View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

business review
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA




197*1

IN THIS ISSUE . . .
Inflation and Economic Policy
. . . An effective and responsible monetary
policy is the Fed's main tool for dampening
inflation, but coping with the overall prob­
lem requires realistic assessments of the
nation's capacity to fulfill its wants.
State Laws Affect the Pace
Of New Bank Charters
. . . The lion's share of new chartering is in
states that prohibit branching bu „ allow
multibank holding companies.
Foreign Exchange Markets:
Booming and Bustling
. . . Foreign currency markets are among the
fastest growing in the world, and their con­
tinued expansion hinges on such impondera­
bles as reimposed controls on capital flows
and changes in the international monetary
system.

On our cover: West of Pottstown, Pennsylvania, off US 422, stands Pottsgrove Mansion. Built in
the 1750s by John Potts, a wealthy ironmaster, the Georgian mansion has withstood well the
passage of two centuries as an example of outstanding colonial architecture. (Photo by the
Pennsylvania Historical and Museum Commission, Harrisburg, Pa.)

BUSINESS REVIEW is produced in the Department of Research. Editorial assistance is provided by Robert
Ritchie, Associate Editor. Ronald B. Williams is Art Director and Manager, Graphic Services. The authors will be
glad to receive comments on their articles.

Requests for additional copies should be addressed to Public Information, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19105. Phone: (215) 574-61 15.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Inflation and
Economic Policy*
By David P. Eastburn, President
Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia

I welcome the opportunity to be with you
today. When Congress created the Federal Re­
serve System over 60 years ago, it was fearful of
too much power concentrated in too few hands.
Thus, it wisely established a decentralized cen­
tral bank with powers shared by a seven-man
Board of Governors in Washington and 12 re­
gional Banks throughout the country, all outside
the Executive Branch. But this organizational ar­
rangement in no way was intended to reduce the
accountability of the Federal Reserve to Con­
gress. We are a creature of Congress and ac­
countable to it. I think it is most appropriate,
therefore, that Federal Reserve officials testify
frequently before the various committees of the

Congress and also that from time to time you
hear from the Presidents of the various Reserve
Banks.
I should like to talk briefly about four closely
related problems: causes of inflation; what to do
about inflation; the role of interest rates; and
evening out the burdens of fighting inflation.
CAUSES OF INFLATION
If we could somehow create an economic dis­
comfort index the way weathermen combine
temperature and humidity, I suspect we would
find ourselves about as uncomfortable as at any
time in recent years. Prices are soaring, the un­
employment rate is creeping up, and interest
rates are at record levels.
Without minimizing any of the difficulties we
face, I believe the major problem is inflation. We
are in perhaps the worst peacetime inflation in
our history. Unless we begin to unwind inflation,

Testim ony before the Committee on Banking and Cur­
rency, U. S. House of Representatives, Washington, D. C.,
July 17, 1974.




3

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

I am fearful of the consequences not only for the
economy but for our entire social fabric.
Our current inflation has many causes, but it is
helpful to divide them into two main aspects.
One aspect involves extraordinary events such
as crop failures, oil embargoes, and dollar de­
valuations. They come and go and often not
much can be done about them. Beef prices
skyrocket then taper off; wheatsuppliesdiminish
then expand; anchovies disappear from the
coast of Peru and then reappear. If we are lucky,
these phenomena occur at different times. In the
last couple of years we have been unlucky; many
extraordinary events have occurred together.
A second aspect is monetary. Whatever im­
mediate events may cause prices to rise
— including shortages and higher wage costs—a
higher price level cannot be sustained without
sufficient money. In retrospect it would have
been better if money had not grown so rapidly
over much of the past decade. The reasons for
this growth go to a large extent to considerations
other than inflation which the Federal Reserve
has believed to be important. Throughout much
of the period there are primary concerns about
the disadvantaged—those unemployed, living in
dilapidated housing and attending crowded
schools. Ample growth in money was necessary
to meet these economic and social problems. In
more recent periods, the Federal Reserve, partly
reflecting views of Congress, has been con­
cerned about the effects of high and rising in­
terest rates. Still more recently, concerns for the
stability of financial institutions have come to the
fore.
Whatever the reasons, the consequence of this
history is that we find ourselves with rapid in­
creases in both prices and money. The question
is how to deal with them.

our capacity to fulfill our wants. There has been a
tendency in recent years to pass over a hard fact
of life— scarcity of resources. We simply cannot
fulfill all desires, for all people, all at once, al­
though we may earnestly wish to do so. Scarcity
is still with us even in an affluent society.
A second requirement for fighting inflation is a
firm handle on fiscal policy. In this regard, Con­
gress is to be congratulated for passing the recent
budget reform bill. This legislation can give Con­
gress the kind of control that is long overdue.
Third, I believe there is a limited role for an
incomes policy. We've just been through 32
months and four phases of controls, and the
economy has just plain had it with controls for
awhile. But there could still be a useful role for
monitoring and publicizing key wage and price
decisions.
Finally, we need to keep a firm grip on money
and credit. History teaches two lessons about the
impact of monetary policy. One is that inflation
cannot continue without the money to finance it.
Therefore, if inflation is to be moderated, growth
in money must also be moderated. A second
lesson is that growth in money must be moder­
ated slowly to avoid sending the economy into a
serious recession.
Translated into current policy, these lessons
mean that the recent 7 percent growth in money
(the narrow money supply or
must be mod­
erated over a period of time, and the time could
be quite long. I believe it is important, therefore,
for the Federal Open Market Committee to set
long-run targets for moderating growth and then
diligently pursue hitting these targets. In fact, the
FOMC has been attempting such a procedure for
over two years now. I'm hopeful that with ex­
perience and resolve we'll be able to improve
the accuracy of our aim.

WHAT TO DO ABOUT INFLATION

ROLE OF INTEREST RATES

There are no quick or painless answers. Infla­
tion has taken nearly a decade to build up and
will take considerable time and discipline to
unwind. There are, I believe, four essential re­
quirements for dampening inflation.
First, we have to become more realistic about

What would such a policy mean for interest
rates? I am uncomfortable with high interest
rates, especially with the record levels we are
currently experiencing. But we should be clear
about two things: one is what is necessary to
bring interest rates down; the other is the role




