View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

September • October 1980

How Do Changes
in Market Interest Rates
Affect Bank Profits?

THE NATIONAL STOCK MARKET:
TAKING SHAPE
John J. Mulhern
... Over the last five years, automation and
reorganization have produced some basic
changes in the U .S. stock market.

HOW DO CHANGES
IN MARKET INTEREST RATES
AFFECT BANK PROFITS?
Mark J. Flannery
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
100 North S ixth Street
(on Independence Mall)
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106

The BU SIN ESS REVIEW is published by
the Department of Research every other
month. It is edited by John J. Mulhern, and
artwork is directed by Ronald B. Williams.
The REVIEW is available without charge.
Please send subscription orders, changes
of address, and requests for additional copies
to the Department of Public Services at the
above address or telephone (215) 574-6115.
Editorial communications should be sent to
the Department of Research at the same
address, or telephone (215) 574-6426.
*’

*

*

*

*

The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
is part of the Federal Reserve System—a




... Banks use portfolio management tech­
niques that shield them from the effects of
swings in interest rates.

System which includes twelve regional banks
located around the nation as well as the
Board of Governors in Washington. The
Federal Reserve System was established by
Congress in 1913 primarily to manage the
nation’s monetary affairs. Supporting func­
tions include clearing checks, providing coin
and currency to the banking system, acting
as banker for the Federal government, super­
vising commercial banks, and enforcing
consumer credit protection laws. In keeping
with the Federal Reserve Act, the System is
an agency of the Congress, independent
administratively of the Executive Branch,
and insulated from partisan political pres­
sures. The Federal Reserve is self supporting
and regularly makes payments to the United
States Treasury from its operating surpluses.

I

;;

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The National
Stock Market:
Taking Shape
B y Joh n J. MuJhern*
be dealt with first. In the absence of detailed
guidelines, most of the attention has focused
on developing a nationwide system for that
portion of the industry which deals in resale
of corporate equity securities—the stock
market.
The established markets, which include
stock exchanges and networks of dealers,
have responded by investing in equipment to
make their operations more efficient and to
improve intermarket communications. It
seems clear now that the market will continue
to evolve toward greater automation and less
fragmentation—responding to changes in
the financial environment and in available
technology as well as to planning efforts in
government and in the securities industry
itself. But how much further it will go, and in
what direction, may well depend heavily on
how large the cost is and who is willing to
pay it.

F iv e y ea rs ago, C ongress passed a la w —
the S e cu ritie s A cts A m end m ents o f 1 9 7 5 —
w h ich d irected the S e cu ritie s and E x ch an g e
C om m ission , in part, “to fa c ilita te the e sta b ­
lish m en t o f a n a tio n a l m ark et system for
s e c u r itie s .” T h e sen se in w h ich this m arket
should be n atio n al w as fa irly clear: it should
give m ark et p articip a n ts in one part o f the
co u n try a c c e ss to in fo rm atio n about secu ­
rities p rices in any o th er part o f the cou ntry
and en ab le them to buy or sell at the best
p rice a v a ila b le in any m a rk et.B u t w hat sort
o f system it should be w as not spelled out in
the law . N or did the law in d icate w h ich part
o f the secu rities m a rk e t— the m ark et for
eq u ities, say, or fo r notes or b o n d s— should
‘ John J. Mulhern, who specializes in organization
and strategic planning, joined the Department of Re­
search in 1976. He received his Ph.D. from the State
University of New York at Buffalo.




3

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

THE STOCK MARKET DEVELOPS
The stock market in the United States
today actually is several markets. It includes
traditional exchange trading floors in five
leading cities, electronic trading networks,
and broker-dealer firms that offer alternative
facilities for stock trading.1
And it’s a growing market. Since 1970, for
example, yearly volume of shares traded on
the New York Stock Exchange, which trades
the lion’s share of exchange-listed stocks,
has grown from under three billion to over
eight billion. (A listed stock is one for which
an exchange has agreed to provide a market­
place.) Growth in trading volume of securities
quoted on the National Association of Secu­
rities Dealers’ automated quotation system
(NASDAQ) also has risen sharply, about
tripling since 1974 (see GROWTH IN OVERTHE-COUNTER MARKETS).
Another measure of growth is dollar vol­
ume of trading. In 1970, for example, the
value of shares traded on the Big Board was a
little more than $100 billion; in 1979, that
volume was up to nearly $V4 trillion.
But growth brings challenges of its own.
Larger aggregate volume can strain a mar­
ket’s ability to keep up with trading activity.
In the late 1960s, for example, the market’s
inability to keep pace with a sharply higher
number of trades produced a back-office
paper glut. And recently one large brokerage
firm has suffered a recurrence of this kind of
backlogging. In a business where time is of
the essence, a market’s inability to process
trades quickly and accurately can be devas­
tating.
Aggregate volume growth is not the only
source of strain. So is growth in the size of
individual trades. Large blocks of stock may
require special handling. Treating a large
block as if it were a much smaller lot—

GROWTH
IN OVER-THE-COUNTER
MARKETS
Trading off the organized exchanges has
grown considerably in recent years. By the
end of 1979, about 2,500 domestic common
stocks were being quoted on the automated
quotation system (NASDAQ) operated by the
National Association of Securities Dealers,
and NASDAQ share volume was up sharply
from 2.8 billion in 1978 to 3.7 billion in
1979—or 45 percent as large as Big Board
volume.*
The large institutional investors, such as
bank trust departments, mutual funds, and
pension funds, began directing more of their
orders to the OTC market in the late 1960s,
partly because of the exchange brokers’ fixed
commission rates. Over-the-counter brokers
offered their services for less. Many of the
large institutions that now trade in OTC
markets cannot be lured back by negotiated
commission rates at the exchanges.
The NASD, which acts as self-regulator
for the OTC marketplace, is approaching a
membership level of 3,000 firms with nearly
7,000 branches. It grossed nearly $34 million
on a consolidated basis in 1979 and currently
is engaged in a facilities upgrade which
should help it handle a larger volume of
orders at a higher speed, reduce unit cost,
and compete more effectively for order flow.
’ National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc.
1979 Annual Report, p. 4.

advertising the whole block at something
near the market offer price—may drive down
the price of the stock, harming the financial
positions of all holders. But breaking up the
block into smaller lots may delay its sale.
Thus the preferred course often is to find a
buyer or buyers for the block without ex­
posing its size and then to negotiate the
price; but not every market has the depth to
accommodate such large trades efficiently.
Further, as more shares are traded or

1In their brokerage role, firms handle public orders
on an agency basis; as dealers, they buy and sell for their
own accounts.




