View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Ted Temzelides

Are Bank Runs Contagious?
Ted Temzelides*

B

anks are a vital part of the economy because they provide an important channel
through which many businesses get their financing. However, as we know from the history of the United States and other countries,
banks can be subject to runs and panics. A panic
that encompasses a large part of the banking
system can seriously disrupt economic activity.
During a run, a bank experiences much
heavier demand for deposit withdrawals than
it can easily meet. If the run is severe enough,
the bank will not be able to meet the demands
*When this article was written, Ted Temzelides was an
economist in the Research Department of the Philadelphia
Fed. He is now in the Department of Economics at the University of Iowa.

of all depositors trying to withdraw money and,
consequently, will have to suspend payments.
During a panic, runs occur on a large number
of banks.
Panics may occur because of regional or
economywide problems, such as a real estate
bust, during which the portfolios of many banks
lose value. If depositors have not completely
lost confidence in the banking system, they will
transfer their deposits from failing banks to
solvent banks. But panics may also occur because runs on a few banks cause depositors at
other banks to lose confidence and, therefore,
to withdraw indiscriminately from both solvent
and insolvent banks. These types of panics,
which involve runs on a few banks spreading
to otherwise solvent banks, are said to involve
contagion.
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

This general definition of contagion does not
specify the precise reasons that bank runs might
spread. Later, we will discuss several recent
studies that test for different factors that can
lead to contagion.
In the late 1800s and early 1900s, there were
several episodes of widespread runs on banks.
Even the 1980s saw a number of well-publicized
runs, including those involving S&Ls in Maryland and Ohio, Penn Square Bank, and the Seattle First National Bank. Despite these more
recent occurrences, the number of runs has
fallen dramatically since deposit insurance was
established in 1933.
Of course, deposit insurance is not without
its own problems. For example, it has recently
been criticized for distorting banks’ incentives
for taking excessive risk—the so-called moral
hazard problem. This can lead to problems for
institutions that are poorly capitalized. In fact,
excessive risk-taking, fueled by distortions
caused by deposit insurance, has been implicated in the S&L debacle of the 1980s. While a
bank enjoys higher profits if risky projects pay
off, it does not always have to pay for taking
the additional risks. Rather, the FDIC bears the
cost of paying off depositors when the bank
cannot. Also, insured depositors, knowing the
FDIC will repay them if their banks cannot, lose
the incentive to try to assess the riskiness of their
banks and, therefore, do not require higher interest rates from banks with riskier portfolios.
Although the FDIC Improvement Act of 1991
introduced risk-based deposit insurance premiums to try to mitigate excessive risk-taking,
today’s premiums do not vary much with the
riskiness of a bank’s portfolio. According to
FDIC data, 94.4 percent of banks, which hold
96.8 percent of total deposits, pay the same premium (which is currently zero) for FDIC insurance. These banks are not identical in terms of
the riskiness of their portfolios. Thus, the current risk-based premiums are unlikely to have
a large effect on banks’ risk-taking behavior.1
Because of the potential distortions caused
4

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

by deposit insurance, some economists advocate scaling it back or even eliminating it. But
before such steps are taken, analysis is needed
to weigh the costs from the problems created
by deposit insurance against its benefits in preventing panics. One necessary step in this analysis is to assess how serious the problem of runs
would be if there were no deposit insurance.
An insolvent bank should be allowed to close;
however, its failure mustn’t spread to healthy
banks. If runs are contagious, deposit insurance,
regulation, and the ability to borrow at the Federal Reserve’s discount window may all play
an important role in preventing runs from
spreading. In this article, we will review the
basic theory and present some recent evidence
on contagious bank runs.
ILLIQUID ASSETS AND
LACK OF INFORMATION
One of the major roles of banks is to provide
liquidity in the economy by allowing depositors to withdraw money from their bank accounts whenever they want to. But while banks
have liquid liabilities, they invest a large part
of their portfolios in long-term illiquid assets,
for example, real estate or business loans.2 In
normal circumstances, the bank’s loan portfolio has some returns from loans that borrowers

1

Part of the reason most banks currently pay the lowest
premiums is that the Deposit Insurance Funds Act of 1996
restricts the FDIC from collecting excessive reserves. Section 7 of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act sets the target
ratio of reserves to estimated insured deposits at 1.25. Since
the banking industry has been performing well, failures
and, therefore, insurance payouts, have been low, allowing the insurance premiums banks pay to fall. Nevertheless, uniform premiums, regardless of whether they are high
or low, can distort banks’ incentives for taking on more risk
than is best for society.
2
A typical bank holds a higher fraction of loans than
securities in its portfolio; however, these fractions do vary
over the business cycle. On average, over the last nine years,
loans as a fraction of banks’ total assets were 60.5 percent,
while securities, which tend to be more liquid, were 19.6
percent of total assets.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

are paying back. Also, the bank holds enough
liquid assets, such as Treasury securities, to
meet the usual demand for withdrawals.
However, if too many depositors want to
withdraw their money, the bank will have to
begin liquidating some of its long-term assets,
for example, by selling them in a secondary
market, before they mature. Typically, this early
liquidation means the assets will not pay off as
much as they would have, had the bank been
able to hold them to maturity: the bank may
have to sell the assets at “fire sale” prices. In
other words, deposits are liquid—depositors
can withdraw their money from the bank at any
time. But loans are illiquid—it can be very costly
to recall them and difficult for the bank to find
a suitable buyer for them. While innovations
in financial markets have permitted bank portfolios to become increasingly liquid—for example, through the securitization of mortgages
and consumer loans—other bank assets, such
as corporate loans, remain illiquid.
Since all banks keep only a fraction of their
deposits as cash, any level of illiquidity makes
them vulnerable if demand for withdrawals is
high enough. This problem can become so severe that it can lead to insolvency. In a world
without deposit insurance, if a depositor believes, for whatever reason, that her bank is
about to become insolvent, she has an incentive to be the first to get her money out before
the bank runs out of cash. If enough depositors
panic and demand to withdraw their deposits,
a run is created. Even healthy banks, whose
assets would pay off in full if held to maturity,
could fail if faced with a sufficiently large and
unexpected amount of withdrawals. And the
run might spread if depositors at other banks
become worried as well.
When depositors at one bank start a run, why
do depositors at other banks often follow suit?
Banks’ ability to handle unusually large withdrawals depends on what proportion of their
assets is liquid and the quality of their illiquid
assets. If a depositor believes that other deposi-