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

employment benefits, public service jobs, wel­
fare reform, training and education programs are
all ways of dealing with problems of those hit
hardest by slack in the job market.
The financial burdens of a restrictive monetary
policy are also not distributed evenly across the
economy. High interest rates, for example, im­
pact heavily on housing and some public proj­
ects. A logical question, therefore, is whether we
could al locate credit in such a way as to smooth
out the burdens or even favor some high-priority
sectors at the expense of lower-priority ones. In
other words, should the Federal Reserve allocate
credit as well as create credit?
I approach this question with considerable
sympathy. Forces at work in our society, espe­
cially over the past decade, confront us with
aspects of the distribution of burdens and bene­
fits with an urgency that we have never felt
before. They will not go away. There is good
reason for the Fed to consider the matter of the
allocation of credit with great care and concern.
A few years ago I explored the question as
thoroughly as I knew how in an article which I
should be happy to submit for the record.1 I
asked our research staff to undertake further
studies of selective credit controls, their history
and their efficacy. The first volume of these
studies will appear shortly after the turn of the
year. I should like nowsimplyto make five points
in summary.
First, selective credit controls are less neces­
sary when markets are working well. One reason
credit does not flow into markets such as housing
is that artificial limitations are placed on interest
rates and lenders. The point is that action to
eliminate usury ceilings and other such restraints
would make selective credit controls less neces­
sary.
Second, the Fed's experience in attempting to
direct credit into "productive" and away from
"nonproductive" uses has not been good. The
reason is that it becomes virtually impossible in

which interest rates play in combating inflation.
The Federal Reserve could try to lower interest
rates by supplying money and credit more
generously than it has. A faster growth rate for
money would likely lower short-term interest
rates temporarily, but only temporarily. Opening
the money spigot further would add still more
fuel to the fires of inflation. This in turn would
add to inflationary expectations, and interest
rates would rise as lenders protect themselves by
building in larger inflation premiums. So, a
looser monetary policy aimed at lowering in­
terest rates now would eventually lead to higher
rates.
The surer way to lower interest rates is by
reducing inflation. In order to do this, the Federal
Reserve has to be less generous in supplying
money and credit. Cutting back on the flow of
money and credit into the economy itself will
push up interest rates temporarily. In time, how­
ever, slower monetary growth will lead to less
inflation and lower interest rates. So, a restrictive
monetary policy now aimed at slowing the rate
of inflation will lead in time to lower interest
rates, not higher ones.
In the meantime, we should recognize that
interest rates are playing an important role in
combatting inflation. I say this despite the fact
that the effect of interest rates has long been
debated. I believe, however, that rising interest
rates do choke off some demand for credit and
therefore do help to bring total demand for goods
and services into better balance with the ability
of the economy to meet these demands.
A final question remains, however: What is
the impact of credit restraint and high interest
rates on various sectors of our economy and
society?
EVENING OUT THE BURDENS OF FIGHTING
INFLATION
One of the burdens of combating inflation
will be a higher unemployment rate than we
would like. I believe the benefits of moderating
inflation will be widely distributed and therefore
the burden of fighting inflation should be as
widely distributed as possible. Liberalized un­




’ "Federal Reserve Policy and Social Priorities," Business
Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
November 1970, pp. 2-8.
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

the board. The workability of such a program
seems questionable, to say the least. The costs
could be enormous.
Fourth, if, in spite of these difficulties, Con­
gress were to decide that credit should be con­
trolled in accordance with certain social
priorities, I believe that determination of these
priorities is properly a matter for Congress, not
the Federal Reserve.
Fifth, the goal of stimulating certain sectors of
the economy and restraining others might in
some cases better be approached through fiscal
rather than credit action. The variable invest­
ment tax credit is one possibility. Direct provi­
sion of funds for the mortgage market is already
being employed. Other possibilities should be
explored.
I conclude from all this that, over time, the
question of allocating credit should be studied
further. Our analysis to date, however, suggests
serious problems. Perhaps the most important
point is that if we can avoid inflation through
general monetary and fiscal policy, we have less
reason to be concerned with the allocation of
credit. A program of credit allocation is no substi­
tute for responsible policy in dealing with the
overall supply of money and credit.

practice to determine which uses are really pro­
ductive and which are nonproductive. I agree
with those who believe that a basic solution to
inflation is to enlarge the economy's ability to
produce. My point is that selective credit con­
trols offer little practical promise of directing
funds in ways that will accomplish this. If, in fact,
it should be part of policy to direct funds into
capital investment, this is being done quite effec­
tively by today's tight capital market.
Third, the idea that positive incentives might
be helpful in directing funds in certain ways has a
great deal of appeal. We in Philadelphia have
done considerable analysis, for example, of the
proposal that variable reserve requirements be
placed on various kinds of bank assets. A lower
requirement could be placed on high-priority
loans and a higher requirement on lower-priority
loans. Our research indicates a major problem:
credit is extremely mobile and people are in­
genious in substituting one kind of credit for
another. If, for example, reserve requirements
were to favor home mortgages over business
loans, it seems inevitable that businessmen
would simply by-pass banks to go to other
lenders or the open market. An effective program
of credit allocation would have to apply across




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

State Laws Affect
The Pace Of
Sew Hank Charters




l»Y
iloiisilil a. Icoimril

SEPTEMBER 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

CHART 1
BANK CHARTERING ACTIVITY DEPENDS ON BRANCH BANKING
LAWS AS W ELL AS THE ATTRACTIVENESS OF NEW MARKET
OPPORTUNITIES. IN STATES WHERE BRANCHING IS PROHIBITED,
NEW OR EXPANDING MARKETS MUST BE SERVED BY ESTA BLISH ­
ING NEW BANKS RATHER THAN BRANCHES.
Number of New Charters Per
State (1969-1973)

Number of New Charters Per One
Million of Population (1969-1973)

Branching States
(35 + D. C.)

Branching States
(35 + D. C.)

Sources:




American Banker (March 16, 1974), Association of Registered
Bank Holding Companies Compilation of State Laws, Rand
McNally International Bankers Directory, U. S. Census Bureau.

8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

CHART 2
SIM ILARLY, SOME MULTIBANK HOLDING COMPANIES HAVE USED
NEW CHARTERS EITHER TO ENTER MARKETS WHERE TH ERE IS NO
ATTRACTIVE ACQUISITION PARTNER OR TO EXPAND WITHIN MAR­
KETS WHERE ANTITRUST REGULATIONS MIGHT LIMIT FURTHER
BANKING CONCENTRATION.
Number of New Charters Per
State (1969-1973)

■

Number of New Charters Per One
Million of Population (1969-1973)

Restricted Multibank
HC** States (17)

Restricted Multibank
HC States

5
4
3
2
1

0
* Restricted multibank holding company states are considered to be those
states that at the very minimum prohibit a holding company from acquiring
a 25 percent or greater share ownership in a second bank when there is
demonstrated control in a first bank. This is comparable to the share owner­
ship guideline used in the 1956 Federal law on bank holding companies.




9

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

CHART 3
THEREFO RE, THE HIGHEST LEVELS OF NEW CHARTERING ACTIVITY
ARE FOUND WHERE MULTIBANK HOLDING COMPANIES ARE PER­
MITTED BUT BRANCHING IS PROHIBITED.
Number of New Charters Per
State (1969-1973)

■
Si




Number of New Charters Per One
Million of Population (1969-1973)

Branching MBHCs
Restricted (10 States)

Branching MBHCs
Restricted

Branching MBHCs Allowed
(25 States + D.C.)

