View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October

Inflation Insurance:
An "Escalator Clause" for Securities?
Vietnam Vets and the Job Scene
Regional Growth:
The Whys and Wherefores

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA

business rerieu*




Inflation Insurance:
An "Escalator Clause" for Securities?
. . . Securities tied to changes in the cost of
living would offset some of the redistributive
effects of inflation and may even improve
policymaking, but introducing the proposal
into the marketplace may require Uncle
Sam's help.
Vietnam Vets and the Job Scene
. . . Most Vietnam veterans have returned
to the job market or to school, yet many re­
main unemployed or have dropped out of
the labor force, not taking advantage of new
job-training and education programs.
Regional Growth: The Whys and Wherefores
. . . Interest in encouraging local economic
growth abounds, but the methods that local
leaders employ to achieve prosperity can
often be inadequate.

On our cover: The Birkenhead Mills are part of the original Du Pont powder mills at the Hagley Museum,
Greenville, W ilmington, Delaware. From the early 1800s various types of mills— flour, paper, textile,
iron— flourished along the Brandywine River. It was there that E. I. Du Pont in 1802 began building his
black powder works. The Birkenhead Mills, built in 1822-24, are typical of the more than 20 stone build­
ings that appear much as they did when the powder yard was in operation. (Photo courtesy of the
Hagley Museum)

BUSINESS REVIEW jS prod uced in the Department of Research. Ronald B. Williams is Art Director and Manager,
Graphic Services. The authors will be glad to receive comments on their articles.
Requests for additional copies should be addressed to Public: Information, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19101.



Inflation Insurance:
An "Escalator Clause"
For Securities?
By Donald J. Mullineaux

Sagacious Professor Newthought delights
in demolishing maxims and substituting new
ones— often his own. Recently he claimed
"you can have your cake and eat it too"—
by simply lending it out at interest.
A student sharply dissented, holding that
in modern economies where people lend
dollars in lieu of cakes or other "real" goods,
lenders sometimes receive crumbs in value
rather than their cake and a muffin for in­
terest. If prices are increasing rapidly, he
noted, borrowers pay off lenders with dol­
lars that command fewer goods than during
the period when the loan was contracted.
Quite right, answered Professor Newthought, inflation can "eat" away the pur­
chasing power of loan repayments and in­
terest. But lenders will protect themselves
from this "wealth erosion" by demanding
"inflation premiums"— that is, more interest
to cover any expected price increases. So, to
have their cake and eat it too, he added,
lenders must anticipate the course of infla­




tion and adjust their lending terms accord­
ingly. If they get only "crumbs" in return,
they've either erred badly in their inflation
forecasts or failed to cover themselves
adequately.
When the classroom debate had ended,
neither pedant nor pupil had considered a
larger question: Is there a better way of cop­
ing with the wealth-eroding effects of infla­
tion? For example, can't we lessen the impact
of human error on society by including
"wealth-protection insurance" in financial
contracts? Many wage contracts already in­
clude "escalator clauses" which "link" pay­
ments to changes in some cost-of-living index.
Actually, "index-linked" securities offer
potential advantages and disadvantages and
thus from time to time have surfaced as a
politically sensitive issue. Both public and
private debate, however, require a better
understanding of the way financial markets
presently cope with inflationary expectations.
3

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

willing to pay him the "extra" $25 a year,
however, since the firm also expects a similar
rise and will, therefore, be paying off the
principal (and interest over the intervening
years) in "cheaper" dollars.
In the absence of expected inflation, then,
Neversink bonds would yield 4 percent.
Since bond purchasers and Neversink agree
that prices are likely to rise at an annual rate
of 2 V 2 percent over the next 20 years, an
"inflation premium" of about this amount is
tacked on to the 4 percent. The yield in the
absence of inflationary expectations is re­
ferred to as "the real rate of interest," while
the sum of the real interest rate and the
inflation premium is called the "money rate"
or "nominal rate of interest." Obviously, if
prices are expected to decline, then the
nominal rate of interest is less than the real
rate. The "inflation premium" becomes a
"deflation discount." This relation between
the expected rate of price change and the
level of interest rates is called "Fisher's Equa­
tion" after its originator, Irving Fisher of Yale
University.2

THE "REAL" VS. THE "MONEY"
RATE OF INTEREST
In this credit-card age when consumers
as diverse as teachers, technicians, and tele­
phone operators, use charge-a-plates, few of
us escape interest rates. Whether applicable
to a savings account, a corporate or govern­
ment bond, or an installment loan from a
bank or department store, an interest pay­
ment typically represents a reward to lenders
for parting with some of their accumulated
purchasing power. In this sense, then, an
interest rate is a price of credit, and as credit
arrangements come in numerous shapes and
sizes, so do interest rates.
A typical credit contract promises to repay
the amount borrowed (principal) after an
agreed upon time period and to make peri­
odic payments (interest) in the interim for
the right to use the principal. For instance,
a Mr. Appleby lends $1000 to the Neversink
Screendoor and Submarine Company by
buying a debenture1 promising to pay him
$65 annually until 1992 and then return the
$1000. In other words, Appleby has "in­
vested" $1000 in corporate bonds at a yield
of 6V 2 percent.
When entering into the contract, Appleby
realizes that a thousand dollars 20 years from
now will most likely not buy the same sack
of groceries it does today. Because inflation
seems the "normal course of affairs," the
principal (and interest over the intervening
years) will buy fewer goods; in other words,
the greater the price rise, the lighter the gro­
cery sack. To protect himself from this ero­
sion of purchasing power, Appleby has de­
manded more in interest payments than he
would have had he expected prices to re­
main constant between now and 1992. In
fact, Appleby would have settled for $40 a
year as reward for parting with his funds in
the absence of inflation. Neversink is quite

FISHER'S EQUATION
*Money Rate =
Real Rate + Inflation Premium
*Fisher's equation for the money
rate also includes a term reflecting
the interest earned on the infla­
tion premium, but it is typically so
small that it can be ignored.
If, for some reason, borrowers or lenders
expect the rate of inflation to accelerate, this
should be reflected in increased inflation
premiums and higher interest rates. Like­
wise, if market participants expect a decline
2Professor Fisher is often considered the foremost
American monetary economist of the early twentieth
century. Perhaps his most famous work is The Theory
of Interest (New York: Macmillan, 1930). Fisher had
emphasized the relation between price expectations
and interest rates as early as 1896, however, in
Appreciation and Interest (New York: Macmillan).

’ A debenture is a bond backed only by the general
creditworthiness of a corporation.




