Hence, the dollar
price of the foreign currency will rise: the dollar will depreciate--it’s worth less in terms of
the foreign currency.
Money supplies are not the only economic
fundamentals in the monetary model. The level
of real output in each country matters as well
because it affects the price level. For example,
if the level of output in the United States rises,
but other fundamental factors, such as the U.S.
money supply, remain constant, the average
level of prices in the United States will tend to
fall, producing an appreciation in the dollar.2
Future economic fundamentals also matter
because they determine the market’s expectations about the future exchange rate. Not surprisingly, market expectations of the future
exchange rate matter for the current exchange
rate. If the market expects the dollar price of
the yen to become higher in the future than it
is today, the dollar price of the yen will tend to
be high today. But if the market expects the
dollar price of the yen to be lower in the future
than it is today, the dollar price of the yen will
tend to be low today.
Here’s an example of how to use the monetary model: suppose we wanted to predict the

1
When purchasing power parity holds, particular goods
and services cost the same amount in the domestic country
as they do in the foreign country. There is an extensive literature that documents that purchasing power parity
doesn’t hold except perhaps in the very long run.
2
In the monetary model, the price level must fall in this
situation to ensure that money demanded by consumers is
the same as money supplied by the central bank.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

dollar-yen exchange rate. The first thing we
need to do is think about the relationships between the fundamentals and the exchange rate.
The monetary model implies that if the U.S.
money supply is growing faster than the Japanese money supply, the dollar price of the yen
will rise: the dollar will depreciate and the yen
will appreciate. So, the analyst needs to assess
monetary policy in the two countries. The monetary model also implies that if output is growing faster in the United States than it is in Japan, the dollar price of the yen will tend to fall:
the dollar will appreciate and the yen will depreciate. Finally, the analyst must assess expectations about the future exchange rate. If the
market’s expectation of the future exchange
rate were to change, the current exchange rate
would move in the same direction. When making an exchange-rate forecast based on the
monetary model, the analyst must consider the
effect of all the fundamentals simultaneously.
He can do this by using a statistical model or
by combining judgment with the use of a statistical model.
In practice, using the monetary model to
make exchange-rate forecasts is difficult because the analyst never knows the true value
of the economic fundamentals. At any time,
money supply and output levels are not known
with certainty; they must be forecast based on
the available economic data. Of course, expectations about the future of the exchange rate
are even harder to assess because these expectations are unobservable. The analyst can always survey market participants about their
expectations, but he can never be sure if the
surveys accurately reflect the market’s views.
If we assume the monetary model is valid, the
goal of the successful exchange-rate forecaster
is to predict the values of the fundamentals
better than the competition and then use the
monetary model or some variant to derive forecasts of the exchange rate.
The fatal flaw in this strategy is the assumption that the monetary model can be used to

Loretta J. Mester
Gregory P. Hopper

successfully forecast the exchange rate once the
values of the fundamentals are known. Although the monetary model had some early
success, economists have established that the
model fails empirically except perhaps in unusual periods such as hyperinflations.3 For one
thing, research did not establish a strong statistical relationship between exchange rates and
the values of the fundamentals. Moreover, a
key assumption of the model was found to be
false: the model assumes that the price level
can move freely. Yet the price level seems to
be “sticky,” meaning that it moves very slowly
compared with the movement of the exchange
rate.
What about other models? After the failure
of the monetary model became apparent,
economists went to work developing other
ideas. Rudiger Dornbusch developed a variant of the monetary model called the overshooting model, in which the average level of prices
is assumed to be fixed in the short run to reflect the real-world finding that many prices
don’t change frequently. The effect of this assumption is to cause the exchange rate to overshoot its long-run value as a result of a change
in the fundamentals; eventually, however, the
exchange rate returns to its long-run value.
Ultimately, this model was shown to fail empirically: economists couldn’t find the strong
statistical relationships between the fundamentals and the exchange rate that should exist if
the model were true.4
Another extension of the simple monetary
model is called the portfolio balance model. In
this approach, the supply of and demand for
foreign and domestic bonds, along with the

3

See the papers by Frenkel (1976, 1980), Bilson (1978),
and Hodrick (1978) for empirical analysis of the monetary
model.
4

For an empirical treatment of the overshooting model,
see the paper by Backus (1984).
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

See, for example, the paper by Branson, Halttunen, and
Masson (1977).