Ted Temzelides

tors at her bank plan to withdraw their funds,
she may start worrying about her own money.
She knows that if withdrawals are large enough,
the bank could fail. In this case, an amount less
than the initial deposit will be left for her if she
waits too long, so she may decide to withdraw
her deposits immediately. If all depositors share
her beliefs, a run could start and that bank could
fail regardless of the condition of its assets. A
run on one bank may lead depositors at other
banks to form similar beliefs about the behavior of other depositors and to start a run on their
banks. In this case, failures could spread among
both solvent and insolvent banks because runs
on a large number of banks could lead depositors to lose confidence in the banking system
as a whole.
Alternatively, depositors might have some
information about the quality of their bank’s
assets. If the assets turn sour—for example,
during a period of unfavorable economic conditions—these depositors might start a run on
the bank. Subsequently, depositors at other
banks may start runs if they think their banks
have assets similar to those of the first bank.
Thus, panics can be triggered when depositors,
in the light of new information, revise their beliefs about the quality of their banks’ assets.3
In this case we might expect informed depositors to start runs mainly on troubled banks.
Then, as they got more information about which
banks were solvent, we would expect them to
move their money from failing banks to healthy
ones. Therefore, this type of run appears to be
less costly for society. On the whole, it could
even be beneficial, since monitoring bank performance helps to distinguish between good
and bad banks. However, accurate monitoring
relies on depositors’ having perfect information
about their banks’ condition—but information
about the economic condition of banks is almost
never perfect. In times of financial distress, de-

3

See, for example, Calomiris and Gorton (1991).
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

positors are particularly
sensitive to any kind of
news and may start runs
on some liquidity-constrained but otherwise
healthy banks, thereby
causing them to fail.
Usually, economists
view these as opposing
theories of why runs occur, but real world episodes probably contain
features of both. This article will discuss the evidence on whether certain
historical episodes of
bank failures have involved contagion and
why or why not.
ONE VIEW: NO
CONTAGION EFFECTS
During the National
Banking Era (1863-1914),
there were five major
banking panics: 1873,
1884, 1890, 1893, and 1907,
roughly one a decade. All
these panics occurred before either the Federal Reserve System or deposit
insurance was created.4 In
most of these episodes,
large numbers of banks
temporarily suspended
the convertibility of de-

4

See the box Selected Bank
Runs During the National Banking
Era for brief descriptions of the
proximate causes and the main
sequence of events during selected panics from this period.

6

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

Selected Bank Runs
During the National Banking Era*
1873
Economic Environment: Railroad boom; four years of rapid economic
growth.
Proximate Cause: Excessive loan expansion to railroad companies and
decline of the railroad business.
Major Events:
Sept. 8: Suspension of the N.Y. Warehouse and Security Company,
which was financially involved with the Missouri, Kansas, and Texas
Railroad.
Sept. 13: Failure of Messrs. Kenyon, Cox & Co., which endorsed Canada
Southern Railway paper.
Sept. 18: Major bank runs started.
Sept. 20: Closing of N.Y. Stock Exchange.
Sept. 24: Suspension of currency payments by N.Y. banks.
1893
Economic Environment: Monetary disturbance caused by Sherman Silver Purchase Act and international gold flows.
Proximate Cause: Stock market collapse in May.
Major Events:
Feb. 26: Failure of Philadelphia and Reading Railroad.
May 4: Failure of the National Cordage Company (trust company),
which caused the stock market collapse.
July: Numerous bank failures throughout the nation. Reserve outflows
from N.Y. banks.
Aug 5: Suspension of payments by N.Y. banks.
1907
Economic Environment: Steady rise in the price level and economic boom
in the 1900s.
Proximate Cause: Failure of an attempt to corner copper stocks.
Major Events:
Oct. 17: Runs on the Mercantile National Bank, which attempted to
corner the stock of the United Copper Company.
Oct. 21: Runs on Knickerbocker Trust Company, which was financially
involved with the Mercantile National Bank. Major bank runs started.
Oct. 22: Suspension of Knickerbocker Trust Company.
Oct. 23: Major runs on trust companies.

*Taken from Sangkyun Park, “A Triggering Mechanism of Economywide
Bank Runs,” in Allin F. Cottrell, Michael S. Lawlor, and John H. Wood, eds., The
Causes and Costs of Depository Institution Failures, Kluwer, Boston, 1995. Used
with permission.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Ted Temzelides

posits into cash. In other words, depositors
could not withdraw their money from the bank.
A suspension would typically start at banks in
the East, commonly New York, and subsequently spread westward. Panics tended to occur during the fall when the demand for liquidity was higher, mostly because of the seasonal
increase in demand for currency to cover needs
related to agriculture and the seasonal movement of crops. Panics were also associated with
recessions, during which nonbank businesses
also experienced difficulties. But the nature of
the economy is not the only determinant of
banking system stability.

While the economies of the United States and
Canada were quite similar in the late 1800s and
early 1900s, the experiences of their banking
systems were very different. During 1930-33,
more than 9000 banks failed in the United
States, but none failed in Canada. (Figures 1 and
2 show the number and percentage of bank failures in the United States from 1876-1935.) And
unlike in the United States, panics were not
widespread in Canada.
Stephen Williamson has argued that this difference in failures and panics was partly due to
the structure of the banking systems in the two
countries. Because of branching restrictions, the

FIGURE 1

Number of Bank Failures
1876 - 1935

Data Source: Table 2, Chapter 2, in George J. Benston, Robert A. Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J. Kane, and
George G. Kaufman, Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking: Past, Present, and Future. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1986.

7

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

U.S. system consisted of a large number of relatively small banks. In fact, in 1890, there were
more than 7000 banks in the United States.5 At
the same time, Canada had a branch banking
system without geographic restrictions—about
40 chartered banks with about 400 branches.
Williamson argues that the ability of bigger
banks to diversify in Canada was one of the
factors that prevented widespread crises there
in the early 1930s.6
5

By 1920, the number of banks in the United States had
grown to more than 30,000.

Researchers are not in complete agreement
about whether certain historical episodes in the
United States were severe enough to constitute
banking panics or were merely less significant
episodes in which a small number of banks
failed. Moreover, even when researchers agree
that a certain episode was a panic, they do not
always agree about whether contagion effects
played an important role in the panic’s development.
6
Nationwide branching was permitted in the United
States as of June 1997.

FIGURE 2

Bank Failure Rate*
1876 - 1935

*Failures during the year as a percent of the total number of banks at year-end.
Data Source: Table 2, Chapter 2, in George J. Benston, Robert A. Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J. Kane, and
George G. Kaufman, Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking: Past, Present, and Future. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
1986.
8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Several researchers have questioned the
widespread existence of contagion effects.7 Instead, they argue that panics are the result of
bad economic times that cause weak banks to
become insolvent. They think it unlikely that
depositors’ loss of confidence in banks or the
banking system can, by itself, cause a financial
crisis. They argue that depositors who withdraw funds generally transfer them to another
bank that is considered safe, in which case the
total deposits of the banking system are not affected.
In addition, banks’ own actions helped stop
contagion. During some panics in the National
Banking Era, bankers lent money among themselves to help one another meet the high demand for withdrawals. In several episodes, a
coalition of banks, such as the New York Clearing House, acted collectively by issuing clearing house loan certificates to help banks that
needed temporary liquidity. Because these certificates were joint liabilities of the entire group,
this action helped the coalition’s member banks
that were in good standing but that were nevertheless facing liquidity demands they could
not meet. While such cooperative arrangements
did not succeed in eliminating panics altogether, there is evidence that they were successful in reducing the frequency and severity of
panics. The “no contagion” view, then, maintains that, on the whole, contagious bank panics were rare events.8
A recent study by Charles Calomiris and
Joseph Mason investigates whether, in the absence of deposit insurance, differences in infor-

7
See the articles by George Benston and coauthors;
George Kaufman; and Charles Calomiris and Gary Gorton.
8
Even this camp considers the events of late 1932
through early 1933, which brought the entire banking system to a halt, to be consistent with contagion effects. The
disagreement between researchers seems to be about how
frequently we would expect to observe such events in an
environment without government deposit insurance.