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

INDEX-LINKED SECURITIES
Since we do not know the price expecta­
tions of those who buy and sell financial
securities, "your guess is as good as mine"
concerning the size of the inflation premium
in current financial markets. This would not
be the case, however, if the amount of inter­
est and principal in a credit contract were
linked to changes in some general index of
prices. For example, if the interest on 4 per­
cent Neversink bonds were linked to the con­
sumer price index, then a 2-percent annual
increase in consumer prices over the life of
the contract would push the yield on these
securities to 6 percent. Likewise, reductions
in prices or in the rate of price increases
would be translated into yield reductions on
Neversink securities. With protection against
loss in the real value of their savings, lenders
would be content with a lower rate of in­
terest than if such "insurance" were not
offered in the credit contract. In fact, the
difference between the interest rates on
index-linked and nonindexed securities of
the same maturity could be taken as the "mar­
ket" measure of price expectations. How­
ever, a 5-percent yield on 10-year nonindexed
bonds and a 3-percent yield on indexed
bonds does not mean that all investors ex-

in the inflation rate, interest rates should
eventually fall (see Appendix). While few
economists question the existence of these
"Fisher effects," most of them disagree over
the time required for changes in price expec­
tations to be reflected in interest rate changes.
In fact, many economists believe that Fisher's
equation is valid only in the "long run"—
that is, during very long periods in which
markets could adequately adjust to changes
in expectations. Some have suggested that
this may require 30 to 50 years or more, but
no one knows for sure.
Thus, under the current scheme of things
in financial markets, net lenders will suffer
when inflation accelerates more rapidly than
anticipated. They will fail to demand an
adequate inflation premium. Net borrowers,
however, will be hurt when prices rise more
slowly than expected, having agreed to pay
an excessive premium. Some evidence sug­
gests that in recent years market participants
have underestimated the rate of inflation (see
Table 1) so that net borrowers probably have
increased their real wealth at the expense of
net lenders. Some of this redistribution
could have been avoided had loan contract
terms been tied to, say, the consumer-price
index.

TABLE 1
ACTUAL INFLATION HAS OUTPACED
EXPECTATIONS IN RECENT YEARS
Expected Change in
Consumer-Price Index
(Percent)
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971

.............................................
.............................................
.............................................
.............................................
.............................................

Actual Change in
Consumer-Price Index
(Percent)

3.12
3.29
3.33
3.39
2.89

2.88
4.02
5.37
5.92
4.30

Sources: University of Michigan, Survey Research Center, Survey of Consumer Finances, U.S. Depart­
ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.




5

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

pect inflation of 2-percent per annum over
the next decade. Rather, the market mea­
sures the price expectations of only those
investors who are indifferent about indexed
and nonindexed securities.3 If these market
participants expected more (less) inflation,
pressures on interest rates would result.
Such pressures would increase (decrease) the
yield spread of nonindexed over indexed
securities (see Box).

rates of inflation outweighs all the proposed
benefits for society.4
*
SOME POTENTIAL ADVANTAGES
FROM UNKING
Less Reshuffling of Wealth. Supporters of
index-linked securities often note that imple­
mentation of their proposal would alter
some of the wealth distribution effects of
inflation. When prices rise faster than ex­

MEASURING THE INFLATION PREMIUM IN A WORLD
OF INDEX-LINKED SECURITIES
An arithmetic example can convince us why a 6-percent rate on 10-year bonds
with no price-level insurance and a 4-percent rate on indexed securities of like
maturity must mean that 2-percent inflation is expected by market participants
who will hold either type of security. Suppose in this situation that all borrowers
and lenders revise their inflation expectations upward by one percentage point,
but that interest rates are unchanged. Lenders who were previously satisfied with
either indexed or nonindexed securities will now prefer indexed loans since they
now expect these securities to yield 7 percent (vs. 6 on nonindexed loans). Previ­
ously indifferent borrowers will demand only nonindexed loans which now have
an expected lower cost. Revised expectations will thus increase both the demand
for indexed securities and the supply of nonindexed securities. But this will serve
to increase the rate on nonindexed securities relative to indexed securities. In
fact, the yield spread will expand until it once again reflects the price expectations
of participants who are indifferent to either type of security. Only when the
spread satisfies this condition will pressures making for further rate changes be
absent. In our example, this would call for a yield spread of approximately
3 percentage points.
Index-linked securities obviously reduce
risk by insuring against capital loss. Propo­
nents of indexing also suggest that the sale
of these securities may yield still other bene­
fits such as a more equitable distribution of
wealth and improved economic policymak­
ing. Despite these advantages, however,
some economists oppose indexing on the
grounds that the harm resulting from higher

pected or when families have difficulty ad­
justing to expected inflation, those who owe
more in money terms than they have owed
to them will increase their wealth relative to
other families. Since these net monetary
debtors repay their liabilities in "cheaper"
dollars (in terms of real purchasing power),
inflation transfers real wealth from net cred­
itors to debtors. Likewise, net creditors gain
relative to debtors when inflation is overesti­
mated.

3 In economists' jargon, the yield spread between
indexed and nonindexed securities must reflect price
expectations "at the margin," that is, of the marginal
investor and borrower in each type of security.

4For a discussion of the gains and losses associated
with inflation, see W. Lee Hoskins, "Inflation: Gainers
and Losers," Business Review of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, February 1970, pp. 23-30.




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

investors a "hedge” against inflation by
appreciating in price require large amounts
of capital. Then "small" investors incur the
additional cost of pooling their funds in
order to acquire enough capital for purchas­
ing the asset. This assertion may be valid for
assets such as real estate, paintings, diamonds,
and the like. However, for other potential
hedges such as mutual-fund shares and for­
eign currencies which are available in small
denominations, the argument is less convinc­
ing. Accordingly, the notion that lowerincome families find it more difficult to ad­
just to inflation is likely to remain unsettled

Since several factors account for the
wealth redistribution effects of inflation, it is
difficult to assess which income classes bear
the major burden. Some limited evidence
suggests that middle-income families may
suffer most from that part of the redistribu­
tion stemming from underanticipation of
actual inflation, while low-income families
may be gainers.5 At the same time, it is often
argued that low-income families find it more
costly to adjust and avoid the wealth-rob­
bing effects of an inflation they see coming.
This may be true if assets which provide

TABLE 2
THE POOR HOLD SMALLEST PROPORTION OF WEALTH IN
MONETARY ASSETS AND THUS MAY BE GAINERS
DURING UNANTICIPATED INFLATION
1958 Family Income
(dollars)

Net Monetary Assets as
a Percentage of Wealth

$0-999 ........................................................................
$1,000-2,999 ...........................................................................
$3,000-4,999 ...........................................................................
$5,000-7,499 ...........................................................................
$7,500 or m o re ......................................................................