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

listing exchange will provide a mostly un­
fragmented market for the listed stock, but
also that the order flow will continue to
generate economic opportunities for mem­
bers and employees of the exchange. Under
the new Rule, however, any stock not already
being traded on an exchange as of April 26,
1979 can be traded off board by member
firms as well as on the floor. The net effect of
this Rule is to let member firms continue to
trade newly listed stocks over the counter, if
they wish, as well as on the exchange floor.
The SEC points out in its 19c-3 release
that, “since the Rule will provide the secu­
rities industry with an opportunity to experi­
ence an environment involving competitive
over-the-counter and exchange trading, it
may be helpful in evaluating the effectiveness
of current efforts to facilitate the develop­
ment of a national market system.” And it
points especially to the steps toward auto­
mation that the industry already has taken
and plans to take. Clearly, those steps are
crucial to the development of a national
market for stocks.

shares are traded in larger lots, demand for
trading services attracts new people and new
methods into the industry. The new markets
that develop get a portion of customers’ buy
and sell orders in certain stocks, and, as a
result, the flow of orders is fragmented—
dispersed among market centers or networks.
If the same stock were traded in its primary
market—say the New York Stock Exchange—
and on another exchange or over the counter,
for example, some of the bids and offers
would not come to the primary market (as­
suming no link of one market to the other)
and so the efficiency of that market would be
impaired. Buyers and sellers in either market
might not be getting the price they would get
if all orders were to come to the same
market.
The exchanges and securities dealers,
which have certain self-regulatory powers,
have sought to deal with these growthrelated difficulties by upgrading their hard­
ware and procedures for handling share lots
of different sizes and by exchanging price
information. Evolution along these lines has
been rapid. In fact, many initiatives might
have been taken even without the 1975
Amendments, as market participants sought
new ways to deal with changing conditions.
But because of the public interest in the stock
market, it is regulated also by government
through the Securities and Exchange Com­
mission, whose efforts have been devoted to
encouraging interaction and competition
among the several markets, in the hope that
fragmentation will be reduced and that the
industry will operate more cost-effectively
on a national scale.
Most recently, for example, the Commis­
sion, which has the authority to override the
rules of stock exchanges, issued its own Rule
19c-3, which sets aside exchange rules that
kept member firms from trading certain
listed stocks off board. The typical exchange
has bound its members to trade listed stocks
only on the exchange floor. If observed, a
rule of this kind guarantees not only that the




LINKING THE MARKETS
Tying the several stock markets together
into a national market is a matter of setting
up mechanisms that will allow a participant
in one market to gain access to the facilities
of another market. Those facilities include
order price and quantity information, order
routing, execution, reporting, and clearing
and settlement. The separate markets limit
access to one anothers’ facilities at present,
but some links are in place, and more appear
to be in the offing. And the feasibility of
linking the markets increases as each be­
comes more completely automated internally.
Consolidated Information. The best known
vehicle for providing market information
probably is the NYSE ticker, which has
provided showers of paper for so many
lower Manhattan parades. But today’s con­
solidated tape is a far cry from the old ticker.
Just days after passage of the 1975 Amend­
5

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

the trading floor, where floor brokers would
pick them up and take them to trading posts
to be matched. Maintaining several booths
on the floor with personnel and equipment,
as the larger firms did (and still do), was not
cheap, however; and because of the cost to
their members, exchanges have had to come
up with more efficient routing systems.
At the New York Stock Exchange, the
Designated Order Turnaround (DOT) system,
inaugurated in 1976, allows a firm to transmit
smaller routine orders directly to the special­
ist at his trading post on the floor, bypassing
the floor booth (see MAKING M ARKETS
for the role of the specialist). Upon execution,
the specialist sends confirmation of the trade
back to the member firm office over the same
data link that brought it in. DOT orders now
participate in about 45 percent of all Big
Board trades, and that percentage is expected
to rise. At the American Stock Exchange, a
similar but less comprehensive system—
Post Execution Reporting (PER)—handles
routing of market orders and odd lots (less
than 100 shares). These routing systems
represent a considerable saving in floor
brokerage.
The NYSE and AM EX routing systems are
just that—internal routing systems. The
Philadelphia Stock Exchange and the Pacific
Stock Exchange both use systems that not
only route but also execute orders. The
Philadelphia Automated Communication and
Execution (PACE) system, which handles
about 20 percent of Philadelphia’s total equity
share volume, automatically executes orders
under 400 shares at the better of the prices
available in Philadelphia and on the Big
Board, and it does so without levying a floor
brokerage fee or a specialist fee on any
order. Although some market observers fear
that regional automated execution systems
may introduce a certain amount of frag­
mentation and keep some bids and offers
from meeting, the users apparently find
them to be highly cost-effective.
Just how attractive automated small-order

ments, the Big Board inaugurated its full
consolidated tape, which immediately prints
all trades of its listed stocks on participating
markets—these being the two exchanges in
New York (Big Board and American) and the
four regionals (Boston, Midwest, Pacific,
and Philadelphia), along with the Cincinnati
Stock Exchange, the National Association
of Securities Dealers, and Instinet (Institu­
tional Networks Corporation—a system tai­
lored for institutional investors). Trades of
stocks listed on other exchanges also are
reported promptly and automatically, and
over-the-counter transactions are reported
through NASDAQ.
Information on the latest trade, however,
is only one part of the picture. For trading
purposes, the really vital information is in
the quotes. The trader has to know at what
prices a quantity of stock is being bid or
offered. In the past, up-to-date bid and offer
information would be available only from
the local exchange specialist for listed stocks,
and only for one exchange. In 1978, however,
with the advent of the consolidated quotation
service, bid and offer prices from the various
registered exchanges were brought together
for display on a single screen. The specialist
or broker could look at this screen to see
where the best price was to be had and, if the
best price was in another market, he could
communicate with that market. Since 1979,
NASD over-the-counter quotes have been
listed in the consolidated service along with
the exchange quotes.
Order Routing and Execution. The reason
for consolidating information is to make
trading in other markets not only possible
but as easy as possible. It’s a way of reducing
the information cost of getting the best trade.
But some of that gain may be lost if market
participants are not able to route their orders
to the preferred market and get them executed
efficiently.
At the exchanges, for example, incoming
orders typically used to be routed from
member firms’ offices to their booths around