Ted Temzelides

mation across depositors induced runs on solvent banks and involved contagion effects in
the June 1932 banking panic in Chicago. Although the number of bank failures at the national or state level was not particularly high
that month, there was a very strong concentration of bank failures in Chicago during the week
of June 20. Calomiris and Mason report that 40
bank failures took place in Chicago in June, 26
of them during that week. In addition, the pattern of deposits shows that Chicago banks experienced a large decline in deposits during late
June, and this pattern was not observed in other
areas of the country.
By focusing on a particular location,
Calomiris and Mason ensured that the banks
they studied faced similar economic environments, e.g., the mix of industries of potential
borrowers, and the incomes of potential depositors. Using a variety of measures, they investigated whether banks that failed during this
episode were weaker and thus—panic aside—
more vulnerable to declines in the prices of assets than banks that survived. The authors
looked at market-to-book value of equity, interest rates paid on borrowings from other
banks, and other accounting measures that gave
them information about the probability of a
bank’s failure. They compared these factors at
banks that failed during the panic with those
at banks that survived. They found that the
banks that went on to fail began with lower
market-to-book values of equity, higher estimated probabilities of failure, and higher borrowing rates. In other words, they were weaker
banks, and they shared characteristics with
banks that failed outside the panic period.
Calomiris and Mason concluded that bank
failures in Chicago in June 1932 were due to
declines in asset values at the failed banks and
not to panic-induced withdrawals because of
depositors’ confusion about the status of the
banks or contagion.9 Furthermore, they argued
that contagion to solvent banks was avoided
because the banks knew each other’s status bet9

BUSINESS REVIEW

ter than depositors did. Therefore, they helped
each other by making loans backed by very
high-quality assets. Hence, solvent banks that
could post collateral avoided failure during the
crisis. Some banks with sufficient collateral also
borrowed from the Fed’s discount window. But,
in general, banks preferred borrowing from one
another, since this action was less public: they
feared that borrowing from the Fed might be
misinterpreted by depositors as a sign of weakness.
Although it is hard to generalize on the basis of one event, the authors’ findings are consistent with many studies that suggest that private interbank cooperation may be sufficient to
reduce, although not necessarily prevent, contagious panics.
ANOTHER VIEW: CONTAGION EFFECTS
While it is difficult to distinguish between
runs that occur at the same time in many banks
and contagious ones, some researchers have
been able to identify contagious runs.10 Milton
Friedman and Anna Schwartz have interpreted
the panic of 1930 as a purely autonomous disturbance largely unrelated to the Depression
and, thus, a candidate for a contagious panic.11
Elmus Wicker studied the same event and ar-

9
But they did acknowledge that some confusion among
depositors was present during this episode.
10
George Kaufman, who maintains that the importance
of contagion effects has been exaggerated, nonetheless cites
examples of runs on neighboring banks that occurred after
the announcement of negative news about the solvency of
one institution. Kaufman also points out four periods in
which the level of deposits in the banking system declined
(1878, 1893, 1908, and 1930-33), a condition consistent with
contagion.
11

In addition to being a candidate for a panic in which
contagion effects were present, the panic of 1930 provides
an example of a crisis that developed after the Federal
Reserve System was created but before deposit insurance
was established.
10

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

gued that the crisis was precipitated by the collapse of the Caldwell financial empire. Caldwell
and Company, located in Nashville, Tennessee,
controlled the largest chain of banks in the
South. Wicker attributes this failure to
Caldwell’s “weak and precarious financial state
on the eve of the Depression.” Caldwell’s collapse caused depositors to revise their expectations about future deposit losses and affected
more banks in later months. Wicker thus disputes the view that the panic of 1930 was a
wholly autonomous event. His view does not
rule out contagion, but makes it less likely that
contagion was present.
Soon after Caldwell’s closing, the Bank of
United States also failed. Friedman and
Schwartz maintained that the bank’s name led
to confusion about its official status, constituting a serious blow to depositor confidence.12
They concluded that the banking panic of November-December 1930 was the result of a contagion of fear that spread among depositors, accelerating the bank failure rate, reducing the
money stock, and worsening the economic
downturn. (See The Banking Panic of 1930.)
Anthony Saunders and Berry Wilson found
evidence for significant contagion effects during the period 1930-32 but no evidence of contagion during the panics of 1929 or 1933. Using
regression techniques, Saunders and Wilson investigated the determinants of deposit withdrawal rates during these periods. Their analysis compares the deposit withdrawal rates at
failing banks in the three years prior to the year
of a bank’s failure with the withdrawal rates at
a matched sample of surviving banks. Each
bank in the sample of banks that survived was

12
Confusion may have arisen because of the similarity
in names between the Bank of United States and the first
Bank of the United States and the second Bank of the United
States, both of which were early attempts at establishing a
central bank. However, the Bank of United States was a
commercial bank with no special ties to the government.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Ted Temzelides