8%
15%
13%
15%
15%

Source: A. Ando and G. Bach, "The Redistributional Effects of Inflation," Review of Economics and
Statistics, 49 (February 1967).

until the statistical evidence is more fully
investigated.6

5Available data show that middle-income classes hold
about the same percentage of their wealth in assets
promising a fixed money return (monetary assets) as
high-income classes (see Table 2). However, these
figures are generally overstated, especially for wealthy
families. In calculating a family's net position in
monetary assets, these figures fail to consider all
monetary liabilities. In particular, indirect indebtedness
in the form of a pro rata share of the net corporate debt
of the companies whose stock shares a family owns
should be subtracted from the stated monetary asset
positions. Since wealthier families hold proportionately
more common stock, their net position in monetary
assets is most overstated. Even after such a correction,
however, it seems likely that the poor would continue
to have the smallest portion of their wealth in monetary
assets and would therefore be relative gainers in wealth
during periods of unexpected inflation.




6It is tempting to argue that because "small" savers
didn't adjust during particular inflationary periods it
must have been more costly for them. For example,
families continued to hold millions of dollars in savings
accounts at financial institutions which paid negative
real rates of return during the period 1967-69 (see Chart).
It should be recalled, however, that the purchase of a
security depends on the expected real rate of return.
Families may not only have continually underestimated
inflation, but they may have expected the monetary
authorities to relax the ceilings on interest rates which
were holding money rates down. These maximum rates
were maintained unchanged throughout this period,
however.
7

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

society. Expectations of future prices are in­
puts into individuals' decisions about current
and future consumption, investment, and
their willingness to supply labor services.
If consensus inflation forecasts can be sup­
plied at low costs, then some resources are
freed to augment the output of goods and
services. And, society will be that much
better off.

The lack of "hard evidence" on who gains
or loses from inflation means that we cannot
assert that the sale of index-linked securities
will result in a more equitable distribution of
wealth. Indexing would, however, cushion
much of the unintended wealth redistribu­
tion effects of inflation (making it easier for
planned redistribution policies such as pro­
gressive taxation to work).
Improved Policymaking. In addition to
eliminating some of the redistributive effects
of inflation, index-linked securities might
facilitate the administration of national eco­
nomic policy. The yield could serve as an
"indicator" by both policymakers and policywatchers for "gauging" the current status of
monetary policy relative to previous periods.
Market rates of interest are often used to
measure the thrust of monetary policy at
present. Rising interest rates supposedly in­
dicate "tight money" as the Federal Reserve
attempts to restrain the growth of economic
activity by slowing the growth of bank re­
serves. Declining rates mean "easy money"
—the central bank is trying to provide ex­
pansionary impetus to the economy.
Using market rates to "read" the stance of
monetary policy can produce conflicting sig­
nals, however. An increase in rates may
reflect a larger inflation premium rather than
the onslaught of a "tight money" policy.
Likewise, rate reductions can simply mean
that market participants expect less inflation.
The rate on indexed securities, however, is
a measure of the real rate of interest and is
unaffected by changes in price expectations.
It should, therefore, prove a less ambiguous
indicator of the stance of monetary policy.7
Finally, market forecasts of inflation, a
by-product of index linking, are valuable for

A POTENTIAL DISADVANTAGE:
STILL MORE INFLATION?
Some opponents of index-linked securities
claim that indexing creates new inflationary
pressures. One view is that since indexlinked securities offer protection against in­
flationary "pains," public pressure for re­
sponsible fiscal and monetary policies will
be lessened. But this argument ignores the
fact that indexing does not alleviate all the
ills of inflation. For example, in a world
of fixed international exchange rates rapid
price increases mean that domestic goods
cost more to foreigners (unless, of course,
foreign prices rise in like fashion). Exports
will, consequently, decline and balance of
payments problems will become worse.
Under such conditions, policymakers are
hardly likely to let the inflation chips fall
where they may in a helter-skelter pursuit of
other goals.
Another view of some economists is that
indexing causes inflation by generating a
cost-push spiral which continuously forces
up prices. Unexpected price rises increase
interest payments which, in turn, raise the
cost of producing additional output. As a
result, producers either bring fewer goods to
the market or increase their asking prices for
goods in current production. This notion,
however, considers only what happens on

7Some caution would still be required, however.
Although an expansionary policy will initially reduce
the real interest rate, income will eventually rise and
with it the demand for credit. The real rate will there­
upon begin to rise. In order to interpret observed
changes in the index-linked rate as a reflection of a

policy shift, some additional evidence is required to
insure that the change in rates was primarily a policyinduced supply phenomenon. Examining the rate of
change in the money stock or bank reserves should
supply some confirming evidence.




8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

the supply side of the market. Increased
costs of borrowed funds will also squeeze
cash flow. Firms may attempt to restore
liquidity by postponing or cancelling invest­
ment expenditures on plants and equipment.
The resulting decline in investment would
reduce aggregate demand and thus moderate
pressures on the price level. This may very
well mean that indexing would affect relative
prices instead of the absolute price level.
This scenario suggests that in a world of
indexed-linked securities the prices of capital
goods will decline relative to other goods
during periods of inflation.




Without a better understanding of how
the inflation process works, it is difficult to
say whether loan indexing would have an
abetting or offsetting effect on the inflation
cycle. Certainly, the case has yet to be made
that indexing would have a strong effect in
either direction.
BREAKING THE I C E LINKED SAVINGS BONDS?
Presently, no private corporations issue
index-linked securities in the United States.
Their absence from our relatively sophisti-

9

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

deposits placed with financial institutions
(see Chart). The Federal government, how­
ever, has "gained" more from inflation than
any other economic unit because it is the
largest net debtor in the economy.
Favorable experience with "tied" savings
bonds might encourage the Treasury to link
a number of marketable issues to price-level
changes. Should these be well received,
competition for funds would probably spur
private corporations and financial institutions
to issue their own indexed securities. These
explicit inflation premiums should alleviate
some of the ill effects of inflation and would
keep unexpected inflation from redistribut­
ing wealth in a manner inconsistent with
expressed social goals. Moreover, the risk
that indexed-securities would create new in­
flationary pressures is probably small enough
to assure that society would be a net bene­
ficiary of index-linked securities.
■

cated financial scene is difficult to explain,
especially given the rapid increase of costof-living escalator clauses in labor and pen­
sion contracts in recent years.
Proponents of indexed securities have
suggested that the United States Treasury
should "break the ice" and that a favorable
reception would insure the spread of index­
linking to the private sector.8 On equity
grounds, savings bonds are an ideal candi­
date for linking, for they are bought mostly
by low- and middle-income families. Small
savers have not only been hurt by recent
increases in the rate of inflation, but by legal
ceilings on the rates they could receive on

8See Edward Kane, "Short-Changing the Small Saver:
Federal Government Discrimination Against Small
Savers During the Vietnam War," Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 2 (November 1970): 513-522.