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

MAKING MARKETS
A public shareholder would like to be sure that he can buy or sell shares whenever he wants to and
at the best possible price. When no public buyer or seller appears on the other side, however, the
market in a stock can evaporate, unless a market maker steps in to buy or sell for his own or his
firm’s account. At the exchanges, specialists and other registered market makers perform this
function, as dealers do in over-the-counter markets; and some large brokerage houses have begun
making their own markets in certain stocks.
At the NYSE, the specialist function is defined to include “effective execution of commission
orders” and “maintenance, insofar as reasonably practicable, of a fair and orderly market on the
Exchange” in assigned stocks (Rule 108). The market is considered fair if it is free of manipulative
and deceptive practices and if it avoids giving any market participants undue advantages; it’s
considered orderly if trading prices are continuous (showing little or no change) from sale to sale and
if large amounts of buying or selling interest can be accommodated without significant price
changes.
In the course of going about his tasks, the specialist may act as an agent for other brokers or as a
dealer for his own account; in fact, however, he acts as a dealer in only about a quarter of all trades.
(There is some double counting here, since the specialist as dealer is handling the same stock
tw ice—once as a buyer and once as a seller.) For the other three-quarters, the specialist is involved
as an auctioneer—arranging bids and offers at the daily opening and otherwise bringing public
orders together.
The specialist must meet the responsibilities and eligibility requirements outlined in the specialist
job description (adopted by the Big Board in 1976) and must conform to a code of acceptable
business practices. Based on the job description and the code, specialists are evaluated quarterly by
the floor brokers they serve. The evaluation questionnaires provide the principal information used
by the NYSE Allocation Committee, which assigns stocks to specialists and, when necessary,
reassigns them.
There are now about 400 members performing the specialist function at the New York Stock
Exchange.

however, human intervention still appears
to be the order of the day.
Intermarket Trades. For the first several
years after the 1975 Amendments were passed,
the industry heard a great deal of discussion
about what form the national market should
take—whether it should build on then-current
organizations or start over from scratch. But
even while that discussion was going on, the
exchanges were working at a trading system
that would come on line in 1978 and help to
reduce regional fragmentation. Extension of
this system to NASDAQ subscribers and
others now appears highly likely.
The Intermarket Trading System (ITS)
provides brokers and market makers with an
electronic link for transmitting buy or sell

routing and execution systems are to the
providers of market services can be seen
from the NASD’s response to Rule 19c-3.
The NASD supported adoption of the Rule,
but it also embarked on an enhancement of
its own trading facilities to make itself more
competitive with exchanges as a market for
19c-3 securities. A new subsidiary, NASD
Market Services, was formed to build a
common message switch, which will link
dealers with off-board market makers, as
well as an order display capability and a
mechanism for computer-assisted execution.
Initial capitalization for this project has been
set at $2 million, according to the NASD’s
1979 Annual Report.
For larger or more complex transactions,




7

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

orders from one exchange to another after
seeing the bids and offers in all markets. So,
for example, a floor broker at the NYSE who
takes an order to a trading post can look at
the ITS television monitor mounted over the
post and see the last trade price, the local bid
and offer spread, and the best prices available
in all of the other markets. And if the price
displayed on the Midwest or Pacific exchange,
say, is better than the Big Board price, he can
communicate across country and make a
trade. Further, ITS trades require no extra
clearing and settlement procedures. In short,
ITS allows market centers to compete in
certain stocks, regardless of location, by
using a central computer to store bid and
offer prices. Some centers are using ITS to
improve their market share (see THE PHILA­
DELPHIA EXCHANGE AND THE NA­
TIONAL MARKET).
The value of ITS as a mechanism for
increasing market share is recognized even
by its arch rival, the Cincinnati Stock Ex­
change’s National Securities Trading System.
The NSTS is a prototype system designed to
provide automated execution without frag­
menting the market by exposing all quotes in
the system to all market participants. Since
1978, it has permitted direct input from
member firm offices as well as from exchange
floors.
A few large brokerage firms in search of
alternatives to maintaining costly exchange
brokerage staffs, and several correspondent
houses, have directed their order flow in
certain issues to Cincinnati. But even with
this support, the N STS has not been able to
capture very much of the business (about
200,000 shares a day compared to upwards
of 40 million on the Big Board), mainly
because it’s so small and its offerings are so
few. In an effort to beef up its volume in the
short run, the N STS is developing an auto­
mated link of its own to ITS. Whether this
link will help the N STS capture enough
order flow eventually to replace ITS or
whether it will lead to some as yet unthought




THE
PHILADELPHIA EXCHANGE
AND THE
NATIONAL MARKET
In April 1978, the Philadelphia Stock E x­
change became the first of the regionals to
link up with the Big Board via the Intermarket
Trading System (ITS) for trading in certain
NYSE-listed stocks. In the pilot phase, 11
stocks were eligible for ITS; by the end of
1979, nearly 700 were eligible.
Measured by prints on the consolidated
tape, which includes all transactions in NYSElisted stocks on participating markets, the
Philadelphia Stock Exchange continued its
strong showing in 1979, increasing its share
to over 2 3 percent of total trades. Con­
A
solidated tape volume was up also—to over
160 million shares, or nearly 1 3 percent of
k
shares traded. While the Philadelphia Auto­
mated Communication and Execution (PACE)
system doubtless contributed to share volume
growth (from about 130 million in 1978 to 173
million in 1979), ITS also surely played a part
in this growth.
Expecting further increases in equity share
volume as well as on its burgeoning options
floor, which provides a primary market for
contracts in energy options and selected
other interests, the Philadelphia Stock E x­
change is anticipating a move into new and
larger quarters in 1981.