The Banking Panic of 1930*
In several of the panics that occurred before the Federal Reserve System was established, banks
temporarily suspended convertibility of deposits into currency. Such suspension of payments, often coordinated by banks in the New York Clearing House, successfully prevented panics from
spreading when banks were suffering mainly from temporary liquidity problems. Restriction of
payments by banks during the early signs of a panic protected the banking system by giving time
for depositors’ fears to wear off and for banks to regain liquidity. Once the danger of widespread
runs had passed, banks resumed converting deposits into currency. During these suspensions,
banks typically carried on with their usual operations: making loans, transferring deposits by
check, and, in certain cases, converting limited amounts of deposits into cash, for example, so that
firms could meet their payrolls. Such limited suspension was not without costs, but the costs were
far smaller than those of the panics of the 1930s.
During the panic of 1930, early suspension of convertibility did not occur. Milton Friedman and
Anna Schwartz maintain that, as a result, the panic of 1930 became the first of a series of crises that
ended only after the banking holiday of March 1933.
Friedman and Schwartz emphasize the importance of the failure of the Bank of United States
on December 11, 1930. This bank was the largest that had failed in the United States up to that time,
and its failure provides an example of how the methods for stemming incipient panics had changed
after the Fed came into existence. Despite various plans sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York and others to save the bank, the member banks of the New York Clearing House withdrew support and did not provide the new capital funds that would have helped in reorganizing
the bank. Personal appeals by the state superintendent of banks and the lieutenant governor of
New York were unsuccessful at changing the position of the clearing house. Instead, the president
of the New York Clearing House suggested that the effects of closing the bank would be only local.
The bank, a member of the Federal Reserve System, borrowed from the Fed, but this borrowing
was not sufficient to save it. It is not certain whether the bank could have raised collateral of high
enough quality to back more substantial lending. In general, banks avoided borrowing from the
Fed during periods in which fearful depositors were looking for signs of weakness, trying to predict which banks were likely to fail. Thus, the Bank of United States failed, and many others followed.
Friedman and Schwartz argue that under the pre-Federal Reserve banking system, banks would
probably have restricted payments to depositors during the final months of 1930, which might
have bought time for the panic to subside. They claim that the existence of the Federal Reserve
prevented suspension by reducing the concerns of stronger private banks, which in the past had
taken the lead in such a move. Furthermore, many people, assuming the Federal Reserve would
deal with such crises, believed such a move was unnecessary. Had suspension of convertibility
taken place during this episode, the Bank of United States might have been able to reopen, since
this bank eventually paid off 83.5 percent of its liabilities at its closing, despite the fact that it had to
liquidate a large fraction of its assets under unfavorable conditions.

*Some parts are based on Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

matched to a failed bank in terms of deposit
size and the city in which it was located.13 The
authors reasoned that if a bank run was not due
to a contagious panic, depositors should withdraw their money from bad banks and re-deposit it with good banks in the same locality. If,
on the other hand, bank runs were developing
into contagious panics, the authors would observe increased withdrawal rates at both good
and bad banks as the time of failure approached.
Saunders and Wilson found that, for banks
that failed in the period 1930-32, deposit withdrawals at good banks increased over the three
years leading up to the failure of their matched
bad banks.14 Withdrawals at banks that failed
and those that survived differed little in the
years prior to failure. In the year of failure, failing banks lost, on average, a higher fraction of
their deposits than banks that survived. For
example, banks that failed in 1932 experienced,
on average, withdrawals of 51.8 percent, while
the matched control banks suffered withdrawals of 19.3 percent in that year.
The authors interpreted these observations
as evidence consistent with contagion. In addition, regression analysis showed that in the
period 1930-32, the rate of withdrawals at the
matched surviving banks was significantly
higher if the rate of bank failures in the surviving bank’s state was higher or if the deposit outflows at their matched failing banks were
higher. We would expect neither of these factors to be positively related to deposit withdrawals at the surviving banks if contagion
were not present because, in the absence of contagion, we would expect to see funds moving

from failing banks to healthy ones instead of
withdrawals from both types.15
Joseph Aharony and Itzhak Swary studied
the behavior of bank stockholders in more recent bank failures. Since these stockholders are
not insured, how they acted might illuminate
how depositors might behave in the absence of
deposit insurance. The authors empirically
tested whether stockholders draw inferences
about the health of a bank by observing similar
banks. Such observations may be one mechanism through which contagion arises.
The authors focused on the failure of five
large banks in the southwestern United States
during the mid-1980s.16 They concentrated on
a set of bank characteristics as a measure for
the information on which depositors base their
assessments of banks’ riskiness. For example,
the distance of a nonfailing bank’s headquarters from a failed bank’s headquarters may be
particularly important: it’s a good indication
that both banks have similar loan portfolios,
and hence face similar risks, because banks in
the same location are subject to similar economic conditions and have similar types of
borrowers. Size may also be important, since
banks of different sizes may engage in different types of activities. For example, large banks
tend to be more involved in wholesale activities, such as offering credit to large firms. So
the failure of a large bank, if there is contagion,
will likely have more of an impact on other large
banks.
The authors’ results indicated that the closer
a large solvent bank is to a large failing bank,
the stronger is the negative impact of the fail-

13
If no such matched bank existed within the city, they
chose the matching bank from a city of similar size.

15
Saunders and Wilson also show that contagion effects
grew worse over the period 1930-32.

14

This was true even when differences in local economic
conditions that could affect deposit withdrawals, for example, differences in personal income, were taken into account.
12

16

The failure of the First National Bank of Midland,
Texas, for example, in October 1983 resulted from a run by
large depositors. This was the second biggest commercial
bank failure in the United States.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Ted Temzelides

ure on the solvent bank’s stock return.17 Joseph
Aharony and Itzhak Swary also found that the
larger the solvent bank is, the larger the decline
of its stock return after the failure of another
large bank. The results are consistent with information-based runs, in which the market assumes that similar banks are likely to have similar problems. The authors interpret their results
as suggesting that the failure of a bank in one
region should make regulatory authorities concerned about the possibility of contagion and,
therefore, of consecutive runs on similar, but
otherwise healthy, banks in the same region.
CONCLUSION
The study by Saunders and Wilson suggests
that contagion effects were present in some

17
Since data on stock returns are easily accessible, both
depositors and stockholders may use them to evaluate the
condition of their bank.

cases and not in others. But additional research
is needed before the magnitude of contagion effects during different episodes is documented
with certainty. Research similar to the Calomiris
and Mason study, which used bank-level data
on local panics that occurred before federal deposit insurance existed, could prove useful in
this endeavor as could more formal statistical
tests.
Historically, the possibility of panics, and
therefore of contagious panics, appears to depend on the structure of the banking system
and the specific private arrangements designed
to prevent such events. But private arrangements have limitations; historically, they did not
eliminate banking crises altogether. Current
evidence suggests that contagion effects have
to be taken seriously in the debate about deposit insurance. Before drastic changes are
made to the safety net, we should remember
what banks experienced when they had to work
without a net.

SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY
Aharony, J., and I. Swary. “Additional Evidence on the Information-Based Contagion Effects of Bank
Failures,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 20, 1996.
Bhattacharya, S., and A.V. Thakor. “Contemporary Banking Theory,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 3, 1993.
Benston, G.J., and others. Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking. Past, Present, and Future. Cambridge:
MIT Press, 1986.
Calomiris, C., and G. Gorton. “The Origins of Bank Panics: Models, Facts, and Bank Regulation,” in R.
Glenn Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and Financial Crises. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1991.
Calomiris, C.W., and J.R. Mason. “Contagion and Bank Failures During the Great Depression: The
June 1932 Chicago Banking Panic,” manuscript (November 1995).
Friedman, M., and A.J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, N.J., 1963.

