View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Hi

Business
Review

The BUSINESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. It is
edited by Sarah Burke. Artwork is designed
and produced by Dianne Hallowell under the
direction of Ronald B. Williams. The views
expressed here are not necessarily those of this
Reserve Bank or of the Federal Reserve System.
SUBSCRIPTIONS. Single-copy subscriptions
for individuals are available without charge. Insti­
tutional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
BACK ISSUES. Back issues are available free of
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may
order up to 50 copies by submitting requests on
institutional letterhead; other orders are limited to 1
copy per request. Microform copies are available for
purchase from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb
Road, Ann Arbor, MI 48106.
REPRODUCTION. Perm ission must be
obtained to reprint portions o f articles or whole
articles. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.
Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes o f address, and requests to reprint to
Publications, Federal Reserve Bank o f Philadelphia,
Department o f Research and Statistics, Ten
Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574,
or telephone (215) 574-6428. Please direct editorial
communications to the same address, or telephone
(215) 574-3805.


2


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

HOW A LITTLE INFLATION
CAN LEAD TO A LOT
Carlos Zarazaga
Why does inflation run out of control in
some countries but not in others? What is
the relationship between inflation—espe­
cially hyperinflation—and central bank
independence? As this article suggests,
the rate of inflation may depend less on
the specific legal independence of the
central bank and more on the nature of
fiscal and budgetary institutions. Coun­
tries that can closely monitor government
spending will keep inflation low. But coun­
tries in which monitoring is nonexistent
or severely limited will almost surely see
a little bit of inflation become a lot.
PUBLIC TRANSIT:
REALIZING ITS POTENTIAL
Richard Voith
The rationale for subsidizing mass transit
is based on the assumption that there are
social benefits associated with transit. The
social benefits of public transportation,
such as reduced congestion and air pollu­
tion, will be large only if transit is success­
ful in the marketplace. Dick Voith looks at
the issue of subsidies for public transit
and concludes that three things are neces­
sary to achieve the greatest benefits from
transit: a measurable objective, appropri­
ate incentives, and a long-run strategy.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How a Little Inflation
Can Lead to a Lot
Carlos Zarazaga*
he past 10 years have witnessed one of the
most amazing streaks of extreme inflation
episodes in economic history. Peru holds the
dubious honor of having the record monthly
inflation rate for those years: 396 percent in
August 1990. Runners-up were Argentina, 197
percent in July 1989; Bolivia, 182 percent in
February 1985; and Brazil, 81.3 percent in March
1990.

T

*When this article was written, Carlos Zarazaga was an
economist in the Research Department of the Philadelphia
Fed. He is now a senior economist and executive director of
the Center for Latin American Economics at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.




The intensity of these inflation rates may be
shocking, but perhaps as striking is their roller­
coaster pattern. For example, in Argentina the
inflation rate fell sharply from a peak of 197
percent in July 1989 to a more “normal" 6
percent a month three months later, only to
jump again to 96 percent in March 1990. A
similar roller-coaster pattern is apparent for
Peru.
Why would countries experiencing already
uncomfortably high inflation rates of 5 to 30
percent a month push those rates to even more
unbearable ones of 100, 200, or 400 percent a
month?
A popular explanation of these extreme in­
flation episodes is that policymakers eager to
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

win reelection surrendered to political pres­
sure for subsidies and tax cuts, leaving money
creation as the only way to finance a huge
budget deficit. Very rapid money growth, in
turn, caused the jump in inflation. One problem
with that explanation is that inflation rates of
100 percent a month were almost always ac­
companied by severe social and political unrest
and, in some cases, by riots. As a result incum­
bents met a poor fate: nearly all of them were
ousted from office shortly thereafter by popu­
lar election or impeachment, or they resigned
voluntarily. Surely policymakers seeking an­
other term in office could not have desired such
an outcome.
It might be argued that even if policymakers
in those countries didn't deliberately seek ex­
treme inflation, they did play with fire: they
were tolerating inflation rates of 5 to 30 percent
a month, exposing themselves to the risk of
runaway inflation. Readers with the view that
a little inflation can lead to a lot are in good
company. The Chairman of the Federal Re­
serve System of the United States, Alan
Greenspan, recently stated, "I don't think that
there is a general agreement that 3 percent is
acceptable, because the trouble with modest
rates of inflation, and 3 percent is a modest rate
of inflation, is that there is a tendency, if it goes
on indefinitely, [for it] to accelerate."1
Appealing as it may be, this argument must
confront the challenge of some examples to the
contrary. Several countries, such as the United
States and Japan, have been running inflation
rates of at most 1.4 percent a month since
World War II, but these countries never expe­
rienced very high inflation.
Why do some countries seem to be capable
of keeping a little bit of inflation under control,

A nsw er to a question during testimony before the Sub­
committee on Economic Growth and Credit Formation of
the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs of
the U.S. House of Representatives, February 22,1994.


4


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

while others don't? And why does the roller­
coaster pattern of inflation appear in the latter?
This article will offer possible answers to
these questions. We will show that the idea that
a little inflation can lead to a lot contains a germ
of truth, but the outcome depends crucially on
the nature of the fiscal and budgetary institu­
tions. Countries in which those institutions
make it possible to establish how government
spending is allocated among different uses will
be able to keep inflation low. But a little infla­
tion will almost surely become a lot in countries
in which such monitoring is nonexistent or
severely limited.
Our interpretation of why a little inflation
may lead to a lot will shed some light on
another important economic policy issue as
well: the relationship between central bank in­
dependence and inflation.2While ironclad in­
dependence of a country's central bank may
guarantee low inflation, we will argue that in
most countries low inflation depends more on
the nature of fiscal and budgetary institutions
than on the formal legislation governing the
central bank.
Because economists and other social scien­
tists have only now started to understand some
of the issues raised above, parts of the follow­
ing discussion will be unavoidably tentative in
nature. Trying to uncover the role that the
interplay of monetary, fiscal, and budgetary
institutions has in generating low, high, or
variable inflation seems worth the effort, how­
ever; countries in Eastern Europe and in what
used to be the Soviet Union, as well as countries
in Latin America, are changing their fiscal and
monetary institutions. So are the European
countries that signed the Maastricht Treaty,
which includes provisions for a European
Monetary Union. Undoubtedly, these coun­
tries would like to avoid adopting the faulty

2For a more thorough review of the literature on this
relationship, see Pollard (1993).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Carlos Zarazaga