these expectations are translated into decisions
to buy or sell currency. These decisions ultimately help to determine the current level of
the exchange rate. Once the government announces the value of the money supply, market participants buy or sell currencies as long
as the news is different from what they expected. Thus, news about fundamentals, under this view, is an important determinant of
the exchange rate.
The difficulty in testing this view is that
economists don’t know how to measure the
news because they don’t know how to measure the market’s expectations. One solution
is to assume that market participants form their
expectations using a statistical device called
linear regression. Using linear regression, an
econometrician could estimate the expected
level of a fundamental, such as the U.S. money
supply, for each quarter during the past 20
years. He could then subtract the value of the
estimated expected money supply from its actual value in each quarter to generate an estimate of the news about the quarterly U.S.
money supply. The news for other fundamentals can be estimated in a similar way.
Once the econometrician has estimated each
fundamental’s news for each quarter during
the last 20 years, he can check to see if it explains the level of the exchange rate. Studies
by economists who have carried out this procedure generally indicate that news about the
fundamentals explains the exchange rate better than the three major exchange-rate models.7 However, two factors make this result
hard to interpret. First, we have no direct evidence suggesting that market participants form
their expectations using linear regression models or that they form their expectations as if
they were using these models. Second, these

6
See the papers by Frankel (1982) and Lewis (1988) for
empirical analysis of the more sophisticated portfolio balance model. The fundamental problem with the model is
that investors must have an implausibly high aversion to
risk to explain the exchange rate.

7
For empirical analysis of news models, see the papers
by Branson (1983), Edwards (1982, 1983), and MacDonald
(1983).

supply of and demand for foreign and domestic money, determine the exchange rate. Early
tests of the model were not very encouraging.5
Later, economists formulated a more sophisticated version of the portfolio balance model,
in which investors were assumed to choose a
portfolio of domestic and foreign bonds in an
optimal way. According to the more sophisticated portfolio balance theory, the degree to
which investors are willing to substitute domestic for foreign bonds depends on how much
investors dislike risk, how volatile the returns
on the bonds are, and the extent to which the
returns on the different bonds in the portfolio
move together. Unfortunately, economists did
not find much empirical support for the more
sophisticated version of the portfolio balance
model.6
Economic News. Thus, the three major models of the exchange rate—the monetary, the
overshooting, and the portfolio balance models—do not provide a satisfactory account of
the exchange rate. Nonetheless, it is possible
that news about the fundamentals affects the exchange rate even if the fundamentals themselves don’t influence the exchange rate in the
manner suggested by the three major exchange
rate models.
The news about the fundamentals can be
defined as the difference between what market participants expect the fundamentals to be
and what the fundamentals actually are once
their values are announced. For example, market participants form expectations about the
value of the money supply before the government announces the money supply figures, and

5

20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

studies use the final values of the fundamentals, values released by governments months,
if not years, after the forecasts were made. Yet,
forecasters must use the government’s preliminary estimates of the fundamentals when they
make their predictions. In other words, the
econometrician is assuming that market participants are making forecasts using information they don’t have. Hence, the result that
news about the fundamentals seems to explain
the level of the exchange rate better than the
models is hard to interpret.
One way to avoid the problem of using final values of fundamentals is to collect the initial estimates from newspapers, government
announcements, and wire services and examine their ability to affect the level of the exchange rate. Studies that have done this have
found that announcements about fundamentals
affect the exchange rate only in the very short
run: the effects of announcements generally
disappear after a day or two.
When we look at the evidence from the three
major exchange-rate models, from the news
analysis, and from the effects of announcements, it is hard not to be pessimistic about
the fundamentals’ ability to explain the exchange rate. But the evidence we have examined so far is backward-looking: the fundamentals don’t seem to explain exchange-rate behavior over the past couple of decades. However,
we can also do a forward-looking analysis: do
the fundamentals help us forecast the level of
the exchange rate?
The surprising answer to this question, given
by economists Richard Meese and Kenneth
Rogoff in the early 1980s, is no. Meese and
Rogoff examined the ability of the fundamentals to predict the level of the exchange rate for
horizons up to one year. They considered fundamentals-based economic models as well as
statistical models of the relationship between
the fundamentals and the exchange rate that
did not incorporate economic assumptions.
They found that a naive strategy of using today’s