Branching
MBHCs Allowed

Unit Banking MBHCs
Restricted (7 States)

Unit Banking
MBHCs Restricted

Unit Banking
MBHCs Allowed
(8 States)

IK

Unit Banking
MBHCs
Allowed-------

13.1

13
12

11
10
9
8

7
6
5
4
3
2
1

0

10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

CHART 4
PREDICTABLY, MORE THAN ONE-THIRD OF THE BANK CHARTERS
GRANTED DURING THE PERIOD 1969 THROUGH 1973 WERE IN
TH REE RAPIDLY GROWING STATES—FLORIDA, TEXAS, AND COLO­
RAD O - THAT PROHIBIT BRANCHING BUT ALLOW MULTIBANK
HOLDING COMPANIES.
Number of New
Charters (1969-1973)

1100 --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------1013

,mP°rtant Areas of New Chartering Activity

1000

900
800
700

—

600

Total New Charters in Unit —
Banking States Which Permit
MBHCs (8 States)

500




Total

FL

TX

CO

5
Other
States

Foreign Exchange
Markets:
Booming and
Bustling
By Janice M. Westerfield

Since Adam and Eve traded their stay in
Eden for a piece of the forbidden fruit, people
have been concerned with the benefits and costs
of exchange. Indeed, the development of money
as a "medium of exchange" represents an at­
tempt to economize on the costs of trading by
eliminating some of the inefficiencies of barter.
Problems arise, however, when individuals use
different kinds of money, as when trade occurs
across international borders. French francs, con­
venient a toute outrance in a Paris dress shop,
become bothersome if the desired gown sits in a
New York boutique. Such inconveniences can
be avoided, however, by simply trading francs
for dollars— a simple task in today's welldeveloped foreign exchange markets.
Foreign currency markets are among the fast­
est growing of their kind in the world. Given
the soaring volume of goods exchanged across
international borders, a boom in currency ex­
change is not surprising. In addition, however,




individuals and corporations can and do trade
foreign currencies without any accompanying
flow of real goods. In fact, new sets of institutions
have recently developed to accommodate
buyers and sellers of foreign exchange whose
aim is quite simple—to "make a buck" through
buying low and selling high. These new institu­
tions reflect an innovating approach to the small
investor's needs and thus complement the
growth of international trade.
A number of factors, including the spread of
multinational enterprises, the relaxation of capi­
tal controls, and the existence of a new interna­
tional monetary system, have contributed to the
growth in trade and expanded opportunities for
profitable trading of foreign currencies. Whether
exchange markets will continue their spectacu­
lar expansion, however, hinges on factors which
are difficult to forecast, such as the possible
reimposition of controls on capital flows and
changes in the international monetary system.
12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

the place position, but recently the deutsche
mark has probably taken over the runner-up
spot. The dollar/German mark rate has become
a leading indicator of the strength of the dollar.
The Japanese yen and the Swiss franc have
likewise experienced considerable increases in
trading activities.
Locally the pound sterling is definitely the cur­
rency most in demand by corporate customers.
One reason for this is that the Quaker City is a
wool center, and wool is usually bought and
paid for in sterling. By way of contrast, the Cana­
dian dollar, while not as much in demand by
Philadelphia commerce, constitutes a significant
pprtion of the total currency traded because
banks actively deal in this currency for their own
account.

TRANSACTIONS VOLUME BOOMS
IN FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKETS
From almost all perspectives, activity in the
foreign exchange market has soared in the last
few years. Back in March 1966, the largest 15 or
so banks in New York, the major foreign cur­
rency center in the United States, were turning
over about $10 billion monthly in selected
foreign currency dealings among them. Three
years later these same New York banks were
estimated to have doubled their monthly foreign
exchange dealings. (However, these monthly
figures are for selective currencies only and thus
underestimate the size of the market.) Although
hard figures for the foreign exchange market are
very difficult to obtain, the $500 billion figure
sometimes cited as the size of the total annual
transactions involved has been pooh-poohed as
no more than "a drop in the bucket" by the chief
trader of a large New York bank. Claiming 1973
showed "more foreign exchange trading than all
of the world's GNP put together," he implied
that his bank alone handled considerably more
than $200 billion in '72. As for year-to-year in­
creases in transactions volume, during 1970-73
his trading desk experienced a 10 to 30 percent
rise in volume each year.
Although New York is the hub of the financial
action, there are many smaller banks dealing in
foreign exchange whose trading business has
flourished. The head of the trading department at
a nearby Philadelphia bank, known for its
foreign exchange trading, estimated that deal­
ings more than doubled during the past year.
That bank's turnover is now $50 million per
day— and in Philadelphia this is a sizable chunk
of the action.
Besides the actual increase measured in dollar
terms, the currency mix traded in the New York
market over the last few years has changed con­
siderably. Excluding the U. S. dollar, the pound
sterling— the top currency in trading—
accounted for more than half the value of the
turnover in foreign exchange in '66 but since
then has grown less than proportionately with
the market. Nevertheless, it remains number
one. In the mid-'60s, the Canadian dollar held




REASONS FOR GROWTH OF
FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKETS
Foreign Trade. Expanding world trade is the
most obvious and important reason for the
burgeoning foreign exchange market. World ex­
ports, excluding those of the Communist bloc,
have multiplied over five times since 1953, so
that the increase in dollar volume traded from
'72 to '73 was greater than the total yearly trade
20 years earlier. During the last three years
alone, world exports swelled by 80 percent. Dur­
ing that same period U. S. merchandise exports
grew 67 percent while U. S. imports increased
75 percent. In 1973 U. S. merchandise exports
grew at a faster pace than GNP. In fact, some
believe that the traditional 4 percent of GNP for
U. S. exports may be giving way before the im­
pact of the trade explosion.
Foreign exchange trading parallels the growth
in international trade because monies facilitate
the exchange of goods between parties. While
commerce between residents of the U. S. in­
volves only one currency, dollars, trade between
a Philadelphian and a Berliner usually involves
exchanging dollars into German marks or vice
versa (see Box 1). The number of marks received
for a dollar depends, of course, on the dollar
price of marks, the exchange rate. Converting the
home currency into the foreign currency is
13

SEPTEMBER 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

BOX 1

A TRADE EXAMPLE
Suppose IBM makes computers in the U. S. and exports them to its marketing subsidiary in
West Germany. The marketing subsidiary in West Germany in turn sells the computers to the
West Germans, who pay for them in their domestic currency, Deutsche marks (DM). Suppose
the subsidiary sells 500,000 DM worth of computers with payment to be made 90 days hence.
So far so good. Now IBM is primarily interested in selling its exported goods at an economic
profit. The question is what to do with the German marks. IBM has several alternatives. On one
hand, IBM can wait until it receives the DMs and then sell them (buy dollars) immediately on
the spot foreign exchange market. Then the dollars can be transferred to the home office for use
in the United States. Since IBM doesn't know what the spot price will be in 90 days, some risk is
involved. On the other hand, if the value of the DMs is relatively low in dollar terms when IBM
receives them, someone in the firm may anticipate a better deal by speculating— holding the
DMs and waiting a few days before exchanging them into dollars. Of course, DMs may fall as
well as rise in value during the next few days, but that's part of the exchange risk which IBM
accepts when it embraces this alternative.
No matter when IBM sells its DMs in the spot market, it has chosen to speculate. If it holds the
DMs and sells later, IBM is to profit from the possible increase in value in DMs. In the
meantime, if it sells the DMs now, it is to profit from today's rate since it can always sell later
and borrow dollars at a cost if they're needed.
Is there any way that IBM can avoid the risk of a fluctuating exchange rate? Yes. If IBM wants
to stay strictly in the business of selling computers in Germany, and out of the business of
speculating against the $/DM exchange rate, it can hedge its currency by selling a forward
contract to be delivered in the future at a price agreed upon today. That is, IBM agrees to deliver
500,000 DM and accepts the price currently quoted in the 90-day forward market. Who buys
the forward contract? The partner on the other side of the transaction may be another hedger,
perhaps an importer in the U. S. who is expecting a shipment in three months for which he must
pay in DMs. Or a speculator may want to buy DMs in the forward market, hoping to sell them
immediately upon maturity in the spot market at a higher price than he paid for them.

achieved by contacting a local bank's foreign
exchange department.
However, first the customer must decide
whether he wishes to deal in the “ spot market''
or in the “ forward market." The spot market
provides for immediate delivery within two or
three business days with payment upon delivery.
The forward market, however, involves the
purchase or sale of foreign currency at some
specified future date (see Box 1). Although the




actual delivery may be weeks or months away,
the price or terms of the trade are agreed upon
today. Thus, the forward market al lows traders to
avoid the risk that exchange rates will change
adversely between today and when they will
make payment on the currency. The forward
contract is simply a promise to buy or sell the
currency in the future and is not backed by col­
lateral, although a bank balance may sometimes
be required.
14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

operating earnings, may induce other banks to
explore the profit potential in enlarging their
trading desks.