How a Little Inflation Can Lead to a Lot

institutions that may have been respon­
sible for the roller-coaster inflation ex­
periences of the last 10 years.
WHAT DO EXTREME INFLATION
COUNTRIES HAVE IN COMMON?
A look at the inflation experiences of
several Latin American countries over
the last 10 years shows striking similari­
ties (see Figure). Argentina, Peru, and
Brazil all experienced times when infla­
tion was high—between 3 and 30 per­
cent a month—but fairly stable, and other
times when inflation rose dramatically
for short periods.
Extreme inflation experiences are not
limited to Latin America. Take, for ex­
ample, the case of Ukraine. The inflation
rate in this independent republic of the
Commonwealth of Independent States
had been around 30 percent a month
since shortly after the dissolution of the
Soviet Union until it jumped to 70 per­
cent a month in February 1994. The simi­
larity of these inflation rates to those of
a country as geographically distant and
culturally different as Brazil is striking.
Russia has also been experiencing high
inflation rates (10 to 30 percent a month)
since the dissolution of the Soviet Union,
as have several Eastern European coun­
tries. Turkey would also qualify as a
member of this club: it experienced in­
flation rates between 2 and 4 percent a
month during most of the 1970s and
1980s, with a spike of 21 percent in
February 1980. Intense inflationary pres­
sures have reappeared in that country
lately.
What do all these economies have in
common? Our main hypothesis is that
the common feature ultimately respon­
sible for their extreme inflation is bud­
getary and fiscal institutions that make
it d ifficu lt, if not im p ossible, for



FIGURE

Inflation Rate for Argentina
1985:1 - 1992:10*
Monthly Inflation in %
200
175
150
125
100
75
7

50

A

25
0

u

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

,

1990

1991 1992

*as measured by the Consumer Price Index for Buenos Aires
Source: National Institute of Statistics and Census

Inflation Rate for Peru
1985:2 - 1993:3*

*as measured by the Consumer Price Index
Source: Central Bank of Peru

Inflation Rate for Brazil
1987:1 - 1992:12*

*as measured by the Indice Gral. do Precos - disp. Interna
Source: Current Economic Conditions, Getulio Vargas Foundation
Rio de Janiero
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

policymakers to monitor the allocation of gov­
ernment spending among different uses.
Before describing these institutions in more
detail, it will be enlightening to present a brief
overview of the features and characteristics of
high inflation economies that will be important
for our explanation of how a little inflation can
lead to a lot.
THE ROLE OF A LARGE PUBLIC SECTOR
AND ITS DEFICIT
As in any nation, part of government spend­
ing in the high inflation countries mentioned
above results from the need to provide public
services. These countries need to build and
maintain public buildings, schools, and infra­
structure, and to pay public employees. In this
respect, high inflation economies do not seem
different from low inflation ones.
What makes them different, at least during
the time in which they experienced high infla­
tion, is that their governments (either at the
federal or local level) directly controlled im­
portant sectors of the economy that in other
countries are in the hands of the private sector.
The governments of these countries owned,
sometimes in limited partnership with the pri­
vate sector, an impressive array of physical and
financial assets: mining (oil, copper); industrial
conglomerates (distilleries, petrochemicals,
steel, aluminum, shipyards, defense-related
industries); utilities (electricity, gas, water, tele­
phone, TV, radio); transportation (railroads,
airlines, ports and airports); financial services
(banks).
As President Eisenhower warned in his fa­
mous speech about the military-industrial com­
plex in the United States, public-sector indus­
trial complexes came to amass independent
power. In some high inflation countries they
went as far as refusing to pay taxes for which
they were legally liable or refusing to prepare
financial statements and balance sheets not
only for the public but also for officials in
charge of the government budget.3

6


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

Through a variety of means, such as special
tax treatment, subsidized interest rates, ex­
change rates and tariffs, or artificially inflated
wages, these public-sector industrial complexes
strained government budgets. It's tempting to
buy the conventional explanation that the fiscal
authorities decided to finance the resulting
huge fiscal deficit with money creation and that
this fast expansion of the money supply was
ultimately responsible for the extreme inflation
described above. But this conventional view
presents some problems.
First, when inflation rises, people hold a
smaller fraction of their wealth in money. As a
result, very rapid money creation doesn't re­
ally help much in financing higher government
spending in real terms.4 Second, the conven­
tional view does not explain the inflation spikes
we observed. Third, as mentioned in the intro­
duction, inflation rates of 100 percent were not
conducive to the political survival of incum­
bents and policymakers.
So, why did policymakers allow inflation to
reach extreme levels? Unless we assume they
were plainly irrational or perverse, their intent
must have been to finance the fiscal deficit with
much lower rates of money creation (and infla­
tion). This may have appeared a sensible deci­
sion at the time, given that economic research
has argued that financing a fiscal deficit with
moderate amounts of money creation is the
right thing to do in many circumstances.5

3Thus, we find that in a high inflation country such as
Turkey "the ordinary budget statistics conceal how much of
the taxpayers' money goes into the three dozen main state
economic enterprises and the 100 or so they wholly or
mainly own." (From "A Survey on Turkey," The Economist,
December 14,1991)
4Research shows that there's an inflation rate that gives
the government the most revenue possible. Higher inflation
rates generate less revenue; see Sargent and Wallace (1987)
and Zarazaga (1994).
5Phelps (1973) was the first to discuss this possibility.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How a Little Inflation Can Lead to a Lot

Carlos Zarazaga

example, financing public education, police,
courts, and infrastructure) and how much was
used to funnel funds, mainly through publicsector industrial complexes, to vested inter­
ests?6
An indication of those institutional ailments
is that in many of these countries the fiscal
authorities operated without a lawfully ap­
proved government budget for long periods of
time. In Argentina, for example, in several
years over the past couple of decades the gov­
ernment budget has been approved when the
year for which it was effective had almost
expired. Another case in point is Ukraine, whose
budgetary institutions are virtually nonexist­
ent—not surprising given that this republic
became independent as Soviet economic and
political institutions were collapsing.
The practice of planning government bud­
gets several years ahead, typically observed in
all low inflation industrialized countries, is
almost invariably absent in extreme inflation
countries. Even worse, these countries typi­
cally lack the necessary information to monitor
the execution of previous years' budgets. Even
gross government budget statistics have not
been available except with several years' lag.
Of course, the problem isn't just one of a lack
of statistics about the economic activities of the
public sector; it's actually one of monitoring,
auditing, and management control: missing or
faulty statistics can hide the true state of affairs.
Studies by David Robinson and Peter Stella
(1992) and Mario Blejer and Adrienne Cheasty
(1992) illustrate how misleading government
budget statistics can be because of the manipu­
lation of the valuation of government assets or
the presence of substantial quasi-fiscal deficits
WHERE DID ALL THAT MONEY GO?
A common problem of high-inflation econo­ in the transactions between the central bank
mies was that the nature of their institutional and the financial system. For example, public
arrangements, budgetary processes, and pub­ enterprises can reduce losses by taking depre­
lic-sector statistics was such that no one could
answer a very simple, but important question:
exactly how much government spending was
^The contents of this section are more fully documented
for genuine public goods and services (for in Zarazaga (1992).