10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Appendix: A Graphical Analysis
of Inflation Premiums

BOX A

Inflation
Premium

This appendix demonstrates graphically
how the "inflation premium" is "built into"
the market rate of interest. Box A demon­
strates how the "real" rate of interest is de­
termined. The vertical axis measures the
rate of interest (r) and the horizontal axis
the quantity of loanable funds (Q). Curve L
represents the amount of funds savers wish
to lend at each rate of interest. As the rate
rises, savers will supply more loanable funds.
Curve B shows the amount of funds bor­
rowers would like to absorb at each interest
rate. Obviously, as the rate rises, borrowers
will demand fewer loanable funds. Both of
these schedules represent the desires of bor­
rowers and lenders under the assumption
that prices will be constant over the life
of the loan contract. The real rate of interest
is 4 percent and $100 million is the amount
borrowed.
Box B shows the effect of inflationary
expectations on the level of interest rates.
If lenders expect prices to increase at a 3
percent annual rate over the life of the loan
contract, they will raise (shift leftward) their
loan supply schedule by this amount on the
vertical scale. That is, where they formerly
were willing to lend $60 million at 3 percent,
they now offer the same amount for 6 per­
cent; likewise, they now demand 7 percent
to induce an offer of $100 million. The new
supply schedule is indicated by curve L'.
If borrowers expect a similar amount of in­
flation, they likewise raise (shift rightward)
their loan demand schedule by 3 percentage
points for each quantity of loans— indicated
by schedule B'. Borrowers and lenders will
now be satisfied only with a market rate of
7 percent which includes an "inflation pre­
mium" of 3 percent.




11

BUSINESS REVIEW

OCTOBER 1972

In the preceding case, the existence of
inflation premiums had no effect on the
volume of finance ($100 million in both
cases). However, if borrowers and lenders
disagree about the prospects for inflation,
the amount of funds transferred from bor­
rowers to lenders will be affected. If lenders
expect more inflation than borrowers (Box
C), lending will be less than the volume that
would be forthcoming in the absence of ex­
pected inflation. If borrowers expect a larger
price rise than lenders (Box D), the amount
lent will exceed the volume of lending in the
economy with constant prices.
The notion that borrowers systematically
expect more inflation than lenders is some­
times advanced as the reason borrowers
have not offered securities with interest pay­
ments linked to some index of price level
changes. In the graphical example, indexlinked securities would be sold with a con­
tract yield of 4 percent (the "real" rate) in
an amount of $100 million. If borrowers'
anticipations of 3 percent annual inflation
are realized, they will pay 7 percent over the
life of the loan on an indexed security. If
borrowers issue nonindexed securities, how­
ever, they can obtain $120 million in finance
at 5V 2 percent (see Box D). Lenders are w ill­
ing to offer this amount at 5 V2 because they
expect no inflation. In fact, anytime bor­
rowers expect more inflation than lenders
they can obtain a larger volume of financing
at lower expected cost with nonindexed se­
curities than with index-linked loans.
Although this analysis is accurate, it fails
to offer a firm rationale for the notion that
borrowers will always expect more inflation
than lenders. Economists know very little
about how decision-makers form expecta­
tions, so the case can hardly be made on
theoretical grounds. Empirical evidence on
expectations formation is likewise extremely
sparse. Until this missing link in the argu­
ment is substantiated, economists must look
elsewhere for an explanation of the absence
of index-linked securities.



BOX C*

Percent

BOX D*

Percent

* Lenders expect no inflation.

12

Vietnam Vets and
tfie Job Scene




by Curtis R. Smith

13

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

CHART 1
OVER 8 MILLION AMERICANS HAVE BEEN
UNDER ARMS DURING THE VIETNAM WAR
AND, OF THESE, 6 MILLION HAVE NOW RE­
TURNED TO THE JOB MARKET

if; : j ' S li tW
SS
••i.2 \

.. ...

■
V

(Millions of men)
18

-

;
' /.

ssiitl m
:

PARTICIPANTS IN U. S. WARS

16

CHART 2
MOST VETERANS ARE EMPLOYED AND
MANY ARE IN SCHOOL; HOWEVER, AL­
MOST 9 PERCENT REMAIN UNEM­
PLOYED OR HAVE DROPPED OUT OF
THE LABOR FORCE.

14

12

Percent
10

100 ----\ \ \ W

\ \ \ W

\ \ \

Not in the Labor Force
Unemployed
In School

80

Employed
60

40

20

World Vietnam Korean
War II
War
War

World
War I

Civil War
(Union)
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics

Source: Veterans Administration, Office of
Controller




14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

ALTHOUGH VETERANS SUFFERED DISPROPORTIONATELY DURING THE LAST RE­
CESSION, THEY MADE SUBSTANTIAL GAINS AS AN EXPANDING ECONOMY BROUGHT
THEIR UNEMPLOYMENT RATE DOWN FASTER THAN FOR ALL WORKERS
10 UNEMPLOYMENT RATES: 20 TO 29-YEAR-OLD VETERANS AND ALL CIVILIAN WORKERS
SEASONALLY ADJUSTED

2 I--------1------ 1------ 1------ 1------ 1------1------ 1------1-------1 ___ I_____I
- - _
1969

1970

I

1971

*

i
1972

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics




"

15

•

■

■ 1

~ ................

i

BUSINESS REVIEW




OCTOBER 1972

16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

BUT THEIR STATUS AS VETERANS PROVIDES
UNIQUE OPPORTUNITIES TO HELP
One of every five Vietnam-era veterans has less than a high school education. Ten
percent are black or members of other minority groups. These are the men most likely
to have difficulty in the civilian job market. They represent a microcosm of America's
disadvantaged— poor, uneducated, and unemployed. But, because they are veterans,
these men are particularly reachable. Society, through education and training, is making
special efforts to raise the socioeconomic level of disadvantaged veterans. Public opinion
supports the vet, an administrative framework exists, and many programs have already
been started. A principal task remaining is to make the veteran aware of ongoing
efforts.