Various market participants use these spot and
forward markets for thei r operations. Speculators
try to make money in foreign exchange by buy­
ing or selling foreign currency in an open (uncov­
ered) position, accepting the risk of an adverse
change in the value of their holdings in hopes of
making a profit (see Box 1). While speculators
may accept risks by taking either spot or forward
market positions, others who wish to avoid
speculating in the ups and downs of currency
values use the forward market to cover or
"hedge" their risks. Hedgers are in effect
safeguarding against price changes by trading in
the forward market.1
Commercial banks provide foreign exchange
market services primarily to meet their custom­
ers' needs. Although banks are often sensitive
about the profitability of their exchange opera­
tions, those banks with foreign currency trading
desks have recently seen them become profit
centers in their own right. In addition 'to
anticipating the demands of their customers,
traders are frankly hoping "to make a buck."2
Banks have found recently that by accepting lim­
ited risks of uncovered currency positions,
they can often make a handsome return. Morgan
Guaranty, for instance, reported $42 million
gross income before expenses from their foreign
exchange trading in 1973, more than double
what they made the previous year. This figure,
representing about 4 percent of their gross

Capital Restraints Relaxed. Although the
growth in world trade has helped to provide the
impetus for the mushrooming activity in foreign
exchange markets, the recently completed re­
laxation of the restraints on capital outflows
bodes well for the continued growth of currency
trading. The Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint
Program (VFCR), the Interest Equalization Tax,
and the Overseas Foreign Direct Investment
guidelines had constituted a three-pronged
strategy developed in the 1960s to help the U. S.
balance of payments.3 Since the U. S. had been
experiencing continual dollar outflows which
contributed heavily to the balance of payments
deficit, these programs aimed to limit flows of
funds abroad.
By early 1974, however, not only had Uncle
Sam's trade balanced improved, but the dollar
was strong in exchange markets as well. Thus,
the pressure to restrain dollar outflows di­
minished. Since these programs terminated in
January 1974, firms and individuals have been
free to pursue whatever investment strategies
will yield the most profit, regardless of location.
For example, corporations are free to invest con­
siderably more than the $5.3 billion that they
invested in 1972 under the Overseas Direct In­
vestment Program. Similarly, since the U. S.
Treasury reduced the Interest Equalization Tax to
zero, an American buyer of a foreign stock or
bond no longer faces this additional cost previ­
ously imposed upon him. A few months ago he
had to accept a .75 percentage point reduction in
the effective yield, and the borrowing firm no

'Another group of market participants, called arbitrageurs,
takes advantage of the difference in interest rates (as well as
exchange rates) to invest funds in a foreign center for the sake
of benefiting from the higher yield in that center. Thus, an
arbitrageur may invest DMs in the German economy by
purchasing a short-term asset such as Treasury Bills. Whether
or not this option is profitable depends upon the interest rates
in Germany relative to the United States and on the spot and
forward exchange rates between the two countries.
2Some banks have recently learned the hard way that risks
taken in foreign exchange markets can spell disaster as well
as handsome profits. Bank traders can face these currency
risks whether they trade for their own account or for a
customer's account. Highly publicized losses in foreign ex­
change by Franklin National Bank and Bankhaus I. D. Herstatt of West Germany attest to the high stakes sometimes
involved.




3The VFCR, administered by the Fed, was aimed at restrain­
ing foreign lending and investments overseas by U. S. banks
and other financial institutions. The Foreign Direct Invest­
ment restrictions, which were operated by the Department of
Commerce, set ceilings on the allowable investment over­
seas and the transfer of funds to foreign affiliates by U.S.
corporations. The Interest Equalization Tax was imposed on
stock or bond purchases from foreigners.
15

SEPTEMBER 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

longer has to pay higher yields to compensate
the lender at least partially for the tax. Termina­
tion of the controls enabled individual banks and
corporations to expand their foreign lending
and investments freely and to utilize the ex­
change markets in the process.

(those whose value in terms of other currencies is
expected to appreciate) while piling up debt and
other liabilities in currencies expected to depre­
ciate. Multinationals develop good exchange
trading relationships with their banks sothatthey
may reduce exchange risk and proceed with the
"legitimate" business of the multinational. This
also makes it easy for them to transfer funds for
purposes of realigning their investments or to
incur a speculative position.
The continued expansion of multinational
corporations along with the relaxation of capital
restraints and burgeoning world trade activity
have all contributed to the boom of foreign ex­
change trading. Still another avenue for growth,
however, can be found in the development of
new exchanges with expanding trading oppor­
tunities.

Sophisticated Portfolio Management. In addi­
tion to the greater freedom of capital move­
ments, factors such as the sophisticated man­
agement of assets and liabilities by banks and
multinationals, the relatively large companies
that control most foreign investment, have
played a substantial role in the growth of foreign
exchange markets. In response to the high in­
terest rates of recent years, corporate treasurers
have managed funds much more carefully to
insure that no opportunities for profit are over­
looked. Mammoth sums are involved in these
portfolios*. A study by the U. S. Traffic Commis­
sion estimated that in 1971 banks and corpora­
tions held a $268 billion pool of liquid assets,
more than three times the $ 88V2 billion of cur­
rency reserves held by the central banks of the
industrial countries. This pool of short-term as­
sets grew by $100 billion overatwo-year period.
Large multinational corporations literally move
billions of dollars through the currency ex­
changes every year. In investments alone, U.S.
multinationals have been responsible for nearly
$80 billion in direct foreign investment by 1970.
Foreign exchange risks and opportunities are
certainly factors which govern the movement of
multinational funds. Exporting and importing
firms are developing strategies to protect them­
selves against foreign exchange losses. Currency
risks are increasingly hedged in the forward mar­
ket on a regular basis,4 so much so that the hedg­
ing of foreign exchange risks has become "just
another cost" of doing business overseas. Elabo­
rate strategies proliferate such as switching cash
and other current assets into "strong" currencies

NEW INSTITUTIONS JOIN BANKS IN
PROVIDING EXCHANGE SERVICES
Although the bank system of spot and forward
markets handles most foreign exchange transac­
tions, several newcomers have arrived on the
scene in the last five years.
The International Monetary Market. The most
important of the newcomers is the International
Monetary Market (IMM), a currency futures mar­
ket which opened in May 1972 (see Box 2). A
child of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange
(CME), the IMM sees its role as facilitating foreign
trade and investment by helping to insure against
the risk encountered by importers, exporters,
and international traders, resulting from fluctua­
tions in the prices of various currencies. At pres­
ent "futures" in seven foreign monies are traded,
in addition to U. S. and Canadian silver coin
futures. A futures contract specifies the purchase
or sale of currency for future delivery. Trading is
continuous in each contract from the time the
first contract is issued until the delivery month.
The contract sizes are standardized, and they
range from about $42,000 to $100,000 in U. S.
dollar equivalents (see Table for details). Traders
pay a commission charge for each trade. Of
course, multiples of the standard contract may
be traded. (For a comparison of the IMM and

■•See Norman S. Fieleke, ''Exchange Rate Flexibility and
the Forward Exchange Markets: Some Evidence from the
Recent Experience with the German Mark,” New England
Economic Review, May/June 1972, pp. 2-10.