But the road to hell is paved with good
intentions, and this was no exception. In decid­
ing to finance the fiscal deficit with a little bit of
money creation, policymakers in extreme infla­
tion countries may have acted a little bit like the
Sorcerer's Apprentice. In the version of the
story presented in the classic movie "Fantasia,"
the Sorcerer orders his Apprentice to take some
buckets of water to fill the big fountain in the
lower level of the castle. After a while, tired of
this taxing chore, the Apprentice decides to put
to use the magic formulas he is just learning to
master. At the sound of his magic words, two
brooms start carrying buckets full of water
from the spring to the fountain. Proud of his
skills as a sorcerer and feeling relieved from the
arduous task, the Apprentice falls asleep. Un­
fortunately, he has forgotten a little detail: each
broom replicates itself after each trip. The Ap­
prentice suddenly wakes up in the middle of a
flood caused by an ever-growing army of
brooms. Only the intervention of the angry
Sorcerer stops the process and saves the castle
from total collapse.
What the policymakers of these high infla­
tion countries may have forgotten is that fi­
nancing the fiscal deficit with a little bit of
money creation may be the right thing to do
only when there is perfect knowledge of the
exact amount of government spending appor­
tioned among different uses. Unfortunately,
this condition was violated in the economies
that suffered the high inflations described above,
and sadly, these policymakers woke up to the
reality of inflation rates several times higher
than they had intended.




7

BUSINESS REVIEW

ciation allowances for a lower amount than
would be required by the economic deprecia­
tion of their capital. Likewise, the central bank
can overvalue the assets offered as collateral by
financial institutions borrowing from it.
Put simply, in the past 20 years the highest
inflation rates have been observed in econo­
mies in which it was difficult to determine
where the public monies went. In contrast,
countries with the lowest inflation rates have
had more transparent and accountable budget­
ary institutions. Thus, the evidence suggests
that the nature and quality of the fiscal institu­
tions involved in the preparation, adoption,
and execution of the government budget may
be an important determinant of a country's
ability to keep inflation under control.
NOT KNOWING WHERE THE MONEY
WENT AND HIGH INFLATION
Let's consider a simplified example that of­
fers some insight into the importance of fiscal
institutions. This example is meant to illustrate
some common features of high inflation coun­
tries, rather than the details of any one coun­
try.7
All governments need to provide public
goods and services, such as maintenance of
essential infrastructure (for example, roads and
highways). Typically, the amount of spending
required to provide those goods and services
varies unpredictably, for reasons such as tech­
nological changes, changes in the price of ma­
terials needed to repair and maintain the infra­
structure, or even bad weather. Imagine a situ­
ation in which those expenditures are "nor­
mal" 90 percent of the time and abnormally
high 10 percent of the time.
Suppose the benevolent policymaker in
charge of providing public goods and services
is convinced, perhaps because of the economic

7The theory behind the analysis in this section is formally
developed in Zarazaga (1993).


8


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

research mentioned earlier, that it's a good idea
to finance those expenditures not only through
the usual means (collecting taxes and issuing
debt) but also with a little bit of money creation
(and thus a little inflation). In normal periods,
a low rate of expansion of the money supply—
say, 3 percent growth—will be enough to pay
for those expenditures. But in abnormal peri­
ods those expenditures rise, so a faster exp an ­
sion of the money supply— say, 6 percent
growth—is needed.
In other words, the intention of the benevo­
lent policymaker in charge of providing public
goods and services is to finance them with a
moderate amount of money creation: the money
supply will grow at a rate of, at most, 6 percent.
But this intention can be thwarted by the pres­
ence of other, less altruistic policymakers, who
funnel funds to their constituencies mainly
through the public-sector industrial complexes.
Imagine, for example, the situation at the
Ministry of Public Works and Transportation.
The request for funds from that Ministry may
reflect such legitimate expenses as the cost of
replacing several hundred miles of obsolete
railways. But it may also include special ben­
efits—a generous retirement plan for railroad
workers or subsidized shipping rates for farm­
ers—for powerful constituencies with vested
interests in the railroad system.
Likewise, imagine the situation at the Minis­
try of Industry and Public Utilities. Its legiti­
mate expenditures include maintaining the
equipment required for the production and
transmission of electricity. But its budget may
also contain implicit subsidies, such as reduced
electric rates for certain industries or artifi­
cially inflated fees paid to contractors.
What's important for our explanation is that
certain constituencies with substantial eco­
nomic, financial, and political ties to different
government agencies can manipulate the bud­
gets of those agencies. Subsidies favoring these
constituencies can be disguised as expendi­
tures for public goods and services; therefore,
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How a Little Inflation Can Lead to a Lot

the benevolent policymaker will authorize such
expenditures (financed with money creation),
even if in reality at least part of that money
creation finances hidden subsidies. So on top of
the money created to finance essential public
goods and services, there is the money created
to funnel subsidies to particular constituencies.
Because policymakers can't determine ex­
actly which part of government spending went
to finance public goods and services and which
part went to subsidies, we say that the economy
suffers from imperfect monitoring. By con­
trast, if a policymaker could say exactly how
much money was apportioned to each of those
two possible uses, the economy would be
characterized by perfect monitoring.
Why is information about the use of the
public monies so important? Because the avail­
ability (and quality) of that information will
have dramatic consequences for inflation. Un­
der perfect monitoring, it will be possible to
keep inflation low. By contrast, under imper­
fect monitoring, the attempt to finance public
goods and services with a little inflation will
lead to political pressures for higher subsidies.
As a consequence, a little inflation will end up
lead ing to a lot, som etim es even to
hyperinflation.
Inflation Bias. Economies such as the one
described above have a high inflation bias. This
bias arises when each policymaker cares only
about his own constituents and not about the
harm that inflation causes to other constituen­
cies. U nder these circu m stan ces, each
policymaker representing a constituency will
try to put in place fiscal programs that benefit
his constituency—even if financing such pro­
grams with money creation produces inflation
that hurts other constituencies. The money cre­
ation induced by the actions of each individual
policymaker adds up to rapid overall expan­
sion of the money supply. As a result, money
creation— and, therefore, inflation—ends up
being much higher than each policymaker had
individually intended. The costs of higher in­



Carlos Zarazaga

flation more than offset any benefits a constitu­
ency may have gained from the subsidies it gets
and makes all constituencies worse off.
Is there any way of d eterrin g each
policymaker from requesting subsidies that
just end up causing high inflation? The answer
is a resounding yes under perfect monitoring,
but not under imperfect monitoring.
Inflation When Policymakers Know Where
the Money Went. The perfect monitoring sce­
nario is ideal for understanding why having
fiscal and budgetary institutions that make it
possible to monitor government expenditures
can help to avoid undesirably high inflations.
If the different constituencies of the economy
expect to interact indefinitely with each other,
policymakers representing them could prom­
ise not to grant any subsidies in excess of a
certain amount. However, both parties would
understand that if any one party breaks the
agreement, the others will retaliate by giving to
his own constituents the same amount of excess
subsidies given by the policym aker who
cheated.
Because under perfect monitoring cheating
can always be detected, the only thing that
cheating will accomplish will be retaliation by
the other policymakers. The result of this "re­
taliation" or "punishment phase" will be the
outcome described in the previous section:
higher inflation without any net gains to any
constituency. Thus, the temptation to grab the
short-run gains from cheating just once (that is,
from giving excess subsidies) will be offset by
the long-run costs of the punishment that will
follow.
With perfect monitoring, then, the different
constituencies have the ability to keep each
other from demanding more than their fair
share of subsidies. This prevents the rapid
money growth that the financing of higher
subsidies would require and, therefore, pre­
vents undesirably high inflations. For example,
France, which publishes detailed government
budget figures and thus allows policymakers
9