13

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY

(continued)

Kaufman, G.G. “Bank Contagion: Theory and Evidence,” manuscript (June 1992).
Lucia, J.L. “The Failure of the Bank of United States: A Reappraisal,” Explorations in Economic History,
22, 1985.
Mester, L. “Curing Our Ailing Deposit-Insurance System,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Business Review September/October 1990.
Park, S. “A Triggering Mechanism of Economywide Bank Runs,” in Allin Cottrel, Michael Lawlor,
and John Wood, eds., The Causes and Costs of Depository Institution Failures. Kluwer Academic
Press, 1995.
Saunders, A., and B. Wilson. “Contagious Bank Runs: Evidence from the 1929-1933 Period,”
Journal of Financial Intermediation 5, 1996.
Wicker, E. “A Reconsideration of the Causes of the Banking Panic of 1930,” Journal of Economic History, 6 (September 1980).
Williamson, S. “Bank Failures, Financial Restrictions, and Aggregate Fluctuations: Canada and the
United States, 1870-1913,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, Summer
1989.

14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?

Ted Temzelides

Network Issues and Payment Systems
James J. McAndrews*

N

etworks play an integral part in the production and consumption of certain goods and
services, including transportation, communications, and payment systems. A network good
or service has two main characteristics: the
value a person gets from the product increases
as more people consume it and the technique a
firm chooses to produce the product will depend on techniques chosen by other firms. For
example, consider a telephone system. The
greater the number of people connected by tele-

*When this article was written, James McAndrews was
a senior economist and research advisor in the Research
Department of the Philadelphia Fed. He is now in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York.

phone lines, the greater the number of people
any member of the system can call and the more
he or she will enjoy belonging to that telephone
network. Similarly, firms that offer phone service will produce switches and lines compatible with those of other firms that offer phone
service, so that they can offer their customers
the valuable service of connecting to all other
parties.
It is helpful to think of network components
as nodes connected by links.1 Perhaps the most
transparent example is a railroad system, a

1
See the article by Nicholas Economides for a good survey of network economics and an example of an approach
using nodes and links as the basic network components.

15

BUSINESS REVIEW

physical network composed of lines (the links)
that connect destinations (the nodes). A railroad
to one destination is of some value, but a railroad system that connects a traveler to many
destinations potentially has great value. To create an extensive railroad system, regional rail
lines must use compatible gauges. This
complementarity between the components of
a network leads consumers to place a higher
value on larger networks and leads firms to take
into account the production decisions of their
rivals.
Other examples of physical networks include
highways, oil and natural gas pipelines, water
systems, and computerized airline reservation
systems. Certain information services also have
network characteristics. The Internet, for example, can be thought of as a network in which
the computers are the nodes, and the software
and the telephone lines to which the computers are connected form the links that allow files
to be exchanged and seamlessly read by different machines.
Payment systems, such as credit cards,
ATMs, currency, and checks, are also examples
of network goods. Here, the nodes might be
merchants, consumers, and banks, which are
linked by the exchanges of information among
them. In some cases, such as in an ATM network or a point-of-sale (POS) debit system, the
links may also consist of telephone lines. In
others, such as in the checking system, the links
consist of methods of delivery of the check from
the merchant to its bank, and from that bank,
through a clearinghouse (similar to a telephone
switching system), to the consumer’s bank. In
a credit card system, the complementarity between the components is obvious: as more
people use credit cards, more merchants are
induced to add terminals, since allowing customers a convenient means of payment will
potentially increase their sales, and as more
merchants permit credit card payment, the
value to the customer of having a credit card
increases, too.
16

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

Economists have recently renewed their interest in many of the unique issues that arise in
network-dependent industries. Below, we’ll
discuss some of these issues, including compatibility and standard-setting among service providers, the role of an installed base of network
facilities, and access to network facilities.2 In
addition, the more common economic issues of
pricing policies, the tendency toward monopoly, and the introduction and adoption of
alternative technologies take on new dimensions in network industries. Network economics is increasingly relevant in today’s economy
because of the growth of the communications
industry and the computer hardware and software industries and the introduction of new
forms of payment systems such as electronic
money. An understanding of the economics of
networks and the unique features of network
goods gives insight into the organization of
markets for these goods and provides the basis
for formulating good business and public policy
concerning these goods.
Below, we’ll also analyze some payment-system issues from the perspective of network economics and show that formulating appropriate public policy would be difficult without a
knowledge of the economics of payment networks.
NETWORK ISSUES
Not all goods have network characteristics.
For non-network goods, firms compete to be
the main producer, and the techniques one firm
uses in producing the goods need not be related
to the techniques used by other firms. Typically,
the firm that is the most efficient producer will
gain market share, and other firms will lose

2
Among the many papers that explicitly analyze
network issues are those by Jeffrey Rohlfs, Joseph
Farrell and Garth Saloner, and Michael Katz and Carl
Shapiro.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Network Runs Contagious?
Are BankIssues and Payment Systems

James Ted Temzelides
J. McAndrews

market share or be driven from the market entirely. Moreover, the pleasure one person receives from purchasing the good would be the
same no matter how many other people purchase it. Think of ice cream: different firms compete to be the most popular brand, each using
a technique it believes produces the tastiest
product, and one person’s pleasure from eating a cone doesn’t depend on how many others buy ice cream cones.
But the situation is different for network
goods. Consider a communications system: if
one person uses Morse
code and another uses
semaphores, they could
not communicate. For
communication to flourish, a coordinated system of signals that can
be mutually understood
is necessary. So firms
that want to provide
some of these services
must consider what
other firms are providing. Rather than competing, these firms’ decisions complement one
another.3 Furthermore,
as more people adopt
the communication system, its value increases,
since it provides access to more people; this encourages larger networks.
Not only do the benefits increase as the network expands, but the per unit cost of production falls. One reason for the economies of scale
is that networks are often set up with centralized switching facilities to route delivery of service. For example, in a local telephone network,
rather than stringing wires from each house to

all other houses, one line is strung from each
house through a series of trunk lines to a central switch. As telephone traffic increases, the
cost per call declines, since the fixed cost of the
switch can be spread over more calls. This decline in average cost encourages larger networks.
In the 1970s and 1980s, economists began to
recognize networks as distinct features of certain industries and subsequently outlined various economic issues unique to these industries.
Compatibility. One
key to extending the size of
a network is the compatibility of network components. Networks combine
complementary components of a technology that
makes possible the creation
of goods and services. But
the components’ compatibility makes possible their
complementarity.
For
many products, compatibility can be achieved only
by adherence to technical
standards.
Take the case of railroad gauges. U.S. railroads
employed different gauges
of track—the distance between the rails—for decades, necessitating the
use of costly devices (including laying third rails
in some cases, and having railroad cars with
adjustable axle widths) to transport goods
across different rail lines. In the 1830s, at the
beginning of intercity rail service in the United
States, three gauges emerged as the most popular. The three—4 feet 8.5 inches, 4 feet 10 inches,
and 5 feet—varied only slightly from one another but were sufficiently different to prevent
the interchange of rolling stock (railroad cars
and engines). Hence, goods typically had to be
unloaded and reloaded as they were shipped
from one region’s lines to another’s. As long

Networks combine
complementary
components of a
technology that
makes possible the
creation of
goods and services.