of accommodation, however, is a question
that will be answered only in the longer term.
Thus the stock markets appear well on the
way toward achieving the goal of providing
access to best available execution nation­
wide, regardless of where the market par­
ticipant happens to be. But that may be only
the beginning of the development. And it is
not easy to predict what will happen as the
market reacts to Rule 19c-3. Will the effect
of invoking the Rule in this new systemsoriented environment be a net benefit to all
investors or just to some? What will be the
effect on exchanges, or on brokerage firms?
8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Member firms and brokers who must pay
these charges naturally want to be sure that
they are getting their money’s worth and that
they could not do better at another exchange
or with a different market structure. And
they are under pressure from the ultimate
consumers of their services—the public in­
vestors—who want to get the lowest price
they can for trading services.
In order to keep overall costs down, the
exchanges and the over-the-counter markets
must control unit costs. Further automation
and reorganization appear to offer ways of
controlling these costs. But further automa­
tion and reorganization won’t be cheap. The
NYSE, for instance, is engaged right now in
a multi-million-dollar facilities upgrade,
roughly half of which is for automation or
automation-related improvements. The pay­
off is expected to be large—the ability to
handle three times current daily volume
without skipping a beat. But whether the
order flow to the NYSE will reach this level
will depend in part upon just how costeffective the upgraded trading system turns
out to be with respect to the alternatives.
Less Obvious Costs. Beyond trading costs
lie the costs to U .S. industry and to the
economy at large. These include the fees
paid by listing corporations and other costs
of maintaining a market for raising invest­
ment capital.
A company that wants to have its stock
listed on the NYSE, for example, not only
must meet certain standards for earning
power, net tangible assets, and market value
of publicly held shares, but also must pay a
listing fee. In 1 9 7 9 , listing fees amounted to
about $35 million in cost to listing firms and
in revenue to the New York Stock Exchange.
Listing firms must ask themselves whether
an exchange listing—which tends to increase
institutional interest and aid capital raising
in the primary market—is a cost-effective
method of making their securities available
for trading after the initial offering, again
with respect to the alternatives. Rule 19c-3

W ill the sm aller m em bers o f the N A SD be
able to com p ete w ith the giant m arket m aking
b ro k ers?

So far, little research has been done to
determine who will benefit and who will pay
under the emerging national market scenario.
But even without a lot of empirical research,
it seems possible to identify where the bene­
fits and costs are likely to be found, and
perhaps to indicate how they should be
related.
WHAT ARE THE COSTS?
In stating th at the secu rities m arkets are a
n a tio n a l asse t, the 1975 A m end m ents re co g ­
nize th at the b e n e fits o f th ese m arkets extend
fa r beyon d th o se w ho ow n sto ck s d irectly or
are engaged d irectly in trading them . T h e
co sts o f m aintain in g m ark ets also spread
beyon d this circ le . A nd th ese co sts w ill be
redistribu ted b y ch an g es in the m ark et sy s­
tem . A lthough it m ay not be p o ssible at this
point to estim ate the size o f the co st ch an g es
under d iffere n t n atio n al m ark et scen ario s,
the first step in su ch an effo rt w ould be to
id en tify w h ere th ey m ight be found.

Functional Costs. The costs of handling
trades are the most visible costs on a narrow
view of the industry. These costs fall first on
those who operate the markets as a business—
the exchanges, the over-the-counter groups,
and others who provide facilities for trading.
But they are passed through to brokers and to
the investors who use their services.
A t a ty p ical e x c h a n g e, these co sts include
salaries and b en efits, equipm ent for handling
sto ck trad es, p ro fessio n al serv ices, d epre­
cia tio n o f ca p ita l item s, and a v ariety o f
oth er ex p e n ses. T h e y are passed through in
the form o f co m m issio n ch arges and a range
o f fe e s fo r co m m u n icatio n s serv ices, reg is­
tration , a p p licatio n , m em bership , and the
lik e . In 1 979, su ch ch arges am ounted to
roughly o n e-h a lf o f the N Y S E ’s to tal p retax
rev en u e, or about $53 m illio n , accord ing to
its A n n u al R ep ort. T h e N A SD has a sim ilar
list o f e x p e n ses and revenu es.




9

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

could make listing less attractive to some
corporate equity issuers, but that outcome is
far from certain.
Changes in market organization could im­
pose costs also upon industries and firms
that provide support to the current markets
or have close working relations with them—
suppliers of goods and services, for example.
Along with the exchanges and dealers, these
associated industries and firms employ
thousands of people and considerable assets
of other kinds. Even where these assets are
reemployable, the cost of adjustment could
be important to decisionmakers.
And finally there is the public interest in
maintaining healthy capital markets. The
health of the capital markets is a prerequisite
to productivity gains f or U . S . industry and to
growth for the economy at large; without
infusions of capital, productivity gains will
not be realized. The question for the public
and for government, then, is what market
arrangements will be most likely to keep
capital flowing to its most efficient industrial
users.
All in all, discussion of the national market
system has featured comparatively little hard
data on costs other than estimates of the
capital costs for hardware and programming.
But the costs to the investing community and
to the economy at large also matter. And the
SEC’s 19c-3 monitoring program, which will
measure the impact of competitive market
making on market quality (width of bid-ask
spreads, depth, and continuity), quality of
execution, and market structure, should give
some feel for how costs could be affected.2

Decisions that the players make on how to
proceed with the national market will depend
on what they conceive to be the additional
economic benefit to them of each extra dollar
spent—subject, of course, to regulatory con­
straints that alter the cost balance.
Continued Growth. Clearly, the registered
exchanges and the NASD, along with the
large broker-dealer firms that make their
own markets, are behaving as if they believe
that the equity business is a growth business.
One sign of this belief is the amount they
spend on servicing the automated compo­
nents of the ITS through the Securities In­
dustry Automation Corporation (SIAC)—a
subsidiary of the NYSE and the AMEX.
Since 1973, SIAC annual revenues have
nearly doubled, finishing 1979 at about $70
million, over half of which goes for exchange
trading and clearing services.
The kind of growth that market partici­
pants expect and plan for is evolutionary.
Each major group has a multi-year develop­
ment plan which fits automation and orga­
nizational changes into financial and other
operating constraints. The Big Board, for
example, had SIAC develop a five-year auto­
mation plan for the period 1977-81. SIAC
undertook a similar effort for the AM EX in
1978. The exchanges and the NASD would
not be willing to plan and execute major
automation efforts without the prospect of
economic benefits to their members. Growth
can be expected to continue only on lines

and selling interest without significant price changes.
Its continuity is its property of keeping prices relatively
constant from trade to trade. Depth can be measured as
price change per number of shares traded, continuity as
price change per number of trades.
Execution quality is a matter of pricing: best execution
is execution at the best price available in the market.
The SEC plans to monitor execution by comparing
prices at which agency orders are executed to the
quoted market at the time of execution.
Market structure is determined by the number of
competitors in a market and the distribution of volume
among them.