BUSINESS REVIEW

to closely monitor the government budget, has
low inflation despite the presence of a large
public sector.
The situation changes dramatically, how­
ever, when faulty fiscal and budgetary institu­
tions make it impossible to perfectly detect
cheating (i.e., giving excess subsidies) by
policymakers trying to favor a particular con­
stituency.
Inflation When Policymakers Don't Know
Where the Money Went. Under imperfect
monitoring no policymaker will be able to es­
tablish with certainty whether others have
cheated each time the money supply grows at
an abnormally high rate.8 This poses a quan­
dary. If a policymaker observes unusually rapid
money growth but does not retaliate—on the
assumption that this is merely an abnormal
period in which the provision of necessary
public goods and services requires unusually
high spending—he creates the potential for
other policymakers to increase the money sup­
ply every period by giving subsidies to their
constituents. On the other hand, if a policymaker
retaliates on the suspicion that it's a normal
period but other policymakers are cheating, he
may be retaliating for something that never
happened, since legitimate spending will be
abnormally high some of the time. Is it possible
to sustain the low subsidy, low inflation out­
come of the perfect monitoring case? The an­
swer is no when there is imperfect monitoring.
Each policymaker will provide extra subsi­
dies to his constituents every time he sees
unusually high money growth, regardless of
whether the cause of that unusual growth was

8The uncertainty about the use of the public monies in a
high inflation country such as Bolivia is apparent in Jeffrey
Sachs's account of that country's experience with extreme
inflation during 1982-85: "Surprisingly, it is difficult, even
four years in retrospect, to uncover precisely the causes for
this jump in money creation...The problem with nailing
down a culprit lies with the disarray of Bolivian fiscal data
during this period." (Sachs, 1986).


10


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

cheating by some other policymaker or the
spending required for the provision of public
goods and services in abnormal times. The
reason is that, unlike in the perfect monitoring
case, the subsidy war must be actually carried
out if it is to deter cheating. This is analogous to
the rule in baseball that specifies that a batter is
always awarded first base when hit by a pitch.
If pitchers weren't effectively punished for hit­
ting batters, pitchers would have an incentive
to hit batters more often and plead accident.9
*
To be effective, the subsidy war must be carried
out in economies with imperfect monitoring.
This is the crucial fact in explaining why infla­
tion remains low in economies with perfect
monitoring but stays high—and occasionally
shoots up in the form of hyperinflationary
spikes—in economies with imperfect monitor­
ing.
Inflation Under Perfect and Imperfect
Monitoring. As explained above, subsidy wars
never occur under perfect monitoring. The
threat of retaliation deters deviations from a
low subsidy policy because such deviations
would always be detected without ambiguity;
subsidies remain at low levels because each
policymaker knows that the benefits of extra
subsidies to his constituents would be more
than offset by the harm from extra inflation.
The growth of the money supply financing
subsidies, and therefore the associated infla­
tion, remains low as well. In the case of imper­
fect monitoring, however, the low subsidy
policy will be abandoned during abnormal
periods when financing public goods and ser­
vices requires unusually high growth of the
money supply. Since the higher subsidies of

9Porter (1983) and Green and Porter (1984) were the first
to examine what happens when there is imperfect monitor­
ing of the actions of participants in strategic games or
situations (such as baseball) and to formally analyze the
clever mechanisms and rules participants might use in
those circumstances.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Hozv a Little Inflation Can Lead to a Lot

this retaliation stage are paid for by printing
money, the result is even higher growth of the
money supply in abnormal times and a consid­
erable acceleration of inflation, perhaps to the
levels of 100,200, or 400 percent observed in the
countries discussed earlier.1
0
The argument we've been making also ex­
plains why inflation in economies with imper­
fect monitoring is higher than in their perfect
monitoring counterparts even in normal times.
That is, the low inflation of normal times under
imperfect monitoring is higher than the perma­
nently low inflation that would prevail in that
same economy under perfect monitoring. Es­
sentially, the problem is that under imperfect
monitoring the threat of a subsidy war means
the various policymakers won't cooperate as
they would under perfect monitoring. As a
consequence, subsidies in normal times (and
therefore money growth and inflation) are not
as low as in the perfect monitoring case.1 To
1
illustrate the point, compare the normal infla­
tion rate of an economy with poor monitoring
of the government budget, such as Argentina,
with the normal inflation rate of a country with
adequate fiscal and budgetary institutions, such
as the United States. The normal inflation rate
for Argentina has been about 10 percent a
month in the last 20 years, while for the United
States it has been about 0.3 percent a month
during that same period.
CENTRAL BANK INDEPENDENCE AND
FISCAL INSTITUTIONS
A possible objection to the analysis above is
that high inflation comes about only because
the central bank prints money at the command

10We discuss elsewhere (Zarazaga, 1993) that these in­
flationary outbursts are not a figment of the data, somewhat
artificially induced by factors other than those discussed in
this article, such as the lifting of price controls or wars.
n The reasons for this outcome are rather technical and
are discussed in detail in Zarazaga (1993).




Carlos Zarazaga

of the different policymakers who directly or
indirectly control monetary policy.
Had the central bank been completely inde­
pendent and charged solely with avoiding in­
flation, policymakers would have found it im­
possible to finance the provision of public goods
and services, or subsidies, with money cre­
ation. This by itself would have eliminated the
imperfect monitoring problems and the associ­
ated high inflation.
But as noted earlier, many economists argue
that it may be best to use money creation to
finance part of the fiscal deficit. In this case, it's
not clear that complete independence of the
central bank is always desirable. Judging by the
fact that inflation is a worldwide phenomenon,
every country is directly or indirectly financing
part of its deficit with money creation. None
appears to have a perfectly independent cen­
tral bank focused solely on preventing infla­
tion.
Perhaps more important, there's no
such thing as ironclad legal protection of cen­
tral bank independence. The evidence suggests
that written laws cannot preserve the effective
independence of the central bank any more
than a wedding ring can preserve fidelity.1 As
2
O tm ar Issin g , ch ief econ om ist of the
Bundesbank, aptly said in a recent speech,
"Central banks alone cannot ensure, or guaran­
tee, monetary stability and are dependent on
other sectors of the economy for maintaining
stability...In the long term, central banks are
powerless in the face of differing social de­
mands."1
3

12For example, the German Reichsbank was formally
declared independent on May 26,1922. In Cagan's chronol­
ogy (Cagan, 1956) this was just three months before the
1922-23 German hyperinflation started! For more detail on
how the formal legal independence of the central bank can
and has been circumvented, see Cottarelli (1993).
13Extracted from Mr. Issing's speech at the University of
Freiburg, as reported by the Knight-Ridder wire service,
March 3,1994.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

Our analysis suggests that one of the "other
sectors of the economy" needed to maintain
monetary stability is transparent fiscal and
budgetary institutions. This may explain why
countries such as Belgium, Japan, and Norway,
whose central banks rank almost at the bottom
in terms of legal independence, have a much
better inflation record than countries such as
Argentina, Peru, or Turkey, whose central banks
rank much higher in that regard.1 The fiscal
4
and budgetary institutions of Belgium, Japan,
and Norway allow much better monitoring of
public-sector spending than their counterparts
in Argentina, Peru, and Turkey.
CONCLUSION
This article has shown that there is more
rigorous economic theory than generally be­
lieved behind the argument that a little infla­

14See Cukierman, Webb, and Neyapti (1992), especially
their Table 2.