Loretta J. Mester
Gregory P. Hopper

exchange rate as a forecast works at least as
well as any of the economic or statistical models. Worse, they found that when they endowed
the economic or statistical models with final
values of the fundamentals—giving the models an advantage that forecasters could not
possibly match—the naive strategy still won
the forecasting contest. Despite many attempts
since the publication of Meese and Rogoff’s
results, economists have not convincingly overturned their findings.
Thus, if we look backward or forward over
periods of up to a year, the fundamentals don’t
seem to explain the exchange rate, contrary to
what standard models in international finance
textbooks imply. But this result might be dismissed by claiming that only the models tested
have failed to explain the exchange rate. Perhaps economists will discover a model that
works in the future.
Although a fundamentals-based model that
works is a possibility, evidence from other
countries suggests otherwise. In the European
Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM), exchange
rates between major European currencies are
kept relatively stable by the countries’ central
banks. If fundamentals are closely associated
with the currencies, they should be stabilized
as well. However, when we examine European
fundamentals, we find that they fluctuate about
as much as do the fundamentals of
nonstabilized currencies, such as the U.S. dollar. Hence, the evidence from the European
experience does not suggest a close connection
between the fundamentals and the exchange
rate, leading one to suspect that no fundamentals-based model will predict the short-run
exchange rate.8
It’s possible that the fundamentals really do
explain the exchange rate, but we can’t see the
relationship because we can’t observe the true
fundamentals. Perhaps if economists discov-

8

See Rose (1994) for a detailed discussion of this point.
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

ered different economic models that use fundamentals other than money supplies and real
output levels, the exchange rate could still be
explained in terms of basic economic quantities. For example, some economic models imply that the true fundamentals are business
technologies and tastes and preferences of consumers. However, the evidence from European
countries renders this potential solution implausible. According to such a model, stabilization of European currencies in the ERM corresponds to stabilization of the true fundamentals. But why should business technologies and
tastes and preferences of consumers change less
in Europe than they do in the United States?
At present, economists have found no evidence
to suggest they do and, indeed, have little reason to suppose that they will ever find such
evidence.
THE ALTERNATIVE VIEW:
MARKET SENTIMENT MATTERS
The alternative view is that exchange rates
are determined, at least in the short run (i.e.,
periods less than two years), by market sentiment. Under this view, the level of the exchange
rate is the result of a self-fulfilling prophecy:
participants in the foreign exchange market
expect a currency to be at a certain level in the
future; when they act on their expectations and
buy or sell the currency, it ends up at the predicted level, confirming their expectations.
Even if exchange rates are determined by
market sentiment in the short run, the fundamentals are still important, but not in the commonly supposed way. From reading the newspapers, we know that market participants take
the fundamentals very seriously when forming exchange-rate expectations. Thus, if we
wish to understand the level of the exchange
rate, we need to know the values of the fundamentals and, more important, how market participants interpret those levels. However, the
evidence we reviewed shows no pattern or
necessary connection between the fundamen22

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

tals and the level of the exchange rate. When
market participants use the fundamentals to
form expectations about the exchange rate, they
don’t use them in any consistent way that could
be picked up by an economic or statistical
model. As we have seen, we can do as well
forecasting the exchange rate by quoting
today’s rate.
Although the naive forecast is at least as accurate as statistical or model-based forecasts,
it’s still not very good. It’s just that statistical
or model-based forecasts are so bad that even
the naive forecast can do at least as well. How
can we improve our forecast? Unfortunately,
economists are just starting to build models of
market sentiment, so we can’t get much guidance from economic theory just yet. Nonetheless, we know that exchange rates are likely
determined by market sentiment, so it seems
reasonable to try to understand the psychology of the foreign exchange market to improve
forecasts of the short-run exchange rate.
To understand the psychology of the foreign
exchange market, we need to know about the
various economic theories. Even if they aren’t
very accurate, their implications may still influence expectations in the market, although
we would not expect any particular model to
have any consistent influence. We also need to
find out what the market is thinking. Probably
the best way to do so is to be an active participant in the foreign exchange market and to talk
to other participants to learn which events they
think are important for a particular currency’s
outlook. These events might be announcements of fundamentals, political events, or
some other factors. The analyst could then
concentrate on forecasting those events. Of
course, there will probably be no pattern to
which events are important. For example, the
U.S. budget deficit may well be important for
the dollar one year and unimportant the next.
Speculative Attacks. In some cases, the
forecaster might be able to make a reasonable
guess about the direction of the exchange rate’s
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