o
The amount by which the bid price differs from the
offer price is the quotation spread. NYSE spreads have
narrowed over the last ten years: about a quarter of all
spreads were of the minimum possible magnitude (V
s
point or 12V2<t) in 1979, roughly double the percentage at
the beginning of the decade; about three-quarters had
spreads of V point or less. Some observers believe that
»
increased competitive market making will narrow
average spreads still further.
A market’s depth is its ability to accommodate buying




10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

methods for meeting the capital requirements
of industry and the investing preferences of
the public. The several market centers and
networks are linked more closely than ever
before, better able both to cooperate and to
compete for portions of the trading business.
Has the national market system arrived?
As yet, probably not. But the shape that it
will take on, in the near term at least, is
becoming clearer each day—a system that
links established markets rather than an
utterly new kind of market. Further techni­
cal and regulatory developments that will
unbind stock trading from geographical and
institutional restrictions appear to be just
around the corner. All the players will have
their eyes on the data produced by the SEC’s
19c-3 monitoring efforts. But before they
plan any new moves, they’ll be taking a long
look at their own cost and revenue projections.

which are perceived to promise economic
benefits to those concerned.
Thus, because of the complexity and long­
term nature of the industry decisionmaking
process, and because of the way it institu­
tionalizes cost considerations, further de­
velopment of the national market system is
almost certain to be consistent with develop­
ments to date. And the SEC can concur in
that growth as long as the industry remains
adequately competitive and provides the
requisite services to its many publics.
SHAPING UP
The years since the national market legis­
lation have witnessed remarkable develop­
ments in the securities industry. In the stock
market alone, the exchanges, dealers, and
brokerage houses have moved decisively
into a new era of information-driven re­
structuring—finding more cost-effective




11

From the Philadelphia Fed . . .
This booklet contains summaries of four
panel discussions of Philadelphia’s eco­
nomic future held at the Federal Re­
serve Bank in 1978 and 1979. Copies are
available without charge from the De­
partment of Public Services, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 100
North Sixth Street, Philadelphia,
Pennsylvania 19106.




12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

How Do Changes
in Market Interest Rates
Affect Bank Profits?
B y Mark ]. Flannery*
In the past year, interest rates in the
United States have been both unusually high
and unusually variable. The prime loan rate,
for example, stood at 15 percent in early
1980, increased to a peak of 20 percent in
April, then plummeted to 11 percent by
August. Other short-term rates exhibited a
similar pattern. As is often the case, how­
ever, bank loan rates have received more
popular attention than other rates, and many
people believe that the banking sector was
making unreasonably high profits from these
higher loan rates.
For many bankers and bank regulators,
though, high and rising market rates do not
necessarily imply record profits. These ob­
servers recognize that greater bank interest

revenues are at least partly offset by the
higher interest costs banks must pay for their
deposits and other liabilities. If market rates
drive up bank costs more rapidly than loan
revenues, bank profits will fall. In the ex­
treme, widespread bank losses could desta­
bilize the financial sector, or so the story
goes.
With bank costs and revenues both re­
sponding to increases in market rates, the net
effect on bank profits is hard to predict. A
recent Philadelphia Fed study concludes,
however, that most banks employ portfolio
management techniques that insulate their
earnings from the effects of high and volatile
market rates. Banks do not reap windfalls,
nor are they in danger of failing, when
market rates change.

*The author, a Senior Economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, is on leave from the
Finance Department of the University of Pennsylvania.
Carole Moeller provided research assistance throughout
this study.

INTEREST RATES AND PROFITS:
A DUAL IMPACT
When interest rates rise, because of Fed
policy actions or other forces, bank portfolio




13

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

also issue variable-rate mortgages, for ex­
ample. The mortgage loan may run 30 years
before it is fully repaid, but the interest rate
is adjusted, say, every six months to bring it
more nearly into line with current market
rates. For purposes of judging its impact on
revenues, this mortgage should be considered
a six-month asset.
The second way market rates affect bank
revenues is through their impact on the
bank’s decisions about which loans and
securities to purchase and how much to hold
in cash reserves. Some loan customers may
find it more difficult to borrow in the open
market when rates are high. This difficulty
might cause them to bid up bank loan rates
even more than, say, the Treasury bill rate
increases. If so, banks could earn more
profit from making loans than from buying
marketable securities, and revenues would
fluctuate as the asset portfolio is reshuffled.
Likewise, a bank’s holdings of cash reserves
and other nonearning assets should decrease
when the return on earning assets rises.
Total bank revenue therefore will rise more
than in proportion to the market rate if
nonearning assets come to occupy a smaller
percentage of the portfolio.
Thus after a permanent increase in market
rates, a bank’s average return on assets rises.
The extent of the adjustment and the time
period involved depend on the portfolio’s
structure at the time and the behavior of loan
customers in response to higher rates.
The Liability Side. In a similar way, the
impact of market rate changes on bank costs
depends on the average maturity and com­
position of the liability portfolio. Negotiable
certificates of deposit, Federal funds bor­
rowed, and subordinated debentures (long­
term borrowings secured by a bank’s general
credit and subordinated to deposits) all have
well defined interest costs and maturities.
For other (primarily retail) deposit types, the
picture is more complicated.
Some liability maturities are poorly defined.
What is the maturity of a demand deposit

managers can expect changes on both the
asset and liability sides of their balance
sheets.1 Bank revenues and costs will adjust
to reflect the new level of market rates at
different speeds, depending on each bank’s
collection of assets and liabilities. Rearrang­
ing the portfolio to make the most of new
market circumstances also may take longer
at one bank than at another.
The Asset Side. Market rates affect bank
revenues in two distinct ways. First, an
increase in market rates raises the amount of
income a bank can earn on new assets it
acquires. If a bank were 100-percent invested
in overnight loans and securities, for ex­
ample, its average revenues would change
every day to reflect current market interest
rates. Of course, no bank holds such an asset
portfolio. Assets mature over time and are
liquidated, with the proceeds only gradually
being reinvested at the new higher interest
rates. All earning assets eventually will roll
over into securities bearing the new higher
rate, but the time involved will vary across
banks.
For each bank, the speed with which
revenues adjust to new market conditions
depends on how long it takes for the average
asset’s interest rate to adjust to current mar­
ket rates. The adjustment may occur either
when the asset matures (an old loan is repaid
and a new one bearing the current market
rate is issued) or when a variable-rate clause
causes the contract rate to change.2 Many
bank loans, especially loans to business,
carry an interest rate that can change before
the loan must be fully repaid. Some banks

■^Exactly the same principles apply to rate decreases.
o
Strictly speaking, the asset’s maturity is an inappro­
priate measure since it ignores cash flows prior to the
repayment of principal. G. O. Bierwag, “Immuniza­
tion, Duration, and the Term Structure of Interest
Rates,” Journal o f F in an cial and Q uantitative A nalysis
12 (1977), pp. 725-742, explains why duration is a better
measure of a security’s response to interest rate changes.
Maturity is used here for simplicity.