3

This aspect of networks is made clear in the paper by
Philip Dybvig and Chester Spatt.

17

BUSINESS REVIEW

as the volume of shipments between regions
was not too great, the different gauges could
survive.
From the 1840s through the 1860s, additional
gauges were introduced and survived, resulting in a balkanized railroad system. In a 1991
article, Douglas Puffert identified nine regions
of the country that, in the 1860s, used common
gauges within the region. By the 1890s, though,
U.S. railroads had fixed on 4 feet 8.5 inches
(called the standard gauge) as the measurement
for rails across the country.
Puffert explained the evolution of railroad
gauges in the United States in this way: In the
early years of railroad development, purely local considerations were paramount. Railroads
were built to gain access to ports, rivers, canals,
and large regional markets and were not
interlinked with other railroads. However, as
the industrialization of the United States proceeded in the post-Civil War period, the higher
cost of shipping goods across lines of different
gauges became more apparent. In the late 1880s,
those lines that did not use the standard gauge
decided voluntarily to move their rails to adhere to the standard gauge across the United
States. After that, an extensive system of car
interchange developed among the railroads.4
Underproduction. Another issue is the possible underproduction of network services. Economic models suggest that market production
of network services may often be inefficiently
low because using a network imposes an external effect on other users of that network, an effect these other users typically disregard in
making their own production decisions.5
Since expanding a network requires additional facilities, the new facilities create the possibility for new products and services. For example, suppose a business installs a fax ma-

4
See the publications by Douglas Puffert; John Stover;
and George Taylor and Irene Neu for excellent analyses of
the history of U.S. railroads.

18

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

chine, adding one machine to an existing network of 100 machines owned by other businesses. This installation allows the business to
send messages to 100 other businesses, which,
in turn, can send messages to the business with
the new fax machine. The existing fax machine
owners generally place a positive value on the
extra machine, but typically do not subsidize
its installation. And businesses deciding
whether to install a new fax machine would not
take into account the positive effect on other
businesses. Thus, an externality exists in the
purchase and use of network goods.6 Because
the prices for network goods and services do
not typically reflect this externality, the consumption of network goods and services is expected to be inefficiently low in a competitive
market: A business might decide it is too expensive to install the new fax machine, even
though the value to the 100 other firms exceeds
the cost of the machine.
Standards. The process of setting standards
for network components is vital to achieving
the compatibility that makes network
complementarity fully possible. Setting standards can be done, as in the U.S. railroad case,
by the marketplace, through cooperation (industry forums on setting standards), or by the
government. Although the U.S. railroad indus-

5

This applies to models of markets with a competitive
or a monopolistic structure.
6
An externality exists when the decisions or activities
of one entity affect, positively or negatively, the environment (excluding prices) of another. In the example in the
text, the firm’s decision to install a fax machine imposed a
positive externality on the 100 other firms because it increased the ability of all the firms to communicate (and
hence do business) more efficiently and more quickly with
one another. The externality imposed by increasing network
traffic need not always be positive, however. Network facilities, like many other economic facilities, can become
congested: A negative externality is imposed when one
party increases network traffic when the network is already
operating at capacity.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Network Runs Contagious?
Are BankIssues and Payment Systems

try developed a standard gauge through market forces at work over half a century, one analyst of the issue called for legislation to lead the
way in adopting one of the early gauges as a
standard. Puffert quotes an unsigned commentary from an 1832 issue of the American Railroad
Journal:
It is a matter of regret with many of the
friends of railroad improvements that no
measure has been taken to insure a uniform width of track. The advantages of
such uniformity must be perfectly
obvious...we are forced to conclude that
this discrepancy in the width of tracks will
ultimately produce an infinitude of vexation, transfers and delays which might
easily have been avoided.The establishment of a particular width, by statute, in
two or three of the principal States, would
probably have influence sufficient to produce the desired uniformity in most cases
throughout the United States.
This commentator suggests the advantage of
a mandatory, or legislated, standard. The “infinitude of vexation,” occasioned by differing
gauges, that persisted for decades could have
been avoided. The disadvantage of the mandatory approach is that the legislature may decide on an inferior gauge.
Today, many industries cooperate in setting
technical standards for products. For example,
checks, smart cards, ATM cards, credit cards,
and other components of the payment system
are all carefully designed to maintain compatibility among different network components
and providers of network services. The placement of information on the magnetic stripe on
cards, the encryption devices and codes, and
other technical standards must be common
among the parties to a card-based payment for
the system to operate. A cooperative industrysponsored approach to standardization can
achieve rapid adoption of standards while al-

James Ted Temzelides
J. McAndrews

lowing those with the greatest interests and
technical expertise to participate in setting the
standards.
This type of cooperation among firms that
are essentially supplying various components
of an integrated product must be distinguished
from collusion among competitors, which leads
to price fixing and other anticompetitive outcomes. The practical difficulty lies in correctly
identifying which type of cooperation is at
work.
Installed Base. Sometimes, a technology
used by an early leader in a network industry
can establish a dominance that gives it an advantage over alternative technologies in the
race for the industry standard. For example, the
gauge eventually set for American rails was the
early leader in number of miles of rail and the
one most often used in the more industrialized
Northeast and Midwest. This example reflects
the fact that, in network industries, a large installed base of network facilities has an inherent advantage over new technologies that might
otherwise satisfy consumer demand.7 A technology that wins an early lead can serve as a template for other competing technologies: Those
compatible with it have an advantage, and
those not compatible have a disadvantage.
Furthermore, a large installed base of network facilities can increase demand for a particular system. Consider the competition
among early telephone networks, which were
not interconnected. For example, in a city with
two telephone companies, the larger company
could offer its subscribers wider service, making it unnecessary for those subscribers to purchase both companies’ services. Hence, a large
group of existing users enhances a system’s
chances for success.
Color television provides another example
of the effect an installed base has on the pat-

7

Indeed, Puffert points out that railroad engineers are
still undecided on the technically preferred gauge.
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

tern by which people adopt a system. Early on,
color TV was available in competing formats.8
The first system approved by the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) in 1953 was
incompatible with black-and-white receivers,
and it never gained widespread acceptance.
Also in 1953, the FCC approved an alternative
system that was compatible with the existing
black-and-white television system, so that consumers could receive programs transmitted in
either format. Because local stations had to purchase expensive equipment to carry color programming, all programs
weren’t broadcast in color
until 1970. Had consumers been forced to choose
between keeping their
old sets or buying new
color sets—or owning
both—and receiving limited programming on
each system, the transition to color television
would most likely have
been delayed. This faster
transition to color TV was
accomplished at the cost of what some consider
to be a lower quality system than others that
were possible.
The influence that a large installed base has
on the success of a network product points to
the importance of three other common features
in network industries: low introductory pricing, the role of expectations, and leveraging a
firm’s dominance in one product to dominance
in another. All these potential business strategies reflect the explicitly dynamic (time-dependent) nature of network economics. The cur-