movement, even if he can’t be precise about
the timing. As an example, let’s review what
happened to the exchange rate between the
Swedish krona and the German deutsche mark
in the early 1990s.
Sweden applied to enter the ERM in May
1991 in a bid to stabilize its currency. To stabilize the krona-deutsche mark exchange rate,
interest rates in Sweden and Germany had to
be the same. Therefore, the Swedish and German central banks couldn’t independently use
monetary policy—that is, change short-term
interest rates—if they wanted to keep the exchange rate stable.9 If Sweden wanted to act
independently, it had to use fiscal policy (tax
and government spending policies) to stimulate the country’s growth rate.
However, a weak Swedish economy provoked speculators, who mounted an attack on
the krona in September 1992. Speculators knew
that the weak economy would tempt Sweden
to abandon its fixed exchange rate and use
monetary policy to cut short-term interest rates,
especially since the new Swedish government
was adopting restrictive fiscal policy. Speculators believed that if the Swedish central bank
cut the short-term interest rate, the krona
wouldn’t be as attractive to investors. Thus,
the speculators thought that after interest rates
were cut, the currency would depreciate with
respect to other ERM currencies. But since
speculators expected the depreciation to happen, they decided to sell the currency immediately, i.e., mount a speculative attack on the
currency.
This attack put the Swedish central bank in
an uncomfortable position. To combat the
currency’s depreciation, the central bank raised
short-term interest rates temporarily to repel
9
If a central bank can’t change the short-term interest
rate independently, it can’t use monetary policy independently to stimulate the economy. Hence, countries with stabilized exchange rates must give up the independent use of
monetary policy.

Loretta J. Mester
Gregory P. Hopper

the speculative attack—exactly the policy it
didn’t want in the face of sluggish economic
growth. In fact, the Swedish central bank raised
the short-term interest rate to an astonishing
500 percent and held it there for four days.10
The speculators were deterred, but not for
long. The speculators understood that the
Swedish central bank had to raise short-term
interest rates temporarily to support the currency. But they were betting that the central
bank wouldn’t fight off the attack for long, especially in the face of disquiet in the country
resulting from weak economic growth and the
higher interest rates needed to fight the speculative attack. The high short-term interest rates
had made the economic situation in Sweden
even more precarious, so, in November, the
speculators attacked again, selling the krona
in favor of other ERM currencies. This time the
Swedish central bank did not aggressively raise
interest rates and the krona depreciated.
Profit opportunities such as this one can
sometimes be exploited by speculators who
recognize that a country’s exchange-rate policy
is inconsistent with the monetary policy
needed, given a country’s domestic situation.
By paying careful attention to a country’s economic and political developments, a speculator can sometimes forecast the direction of a

10

If speculators expect the value of the currency to fall,
and they are right, speculators can profit by selling the currency short. As an example, suppose a speculator anticipates that the value of the Swedish krona with respect to
the deutsche mark will fall in one week. The speculator
could borrow krona and sell them for deutsche marks at
the current exchange rate. If the speculator is correct and
the krona does depreciate, at the end of the week the speculator can buy back the krona for fewer deutsche marks than
he sold them for. Provided the krona fell enough over the
week, the speculator can repay the loan with interest and
make a profit in deutsche marks. However, if the central
bank makes short-term interest rates high enough, it can
make this transaction unprofitable. Thus, one defense
against a speculative attack is to dramatically raise shortterm interest rates.
23

BUSINESS REVIEW

currency’s move when it breaks out of a stabilized exchange rate system. But the timing is
not easily forecast; it is probably determined
by market sentiment.11
WHAT ABOUT TECHNICAL RULES?
Many market participants don’t rely on the
fundamentals. Instead, they use technical rules,
which are procedures for identifying patterns
in exchange rates. A simple technical rule involves looking at interest rates in two countries. Suppose the first country is the United
States and the second is Canada. If the onemonth U.S. interest rate is higher than the onemonth rate in Canada, the U.S. dollar will tend
to appreciate with respect to the Canadian dollar. But if the one-month Canadian interest rate
is higher, the U.S. dollar will tend to depreciate with respect to the Canadian dollar. Economists and foreign exchange participants have
often noted this fact.12
Indeed, it is possible to make money, on average, by using this rule. The problem is that
implementing this rule carries risk. There is an
ongoing debate about how big this risk is, and
whether the average profits are explained by
the level of risk. After all, it would not be surprising that the market pays a premium to those
willing to assume substantial risk. Furthermore, the profits may have occurred only by
chance and may not recur. Sometimes, economists report other technical rules that seem to
make money in the foreign exchange market. 13
However, the considerations noted in the interest-rate differential rule apply to any tech-

11

For further discussion of the myriad problems that can
arise when countries attempt to fix their exchange rates,
see the article by Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995).