16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

BOX 2

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY MARKET
The International Monetary Market opened in Chicago on May 16, 1972 and has been
growing ever since. The IMM originally traded futures contracts in seven currencies—the
pound sterling, Swiss franc, German mark, Italian lira, Mexican peso, Canadian dollar and
Japanese yen— and in May 1973 added the Dutch guilder. Spot contracts are not traded. A
futures contract (similar to a forward contract in the bank market) is a standardized agreement
to buy or sell the currency in a future month at a price agreed upon today. Futures are traded
for the next three months and at three-month intervals thereafter up to eighteen months. All
deliveries are made on the third Wednesday of the contract month.
The contract size is standardized for each currency and averages around $70,000. All
currency contracts are settled in terms of U. S. dollars. Each currency has a minimum
fluctuation and a (normal) daily limit. For instance, the DM contract size is 250,000 DM with a
minimum fluctuation of .00005 ($12.50) and a normal daily limit of $.005 or about $1,250. In
other words, the price of DMs is not permitted to change more than V2 a cent per DM (or $1,250
for the contract value of 250,000 DM) in a normal trading day. The "round-trip" commission
to buy a near futures and sell a longer maturity futures comes to $45. Both the buyer and the
seller are required to maintain a security deposit averaging 1 or 2 percent of the total value of
the contract depending on the currency.
The IMM has modified several of its original specifications. A two for one split in all contracts
but the Mexican peso and the Dutch guilder, effective June 1 of last year, made the exchange
available to the moderate investor. New daily trading limits were implemented whereby if the
currency closes at the normal limit for two successive days, the limit of the following days is
expanded if necessary until the fifth day when there is no daily price limit.
Orders are executed in the trading pit by the floor brokers, who confirm the order to the
member firms which then report all the transactions at the end of the day to the clearing house.
The clearing house matches the trades and assumes the opposite side of the contract for both
buyers and sellers. Besides making sure that the trading flows resulting from execution are
orderly, the clearing house guarantees performance of the contract and oversees contract
deliveries.

year earlier, the total number of equivalent con­
tracts increased by 11 percent. Over $35 billion
worth of foreign exchange was transacted at the
IMM in 1973. This figure includes a considerable
spurt for December, which had by far the largest
number of contracts traded in both years. Of the
individual currencies the German mark and the
M exican peso were the biggest gainers
percentage-wise, while the Canadian dollar and
Swiss franc contracts lost ground.
The IMM in its infancy had the advantage of
the communications system already set up at the
Chicago M ercantile Exchange. Substantial

the bank market, see Box 3.)
The IMM has gradually strengthened its foot­
hold in the market.5 Comparing the June through
December period in 1973 with the same time a

5The IMM may soon be facing some stiff competition. The
New York Mercantile Exchange plans to open a futures mar­
ket in foreign currencies in a couple of months. This new
exchange will be modeled after the IMM with trading in the
Italian lira and the commercial Belgian franc in addition to
the seven currencies traded in Chicago. Contracts are stan­
dardized with the same trading units specified by the IMM to
facilitate arbitrage between the two markets.




17

SEPTEMBER 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

NEW INSTITUTIONS OFFER STANDARDIZED CONTRACTS
IN ANUMBER OF FOREIGN CURRENCIES
AMERICAN BOARD

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY

OF TRADE

MARKET
Contract
25,000
100,000
125,000
250,000
12,500,000
1,0.00,000
250,000

BP
CD
DG
DM
JY
MP
SF

U. S. $

Fluct. Min.

55,000

5 pts. ($12.50)
lO pts. ( 10 . 00)
4 pts. ( 5.00)
5 pts. (12.50)
10 pts. (12.50)
1 pt. ( 10 .00)
5 pts. (12.50)

100,000
42,500
90,000
42,000
80,000
75,000

Limit
300
750
600
500
600
75
500

pts.
pts.
pts.
pts.
pts.
pts.
pts.

Contract
1,000
2,500
10,000
1,000,000
10,000
10,000
1,500,000

BP
CD
DM
JY
SF
FF
IL

Effective January 1974
Key
BP British pound
JY Japanese yen
CD Canadian dollar MP Mexican peso
DG Dutch guilder
SF Swiss franc
DM German mark
FF French franc
IL Italian lira

commodities trading was already taking place
with an organized group of floor traders, local
speculators, floor brokers, and phone lines to
banks and brokers elsewhere. Over three million
contracts were traded on the CME in 1971. These
factors reduced information and transaction
costs of the untried contract and probably helped
the IMM get off to an auspicious start.6

The American Board of Trade. Customers
with pint-sized transactions in foreign exchange
will welcome the appearance of another new­
comer, the American Board of Trade Foreign
Exchange Market located in New York City.
Founded in 1969, the American Board of Trade
(ABT) has been trading in foreign exchange since
'71, yet it is not as well known in exchange

6The International Commercial Exchange, a currency fu­
tures market based in New York City, was not so lucky. It
opened a couple of years ago and folded within a short time.
In an explanatory brochure, international commodity bro­
kers Brodie, White, and Company of New York highlighted
some of the problems encountered by the ICE which were
less likely to be obstacles at the IMM. Because most of the

commodities brokerage houses which service the country's
speculators did not have telephone and Telex lines with this
exchange, an ICE communications system was lacking. This
discouraged new clients who did not have other business
with the exchange. The small-sized contracts approximating
$25,000 discouraged bank participation.




18

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

BOX 3

DISTINCTIONS BETWEEN THE IMM AND THE BANK MARKET
Although the IMM complements and supplements the bank market by furnishing facilities for
trading futures contracts in foreign currencies, there are several distinctions between the two
markets. First, the market participants differ. Whereas the bank market is primarily for large
transactions by banks, multinationals, and others with overseas operations, IMM's average
single contract has a value of only $70,000, so that in addition to the large concerns (who might
want multiples of contracts), the contracts are within easy reach of the medium-size investor.
Second, the timing and frequency of delivery of the currency differ substantially in the two
markets. Delivery dates are standardized and occur once a month in futures contracts at the
IMM while forward contracts on the bank market may mature on any business day. Some 90
percent of the forward contracts are settled by actual delivery whereas futures markets such as
the IMM have almost no deliveries. Why? Because contracts for June DMs are sold over a year
previous to the maturity date of June 19 and can be offset by buying a June contract at any time
until the last day of trading. The ease of offsetting a contract (that is, of cancelling out a purchase
or delivery of currency for the same maturity date) in the futures market encourages offsets and
facilitates the entry and exit of speculators. For instance, the customer can buy a June futures
contract the previous December, close out (sell) the contract on June 1, and buy the spot
currency at the bank. During this transaction, the customer is fully hedged. In other words,
what he gains in the futures contract he loses in the spot market. On the other hand, the
customer can simply purchase a forward contract to mature some day in June at the bank.
Whereas delivery dates and contracts are standardized in the currency futures markets,
contracts are tailor-made (but at a price) to the needs of the individual in the bank market. The
cost of a bank forward contract is the difference between the rate quoted on the purchase and
simultaneous sale of a given forward contract with specified currency, and the cost varies with
the size of the transaction. Banks attempt to marry the demands of their customers. Bank trading
rooms typically have several traders seated at a desk with telephone and Telex communica­
tions to the customers, brokers, and other banks. Each trader deals with specific currencies
and keeps an up-to-the-minute tally of the bank's positions.