rent size of the installed base influences the
current demand for a service, but is itself the
result of past decisions of those who supply and
demand the service.
Low introductory pricing is a technique used
to build a large base of users quickly, and it’s a
common one among many firms in network
industries. If a firm succeeds in establishing its
brand quickly among a sizable base of users, it
has a good chance of charging higher prices to
later users, and the higher
prices will cover its costs.
The competition between
Netscape’s Navigator and
Microsoft’s Explorer, in
which both firms initially
gave away their Internet
browser, can be understood in this light.
The second feature related to an installed base
is the role of expectations.
When introducing new
products and marketing
existing ones, it’s important to create expectations
among current and potential consumers that the
product will have a large installed base, even if
it doesn’t at present. For example, advertising
for credit cards touts their ubiquity. Many
people are establishing e-mail accounts, since
e-mail is expected to become a permanent
means of communication. For competitive
firms, using false advertising and falsely undermining consumers’ expectations about a
rival’s products are techniques that can illegitimately affect market expectations.
The success of compact disc players shows
the importance of expectations. The widespread
adoption of CD technology happened quickly,
even though compact disc players were incompatible with the existing record technology and
in spite of the installed base of record players.
A key difference between the case of color TV

A well-established
network with a large
base of users can
extend a firm’s
dominance into
new products.

8
The article by Neil Gandal and Rafael Rob presents the
history of the adoption of color TV and compact disc players.

20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Network Issues and Payment Systems
Are Bank Runs Contagious?

and that of CDs is that the firms that developed
the compact disc player, Philips and Sony,
jointly operated the first two plants for producing compact discs, ensuring a steady supply of
discs for the players to use. Unlike the case with
TV, recording studios did not have to purchase
costly equipment to produce music for compact
discs. Hence, potential purchasers could expect
that virtually all recorded music soon would
be available on compact discs, whereas some
TV programs were produced and broadcast
only in black and white for almost 20 years after the introduction of color TV.
A well-established network with a large base
of users can extend a firm’s dominance into new
products. A firm that controls a network product can, in some cases, control the standard for
a complementary product by incorporating the
second product into its offering of the first. For
example, the maker of a dominant computer
operating system may incorporate more and
more “applications” software in each succeeding generation of the operating system software. This tactic essentially leverages the ability of the provider of network services to influence the market’s choice of new technologies.
In some cases, of course, the dominant firm does
so by offering the best possible second product, but this need not be the case. Indeed, by
limiting the ability of competitors to introduce
complementary (or next generation) products
that are compatible with current technology, the
dominant network’s provider can gain an advantage for its own complementary products
(which may be inferior to those sponsored by
competitors).
A more worrisome abuse of the power held
by a dominant network’s provider is tying the
sale of network services to ancillary products
that consumers would otherwise be able to buy
more cheaply from competing suppliers. In this
case, the dominant provider enjoys an advantage because of the large base of users. Alternative providers of network services cannot compete, since their small size makes their product

James J. McAndrews
Ted Temzelides

less valuable. Therefore, the dominant provider
can overcharge for ancillary services because
users will not defect to the alternative (smaller)
network.
In an anti-trust suit, the U.S. Department of
Justice accused Electronic Payment Services
(EPS), the operator of the MAC ATM network,
of tying the sale of ATM processing (an ancillary product) to the sale of ATM network access. In the 1994 consent decree, EPS agreed to
allow other processors to compete for that ancillary service.
Access. Once established, a network that has
a large base of users must determine which
firms will have access to its facilities, that is,
whether the network standard will be “open”
or “closed.” With an open standard, many firms
can design and sell products compatible with
the standard; a closed system limits the number of firms that can use the standard to sell
products. In the late 1970s and the early 1980s,
bank customers began to have access to their
deposit accounts through ATMs. Most of these
systems were proprietary and therefore closed.
In the mid 1980s, many banks struck agreements to share access to ATMs, thereby creating shared ATM networks—an open standard.
Successful networks can create a type of monopoly called bottlenecks or essential facilities.
By restricting access to such facilities, their
owners place competing producers of a service
at a significant competitive disadvantage. For
example, the Telecommunications Act of 1996
directed the FCC to establish the detailed conditions under which competitors to the “baby
Bells” could gain access to the local telephone
network’s lines and switches to provide telephone service. Without mandated access, a local phone network has little incentive to give
competing providers access to its facilities (even
at a cost). And without access to the local telephone network, the alternative provider would
have to build a large network facility to attract
a critical mass of users. By denying access to its
competitors, the local network enjoys a consid21

BUSINESS REVIEW

erable advantage over entrants into the market. Such bottleneck monopolies have been successfully challenged under the antitrust laws
of the United States.
APPLICATION TO PAYMENT SYSTEMS
Recognition of the network characteristics of
payment systems can yield insight into important public policy issues. To be successful, payment systems, which are technologies for the
exchange of value among participants, must
have wide acceptability. A card-based payment
product, whether a debit or credit card, requires
that consumers have the cards and that merchants have authorization terminals. These two
pieces of equipment are complementary, and
the more terminals that retailers deploy, the
more potential transactions are available to a
cardholder. Currency and coin, too, require a
network of facilities for reading, counting, and
sorting so that bills and coins can be accepted
at vending machines.
The failure of the Susan B. Anthony $1 coin
can be better understood once we recognize the
dominance of the network effects that support
the dollar bill. John Caskey and Simon St.
Laurent argue that the popular explanation for
the failure of the $1 coin—that it was poorly
designed because it was hard to distinguish it
from the quarter—is suspect. Although the Susan B. Anthony coin is similar to the quarter in
terms of its color, reeded edge, and thickness,
it weighs 43 percent more than a quarter, has
the same size relationship to the quarter as the
quarter has to the nickel, and has distinctly different engraving from the quarter. Instead of
design, Caskey and St. Laurent focused on network effects, primarily those involving vending machines. The $1 coin can make higher
value transactions easier in vending machines,
but only if vending machine owners spend the
resources necessary to convert their machines
to accept the coins. They will do so if they expect the public to use the coins. Likewise, the
public will use the coins if they expect them to
22