14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

(checking) account? Of a passbook savings
account? Some would argue that these are
very short-term liabilities: demand deposit
balances can be withdrawn without notice,
and savings account balances are de facto (if
not de jure) payable on demand. But every
banker is familiar with the notion of core
deposits—balances that will remain with the
bank for long periods of time almost irre­
spective of market conditions. Are demand
and passbook balances zero-maturity or infinite-maturity liabilities? This issue is ex­
tremely important in assessing a bank’s ex­
posure to interest rate risk. (Account balances
with ill defined maturities made up 59 per­
cent of all insured commercial bank deposits
and 45 percent of total assets in May 1980.)3
Another complication arises because a
bank’s true cost for some deposit types
exceeds the explicit interest payments made
to depositors. Federal bank regulators have
prohibited the payment of any interest on
demand deposits since 1933. In addition,
R eg u latio n Q lim its the m axim u m rate pay­
able on time and savings accounts,4 and
these rates have been below their competitive
level for a number of years. This situation
creates an incentive for banks and thrift
institutions to compete with one another by
offering implicit interest payments (free
checking, for example, or toasters, or Snoopy
dolls) to attract and keep deposits. Bankers
also try to attract funds by making it cheaper
for people to do business with them—building
new branches, extending business hours,
and paying bank-by-mail postage—so that it
becomes easier to hold savings in the form of
bank deposits than in other available in-

struments. When market rates rise, bankers
heat up their implicit interest competition
for these regulated accounts, incurring addi­
tional expenses in the process. The true cost
of funding a bank’s asset portfolio therefore
includes both interest and noninterest ex­
penses.5
Aside from these complications, the re­
sponse of bank costs to a market rate change
is analogous to developments on the asset
side of the balance sheet. Liability costs
eventually will follow market rates with the
speed of adjustment depending on the bank’s
initial liability portfolio composition and the
nature of its depositors.
The Net Effect. A stylized example can
best describe the net effect of market rate
changes on bank costs versus revenues. Sup­
pose that the market rate of interest has been
fixed at 9 percent for as long as anyone can
remember, then suddenly and permanently
rises to 10 percent.6 Bank costs and revenues
both begin to rise almost immediately, with
th eir relativ e resp o n ses determ ining the im ­

pact on bank profits (Figure 1 overleaf).
Whether profits go up or down depends
largely on the average maturity of bank
liabilities and assets.7
A perfectly balanced asset/liability posi­
tion would leave the intermediary’s profit
5For more detailed discussion of this phenomenon as
it has applied to Massachusetts and Connecticut, see
Robert A. Taggart and Geoffrey Woglom, “Savings
Bank Reactions to Rate Ceilings and Rising Market
Rates,” New England Econom ic Review, September/
October 1978, pp. 17-31; and Michael A. Klein, "The
Implicit Deposit Rate Concept: Issues and Applica­
tions,” Econom ic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, September/October 1978, pp. 3-12.
6It is unlikely, of course, that the market rate will
remain unchanged for very long. One should think of
this example as describing a permanent change in
average rates: instead of fluctuating around an average
level of 9 percent, they fluctuate around an average of
10 percent.

3Note that the effective maturity of demand or
savings balances need not be constant across individual
banks.
4The Monetary Control Act of 1980 requires that
Regulation Q ceilings be phased out by 1986. As this
occurs, bankers will most likely reduce their noninterest
expenses and compensate depositors more directly via
explicit interest.




7Bankers sometimes refer to a funding gap, by which
they mean the difference between average asset and
liability maturities.

15

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

FIGURE 1
THE EFFEC T OF A MARKET INTEREST RATE INCREASE
ON BANK PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE
DEPENDS ON THE ASSET/LIABILITY BALANCE*

Returns

The Income-to-Asset Ratio Remains Constant
When the Portfolio is Fully Hedged

Longer than Liability Maturity

Returns

Shorter than Asset Maturity

*TR/TA is the ratio of total revenues to total assets; TC/TA is the ratio of total costs to total assets; NI/TAis the
ratio of net income to total assets.




16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

stream unaffected by market interest rate
changes. This balance can be achieved only
if each asset is financed by a liability of
similar maturity. Market rate changes then
affect revenues and costs equally promptly or
slowly.
Whether a bank finds this so-called hedged
position desirable depends on its expecta­
tions about future interest rate movements
and the shareholders’ willingness to accept
risk. Suppose a bank portfolio manager
expects interest rates to rise and wishes to
profit to the fullest possible extent based on
that development. Then the bank should
issue liabilities with an average maturity
exceeding its average asset maturity. If rates
do rise, interest costs will rise more slowly
than revenues (because liability rates are
locked in) and the bank will earn a handsome
profit until its cheap liabilities must be rolled
over. Of course, if interest rates fall (contrary
to expectation), asset returns would decline
more promptly than liability costs and the
bank would show poor earnings. This is the
risk of an unbalanced asset/liability position.
An unbalanced portfolio offers more op­
portunity for profit, but, like a wager, also
offers the prospect of loss.
Many people (including many bank regu­
lators) feel that the nature of banking in the
real world requires these institutions to bor­
row short and lend long—to structure their
portfolios so that the average maturity of
their assets exceeds the average maturity of
their liabilities. But such an asset/liability
imbalance is most appropriate for a bank
that expects market rates to fall. If banks
cannot avoid holding this sort of unbalanced
portfolio, a sharp market rate increase may
threaten their viability.
Market rate changes, then, can have two
separate effects on bank profits. The im­
mediate or short-run effect reflects primarily
the relative maturities of the asset and liability
portfolios. After all assets and liabilities
have matured, a second effect may emerge:
the higher market rate may induce permanent