markets as the IMM. The ABT deals in spot and
30-, 60-, 90-day forward contracts (see Box 4)
much as the bank market does. Their basic ob­
jective is to “ serve as an exchange and market
place which will offer . . . sound and profitable
investment and speculative mediums . . . until
now unavailable to the average investor." En­
ticement for the small speculator is provided by
standard unit contracts in the $3,000 range. In
addition to several foreign currencies, the ABT
has markets in silver futures, spot silver, silver
coins and silver coin futures, but has no broad




commodity base such as that of the Chicago
Mercantile Exchange. It is impossible to get any
volume data on this fledgling market but it ap­
pears to be holding its own.
The IMM and the ABT did not make their
appearance on the financial scene without some
economic justification. Indeed, the reasons for
their development and growth can be traced to
the changes in the international monetary sys­
tem, the demand for speculative services, and
the lack of inhibiting formal regulations on the
foreign exchange markets.
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

BOX 4

AMERICAN BOARD OF TRADE
The Foreign Exchange Market of the American Board of Trade opened in New York City in
September 1971. The ABT deals in forward contracts of seven currencies—the pound sterling,
Swiss franc, German mark, Canadian dollar, Japanese yen, Italian lira, and French franc—the
last two currencies being the only ones not covered in the IMM. Thirty-, 60-, and 90-day
forwards are the primary contracts.
The standard unit contract varies from around $2,000 to $4,000 and can be purchased in
multiples of two, five, or ten units. The purchase of a five-unit contract in DMs (50,000 DM) for
30 days and the simultaneous sale of a 90-day contract of the same amount entail a margin
deposit of $750 (about 4 percent) and a $37.50 commission fee. (The investor establishes the
spread and then liquidates it when the shorter contract has matured 30 days later by selling in
the spot market and simultaneously purchasing a 60-day forward contract).
The ABT has made several innovations in the foreign exchange market. They offer options in
maturities of three months, six months/ten days, and one year which are backed by actual
futures positions. There are a variety of options not available elsewhere. An affiliate, the ABT
Service Corporation, acts to assure a fluid and orderly market and cushion against “ capricious"
exchange fluctuations. The ABT does not permit members of the exchange to trade for their
own account on the exchange floor; ABT administrative personnel execute orders on the floor
of the exchange.

A New International Monetary Environment.
Nineteen seventy-one signaled several mo­
mentous changes in the international monetary
system which IMM officials felt “ created an envi­
ronment conducive to a futures market in foreign
exchange." One crucial element of the “ new"
system is that most exchange rate changes are no
longer limited in size by formal agreements
among trading nations. Under the old system of
“ fixed" exchange rates, foreign currency prices
could not deviate up or down from specified
values by more than a given percentage amount.
Only rarely, when in a “ fundamental disequilib­
rium," were changes in the parity values permit­
ted. Presently, however, few such formal limits
on the size of permissible price changes exist, so
that currency prices are in principle free to
“ float" to values determined by the market
forces of supply and demand— hence the term
floating exchange rates. These market forces re­
sult in greater spot and forward rate fluctuations




on a day-to-day basis.7 Greater price fluctuations
translate into more opportunity for profit and
loss. Hedgers therefore increase their demand
for services to guard against the risk of currency
price changes while speculators want more ser­
vices enabling them to accept risks and exploit
the workings of the market profitably.
Speculators perform an essential function in en­
couraging the reshuffling of risks. By relieving
hedgers and other traders of unwanted currency
risks, speculators free them to concentrate on
their “ ordinary" day-to-day business. Both new

7Even the Canadian floating rate in the '50s, generally
thought not to be too variable, was estimated to be 2Vi times
more variable than any of several fixed rates for the '60s.
However, many floating rates are subject to varying degrees
of government intervention, ranging from little or no gov­
ernment action to considerable government participation in
a "managed" float. Most of the recent currency floats, espe­
cially those since March 1973, are of this latter type.
20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

exchanges appear to have anticipated these in­
ternational developments and hope to be able to
supply a good portion of these required services.
Since these innovators assume a positive view of
the role of speculation in foreign exchange mar­
kets, they can open the door to a broad class of
customers seeking foreign exchange services.

will be reduced to a more competitive level.
IMM's bank critics respond that the exchange
market is not making the effort to attract a solid
base of commercial firms.
Lack of Regulation. The absence of formal
legal restrictions of foreign exchange markets
probably encouraged the development of new
institutions such as the IMM and the ABT. It is
highly unlikely that such innovative growth via
new institutions would have surfaced so rapidly
in a regulated market. Although IMM officials
discussed their proposed exchange with both the
Treasury and the Fed, they did not have to secure
approval from any government agency to begin
operations. The unregulated market generally
provides an atmosphere where innovative activ­
ity such as a currency futures market can
flourish.
The potential threat of regulation of the bank
market as well as the new exchanges and the
wish to avoid the long arm of the government
probably explain the paucity of statistics and the
secrecy surrounding the magnitude of foreign
exchange dealings.8 Many bankers fear a move­

Speculation Encouraged. Speculators can
hardly be blamed if they try to take advantage of
the new profit opportunities available to them,
yet when they try to finance through the local
bank, they encounter a brick wall. “ Specula­
tion” is ostensibly a dirty word in the bank
foreign exchange market, and it may include
anyone trying to profit from exchange dealings.
Bank traders feel that speculators raise costs for
the legitimate businessman. Take the case of a
local Philadelphia banker who is not prepared to
do business with someone who is “ merely
speculating,” only those with “ legitimate” busi­
ness.
Who is prepared to accommodate the
speculator-investor? The IMM and the ABT. Far
from having a bias against speculation, these
exchanges actually encourage it. The ABT, in
particular, is trying to attract the small
speculator— witness the emphasis on being a
“ speculative medium” in their public state­
ments. The small-sized contracts offered by the
ABT are within range of the average investor and
provide him with new speculative opportunities.
In addition to interesting speculators, the ABT
hopes to attract small transactors for whom the
bank market is too costly or simply unavailable.
IMM officials also have some good words for
the speculator. They not only believe the
speculator lends “ breadth, depth and resiliency”
to the market, they believe the IMM can accom­
modate the speculator and other participants in
small to medium transactions at a lower cost
than the banks. Although the bank market may
service a small account, the prices will not be
very favorable. One reason the IMM gives for
encouraging speculators-investors is that they
increase the number of contracts traded and thus
improve the chances that the bid-asked spread
(difference between buying and selling prices)