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

nical rule. Even if the rule makes profits on
average, the profits might be explained by the
level of risk assumed in applying the rule.
Moreover, the profits may well disappear when
we account for technical statistical problems.
Since economists are undecided at present
about whether technical rules really do make
money, it seems prudent to be cautious when
evaluating the merits of any such rule.
WHAT ABOUT
LONG-RUN FORECASTING?
Even though economic models or the fundamentals don’t help us understand the exchange rate in the short run (except to the extent that they influence market psychology),
there is evidence that models do better in the
long run. For example, economists Martin
Eichenbaum and Charles Evans report that
currencies react as theory would suggest to
unanticipated movements in the money supply, but only in the long run, after a period of
about two years. Standard monetary theories
would imply that an unanticipated decline in
the U.S. money supply would lead to an appreciation of the dollar with respect to other
currencies. Eichenbaum and Evans found that
the dollar does, in fact, appreciate in response
to an unanticipated monetary contraction;
however, the full effects on the dollar are not
registered until two years after the contraction,
suggesting that models may well work in explaining the exchange rate in the long run.14
IS ANY ASPECT OF THE
EXCHANGE RATE PREDICTABLE
IN THE SHORT RUN?
Although the level of the exchange rate in
the short run is not very predictable, volatilities and correlations of currencies are much

12

See my 1994 Business Review article for a nontechnical
discussion.
13

24

For an example, see Sweeney (1986).

14
For further evidence on the effects of unanticipated
monetary contractions on the exchange rate, see
Schlagenhauf and Wrase (1995).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

more predictable. The daily volatility of a currency measures the extent to which the
currency’s value in terms of another currency
fluctuates each day. The value of high-volatility currencies fluctuates more each day than
that of low-volatility currencies. Correlations
measure the extent to which currencies move
together. In general, volatilities and correlations
vary with time, rising or falling each day in a
somewhat predictable way.
The time-varying nature of the daily volatility of the dollar in terms of the deutsche mark
can be seen in the figure. Notice that, in 1991,
days on which the volatility of the dollar is high
tend to cluster together, and in 1990, days with
lower volatility follow one another. Since daily
volatility clusters together, it is predictable. If
we want to predict tomorrow’s volatility, we
need only look at the recent past. If daily volatility has been high over the recent past, we
can be reasonably sure that it will be high tomorrow.
This idea forms the basis for statistical mod-

Loretta J. Mester
Gregory P. Hopper

els of a currency’s volatility. The GARCH
model, developed by economist Tim Bollerslev,
who built on work by economist Robert Engle,
uses the volatility-clustering phenomenon to
predict future volatility. In essence, a GARCH
model measures the strength of the relationship between recent volatility and current volatility. Once this strength is known, it can be used
to forecast volatility. GARCH models have
good empirical support for exchange rates and
are being used in practical applications in the
foreign exchange market.15
GARCH models can be extended to handle
two or more currencies, and they can measure
the strength of recent correlations in predict-

15

GARCH stands for Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity. For the technical details of how
GARCH models work, see Bollerslev (1986). Examples of
technical applications of GARCH models of exchange rates
include Bollerslev (1990) and Kroner and Sultan (1993).
Heynen and Kat (1994) use GARCH to forecast volatility.