12


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

tion can lead to a lot. The theory is still develop­
ing, and it does not attempt to explain all facets
of high inflation, but it does indicate that the
nature of fiscal and budgetary institutions is
central to this issue. The fears that a little
inflation can lead to a lot do not seem justified
in economies where it's possible to monitor the
allocation of government spending among dif­
ferent uses. But when that monitoring is absent
or seriously flawed, the attempt to finance the
fiscal deficit with just a little money creation
(and inflation) may turn out to be a "sorcerer's
apprentice" experiment with unpleasant infla­
tionary consequences. The roller-coaster high
inflation experiences of the last 10 years, with
inflation spikes of 100, 200, and even 400 per­
cent a month, testify that the possibility is far
from a theoretical curiosity. These experiences
also suggest, as the theory argues, that the
transparency of fiscal and budgetary institu­
tions may be more important than formal leg­
islation in making the central bank largely inde­
pendent from the fiscal authorities and, there­
fore, in maintaining low inflation.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Carlos Zarazaga

How a Little Inflation Can Lead to a Lot

REFERENCES
Blejer, Mario, and A. Cheasty. "The Deficit as an Indicator of Government Solvency: Changes in Public
Sector Net Worth," in Mario Blejer and A. Cheasty, eds., How to Measure the Fiscal Deficit: Analytical and
Methodological Issues. International Monetary Fund, 1992.
Cagan, P. "The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation," in Milton Friedman, ed., Studies in the Quantity
Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956.
Cottarelli, C. "Limiting Central Bank Credit to the Government: Theory and Practice," Occasional Paper
110, International Monetary Fund, December 1993.
Cukierman, A., Steven N. Webb, and Bilin Neyapti. "Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and
Its Effect on Policy Outcomes," World Bank Economic Review 3 (1992), pp. 353-98.
Green, E., and R. Porter. "Noncooperative Collusion under Imperfect Private Information," Econometrica
52 (1984), pp. 87-100.
Phelps, E. S. "Inflation in the Theory of Public Finance," Swedish Journal of Economics 75 (1973), pp. 67-82.
Pollard, P. S. "Central Bank Independence and Economic Performance," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review 75, July-August 1993.
Porter, R. "Optimal Cartel Trigger Price Strategies," Journal of Economic Theory 29, (1983), pp. 313-38.
Robinson, D.J., and P. Stella. "Amalgamating Central Bank and Fiscal Deficits," in Mario Blejer and A.
Cheasty, eds., How to Measure the Fiscal Deficit: Analytical and Methodological Issues. International
Monetary Fund, 1992.
Sachs, J. "The Bolivian Hyperinflation and Stabilization," Working Paper 2073, National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1986.
Sargent, T. J., and N. Wallace. "Inflation and the Government Budget Constraint," in A. Razin and E. Sadka,
eds., Economic Policy in Theory and Practice. Macmillan, 1987.
Zarazaga, C. "Hyperinflations, Institutions, and Moral Hazard in the Appropriation of Seigniorage," Ph.D.
dissertation, University of Minnesota, 1992.
Zarazaga, C. "Hyperinflations and Moral Hazard in the Appropriation of Seigniorage," Working Paper 9326, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (November 1993).
Zarazaga, C. "Is There a Laffer Curve for the Inflationary Tax?" Working Paper 94-12, Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia (July 1994).




13




Public Transit:
Realizing Its Potential
Richard Voith*
ost major metropolitan areas provide
subsidized mass transit. The primary
rationale for government support is that public
transportation has benefits that extend beyond
those enjoyed by the riders. Because of these
added benefits, the value of public transporta­
tion to society exceeds the amount that riders
alone are willing to pay for the service.
Proponents of subsidies for public transpor­
tation cite several potential benefits to society
at large. Increased transit use reduces the
number of people using highways, thereby

M

*Dick Voith is an economic adviser in the Research
Department of the Philadelphia Fed.




alleviating congestion and the need for addi­
tional, expensive highway construction. Di­
verting commuters from autos to transit also
reduces auto emissions and thus improves air
quality. Transit service also allows dense con­
centrations of economic activity, which many
economists believe increases overall produc­
tivity. Proponents also note that public transit
can benefit specific groups; for example, it may
provide access to employment for low income
people.
Subsidized public transportation is not with­
out its critics, however. Opponents of govern­
ment transit subsidies suggest that the benefits
to society at large are too small to justify a
subsidy. After all, according to the 1990 cen­
ts

BUSINESS REVIEW

sus, only 5.3 percent of all workers commute by
public transit, down from 6.4 percent in 1980.
Continued decentralization of population and
employment may further erode transit's mar­
ket share in the future. Opponents argue that
low ridership precludes transit from having
large social benefits. They also claim that tran­
sit agencies use their subsidies inefficiently,
resulting in high costs relative to the public
benefits.1 Finally, opponents note that transit
services targeted to disadvantaged groups con­
stitute "in kind" transfer payments and sug­
gest that cash or voucher programs are more
efficient means of improving the welfare of the
targeted group.
While there may be disagreement about the
value of transit subsidies to help specific groups,
transit proponents and opponents alike would
agree that public transit's benefits to society at
large are directly related to the number of
people choosing to ride. For example, transit's
contribution to reducing congestion and pollu­
tion depends on how many people prefer to
ride transit instead of driving.2 Similarly, pub­
lic transit's contribution to productivity growth
will be small unless the service is sufficiently

T o r example, Jose Gomez-Ibanez argues that transit
operators invest in excessively expensive rail transit sys­
tems whose benefits do not justify their costs. See "The
Federal Role in Urban Transportation" in John Quigley and
Daniel Rubinfeld, eds.,American Domestic Priorities, Univer­
sity of California Press (1985). In the popular press Frederic
Rose (Wall Street Journal, June 29, 1993) has argued that
increasing transit subsidies has had little success in increas­
ing transit's national market share.
2A11 public transportation trips may not be of equal
social value. For example, a transit trip during rush hour
may reduce congestion more than a trip at midday. Still, the
assumption that the social benefits are linked to overall
transit use is a good one because the patterns of transit use
are not easily categorized. A person choosing to use transit
during rush hour might have driven instead if he had not
had the opportunity to make a return transit trip midday.
Thus, the social value of the midday trip may be greater than
first appears.