8The ABT, in particular, is very protective of its current
setup and resents what it considers to be harassment by
government agencies and members of the financial com­
munity. The ABT appears to focus considerable energy in this
fight against outside interference. It has even asked Congress
“ for protection against and an investigation of the illegal acts
of suppression, repression and harassment" of the Securities
and Exchange Commission and other government agencies.
Clearly the prospect of any government interference is not
taken lightly by the ABT.
In fact, government agencies have been checking up on
the ABT and the American Association of Commodity Trad­
ers, which have a common organizational structure and are
headed by the same man. Government action against the
AACT has run the gamut from a subpoena for books and
records by the SEC to the denial of nonprofit status by the IRS.
The SEC is investigating the profit structure of this new ex­
change to determine if memberships should be classified as
“ securities" under the 1933 Act. If the SEC decides that the
investment contract does involve “ investment of money in a
common enterprise with profits to come from the money of
others" (the legal definition), the SEC may claim jurisdiction
over these “ securities" and subject the membership to regis­
tration.
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

justable" rates in the near future.
While the energy crisis dashed hopes for a
quick return to the adjustable peg, the huge oil
payments to the petroleum-exporting countries
may also mean large balance of payments def­
icits for oil buyers. These predicted deficits may
tempt some countries to restore barriers recently
removed from capital movements. Renewed
barriers to investment and lending between
countries would discourage foreign currencies
from moving freely and thus put a damper on the
growth of the foreign exchange market.

ment toward control of foreign exchange opera­
tions carried out by commercial banks. Several
countries have already set up procedures for
regular reporting of forward operations. In the
U. S. a reporting system is being developed to
keep the Treasury informed of the spot and for­
ward dealings of large banks and multinationals.
England has instituted control restrictions on the
position that banks can take either for or against
the pound sterling. Recent losses in foreign ex­
changetrading both in the U. S. and abroad have
spurred speculation that the central banks may
impose some restraints to head off further such
losses.

GERMAN MARKS AND IBM STOCK?
Foreign currency markets today are booming
despite the possibility of exchange controls. Ex­
change markets will continue to finance growing
trade in more closely integrated world markets.
Relaxation of capital controls facilitates the
movement of funds between countries. The cur­
rent international monetary arrangement with its
high degree of flexibility in rates presents in­
creased currency risks which must either be
covered by the hedger for a cost or accepted by
the speculator for an expected return. Multina­
tional corporations and large banks employ ex­
change markets to exploit these profit oppor­
tunities to the tune of millions of dollars.
Growth in trading volume has been sup­
plemented by the emergence of new methods of
trading, such as small-size contracts and a cur­
rency futures market. Both new exchanges, the
IMM and the ABT, expand the scope of services
available to the individual who wants to make
money on foreign currencies. Future competi­
tion between the exchanges and the welldeveloped bank market may have a favorable
impact on efficien cy and pricing in the
exchange-trading business. Indeed, a world
where Mr. Average Investor makes a trip to the
local foreign exchange market to buy some
German marks for his investment portfolio
along with his IBM stock may not be far in the
future.
5

FUTURE PROSPECTS: MORE OF THE SAME?
Since the trade flows between countries are
likely to multiply, the opportunities for growth in
foreign exchange are numerous. Whether the
newcomers—the IMM and the ABT—thrive de­
pends upon their ability to attract a faithful clien­
tele and to provide services presently unavail­
able or too costly in the bank market. Bank trad­
ers will undoubtedly continue to service most of
the growing currency market while at the same
time engaging in exchange transactions for their
own account.
Realization of these growth prospects depends
upon several factors. Foremost among them is
the type of international monetary system that
evolves. Recently, an agreement on monetary
reform was postponed almost indefinitely, re­
flecting the difficulties created by the oil situa­
tion as well as the opinion that the ad hoc system
of “ managed" floating rates probably averted a
world-wide monetary crisis. H. Johannes Witteveen, Managing Director of the International
Monetary Fund, concluded that “ in the present
situation a large measure of floating is unavoid­
able and indeed desirable." The energy crisis did
provide a severe test of the floating system and
convinced many that floating rates are working
better than expected. It is unlikely that many
countries will return to the old “ stable but ad­




22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Atlanta May 74 p 58
Delegation of authority April 4, 1974—
FR Bull May 74 p 358
Bank structure— multibank holding
com panies expand with New M exico's
economic growth—
Dallas June 74 p 6

The Fed in Print

BANK HOLDING COMPANY ACT 1956
An analysis of the public benefits test of the
Bank Holding Company Act—
NY June 74 p 151

Business Review Topics,
Second Quarter 7974,
Selected by Doris Zimmermann

BANK LOANS
Changes in bank lending practices, 1973—
FR Bull April 74 p 263

Articles appearing in the Federal Reserve Bul­
letin and in the monthly reviews of the Federal
Reserve banks during the second quarter of 1974
are included in this compilation. A cumulation
of these entries covering the years 1970 to date is
available upon request. If you wish to be put on
the mailing list for the cumulation, write to the
Publications Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia.
To receive copies of the Federal Reserve Bulle­
tin, mail two dollars for each to the Federal Re­
serve Board at the Washington address on page
27. You may send for monthly reviews of the
Federal Reserve banks free of charge, by writing
directly to the issuing banks whose addresses
also appear on page 27.

BANK LOANS— CONSUMER
Consumer credit at banks; mobile home
loans—
Chic April 74 p 13
BANK LOANS— REAL ESTATE
Real estate lending active—
Atlanta April 74 p 52
BANK SUPERVISION
Experimental project in Indiana—
FR Bull May 74 p 405
BANK TAX
The taxman rebuffed: Income taxes at
commercial banks—
Phila May 74 p 11

BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Recent developments in the U. S. balance of
payments—
FR Bull April 74 p 235

BANKERS ACCEPTANCES
Rules April 1, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 321

BANK EARNINGS
Member bank operating ratios—
Chic April 74 p 15
1973: A good profit year—
Atlanta May 74 p 68
Member bank income in 1973—
FR Bull June 74 p 422

BANKING STRUCTURE
Important issues for bankers and the central
bank (Hayes)—
NY June 74 p 135
BON DS— CORPORATE
The yield spread between newly issued and
seasoned corporate bonds—
Kansas City June 74 p 3

BANK HOLDING COMPANIES
Leasing permitted April 17, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 284
Bank acquisitions and future competition—




BRIMMER, ANDREW F.
23

BUSINESS REVIEW

SEPTEMBER 1974

Resigns August 31, 1974—
FR Bull June 74 p 469

Phila May 74 p 7
DEMAND DEPOSITS
Faster turnover indicates increased efficiency
of money—
Dallas April 74 p 7

BURNS, ARTHUR F.
Statement to Congress, April 4, 1974 (foreign
exchange)—
FR Bull April 74 p 268

DISCOUNT OPERATIONS
The seasonal borrowing privilege—
Kansas City June 74 p 10

BUSINESS FORECASTS & REVIEWS
The economy, the Midwest, and Chicago—
Chic April 74 p 3
Our turbulent economy (Mayo)—
Chic May 74 p 3
Financial-developments in the first quarter

DISCOUNT RATES
Change to 8% April 25, 1974—
FR Bull May 74 p 404

of 1974—

EDUCATION— FINANCE
Philadelphia's budget: Past, present, future—
Phila April 74 p 3