Reemployment Rights. A veteran who left a
full-time job is entitled to a position comparable
to one he would have held had he not served.
About 50 percent of the returnees have a legal
right to their old job, but only 30 to 40 percent
exercise it.
Civil Service Preference. Veterans automat­
ically receive a 5-point preference on Civil Ser­
vice exams. Disabled servicemen and Purple
Heart winners can claim a 10-point advantage.
Emergency Employment Act. A major aim of
this program is to fill 30 to 40 percent of its
temporary jobs with veterans. During its first
year, 67,000 Vietnam veterans, 27 percent of the
participants, held EEA jobs. More than 90 per­
cent were unemployed before starting the
program.
jobs for Veterans. This national campaign em­
phasizes the marketable skills and assets of vet­
erans. It concentrates on increasing national
awareness through advertising, forming local ac­
tion groups, conducting Job Fairs, and publicizing
other programs for veterans.
Listing of Jobs. Since 1971, all employers
holding Federal contracts have been required to
list job openings with Federal and state em­
ployment offices, and to report the number
of jobs filled by veterans.
Project Transition. The Defense Department
provides predischarge job counseling and place­
ment assistance. It also cooperates with private
industry in on-the-job training prior to separation.
NAB-JOBS Program. The National Alliance of
Businessmen helps place veterans in private




industry. Over 130,000 were helped in fiscal
year 1972, with a 1973 goal of 150,000.
PREP. The Defense Department's Predischarge
Education Program offers high school completion
and secondary level remedial courses while still
in the service. However, only 7 percent of the
550.000 servicemen needing remedial help are
in the program.
G.l. Bill. Since the beginning of the current
G .l. Bill in 1966, 36 percent of all Vietnam-era
veterans have participated in training. Not all
veterans, however, have used the bill to the same
extent. Although 20 percent of all veterans are
educationally disadvantaged, they comprise only
7 percent of those receiving benefits. A negative
attitude and past academic failures help con­
tribute to low participation. Outreach efforts
sponsored by the Commonwealth of Pennsyl­
vania, the National League of Cities and U.S.
Conference of Mayors, and the National Council
of Churches try to contact new veterans per­
sonally and counsel them regarding further
education. The low level of benefits has also
hampered participation among lower-income
veterans; however, recent Congressional legisla­
tion has raised basic full-time benefits from $175
to $220 a month.
Remedial Programs. The Department of Health,
Education, and W elfare has recently announced
a $5.8 million grant to more than 50 colleges
and universities that are beginning remedial pro­
grams for veterans this fall. Some 10,000 to
12.000 young veterans lacking college-level skills
are expected to participate.
m
17

Regional Growth:
The Whys and
Wherefores
By lames L Freund

growth among regions are temporary
nomena.1
Both economists and policymakers
devote more attention to how regions
and function. For businessmen and
leaders, local economic conditions
never been a secondary consideration.

Differences in the fortunes of regions have
existed for generations. California rushed
ahead when gold was discovered while New
England whaling ports slowly withered. Ex­
panding railroads caused regions to boom
while areas around canals languished. De­
troit grew with the automobile; Appalachia
burned out with coal. Most recently, the
tide of economic growth has moved south­
ward and westward, leaving behind older,
more lethargic regions.
These regional disparities have received
relatively little attention. Rather, economists
have concentrated almost exclusively on
national problems— achieving full employ­
ment and economic growth without infla­
tion. This emphasis probably has followed
from the general belief that differences in



phe­
now
grow
civic
have
They

’ In a perfectly competitive world where regions sell
to one another and resources flow over distances with­
out cost, mobility of factors would equalize earned
incomes in all areas. Capital would flow to regions in
which profitability was highest. This flow would even­
tually equalize the rate of return among regions by
lowering it in the receiving regions and increasing it
in the vacated ones. Likewise, labor would move
geographically to where wages were the highest away
from low-wage areas. The result of mobility and trade
would be an optimal regional allocation of resources
that also provided for the largest possible national
output.
18

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

want to know why one area grows more rap­
idly than another and how to make their area
prosper. Persistent economic disparities also
have troubled economists. Finding that mo­
bility of people and investment funds have
failed to eliminate many of these differ­
ences, they have begun to reexamine the
causes of differential local growth.

other sections of the country.2 These indus­
tries not only create jobs, but, as a bonus, they
attract other firms. For example, a new
automobile plant will attract painters, tire
suppliers, glass companies, and manufac­
turers of accessories. This growth will gen­
erate income for spending on local trade
and services that, in turn, will create more
jobs.
Others argue that such efforts are mis­
guided. Instead of attracting industry and
assuming that workers will follow, local pol­
icymakers are urged to concern themselves
with people. Over the long haul, firms may

REGIONAL GROWTH: PLANTS OR PEOPLE?
While interest in encouraging local eco­
nomic growth abounds, there is consider­
able disagreement over how to accomplish
it. Attracting new industries into their re­
gions is the number one concern of most
local leaders. In national publications and
on signs along almost any highway, com­
munities welcome new industries, extol the
local business atmosphere, tell businessmen
of a particular town's tax advantages, and
brag about the pleasantness of an area's
climate.
These efforts are expressions of the view
that an area's economic health primarily
depends on its "export base." That is, the
key to raising incomes and expanding the
work force is adding to the existing core of
firms industries that sell their products to



2It is often said that not any industry will do; the
object should be to attract “ growth industries." While
these industries do generate new investment over time,
they are not the only path to a successful export base.
In many cases— the South and textiles—areas have
expanded their share of slow-growing industries. In
other areas, “ glamour industries," such as electronics
and defense, have not lived up to expectations. In
short, studies have shown that a region with a “ favorable
mix" of industries does not always have the best growth
record. Likewise, others stress manufacturing firms as
the source of export strength. Nonmanufacturing in­
dustries can be just as important, however. Tourist
facilities, corporate headquarters, and even a major
university have successfully provided regions with
“ export income."