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

be widely accepted. Neither of these expectations was met with the Susan B. Anthony because the $1 note remained in circulation.
In Canada, the adoption of a $1 coin (with
some alternative design attributes—in particular, a gold color) was similarly met with a disappointing level of adoption, even though
Canada’s marketing campaign was much more
extensive than the one the United States used
for the Susan B. Anthony. However, the Bank
of Canada began withdrawing the $1 note, an
action that led vending machine companies to
rapidly convert their machines to accept the
coins. Today the $1 coin is the only circulating
dollar in Canada. This experience focuses attention on the installed base of note users (and
the machines and system by which the notes
are handled). A large installed base that favors
notes makes it difficult to influence expectations
that the coin will gain general acceptance. And
wide acceptance is needed for a coin to displace
a successful (although more costly) note.
ATM networks yield numerous examples of
the importance of network effects. Dennis
Carlton and Alan Frankel offer one example of
how compatibility can increase network output and convenience. They examine the output
effects of the merger of the two ATM networks
in Chicago—Cash Station and Money— in 1986.
They point out that such a merger can lead to
greater convenience and service because of the
complementarity of the network components:
the bank cards and ATMs. Carlton and Frankel
state, “As the number of participants and terminals on the network increases, consumers
might still be better off as a result of the increased network size and geographic density.
As the number of participants and terminals on
the network increases, consumers can rely more
on the network. The full cost of using ATM services, including search costs and the risk of being unable to find an operating terminal, might
have fallen even if some fees increased.”
Carlton and Frankel also show that the number of machines on the network and the numFEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Are Bank Runs Contagious?
Network Issues and Payment Systems

ber of transactions conducted by the network’s
members increased at more than double the
national rate in the first full year following the
merger. In addition, when the seven years following the merger are looked at as a whole, the
number of machines and number of transactions increased faster than the national rate as
well.
The merger of those two ATM networks
made the cards of almost any Chicago bank
compatible with any machine in the Chicago
area, and it resulted in a significant increase in
output, an outcome consistent with the theory
of network effects.9
The recent growth of the “off-line” debit
cards of Visa and MasterCard presents us with
an example of the importance of an installed
base of network facilities. The Visa and
MasterCard off-line debit cards, also called
check cards, can be used at the point-of-sale
(POS) to electronically debit the cardholder’s
deposit account. Other POS card systems,
known as “on-line” debit, are offered by the
regional ATM networks, such as MAC, Honor,
Star, and Pulse. The primary technical difference is that the on-line systems use a personal
identification number (PIN), and the transaction is routed to the cardholder’s bank for authorization; the off-line systems use a signature
rather than a PIN and are routed to Visa and
MasterCard for authorization. The off-line
transactions typically are settled with the
cardholder’s bank within a few days after the
transaction, while on-line systems typically
settle the same day as the transaction or the
following day.
The off-line systems have piggybacked on
the extensive system of credit card authorization devices in retail operations around the

9
My 1995 article points out similar effects after the partial merger, the so-called duality agreement, between the
two largest national networks, Plus and Cirrus, in 1991.

Ted Temzelides
James J. McAndrews

world. Visa and MasterCard have insisted that
retailers accept their check cards as long as they
accept their credit cards. Off-line systems thus
have a huge network with which their cards
are compatible, resulting in great convenience
for consumers.
In contrast, on-line systems have had to sell
their product retailer by retailer. The retailer
(who may already have a credit card authorization terminal) typically must purchase a PIN
pad. Furthermore, while the off-line systems are
accepted and have cardholders across the nation, each on-line ATM/POS system is accepted
and has cardholders from only a particular region of the country. This more limited acceptance of the cards reduces their desirability for
some retailers. By leveraging the widespread
acceptability of the credit card authorization
systems, the off-line cards quickly became the
more heavily used of the two systems.
Some retailers have challenged Visa and
MasterCard over their requirement that retailers must accept their check cards if they accept
their credit cards. In an antitrust lawsuit, they
allege that the credit card associations are guilty
of an illegal tying arrangement, using their
dominance in credit card acceptance to acquire
dominance in the debit card marketplace. The
check card transactions of Visa and MasterCard
typically carry a higher fee for the retailer than
do the on-line POS card transactions of the regional ATM/POS networks.
Another instance of the insight network economics can provide is in the continued dominance of the check for consumer bill payments
and business-to-business payments. Checks are
often derided as an inefficient means of payment compared with electronic alternatives.
Kirstin Wells estimates that the total cost to society of a check is roughly double that of an
automated clearinghouse payment.
Why haven’t individual businesses and
banks done more to convince check writers
(possibly through sharing the potential cost
savings) to move to electronic payment? The
23

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1997

answer, in part, has to do with the large installed
base of network facilities and business practices
that support the check. The paper invoice that
usually accompanies a check payment is universally accepted and understood. The current
electronic alternative, electronic data interchange, is used only by a relatively small group
of banks and firms. Until an electronic alternative to the paper invoice is widely available and
gains dominance, payment by check will remain relatively convenient. And its very convenience reduces the incentives for firms to
adopt an alternative system.
CONCLUSION
Networks have characteristics that create
distinct business-policy issues for the providers and consumers of network services, including compatibility, access to network facilities,

and the creation and exploitation of dominance
in the provision of network facilities.
The economics of networks is an important
advance in the economics of industrial organization, lending insight into important industries, including the payment system. In payment systems, the need for compatible facilities for the exchange of value gives rise to fundamental complementarities among system
facilities, which is the hallmark of network economics.
Our understanding of the failure of the Susan B. Anthony dollar coin, the success of the
off-line debit cards of Visa and MasterCard, the
superior convenience of merged ATM systems,
and the difficulty of replacing the check as a
dominant means of payment are all enhanced
by an understanding of network economics.

REFERENCES
Carlton, Dennis W., and Alan S. Frankel. “Antitrust and Payment Technologies,” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December 1995, pp. 41-54.
Caskey, John P., and Simon St. Laurent. “The Susan B. Anthony Dollar and the Theory of Coin/Note
Substitutions, Part 1” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, August 1994, pp. 495-510.
Dybvig, Philip H., and Chester H. Spatt. “Adoption Externalities as Public Goods,” Journal of Public
Economics, Vol. 20, 1983, pp. 231-47.
Economides, Nicholas. “The Economics of Networks,” International Journal of Industrial Organization,
Vol. 14, No. 6, October 1996, pp. 673-99.
Farrell, Joseph, and Garth Saloner. “Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product
Preannouncements, and Predation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, 1986, pp. 940-55.
Gandal, Neil, and Rafael Rob. “The Dynamics of Technological Adoption in Hardware/Software
Systems: The Chicken and Egg Problem,” mimeo, The University of Pennsylvania, September
1996.
Katz, Michael, and Carl Shapiro. “Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility,” American
Economic Review, Vol 75 (3), 1985, pp. 424-44.

24

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Network Runs Contagious?
Are BankIssues and Payment Systems

James Ted Temzelides
J. McAndrews

McAndrews, James J. “Commentary,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December 1995, pp. 55-59.
Puffert, Douglas J. The Economics of Spatial Network Externalities and the Dynamics of Railway Gauge
Standardization. Ph.D. Dissertation, Stanford University, March 1991, UMI Dissertation Information Service.
Rohlfs, Jeffrey. “A Theory of Interdependent Demand for a Communication Service,” Bell Journal of
Economics, 5, 1974, pp. 16-37.
Stover, John F. American Railroads. Chicago, 1961.
Taylor, George R., and Irene Neu. The American Railroad Network 1861-1890. Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1956.
Wells, Kirstin E. “Are Checks Overused?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
Fall 1996, pp. 2-12.

25