FR Bull May 74 p 325
Minnesota's economic environment: 1985—
Minn May 74 p 12
Economic slowdown: Demand or supply
induced?—
St Louis May 74 p 8

FARM CREDIT
Concern for growing farm debt—
Chic June 74 p 8

CAPACITY
Capacity utilization for major materials:
Revised measures—
FR Bull April 74 p 235

FARM EXPORTS
Farm trade—farmers on threshold of new
opportunity—
Dallas May 74 p 1

CAPITAL EXPENDITURES
Investment ratios and economic-growth
rates—
San Fran Spr 74 p 9

FARM REAL ESTATE
District farmland values soar—
Chic April 74 p 8

CERTIFICATES OF DEPOSIT
CD maturities fall to record low—
Atlanta June 74 p 88

FEDERAL FINANCING BANK
The new Federal Financing Bank—
Chic May 74 p 9

CITIES
Growth of southern cities in the Sixties—
Atlanta April 74 p 42
Small cities of the Tenth District: Population
and employment changes, 1960-70—
Kansas City May 74 p 16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS— DIRECTORS
Changes—
FR Bull May 74 p 404
FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD
Rules of organization November 7, 1973
(managing directors)—
FR Bull May 74 p. 362
ANNUAL REPORT available—
FR Bull June p 471

CONSTRUCTION
Home building cycles in Dallas differ from the
Nation—
Dallas June 74 p 1

FEDERAL RESERVE— CREDIT CONTROL
The short-term commercial bank adjustment
process and Federal Reserve regulation—

CONSUMER EXPENDITURES
The unhappy, important consumer—




24

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

NY April 74 p 83
Inflation and public policy (Balles)—
San Fran Spr 74 p 3

Bost May 74 p 14
Looking into the Fed's crystal ball (Eastburn)—
Phila May 74 p 3
FEDERAL RESERVE— FOREIGN EXCHANGE
Treasury and Federal Reserve foreign
exchange operations—
FR Bull June 74 p 429
Treasury and Federal Reserve foreign
exchange operations interim report—
NY June 74 p 149

INTEREST RATES— PRIME
Bank loan charges—
Chic June 74 p 14

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM— MEMBERSHIP
Falling Fed membership and eroding
monetary control: What can be done?—
Phila June 74 p 3

METROPOLITAN AREAS
Changing SMSA's—
Atlanta April 74 p 48

BHC's permitted—
FR Bull April 74 p 286

MONETARY POLICY
Letter on monetary policy, March 20, 1974
(Friedman)—
Rich May 74 p 20
A monetary prescription for an ailing
economy (Francis)—
St Louis June 74 p 2

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM— PUBLICATIONS
INDEX to Federal Reserve bank reviews
1950-1972 available—
Phila May 74 p 6
FISCAL POLICY
How and why fiscal actions matter to a
monetarist (Francis)—
St Louis May 74 p 2

MONEY SUPPLY
Numerical specifications of financial vari­
ables and their role in monetary policy—
FR Bull May 74 p 333
Short-run variations in the money stock—
seasonal or cyclical?—
FR Bull June 74 p 420
Revisions in money stock—
FR Bull June 74 p 470

FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES
The two-tier exchange rate system—
Bost March 74 p 13
FOREIGN TRADE
Recent and prospective developments in
international trade and finance—
St Louis May 74 p 15

MONOPOLIES
Economic concentration in agriculture—
trends and developments—
Kansas City April 74 p 21

FUEL
Global interdependence and energy—
Chic June 74 p 3

MORTGAGES
Construction, real estate and mortgage
markets—
FR Bull June 74 p 407

GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
National income accounting and economic
welfare: The concepts of GNP and
MEW—
St Louis April 74 p 18
GNP and economic welfare—
Atlanta June 74 p 74

NEW JERSEY—TAXES
Sales levy crucial to New Jersey's tax
revenues—
Phila April 74 p 20

INFLATION
Inflation and the economic outlook (Debs)—




OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS
25

SEPTEMBER 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

Record of policy actions, January 21-22,
1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 275
Purchase of bankers acceptances and bills
of exchange—
FR Bull April 74 p 284
The Federal Open Market Committee in
1973—
St Louis April 74 p 2
Open market operations in 1973—
FR Bull May 74 p 338
Record of policy actions, February 20,1974—
FR Bull May 74 p 351
Record of policy actions, March 18-19,
1974—
FR Bull June 74 p 431

REGULATION L
Amendment June
FR Bull June
Amendment June
FR Bull June

20, 1974—
74 p 445
20, 1974—
74 p 470

REGULATION M
Amendment May 24, 1974—
FR Bull June 74 p 445
REGULATION T
Amendment postponed until January 2,
1975—
FR Bull June 74 p 470
REGULATION Y
Amendment April 17, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 284
Amendment June 20, 1974—
FR Bull June 74 p 446
Amendment June 20, 1974—
FR Bull June 74 p 470

POVERTY
Fighting poverty with jobs: Public and private
payroll weapons—
Phila April 74 p 22
QUANTITY THEORY OF MONEY
Its historical evolution and role in policy
debates—
Rich May 74 p 2

RESERVE REQUIREMENTS
Part I: Comparative reserve requirements at
member and nonmember banks—
Kansas City April 74 p 3
Part II: An analysis of the case for uniform
reserve requirements—
Kansas City May 74 p 3
The case against uniform reserves: A loss of
perspective—
Phila June 74 p 16

REGULATION B
Revoked April 1, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 284
REGULATION C
Revoked April 1, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 284

NOW AVAILABLE:
INDEX TO FEDERAL RESERVE BANK REVIEWS
Articles which have appeared in the reviews of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks have been
indexed by subject by Doris F. Zimmermann, Librarian of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadel­
phia. The index covers the years 1950 through 1972 and is available upon request from the
Department of Public Services, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
19105.




26

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

TIME DEPOSITS
Changes in time and savings deposits at
commercial banks—
FR Bull April 74 p 252

RICE
Rice: Suddenly glamorous food crop of the
world—
Atlanta June 74 p 80
SECURITIES
Modern investment theory: Its implications
for competition among financial institu­
tions—
Bost May 74 p 3

TRUST DEPARTMENT BANK
A suggested approach for determining
functional profitability—
Dallas April 74 p 1
Trust revenue of commercial banks: The in­
fluence of bank holding companies—
St Louis June 74 p 8

SOCIAL SECURITY
Payroll tax relief—
Bost March 74 p 3

VIRGINIA
PROFILE available—
Rich May 74 p 22

SWAP ARRANGEMENTS
Increase March 26, 1974—
FR Bull April 74 p 322

FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS AND BOARD OF GOVERNORS
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Federal Reserve Station
Kansas City, Missouri 64198

Publications Services
Division of Administrative Services
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System
Washington, D.C. 20551

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Federal Reserve Station
Atlanta, Georgia 30303

Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Federal Reserve P.O. Station
New York, New York 10045

Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
30 Pearl Street
Boston, Massachusetts 02106

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
925 Chestnut Street
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19105

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
P.O. Box 27622
Richmond, Virginia 23261

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, Ohio 44101

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
P.O. Box 442
St. Louis, Missouri 63166

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Station K
Dallas, Texas 75222




Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
San Francisco, California 94120
27

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA 19105

business review
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PA. 19105