19

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

comfortably locate in a number of different
areas and still meet growing national de­
mands. This camp contends that only with
an ample supply of workers can firms satisfy
national demand at competitive prices.
Thus, those regions where population is
growing most rapidly have an advantage in
gaining new businesses.
Resolving conflicting views on the im­
portance of attracting people and industries
is basic to future efforts of local leaders
and policymakers. Identifying the key ele­
ment affecting regional growth is a compli­
cated, but imperative, task. Such an effort re­
quires an in-depth look at the basic economic
forces involved.

locate where it is most profitable to do so.
As long as most firms vie for the consumer's
dollar in the national market place, those
locating where the total production costs
are lowest will have an advantage. While
many costs are fairly standard, the transpor­
tation costs of materials used in production
and of products to their markets often differ
significantly among firms and can be im­
portant sources of competitive advantage.
Clearly, geographical cost considerations
mandate the location of some firms. There
is little sense in leaders in eastern states
trying to attract pulp mills when lumber is
grown in the South and Pacific Northwest.
Likewise, nobody would seriously suggest
that New York-consumed beer be brewed
in Georgia. For many firms, however, costs
are such that the most profitable location is
not fixed in any one place; these are, pre­
sumably, the plants that advocates of in­
creasing an area's export base covet.
For these mobile firms the most profitable
location is significantly affected by a com­
bination of transportation and other cost
factors. Firms may move if the geographical
concentration of their customers shifts; that
is, many firms may be attracted to areas
where population is growing. Or a plant
may relocate to another area if it produces
alternative, less-expensive inputs. Moreover,
highways, waterways, or air routes that affect
the expense of transporting goods influence
where total costs are lowest. Changes in
transportation access eventually cause new
places to boom and others with advantages
to lose their edge, thereby causing firms to
shift locations because of lower costs.
Profitability is also related to a region's
economic structure. One firm's costs will
reflect the presence of other firms. Where
other firms are established, a businessman
will find that services are readily available,
that labor is likely to have developed con­
siderable skills, and that news about oppor­
tunities is likely to spread rapidly throughout

ENHANCING A REGION S
INDUSTRIAL BASE
Bringing new industries into a region is
another way of saying that an area will grow
primarily by increasing its productive ca­
pacity through augmentation of its stock of
capital3 increasing numbers of plants, ma­
—
chines, and tools. "Attracting new industry"
is not a simple process, however. Nor is it
the only way to enhance an area's capital
facilities.
Attracting new industry. Most people be­
lieve one or two key factors influence the
location of industry. Some argue that high
taxes drive industry from some regions to
those with lower taxes. Others say that lowwage, nonunion cities are the ones attracting
new plants. Still others argue that comfort­
able suburban settings away from city noises
and problems are magnets to industry. Who
is right?. . . everyone and nobody at the same
time.
The complete picture must be considered.
Over time, competition will force firms to

3 When "export" industries are attracted, product
demand is also provided. People to man the plants are
assumed to be either at hand or will be attracted auto­
matically.




20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

are regional assets in inducing all types of
investment.

the business community. Likewise, in places
in which large numbers of businessmen
interact on a regular basis, new ideas are
more likely to develop. Large differences in
local wages or productivity that affect total
labor costs (whether union-induced or not)
also enter the profitability picture. So do
local taxes and land costs. In short given
transportation costs, local considerations
vary and, if they are large enough can affect
where new investment occurs. Rarely does
any one factor dominate, however. All inter­
act to form the total cost picture.
Other Ways the Industrial Base Grows.
There are other, less spectacular ways in
which an area can acquire new plants and
job-creating machinery that are not typi­
cally emphasized by those who say an ex­
panding industrial base is the key to regional
growth. Additional productive capacity can
also be achieved through making goods
locally that were formerly purchased from
other regions. As income grows, enough
demand can be generated so that local pro­
ducers can make goods for local consump­
tion with local labor. This process is an
integral part of regional growth. National
firms open branch plants to assemble auto­
mobiles or televisions. Local firms begin to
produce furniture, process food, and manu­
facture household goods. In technical terms,
import substitution takes place.
Furthermore, the long-run economic
health of an area can depend upon the
very developments which those that con­
centrate on “ basic," or export, industries
ignore. An efficient and expanding "service
sector" not only autonomously creates jobs
but affects the profitability of investment for
other industries. It can be an inducement
for investment long after a particular export
industry has come and gone. An area having
business services that are adaptable to de­
mands of particular industries and to the
latest business techniques is bound to be vi­
brant. Likewise, efficient and economical
communication and transportation systems



THE IMPORTANCE OF
POPULATION GROWTH
While people stress industrial growth,
population is often regarded as a liability
rather than an asset for regional develop­
ment. In areas where unemployment is
high, problems would seem much simpler
if the workers for whom jobs are hardest
to find were to move to areas where labor
shortages exist. After massive in-migration
leads to mounting social and economic bur­
dens, many long-time residents often have
second thoughts about newcomers. Yet, areas
in which economic activity has expanded
most rapidly have been those with the fastest
population growth— most recently Florida,
California, and the Southwest. Conversely,
areas which have lost population have been
among the slowest growing.
These trends suggest to some observers
that people rather than machines are the
more important factor in growing regions.
Like capital, people are productive assets.
Since investment funds are available at com­
parable costs all over the nation over long
periods, lack of capital need not deter re­
gional growth. It naturally flows where
investment is most profitable. Further, the
argument goes, a large segment of any
growth in national product demand can be
serviced from a wide variety of locations.
For instance, the basic components of prod­
ucts such as computers and automobiles
could be produced in California as well as
in Pennsylvania.
With nearly equal access to market oppor­
tunities and to capital, differences in labor
availability determine which regions will
prosper and which will not. Areas where
firms can get plenty of workers at competi­
tive wage levels will find expansion profit­
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

OCTOBER 1972

the other factor merely follows. The two
aspects of growth are not unrelated in that
a healthy region is one in which new jobs
attract people and the new people, in turn,
enhance the profitability of new plants and
machinery. Since more people encourage
investment by providing manpower as well
as consumer demand, over long periods,
regions with the greatest labor force growth
attract industry and jobs. However, where
people move is partly related to where indus­
try is prospering. While geographical and
sociological factors are important, the growth
of economic activity plays a major role. New
jobs and bright economic prospects often
give a family the strongest reason to move.
Thus, the overall picture of regional
growth is one of interaction of physical and
human resources. One encourages and helps
determine the other. Focusing on one ig­
nores the importance of the other. In some
instances, autonomous population increases
may set off a spiral of economic growth;
elsewhere, a large expansion of the indus­
trial base may come first. The point is that
once growth starts both factors are important.

able. In regions losing labor, or where good
labor is just hard to recruit, firms will find that
they cannot expand as readily. Observers
have noted that manufacturing industries in
areas receiving large doses of migrants or
attracting workers from nearby farms have
grown most rapidly in past decades. The East
and the Midwest, where workers are less
abundant, have lagged.4
Besides providing a valuable productive
asset to a region, growing population over
time has a second beneficial effect. As
new people move into a region, they stimu­
late local industries. For instance, retailers,
wholesalers, and construction firms expand.
As these sectors grow, they will invest and
stimulate further economic expansion. In
short, a strong case can be made that policy­
makers really can't advance the prospects for
their area if they are not affecting a long-run
growth in labor resources.