16


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

attractive to encourage private investment in
dense economic developments.
Since transit's benefits to society at large are
linked to use, the social value of a given level of
subsidy depends on how well transit can com­
pete in the transportation marketplace. This
issue of transit's market potential is more com­
plicated than it might appear for two reasons.
First, public transit's ability to compete varies
from one market to another.3* Second, current
ridership may not be a good indicator of poten­
tial because transit providers may be pursuing
objectives other than attracting the largest num­
ber of riders. Despite these complications,
policymakers need to evaluate transit's market
potential to determine the proper level of sub­
sidy and to monitor the efficiency of transit
providers. Transit providers need to under­
stand the dynamics of the market to attract as
many riders as possible with the level of subsi­
dies granted.
WHAT DETERMINES
TRANSIT'S MARKET SHARE
The potential of public transit depends on
the underlying demand in each market and the
cost of supplying transit to that market. In
markets where the demand for transit is very
low or the cost of supplying it is very high,
transit's potential is low.
The underlying supply and demand for tran­
sit can be difficult to observe for a couple of
reasons. First, for any mass transit system,
whether buses, trains, or airlines, the cost of
carrying each person depends on the number
of other people making the same trip. Thus,
supply and demand are not independent of one

3Despite transit's small national market share, transit
plays a very important role in the central cities of many large
U.S. metropolitan areas. New York, Washington, D.C., San
Francisco, Boston, Chicago, and Philadelphia all have tran­
sit market shares above 25 percent. Although transit's
market share is large in many central cities, it is small in the
suburbs.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Public Transit: Realizing Its Potential

Richard Voith

another. Second, as with any subsidized ser­ higher income people can afford to choose
vice, the price the rider pays and the quality of more comfortable and convenient transporta­
a particular transit route depend on how much tion. Luxury cars with many amenities are
subsidy it receives. The differences in rider- often the chosen means of travel for people
ship observed across routes may reflect differ­ with higher incomes. On the other hand, bus
ent subsidy levels as well as different underly­ transportation is frequently characterized as
ing supply and demand conditions. To evalu­ an "inferior good," that is, people choose to
ate the competitiveness of public transit, it is ride the bus less as their income increases.6
crucial to have a precise understanding of tran­
Regardless of preference or income, the rela­
sit supply and demand and how they interact tive price of transportation is always an impor­
tant factor in an individual's demand for public
with public subsidies to determine ridership.
Demand for Transit Services. Individuals transportation. As with most other products or
choose how to get from one place to another services, a consumer's demand for transit falls
based on the relative price, quality, and conve­ as the price increases. Similarly, as the price of
nience of the alternatives such as the automo­ automobile travel rises, transit demand in­
bile or the bus. To understand transit demand, creases.
For any particular trip, the additional or
we need to know how changes in these factors
affect people's choices between riding transit marginal cost of that trip is the relevant consid­
or driving cars. Of course, demand for public eration. Even though the total private costs of
transit may differ across individuals because automobile travel tend to be higher than those
they have different preferences and incomes.4 of transit, the marginal cost of a trip by car is
Travel, whether for work or leisure, involves very low. The greatest private costs of auto
more than simply moving from point to point, travel are the fixed costs associated with pur­
and people may have strong preferences for chasing, maintaining, and insuring an automo­
how they do so. For example, some people may bile.7 Thus, once a person has made the deci­
like the perception of control associated with sion to own a car, the out- of-pocket financial
car travel; others may prefer to be able to read
on the train. These idiosyncratic differences
explain why two people facing the decision of
5See Kenneth Small, Urban Transportation Economics
taking a car or a train may not make the same (Harwood Academic Publishers, 1992), pp. 43-44, for a
review of the literature examining the link between income
choice.
More systematic differences in individuals' and the value of time in transportation mode choice.
transit demands arise from income differences.
6Curiously, in Paris the bus is not considered an inferior
People with higher incomes tend to value their good, at least when compared with the famous Paris Metro.
time more highly and therefore are more likely According to officials of the RAPT, the agency that operates
to choose a faster mode of travel.5 In addition, the transit system in Paris, wealthier people choose to ride
the bus system rather than the Metro. The Paris bus system,
which provides services that are largely duplicated by the
Metro in central Paris, is also higher priced than the Metro.
4Because people have diverse tastes, economists de­
scribe transit demand in terms of the probability that an
individual will choose public transit rather than a car.
Formally, the theory of transportation mode choice is based
on the random utility model pioneered by Daniel McFadden,
"Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behav­
ior," in Paul Zarembka, ed., Frontiers in Econometrics (Aca­
demic Press, 1973), pp. 105-42.




7For 1991, the total private cost of auto travel is esti­
mated to be 43.6 cents per mile, of which 9.8 cents are for the
out-of-pocket variable costs. Source: American Automo­
bile Manufacturers Association of the U.S., Motor Vehicle
Facts and Figures. The average fare per mile of transit is 15.3
cents. Source: Computed from Tables 20 and 38, 1993
Transit Fact Book, American Public Transit Association.

17

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

expense of a trip includes only the relatively
small cost of gas and perhaps tolls and parking.
On the other hand, a consumer's out-of pocket
expense for transit is usually relatively high
and frequently higher than the marginal costs
of car travel.8
The relative quality of transit and travel by
car is, in some ways, even more important than
the relative price. Because the scope of transit
service is not universal, transit is simply not
available for some trips, while for others the
need to transfer several times may make the
journey by transit absurdly time-consuming.
The automobile, on the other hand, has the
advantage of being available at any time for
any destination. On the basis of availability
alone, the car is the mode of choice for many
trips. For those trips with a transit alternative,
the quality of the transit service—the speed,
frequency, and comfort—will surely affect a
person's choice. (See Demand Comparison:
SEPTA vs. PATCO.) If transit is too slow,
resulting in high travel-time costs; too infre­
quent, resulting in limited choices of travel
time; or too crowded, resulting in an unpleas­
ant trip, there is little likelihood that people will
choose transit. On the other hand, if congestion
erodes the quality of car travel, travelers will
choose transit more frequently.9
Taken together, individual choices deter­
mine a community's travel demand in general
and its demand for public transit services in
particular. A community's demand for transit
depends on the number of people in the com­
munity and the fraction of those people choos­

ing transit. However, even within a relatively
small neighborhood, the attractiveness of tran­
sit service will vary. The convenience and even
the cost of a transit trip will depend, for ex­
ample, on the amount of time a person has to
spend walking or driving to use the service.
Communities that are densely populated are
likely to have more commuters living close to
transit services and, therefore, have higher tran­
sit use. Similarly, communities whose resi­
dents tend to have destinations served by the
transit route will have high demand. The
layout of a community and the destinations of
its residents are crucial for the transit provider
because they have implications for the cost of
supplying competitive transit service.
Supply of Transit Services. There are two
ways to think about the supply of transit ser­
vices. Public transportation providers can be
thought of as simply providing a number of
vehicle-miles of bus or train operation or, more
generally, a number of passenger-trips on buses
or trains. Whether we focus on vehicle-miles or
on passenger-trips depends on the question to
be addressed.
Vehicle-miles of bus operation are "interme­
diate products" because they have no direct
value in themselves; rather they become valu­
able only when people choose to ride the bus.
Focusing on intermediate products is most
useful when we are examining the purely tech­
nical efficiency of operating and maintaining
buses and trains, since the costs of producing
intermediate products are completely inde­
pendent of people's choices about riding public

8Transit agencies sometimes offer monthly, weekly, or
daily passes, so that the consumer's marginal costs of each
trip are zero, at least in the very short run.

travel time increases rapidly, eroding the time advantage of
auto travel. See William S. Vickrey, "Congestion Theory
and Transport Investment," American Economic Review: Pa­
pers and Proceedings,1969, pp. 251-60, for an early discussion
of highway pricing and congestion. The total costs of high­
way congestion for 50 large metropolitan areas were esti­
mated to be about $39.2 billion in 1989. (James W. Hanks
and Timothy J. Lomax, 1989 Roadway Congestion Estimates
and Trends. Texas Transportation Institute, 1991.)