Daily Percent Dollar Return on Deutsche Mark
Percent
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
-4

1990

1991

25

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

ing current ones. Once this strength is understood, it can be used to forecast correlations.
USES OF VOLATILITY AND
CORRELATION FORECASTS
Volatility and correlation forecasts have important uses in finance. First, currency derivatives, securities whose value depends on the
value of currencies, require measures of volatility and sometimes correlations to price them.
GARCH models can supply estimates of these
volatilities and correlations. Second, volatilities of individual currencies coupled with correlations between currencies can be combined

to determine the volatility of a portfolio of currencies. Since the volatility of a portfolio measures the extent to which the portfolio’s value
fluctuates, the volatility can be used to assess
a portfolio’s risk. Portfolios with higher volatilities are riskier because they have a tendency
to lose more per day—or gain more per day—
than do portfolios with lower volatilities (see
Using GARCH to Measure Portfolio Risk). Finally,
knowledge of volatilities and correlations can
help an investor choose the proportions of each
currency to hold in a portfolio. For example,
knowing a portfolio’s volatilities and correlations may show an investor how to rearrange

Using GARCH to Measure Portfolio Risk
Here, we illustrate the use of a GARCH model to manage risk in a simple portfolio of two
currencies, the yen and the deutsche mark. Using daily data on the yen and the deutsche mark from
January 2, 1981, to June 30, 1996, the time-varying volatilities and correlations were estimated using
Engle and Lee’s (1993a,b) GARCH model. Suppose we have a portfolio with $1 million invested in
yen and $1 million invested in deutsche marks. Then we can calculate the value at risk (VaR) of the
portfolio. The VaR is the maximum loss the portfolio will experience a certain fraction of the time
during a specific period. For example, we can see from the table that daily VaR at the 95 percent
confidence level is $12,000. That means that 95 percent of the time, the largest daily loss on the
portfolio will be $12,000. But 5 percent of the time, the loss will be bigger, sometimes by a substantial amount. The daily loss measures the difference between the value of the portfolio at the end of
one trading day and its value at the end of the next trading day.
As another example, consider weekly VaR at the 98 percent confidence interval. The numbers
indicate that 98 percent of the time, the loss over five trading days will not exceed $35,000. But 2
percent of the time, the losses will be bigger. See Hopper (1996) for more discussion.
Value at Risk of a Currency Portfolio
with $1 Million Invested in Both Yen and Deutsche marks

95 percent
98 percent
99 percent

One-Day Horizon
$12,000
$15,000
$18,000

Five-Day Horizon
$27,000
$35,000
$41,000

These numbers for the value at risk apply to the risk in the portfolio on July 1, 1996, the day after the
end of the data period. However, the reason for using a GARCH model is that volatility varies over
time. The value at risk would be higher in times of greater volatility and lower when the market is
less volatile.

26

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

the proportions of currencies in a portfolio so
that he has the same return, on average, but a
lower risk of loss.
CONCLUSION
The evidence discussed in this article suggests that economic models and indeed fundamental economic quantities are not very useful in explaining the history of the exchange
rate or in forecasting its value over the next
year or so. This fact has important implications
for market participants. It is all too common
to encounter private-sector foreign exchange
economists who tell very cogent stories designed to buttress their short-term forecasts for
the values of currencies. These stories are often based on plausible economic assumptions
or models. These economists hope that market
participants will act on their forecasts and trade
currencies. However, if these forecasts are justified by a belief that economic models or fundamentals influence the exchange rate in the
short run, it’s likely they are not very good.
Indeed, we have seen that these forecasts will
probably be outperformed by the naive forecast: tomorrow’s exchange rate will be what it
is today.

Loretta J. Mester
Gregory P. Hopper

On the other hand, to the extent that these
forecasts reflect market sentiment or a self-fulfilling prophecy, they may be useful. Unfortunately, it is difficult to judge when this is the
case. The difficulty is accentuated by the
unobservability of market expectations. A forecaster might be using a model he believes in,
and his forecast might turn out to be correct if
the market also temporarily believes the implications of the model. But it is hard, if not
impossible, to know what the market expects;
hence, it is hard to judge the merits of a forecast.
Fortunately, the situation is better regarding volatilities and correlations, which follow
predictable patterns. The GARCH model and
its more sophisticated variants can be used to
price derivatives, assess currency portfolio risk,
and set allocations of currencies in portfolios.
Economists are continually discovering new
empirical facts about volatility and correlations.
No doubt the GARCH model will eventually
be supplanted by an alternative, but for now,
economists will use the GARCH model, or
some variation of it, to forecast volatilities and
correlations of currencies.

REFERENCES
Backus, David. “Empirical Models of the Exchange Rate: Separating the Wheat from the
Chaff,” Canadian Journal of Economics (1984), pp. 824-46.
Bilson, John. “The Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate—Some Empirical Evidence,”
IMF Staff Papers, 25 (1978), pp. 48-75.
Bollerslev, Tim. “Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity,” Journal of
Econometrics, 31 (1986), pp. 307-27.
Bollerslev, Tim. “Modelling the Coherence in Short-Run Nominal Exchange Rates: A Multivariate Generalized ARCH Model,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 72 (1990), pp.
498-505.