REGIONAL GROWTH:
THE OVERALL PICTURE
There is little disagreement that a pre­
requisite to long-run regional growth is
increasing an area's productive resources.
With more productive inputs, an area is
able to make goods for its own inhabitants
and to sell goods to others. Arguments have
been made on both sides as to the efficacy
and desirability of attracting labor on the
one hand or capital on the other.
Neither side is wholly correct in asserting
that growth in one factor comes first and

WHAT LOCAL LEADERS CAN DO
If regional growth involves the interaction
of labor and capital, what is the best way
for local leaders to encourage prosperity?
Clearly, attracting new firms touches only a
limited aspect of the problem. It ignores
other ways that the industrial base can be
expanded, and it does not deal with popula­
tion growth. Whether policymakers can
exert a more effective role is not certain,
however. Many of the determinants of
growth are beyond their control. To make a
significant difference over the long haul, they
may have to turn to different and innovative
tools.

4Some people will quickly point out that attracting
workers is a good idea— so long as they are skilled and
with high incomes. It is true that this type of migrant is
especially beneficial in terms of increasing a region's
productive capacity, contributing to local taxes, and
stimulating local sales. But despite the higher social
costs of less skilled workers, they too are a valuable
productive asset to the region receiving them.




22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Limitations on Local Initiative. The forces
controlling an area's share of the action are
often determined by national developments.
National policies often govern how much
and where firms invest. For instance, trans­
portation costs, often a key determinant
of differential costs among areas, are fixed
by where Federal highways are routed and
by Washington's regulation of transportation
rates and services. Where defense and sci­
entific projects are located controls who
will garner their beneficial local effects.
Further, without Federal assistance local re­
sources are often technically and financially
inadequate to provide public services that
crucially affect the profitability of investing
in an area-—local transport systems, flood
control projects, and even manpower retrain­
ing programs.5 In a sense, a good regional

development policy may be to have a strong
and effective lobbyist in the nation's capital.
In many ways national economic trends
are much more influential for local develop­
ment than either regional or national policy
actions. Lack of demand for an area's prod­
ucts and consequent local unemployment is
most often the result of national business
conditions. This is especially true in areas
that specialize in producing cyclicallysensitive goods. Such underutilization of
local resources is beyond local control; a
healthy national economy is a prerequisite
for healthy regional economies.
Over the long haul a region's fate is also
determined by the national economy. For
instance, given the rapid rate of techni­
cal progress and often-changing consumer
tastes, finding today's successful industry in
trouble tomorrow is not uncommon. Since
no economy can grow without such changes,
problems will always plague local areas. The
key to avoiding prolonged periods of re­
gional decay is to recognize change and ad­
just to it.

5 The importance of national decisions suggests that
an active national role in regional development may be
appropriate. In many countries national decisions are
made within the framework of a regional development
policy: the Economic Development Act of 1965 was a
first step toward such an effort in the United States.
Any such policy may be hampered, however, by con­
flicts over efficient output growth and regional equity.
Perhaps more important is a recognition that certain
problems are inappropriate for local government ef­
forts. When society as a whole decides to maintain a
minimum standard of living, it is the Federal govern­
ment that should step in. Many local areas have a
disproportionate share of disadvantaged groups and




lack resources to cope with the problem. Further,
there is no guarantee that a person will not absorb all
the benefits and then move on to another area. "Local”
problems such as compensatory education, welfare, and
drug addiction are really national concerns; to attempt
to bear them at the local level is unsound and a source
of severe financial strain.
23

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

many regions, is the eliminating of eco­
nomic inefficiencies and the fostering of
innovations within a region. Resources tied up
in unproductive ventures are wasted. Many
regions have released valuable assets by
having labor and capital which have been
underutilized in agricultural pursuits flow
into the growing sectors. Vested interests in
the business community and labor camp that
tie up resources in declining industries or in
unproductive work rules rob a region of
growth potential. Government programs
which siphon resources in an unproductive
manner are just as bad. Furthermore, it is as
important to encourage new techniques and
investments of local industries as it is to at­
tract a plant. The financial community, of
course, has heavy responsibilities in this effort.
Retaining and attracting human resources
are difficult tasks. Some factors are clearly
beyond the control of local leaders. Among
the more prominent are climate, natural rec­
reational opportunities, and where migrants'
friends and relatives happen to live. Still
there is room for local action. Residential
and cultural amenities carry some weight, as
do convenience and lack of congestion on
local transport facilities. Low crime rates,
clean streets, good medical facilities as well
as efficient and low-cost government ser­
vices are also attractions. Making a town a
“ nice place to live" is not enough, however.
Workers need jobs just as much as the local
economy needs workers. Like attracting new
firms, attracting new people will be easier
when a region is already growing and harder
when it is stagnant.

Even with efficient adjustment to change,
it is simply the case that at times some
places will not grow as rapidly as others.
Local economies will always have unequal
geographic access to demand and new re­
source bases. The changing composition of
output will inevitably favor some over
others. Events will also grace some regions
with greater population growth than others.
In short, differences in location and natural
endowments often make efficient growth of
the national economy unbalanced regarding
subnational areas.
Encouraging Local Growth. Although to
a large extent local economic progress is
determined by outside influences, promo­
tion efforts may enhance the prospects of
a region. In shorter periods, the influ­
ence of local actions may be limited to
capturing a disproportionate share of the
economic growth of the section of the coun­
try in which a community is located. Over
long periods concerted efforts to reduce
total production costs in a region may draw
both men and machines from other sections
of the country as well as encourage expan­
sion of local firms.
Sometimes management exercises consid­
erable discretion over investment, and a
strong local attack on total costs may tip the
scale toward a given community. Improving
public services per unit of tax dollar can be
important in this respect, as will any effort
to lower the cost of investing in an area—
for example, making financial costs as low as
possible on improving the quality and quan­
tity of suppliers of supportive services. Like­
wise, training or retraining those residents
who are most likely to stay in an area will
enhance the overall productivity of a region's
work force. But these efforts would be made
only with full realization of their inherent
limitations—years of work can be wiped out
by a major national economic change.
An approach to increasing a region's
capital assets which is not often considered,
but has been the hallmark of growth in




BETTER BUT NOT BIGGER
Rapid economic expansion is not a reason­
able expectation for many sections of the
country— especially older, manufacturing
states. It may be prudent for leaders in these
areas to shift their attention to other goals.
24