portfolio revisions that can raise or lower
bank income.
THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Some evidence on how banks have been
structuring their asset and liability portfolios
can be obtained by examining the past rela­
tion of bank profits to market rates. Individ­
ual banks regularly report their revenues,
costs, and profits to the Federal banking
agencies. Their records provide annual in­
formation on a sample of 75 United States
banks (in six size categories) for the period
1961-78.
Interest rate data also are readily available,
but accurately summarizing the historical
pattern of market rates can be difficult.
Consider the first half of 1980: the average
Treasury bill rate was 11.5 percent for the
period as a whole, but it varied from 11.7
percent in early January to 15.5 percent in
late March, finally falling to 7.4 percent at
the end of June. This was surely an unusual
period for interest rates, but it serves to
illustrate two distinct components of market
rate behavior—the average level over a time
period (for example, the six-month average
for January through June 1980) and the vari­
ability of rates within each time period.8
These two components cannot perfectly
capture the full richness of each period’s
market rate environment, but they go a long
way toward that goal.
Analyzing the historical experience of 75
banks yields several important conclusions.
One may come as a surprise to many bankers
and regulators: the variability of market
interest rates within a year has virtually no
impact on commercial bank profits. While
the market rate’s average level prominently
influences bank revenues and costs, fluctua­
tions around that average are unimportant.

V a ria b ility can be measured by the range of rates
observed (highest minus lowest) or the standard deviation
of weekly rates around the period’s average.

17

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

of a hypothetical permanent 100-basis-point
increase in all market rates was calculated
for each bank.9 (A permanent rate change of
this magnitude would be large by historical
standards, though temporary interest rate
fluctuations within a year routinely exceed
100 basis points.) Bank responses in each
size class were then averaged (Figure 2). The

The Short Run: Are Banks Well Balanced?
A market rate change endangers bank prof­
itability only if asset and liability returns
adjust at significantly different speeds. Then
an interest rate change can cause sharp
profit fluctuations and, if rates change con­
trary to the bank’s expectations, perhaps
even insolvency.
The historical relations between market
interest rates and each bank’s revenue, costs,
and profits were determined statistically.
Using these estimated relations, the impact

9A basis point is one-hundredth of a percentage
point. Reactions to larger or smaller market rate changes
would be proportional to those in Figures 2, 3, and 4.

FIGURE 2
AT MOST BANKS, ASSET RETURNS AND LIABILITY
COSTS RESPOND ABOUT EQUALLY QUICKLY
TO MARKET RATE CHANGES*
BANKS WITH ASSETS LESS
THAN $25 MILLION

BANKS WITH ASSETS
OF $100-300 MILLION

TR/TA

BANKS WITH ASSETS
OF $25-50 MILLION

BANKS WITH ASSETS
OF $50-100 MILLION

BANKS WITH ASSETS
OF $300-1,000 MILLION

BANKS WITH ASSETS
OF OVER $1 BILLION

TR/TA

TR/TA
TC/TA

TC/TA

TC/TA
1

1

II

T=0

1 1 1 J, 1 I I
,

TIME

111

■ ■

T =0

1■ 1111111111
TIME

‘ Bank classification based on 1978 asset position.




X * ------------------------

18

1

1

1 1 1 1 1 III

T=0

TIME

1 1 1 1 L II.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

have balanced their effective asset and lia­
bility maturities quite closely so that revenues
and costs are about equally affected by a rate
increase. The smaller banks (those below
$100 million) seem to enjoy significantly
increased profitability following a market
rate increase, while larger banks’ revenues
and costs adjust at approximately equal
speed—leaving no great effect on profit even
in the short run. At least over the first 15
years following a market rate increase, no
class of banks is in danger of failing from
adverse market effects.
The Long Run: Are High Rates Good for
Banks? Figure 3 provides information on the
cumulative effect of all these adjustments:
what is the final impact on revenues, costs,
and profits when the market rate of interest
rises permanently by 100 basis points? From
the first two columns of Figure 3 it is clear

evidence shows that different sized banks
respond at different speeds to market rate
changes. In particular, larger banks’revenue
and costs adjust more quickly than smaller
banks’, because larger banks tend to deal
with larger, more interest-sensitive cus­
tomers.
Within each individual bank, of course,
the relative adjustments of revenues and
costs determine the net impact on profitability.
Judging from the ratios of total revenues to
total assets and total costs to total assets,
asset returns respond more promptly than
liability costs to market rate changes at
smaller banks, suggesting that asset maturi­
ties are shorter on average than liability
maturities. The same is true at larger banks,
though the difference between average asset
and liability maturities is not so great. Banks
with assets above $300 million appear to

FIGURE 3
THE LONG-RUN IMPACT ON BANK REVENUES AND COSTS
OF A ONE-PERCENTAGE-POINT INCREASE IN MARKET RATES
IS GREATER AT SMALLER BANKS
Bank Size Class
(millions of dollars)

TR/TA

TC/TA

Difference

< 25

1.36

.558

.802

25 - 50

1.35

.812

.538

50 - 100

1.64

1.217

.423

100 - 300

1,26

1.229

.031

300 - 1,000

.938

1.013

-.075

> 1,000

.852

.900

-.048




19

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

statistical sense), however, and should not
be accorded great significance.
Figure 4 shows the change in net income
associated with a permanent 100-basis-point
increase in market rates. (Net income is
revenues less costs, adjusted for taxes, capi­
tal gains or losses on securities sold, and
other extraordinary income items.) As an
example of how to read this Figure, consider
the banks smaller than $25 million. The
permanent market rate increase ultimately
raises net income as a percentage of total
assets by a tenth of a percent. The size of this
effect should be judged by comparing the
tenth of a percent with the actual ratio of net
income to total assets, which in this case is

that banks below $300 million (approximately
97 percent of all banks in the United States,
holding 33 percent of all bank assets) enjoy a
permanent increase in their pretax interest
income when market rates rise. Equally
clearly, the magnitude of this effect is smaller
the larger the bank: banks under $25 million
enjoy a .802-percentage point increase (1.36
- .558) in their net earnings margin while
banks between $100 million and $300 million
gain only .031 of a percentage point. For
banks with assets above $300 million, market
rate increases induce a slight decline in
operating margin because costs eventually
rise by more than revenues. Differences in
the largest three bank classes are small (in a

FIGURE 4
A ONE-PERCENTAGE-POINT INCREASE IN MARKET RATES
SLIGHTLY RAISES LONG-RUN BANK PROFITS*
1978 Value
of NI/TA

Change in
NI/TA

1.264

.1005

25 - 50

.983

.120

50 - 100

1.042

.0781

100 - 300

.972

.0238

300 - 1,000

.870

.0724

.572

.0330

Bank Size Class
(millions of dollars)
<25

> 1,000

*The change in NI/TA (the ratio of net income to total assets) indicated for each size class is the
average value from a number of banks in the sample. For each individual bank a test can be
performed to determine whether the indicated change in NI/TA is statistically important. Among
the 75 sample banks, 24 showed significant (at the five-percent level) permanent changes in NI/TA
when market rates changed. Of these 24 banks, only two manifest lower earnings at higher market
rates. In the total sample of 75 commercial banks, therefore, only two have been shown to suffer
significant declines in NI/TA when market rates increase.