27

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1997

REFERENCES (continued)
Branson, William. “Macroeconomic Determinants of Real Exchange Rate Risks,” in R.J.
Herring, ed., Managing Foreign Exchange Risk. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press, 1983.
Branson, William, Hannu Halttunen, and Paul Masson. “Exchange Rates in the Short Run:
The Dollar-Deutschemark Rate,” European Economic Review, 10 (1977), pp. 303-24.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. “Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics,” Journal of Political
Economy, 84 (1976), pp. 1161-76.
Edwards, Sebastian. “Exchange Rates and News: A Multi-Currency Approach,” Journal of
International Money and Finance, 1 (1982), pp. 211-24.
Edwards, Sebastian. “Floating Exchange Rates, Expectations, and New Information,” Journal
of Monetary Economics, 11, (1983), pp. 321-36.
Eichenbaum, Martin, and Charles Evans. “Some Empirical Evidence on the Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates,” NBER Working Paper 4271 (1993).
Engle, Robert F. “Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Estimates of the
Variance of U.K. Inflation,” Econometrica, 50 (1982), pp. 987-1008.
Engle R., and G. Lee. “A Permanent and Transitory Component Model of Stock Return
Volatility,” Discussion Paper 92-44R, Department of Economics, University of California, San Diego (1993a).
Engle R., and G. Lee. “Long Run Volatility Forecasting for Individual Stocks in a One
Factor Model,” Discussion Paper 93-30, Department of Economics, University of
California, San Diego (1993b).
Frankel, Jeffrey. “In Search of the Exchange Rate Risk Premium: A Six Currency Test Assuming Mean-Variance Optimization,” Journal of International Money and Finance, 1
(1982), pp. 255-74.
Frenkel, Jacob. “A Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate: Doctrinal Aspects and Empirical Evidence,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 78 (1976), pp. 200-24.
Frenkel, Jacob. “Exchange Rates, Prices, and Money: Lessons From the 1920s,” American
Economic Review, 70 (1980), pp. 235-42.

28

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

What's the Point of Credit Scoring? Economic Factors or Market Sentiment?
What Determines the Exchange Rate:

Loretta J. Hopper
Gregory P. Mester

Heynen, Ronald C., and Harry M. Kat. “Volatility Prediction: A Comparison of the Stochastic Volatility, GARCH (1,1), and EGARCH (1,1) Models,” The Journal of Derivatives, 2 (1994), pp. 50-65.
Hodrick, Robert. “An Empirical Analysis of the Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate,”
in J. Frenkel and H.G. Johnson, eds., The Economics of Exchange Rates. Reading, Mass.:
Addison Wesley, 1978, pp. 97-116.
Hopper, Greg. “Is the Foreign Exchange Market Inefficient?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Business Review (May/June 1994).
Hopper, Greg. “Value at Risk: A New Methodology For Measuring Portfolio Risk,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (July/August 1996).
Kroner, Kenneth F., and Jahangir Sultan, “Time-Varying Distributions and Dynamic Hedging
with Foreign Currency Futures,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28 (1993),
pp. 535-51.
Lewis, Karen. “Testing the Portfolio Balance Model: A Multi-lateral Approach,” Journal of
International Economics, 7 (1988), pp. 273-88.
MacDonald, Ronald. “Some Tests of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis in the Foreign
Exchange Markets,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 30 (1983), pp. 235-50.
Meese, Richard, and Kenneth Rogoff. “Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the 1970s: Do
They Fit Out of Sample?” Journal of International Economics, 14 (1983), pp. 3-24.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. “The Mirage of Fixed Exchange Rates,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 9 (1995), pp. 73-96.
Rose, Andrew. “Are Exchange Rates Macroeconomic Phenomena?” Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco Economic Review, 1 (1994), pp. 19-30.
Schlagenhauf, Don, and Jeffrey Wrase. “Liquidity and Real Activity in a Simple Open
Economy Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 35 (1995), pp. 431-61.
Sweeney, Richard J. “Beating the Foreign Exchange Market,” Journal of Finance (1986),
pp. 163-82.

29