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Such a course need not be discouraging
since growth is not necessarily the only pos­
sible objective. Nor, in the view of some
critics, is it the best. Indeed, even leaders in
regions with substantial potential for expan­
sion may not find unlimited growth to be the
most desirable path. Economic progress has
"quality" elements worthy of consideration.
Likewise, the physical, social and political
structure of the region has economic aspects
which are fertile grounds for attention.
Growth in a region, like a nation, is often
accompanied by problems and ill-effects.
Local leaders may decide to channel their
efforts toward stable industries rather than

well as social sense. A region's geographic
structure affects the economic costs of land,
of communication among people, and of
area travel. Thus, economic performance is
strongly influenced by present physical ar­
rangements. Regions typically consist of
high-density central cities with gradually
decreasing concentrations of people in the
suburbs and large expanses of agricultural
land. Given the trend of many offices to lo­
cate in central cities and more plants in the
suburbs, many workers spend much time and
effort commuting to their jobs. Even more
costly for the local economy is the loss of
valuable labor services of inner-city residents

an ever-expanding number of new ones.
Likewise, they may weigh the pollution costs
of economic progress and decide a larger
economic base means too many undesirable
effects. In the past, the result of growth was
often more jobs and more pollution. In the
future, strictly enforced standards may ad­
versely affect the profitability of investment
and thus give areas the choice of greater
growth or cleaner air and water.
The way regions function internally is
often taken for granted, but changes in this
area may be productive in an economic as

who may be isolated from prospective jobs.
Likewise, a region's total economic per­
formance is almost certain to be adversely
affected by the fragmentation of local gov­
ernment. In almost all sections of the coun­
try, the local government structure is marked
by a multiplicity of units, varying widely in
their responsibilities and fiscal capabilities.
Instead of cooperating to achieve equitable
and efficient arrangements of services, local
governments are often busy competing
among themselves for plants. In short, the
way local laws, attitudes, and traditions shape




25

OCTOBER 1972

BUSINESS REVIEW

they are more successful than when their
sole concern was attracting new industries.
As technology advances and transportation
within the country becomes easier, those
very regions having the best total economic
environment will attract people and capital.
Thus, by striving to make itself a better place
to live, an area may end up with both a bet­
ter and bigger place.
■

the geographic, political, and social fiber of
a region has definite economic ramifications.
Thus, changes enchancing regional efficiency
and productivity are important future con­
cerns.
Ironically, community leaders who direct
their attention to the quality of a region's
growth and its institutions rather than the
magnitude of its economic growth may find

SELECTED READINGS
ON REGIONAL GROWTH
Borts, George and Stein, Jerome. Economic Growth in a Free Market. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1964.
Leven, Charles; Legler, John; and Shapiro, Perry. An Analytical Framework for
Regional Development Policy. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT
Press, 1970.
Mazek, Warren and Chang, John. "The Chicken and Egg Foul-Up in Migration:
Comment." Southern Economic journal 39 (July 1972):
133-139.
Muth, Richard. "Migration: Chicken or Egg?" Southern Economic Journal 37
(January 1971): 295-306.
Nourse, Hugh. Regional Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company,
1968.
Perloff, Harvey; Dunn, Edgar; Lampard, Eric; and Muth, Richard. Regions, Re­
sources, and Economic Growth. Lincoln: University of
Nebraska Press, 1960.




26

FOR THE R E C O R D ...

2 YEARS AGO

YEAR AGO

AUGUST 1972

Third Federal
Reserve District

August 1972
from
mo.
ago

MANUFACTURING
Production.......................................
Electric power consumed . . .
Man-hours, total*....................
Employment, total........................
Wage income*................................
CONSTRUCTION**..........................
COAL PRODUCTION.......................
BANKING
(All member banks)
Deposits............................................
Loans.................................................
Investments....................................
U.S. Govt, securities...............
Other.............................................
Check payments***.....................

year
ago

year
ago

mo.
ago

year
ago

year
ago

LO C A L
CH AN GES
Metropolitan
Statistical Areas*

Wilmington......................
+ 9
- 1
- 2
+ 6
+14
-1 0

+ 3
- 2
- 3
+ 4
-20
- 6

+ 4
+ 2
+ 4
+10
+22

+ 6 N/A
+ 3 + 1
+13 N/A
+16 +13
-1 0 - 6

AUGUST 1972

Manufacturing

Percent change

8
8
mos. August 1972 mos.
1972
1972
from
from
from

+ 5 + 9 + 6
+ 8
+ 3
-1 2
+ 3
+25
-1-34

YEAR AGO

United States

Percent change
SU M M A R Y

2 YEARS AGO

Banking

Employment

Check
Total
Payments** Deposits***

Percent
Percent
Percent
Percent
change
change
change
change
August 1972 August 1972 August 1972 August 1972
from
from
from
from
month year month year month year month year
ago ago ago ago ago ago ago ago
0 + 3

-

6 +11

+15

N/A

N/A

N/A

Trenton............................. + 1 + 1 + 6 +15

+27

+19

Bridgeton......................... + 3

-

Altoona............................. + 1 Harrisburg.......................

0

-

1

N/A

2 + 3

+12
+16
+ 9
- 1
+14
+ 17f

+13
+13
+13
0
+20
N/Af

0 +10
+ 1 +14
+ 1 + 9
0 + 1
+ 1 +13
N/A N/A

+10
+12
+ 9
+ 1
+15
N/A

+ 4 +43

-

Lancaster......................... + 2 + 2
1
2
1
1
1
8t

+ 5 +13

+10

Lehigh Valley................. + 5

+ 2 + 6 +18

Philadelphia.................... + 1 -

•Production workers only
••Value of contracts
•••Adjusted lor seasonal variation




ot

+ 3t

+ 3J

0 -f- 4 + 4
0 + 3 + 3

fl5 SMSA’s
JPhiladelphia

+19

+ 1 +14
+ 2 + 9

+47

+ 1 +15

- 3 + 9

+ 1 +13

1 + 3 + 6 + 6 +18

+ 1 +12

Reading............................ + 4

-

1 + 6 +11

+ 5

Scranton........................... + 2

-

2

-

-

6 + 3

+ 3

+ 3

N/A

N/A

York................................... + 2

+ 2

+ 3 + 8 -

N/A

-

8 + 3 +18

5 +10

0 +16

N/A

Williamsport...................

N/A

2 +10

4 +11

Wilkes-Barre.................. + 2
PRICES
Wholesale......................................
Consumer.........................................

0
-

+ 7 + 2 + 3 + 4 +13

3 + 1 + 8 +12

Johnstown....................... + 1 + 18
+
+
-1
+
+
+

0 + 7

+13

0 + 6 + 3 +21

Atlantic City.................... + 1 + 3 + 3 +16

+33

+ 9 +12
5 +34

+ 2 +13
+ 3 +31
+ 3

N/A

+ 3 +12

•Not restricted to corporate limits of cities but covers areas of one or more
counties.
••All commercial banks. Adjusted for seasonal variation.
•••Member banks only. Last Wednesday of the month.