9The high fixed cost and low marginal cost of auto travel
have implications for the quality of highway travel. Since
the marginal cost of car travel is very low, the use of cars
(among car owners) is limited primarily by highway capac­
ity. As the capacity of the highway system is reached, the


18


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Richard Voith

Public Transit: Realizing Its Potential

Demand Comparison: SEPTA vs. PATCO
The effects of price and service on ridership can be seen in a comparison of two separate, very unequal
rail systems providing commuter service to the central business district of Philadelphia. SEPTA (Southeast­
ern Pennsylvania Transportation Authority) and PATCO (Port Authority Transit Corporation) provide
service to demographically similar suburban neighborhoods, but there the similarity ends.3
As shown in the figure, PATCO's fare is less than half of SEPTA's. PATCO runs almost five times as
many rush-hour trains on its single 14-mile line as SEPTA runs on its average commuter line. PATCO also
runs much more frequent off-peak service. The net effect of the lower-price, higher-quality service is that
PATCO carries over 10 times more people per mile of railroad than SEPTA does.b Thus, for very similar
suburban markets and the same destination, ridership levels are dramatically different. The level of current
SEPTA ridership doesn't necessarily reflect transit's potential.

Communities served by SEPTA tend to have somewhat higher incomes than communities served by PATCO.
bPATCO ridership is higher, in part, because motorists in New Jersey must cross a toll bridge to enter Philadelphia.
cThe PATCO fare is for a trip from Philadelphia to the end of the line. The SEPTA fare is a peak fare for zone two.

transportation. The cost of running a bus for 10
miles, which includes fuel and maintenance
costs plus wages for the operator, is roughly the
same whether four or 40 passengers are on
board. Statistical studies of the transit industry
also suggest that the cost per mile of running a
bus or train is independent of the scale of
operation.1 In other words a transit authority
0
could provide 10 or 100 bus vehicle-miles for
roughly the same cost per mile.
Passenger-trips, on the other hand, are the
"final products" of public transportation. Un-1
0

10See Small (1992) for a review of the literature on the
cost structure of public transit providers.




like the cost of an intermediate product, the
cost of the final product depends, in part, on the
number of people choosing to ride. The cost of
a passenger-trip would vary tremendously de­
pending on whether the cost of operating a bus
were spread over four or 40 people. Moreover,
statistical studies suggest that, unlike with in­
termediate products, producing the final prod­
uct entails economies of scale. More frequent
service enhances the competitiveness of public
transportation, and economies of scale arise
when increased service expands ridership faster
than costs. That is, the cost per person riding
transit falls as service levels increase. (See

Supply Comparison: SEPTA vs. PATCO.)
The cost to supply identical quality service
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

may differ widely from one community to
another. At one extreme, consider a very low
density suburban community whose residents
work at dispersed em ploym ent locations
throughout the region. This pattern of land use
reduces the number of potential transit cus­
tomers because of the great distance between
residents and because of the low probability
that residents along any route will have the
same destination. Simply to cover the destina­
tions of a high proportion of the community,
the transit authority would have to operate
many routes, each serving only a small number
of people. To have frequent service would
require running small buses at substantially
less than capacity most of the time. The costs
per person of supplying service to this commu­
nity would be extremely high.
Next, consider a low density suburban com­
munity that has a relatively high proportion of
people who work in one area, say, the central
business district. In this second community,
the cost of supplying high quality transit ser­
vice will be lower than that in the first commu­
nity. Concentration of destinations means that
many people can be served by a single transit
route, allowing transit vehicles to operate near
full capacity with frequent service. Frequent
service, in turn, attracts a larger share of the
market. If the market is large enough, and if
transit captures a large enough market share,
higher capacity vehicles, such as larger buses
or trains, can lower per-trip costs even further.
Transit is most competitive in communities
that have high residential densities, common
destinations, and high costs of auto travel. This
type of market is most commonly found in
older cities in which employment is concen­
trated in a central business district. In such
markets, passenger volumes are large enough
to justify high capacity, high efficiency tech­
nologies operating at high frequencies over a
wide network of routes.
Like all markets, the market for public trans­
portation is not static. The cost of supplying

20


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

transit services changes over time as communi­
ties change. Incentives in the transportation
system affect the way communities evolve.
These incentives guide long-term choices such
as residential and business location and private
investment in automobiles. For example, if
public transportation is attractive, people and
firms will locate in areas where they can take
advantage of transit services. Households will
make less of an investment in private transpor­
tation by not purchasing a second or third car.
In the long run, high quality transit service
attracts people who have destinations served
by transit and who own fewer cars.1 On the
1
other hand, public transit that is priced too high
or is of poor quality will play little or no role in
long-term decision-making. Little sorting by
destination and car ownership will occur, which
increases the cost of providing transit service in
the long run.
Subsidies and Transit Ridership. In addi­
tion to the underlying supply and demand
conditions, transit ridership depends on the
level of public subsidies. On a per-rider basis,
transit subsidies can be viewed as the price
society is willing to pay to induce a person to
ride public transit. For example, if transit
authorities are willing to provide a high enough
subsidy, they can increase ridership in low
demand, high cost markets. Similarly, very
low per-passenger subsidies may depress rid­
ership well below potential in high demand,
low cost markets. Since per-passenger subsi­
dies are seldom equal across markets served by
a transit authority, actual ridership may not

n In "Transportation, Sorting and House Values," Rich­
ard Voith examines the effects of transportation on residen­
tial location and finds that high quality public transporta­
tion induces people with similar destinations to live in the
same neighborhoods. In addition, households living in
areas with good transit service tend to own fewer cars than
households of similar income living in other areas. (ARE UEA,
1991, Vol. 19, pp. 117-37)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Public Transit: Realizing Its Potential