20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

after that, large money center banks intro­
duced a floating prime rate tied to market
interest rates. These two developments po­
tentially set the stage for much quicker bank
responses to market rate fluctuations than
had occurred during the 1960s.
Statistical tests were conducted to deter­
mine if the 15 largest sample banks exhibited
significantly different interest rate effects
during the latter half of the period (1970-78)
than they had during the former half (196169).12 The answer is No. While market rate
fluctuations were larger during the 1970s,
large banks responded to rate changes with
about the same speed as they had in the
1960s. Floating prime loans and unregulated
deposit rates undoubtedly induced important
portfolio adjustments at large banks, but
these insured that bank profits remained
relatively insensitive to market rate fluc­
tuations. It can be expected that correspond­
ing adjustments will occur in retail banking
practices in response to the regulatory de­
velopments of the 1980s.

1.264 percent. All six bank classes enjoy
greater net income at higher market rates,
though the increases are not particularly
large.10 Overall, the available evidence in­
dicates that changes in market interest rates
have a relatively small impact on the average
bank’s reported profits.11
The historical period covered by this study
ended with 1978. Since then, retail banking
has changed drastically on account of money
market certificates, and even more regulatory
changes are pending in the wake of the
Monetary Control Act of 1980. Policy rec­
ommendations therefore follow from this
study only if its historical results can be
expected to persist into the future. Lacking a
crystal ball, no definitive response can be
given to this concern, but some evidence is
available from evaluating the impact of a
large previous change in banking practices.
Observers often argue that institutional
changes in the early 1970s changed the
nature of banking, at least among large
money market institutions. In mid-1970, in­
terest rate ceilings were eliminated for large
certificates of deposit ($100,000 or more)
with a maturity less than 90 days. Shortly

CONCLUSION
The historical experience of 75 United
States commercial banks indicates that, on
the whole, bank profits are not very respon­
sive to the level of market interest rates.
When market rates change, the responses of
bank revenues and costs approximately can­
cel one another, leaving the level of com­
mercial bank profits only slightly sensitive
to market rates in most cases. The popular
conception that the banking industry reaps
unreasonably large profits during tight money
times thus is not supported by the evidence.

10In the fourth quarter of 1979 and the first quarter of
1980, some large United States banks reported sharp
profit increases, attributing them to the effects of high
market rates on asset/liability balances. Upon closer
inspection of balance sheets and income statements,
however, the bank profit margins emerged as approxi­
mately unchanged from periods of lower interest rates.
(Salomon Brothers’ “Quarterly Banking Review” reports
the average net interest margin for 37 large U .S. banks
declined only 25 basis points—less than 10 percent—
between the first quarter of 1979 and the first quarter of
1980.) The reported large changes in net profits derived
more from overall asset growth than from changing
profit margins.

F or id en tica l re a so n s, the regu latory fe a r
that sharp rate in cre a s e s th reaten the co m ­
m ercial banking system ’s viability also should

11This evidence implies nothing categorical about
the impact of higher market rates on the market value of
bank stock. As a technical matter, however, bank stock
prices must d eclin e when rates rise unless net income
also rises. The evidence in Figure 4 thus allows for the
possibility that bank stock values rise, fall, or remain
unchanged when market rates rise.




12Specifically, a Chow test was performed for the
revenue, cost, and income equations of each bank. Only
one of the 15 banks manifested significant structural
shifts between the two historical periods.

21

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 1980

BUSINESS REVIEW

balanced asset/liability portfolio threatens
bank stability just as much as undue loan
concentration, excessive reliance on bought
money, or low capitalization. Individual
banks certainly can choose asset/liability
portfolios that leave them exposed to interest
rate risks; several recent examples come
readily to mind. But most banks can avoid
such risks if they choose. While selected
banks may be threatened by sharp market
rate changes, the banking industry as a
whole is not.

be questioned. Seriously unbalanced asset/
liability portfolios are not a pandemic feature
of commercial banking in the United States.
Thus relatively large market rate fluctuations
can be tolerated if these prove necessary to
attaining monetary policy goals such as full
employment and price stability. (Another
way to say this is that the banks’ ability to
weather the past year’s market gyrations
reflects their well-hedged balance sheets.)
This conclusion does not imply that regu­
lators should ignore individual bank exposure
to interest rate risks. An excessively un­

SUGGESTED READINGS
G. O. Bierwag, “Immunization, Duration, and the Term Structure of Interest R ates,” Jou rnal o f
F inancial and Q uantitative A nalysis 12 (December 1977), pp. 725-742.
Mark J. Flannery, “Market Interest Rates and Commercial Bank Profitability: An Empirical
Investigation,” Research Paper No. 53, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 1980.
Michael A. Klein, “The Implicit Deposit Rate Concept: Issues and Applications,” E con om ic
Review , Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, September/October 1978, pp. 3-12.
Robert A. Taggart and Geoffrey Woglom, “Savings Bank Reactions to Rate Ceilings and Rising
Market Rates,” New England E con om ic R eview , Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, September/
October 1978, pp. 17-31.




22

he Philadelphia Fed s Department of Research occasionally publishes research papers
™ ‘ en
staff economists. These papers deal with local, national, and international
economics and finance. Most of them are intended for professional researchers and
therefore are relatively technical.
p ADPRQ°nPlete+liSt ° f RESEARCH PAPERS currently available, write to RESEARCH
q - tiTc+S ’ +
,°-f Research> Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 100 North
Sixth Street, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106.




on Independence Mall
100 North Sixth Street
Philadelphia, PA 19106