Richard Voith

Supply Comparison: SEPTA vs. PATCO
PATCO succeeds in carrying many more passengers per mile of railroad than does SEPTA's Regional
Rail system, but at what cost? As shown in the figure, PATCO's costs, on a per-passenger-trip basis, are
one-third of SEPTA's costs. Part of the difference is simply that PATCO's cost of running trains is lower
than that of SEPTA, but by far the major reason for the low costs per passenger is the extremely high
ridership. Because PATCO's costs per rider are low, subsidies per-passenger-trip are only $0.89 on PATCO,
much lower than the per-rider subsidy of $4.37 on SEPTA.
Why would SEPTA management opt for low quality service if it requires higher per passenger subsidies?
The answer is that total subsidies per mile of railroad available to SEPTA are less than those for PATCO.
Communities along the SEPTA lines receive less than half as much in total transit subsidies as communities
along the PATCO line. PATCO's higher subsidies, which allow for higher quality service, have extremely
high returns; they generate ridership that is higher by a factor of 10. PATCO's infrastructure is used much
more intensively than is SEPTA's.
This does not necessarily imply that policymakers have chosen an unreasonably low level of subsidy for
SEPTA. In theory, policymakers should choose a level of subsidy such that the social benefits of attracting
an additional rider are just equal to the marginal subsidy costs. If the marginal benefit of an additional
transit trip declines rapidly as the number of trips increases, then SEPTA's high subsidy per trip, low
ridership regime is appropriate from a social perspective. However, some of the largest social benefits of
a transit trip, such as reduction of congestion and pollution, are unlikely to fall rapidly as transit use
increases. SEPTA's subsidy level may also be appropriate if the cost of attracting additional riders is very
high. However, economies of scale would suggest that the marginal cost of attracting riders is not
increasing, and thus the costs per additional rider are probably lower than the current average subsidy per
rider.3

aSEPTA's marginal subsidy cost of attracting an additional rider might be somewhat higher than PATCO's because New
Jersey motorists must cross a toll bridge to enter Philadelphia and because communities served by SEPTA have higher
incomes. In addition, there may be substantial infrastructure costs in converting the SEPTA commuter rail system to make
it capable of operating at significantly higher frequencies.




21

BUSINESS REVIEW

accurately reflect the fundamental supply and
demand conditions.1
2
Diverting scarce resources from markets
where the price of gaining an additional rider is
low to markets where a high subsidy is re­
quired to attract riders necessarily lowers the
overall ridership on a transit system. Given a
fixed subsidy, maximizing ridership requires
that the change in ridership resulting from an
increase in subsidy must be equal across mar­
kets. In other words, the price that the transit
authority pays to attract an additional rider
must be the same on all its routes. Otherwise
ridership could be increased by shifting subsi­
dies from a market with high costs for an
additional rider to a market with low costs for
an additional rider. (See Intrasuburban and
Reverse Commuting.)
REALIZING TRANSIT'S POTENTIAL
An array of national, state, and local poli­
cies—including investment in infrastructure,
user fees and subsidies, and regulation of land
use— shapes the environment in which con­
sumers choose betw een cars and transit.
Changes in these policies could affect transit's
future potential. But given the current policy
environment, there are three keys to achieving
the greatest benefits from transit: a measurable
objective, appropriate incentives, and a longrun strategy.
A Measurable Objective. Although pub­
licly subsidized transit authorities face a daunt­
ing array of competing demands, not all of
them can or should be met. A measurable
objective is needed to help transit providers
focus resources in areas of high potential and to
help policymakers evaluate the performance of
transit management. Because most of public

12On the SEPTA city transit system in 1992, the subsidy
per rider varied dramatically from route to route. SEPTA's
best route was profitable, with the Authority earning $.08
for each rider carried, while trips on the worst route re­
ceived a subsidy of $15.88.


22


SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER1994

transportation's social benefits are linked to
high use, management's overriding objective
should be to attract the greatest number of
riders.
Appropriate Incentives. Another key to
realizing transit's potential is providing incen­
tives to management to attract the greatest
number of riders. These incentives are a better
tool than the common practice of budgetary
restraint for ensuring the efficient use of public
funds. Because costs per rider tend to fall as
transit service increases, excessively tight bud­
gets may result in higher, not lower, costs per
rider. If, for example, insufficient subsidies
limit transit frequencies to uncompetitive lev­
els, ridership will fall, increasing subsidy per
passenger even though total subsidies are lower.
On the other hand, if management fails to use
its public subsidies to attract the most riders,
the full social benefits of transit subsidies will
not be achieved. With management incentives
tied to ridership objectives, policymakers could
more confidently choose the level of public
subsidies justified by transit's potential social
benefits without being concerned that transit
providers are using public funds inefficiently.
Long-Run Strategy. Because markets evolve
over time, transit authorities need a long-run
strategy to attract riders. Good transit policies
can support development that favors public
transit; however, poor policies can undermine
the very markets for which public transit is
most cost effective. A successful strategy will
support markets in which transit has a poten­
tial competitive advantage and avoid subsidiz­
ing locations in which providing transit ser­
vices is inherently expensive.
The objective of attracting the greatest num­
ber of riders using incentives and a long-run
strategy may appear simple, but it involves
choices that favor some markets over others.
Generating consensus about where public tran­
sit authorities should focus resources tests the
ability of regional leaders to make hard choices
for the common good of the region.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Public Transit: Realizing Its Potential

Richard Voith

Intrasuburban and Reverse Commuting
The rapid increase in suburban employment and intrasuburban commuting has prompted new requests
for public transit service in suburban areas. Public transit is often suggested as a means of linking lower
income city residents with suburban jobs or as a means of reducing suburban congestion. While these are
laudable objectives, public transit is frequently not the answer to the problem. In many suburban markets,
the costs to supply transit services are high because destinations are widely dispersed and demand is low,
in large part because there is extensive free parking.
A comparison of SEPTA city service with special "reverse commute" services provides a good
illustration of the difficulty that transit faces when competing in suburban markets. The figure compares
the performance measures for a "typical" SEPTA transit route in the city of Philadelphia with special
"reverse commute" routes designed to deliver city people to suburban work sites. Ridership per vehicle
hour— the number of people who board a bus or train in an hour— is about 52 on a city route versus only
nine on the reverse commute routes. The low ridership on the reverse commute routes results in an
extremely high cost per rider of $6.52, compared with a figure of $1.47 on a city transit route. Finally, the
subsidy per rider is $3.51 on the reverse commute routes versus $0.63 on the city transit routes. In other
words nearly six people could be carried on the city transit routes for the subsidy provided for a single
person on the reverse commute route. The subsidies for SEPTA's reverse commute routes are generally
borne by companies whose employees use the services, but the numbers illustrate the amount of public
subsidies that would be necessary if the costs were not paid by private employers.
While there are almost certainly some large and growing suburban markets where public transit can be
competitive, that is not the case in many other markets. Attempts to serve these markets will likely fail.
Furthermore, diverting resources to these markets may undermine those in which transit is a viable
alternative. For example, companies that expect the public transit agency to subsidize their employees'
commutes, regardless of where the companies locate, will have one less incentive to locate near a transit hub.
Ultimately, there will be more congestion and less accessibility to employment for residents in older,
densely populated areas because transit will become less and less viable over time.

Rider per
Vehicle H our

Cost per Rider

Subsidy
per Rider




23

3

FEDERAL
RESERVE BANK OF
PHILADELPHIA
Business Review Ten Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574