View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Unequal Subsidies
in Highway Investment:
What Are the
Consequences?

The U.S.
as a Debtor Country:
Causes, Prospects,
and Policy Implications

Richard Voith

Stephen A. Meyer




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

SPECIAL REPORT

The BUSINESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. It is
edited by Patricia Egner. Artwork is designed
and produced by Dianne Hallowell under the
direction of Ronald B. Williams. The views
expressed herein are not necessarily those of
this Reserve Bank or of the Federal Reserve
System.
SUBSCRIPTIONS. Single-copy subscriptions
for individuals are available without charge. Insti­
tutional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
BACK ISSUES. Back issues are available free of
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may
order up to 50 copies by submitting requests on
institutional letterhead; other orders are limited to 1
copy per request. Microform copies are available for
purchase from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb
Road, Ann Arbor, M I 48106.
REPRODUCTION. Permission must be ob­
tained to reprint portions of articles or whole ar­
ticles. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.
Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes of address, and requests to reprint to the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Department
of Research, Publications Desk, Ten Independence
Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574, or telephone
(215) 574-6428. Please direct editorial communi­
cations to the same address, or telephone (215) 5743805.


2


THE NEW THRIFT ACT: MENDING
THE SAFETY NET
Richard W. Eang and Timothy G. Schiller
Signed into law this p ast A u gu st, the

FIRRE Act will mean dramatic changes
for S&Ls and banks alike, while reinforc­
ing the "federal safety net" for deposi­
tors.
UNEQUAL SUBSIDIES IN HIGHWAY
INVESTMENT: WHAT ARE THE
CONSEQUENCES?
Richard Voith
A new highway may be highly subsi­
dized, but a good investment nonetheless
if the time savings to motorists and the
net benefits to the community are greater
than the subsidy. But who ends up pay­
ing for the investment?
THE U.S. AS A DEBTOR COUNTRY:
CAUSES, PROSPECTS, AND POLICY
IMPLICATIONS
Stephen A. Meyer
Having a large and growing foreign debt
has reversed our status from that of net
creditor to net debtor. Will this debt
mean lowered living standards for future
generations? And will higher inflation
necessarily result?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The New Thrift Act:
Mending the Safety Net
Richard W. Lang and Timothy G. Schiller*
When the Federal Reserve Banks opened
their doors on November 16,1914, the nation's
financial system was on the threshold of his­
toric change. Seventy-five years later, it faces
dramatic change again. The new Financial
Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforce­

*Richard W. Lang is Senior Vice President and Director
of Research at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
Timothy G. Schiller is the Research Department's Coordina­
tor of Technical Support.




ment Act, designed to mend the federal safety
net for depositors, will not only restructure the
thrift industry, but alter the banking industry
as well.
Weaving the Safety Net
Just as the new legislation is intended to
stem a crisis in the financial industry, the Fed­
eral Reserve Act was a response to the financial
panics of the late 19th and early 20th centuries.
Wanting banks to be able to meet liquidity
crises, Congress created the Federal Reserve
System in 1913. The 12 Federal Reserve Banks,
3

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

BUSINESS REVIEW

which opened less than a year later, were au­
thorized to hold reserves for member banks in
their districts and to lend to them for short
periods. For member banks experiencing short­
term liquidity problems, the Federal Reserve
was to be the lender of last resort—the first
piece of the "federal safety net."
With the Great Depression and the numer­

ance and bank powers. Many legislators be­
lieved that the 1929 stock market crash, the
widespread bank failures that followed, and
the onset of the Depression were all tied to
abuses of the connections permitted between
investment banking and commercial banking.
Congress passed the Banking Act of 1933 to
1) separate commercial banking from securi­

ous bank failu res o f the early 1930s, C o n g ress's

ties underw riting and 2) insure deposits. Popu­

attention turned to two issues: deposit insur­

larly known as the Glass-Steagall Act (named

Old Regulatory Structure
Treasury Department
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
— Charters national banks
— Supervises and regulates national banks

FDIC
— Insures deposits at commercial and savings banks
— Manages assets and liabilities of insolvent banks
— Supervises and regulates state-chartered banks that are not members of the Federal
Reserve System

Federal Home Loan Bank Board
—
—
—
—

Charters federal S&Ls
Regulates and supervises federal S&Ls
Oversees the FSLIC
Oversees the 12 regional Federal Home Loan Banks

FSLIC
— Insures deposits at S&Ls
— Manages assets and liabilities of insolvent S&Ls
Federal Home Loan Banks
— Lend (make advances) to member S&Ls
— Examine S&Ls

Federal Reserve
— Supervises and regulates state-chartered member banks, bank holding companies and their
nonbank subsidiaries, the international activities of banks and bank holding companies,
and the U.S. banking and nonbanking operations of foreign banks
— Sets reserve requirements for all banks, S&Ls, and credit unions
— Through the 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks, provides discount-window loans to
depository institutions


4


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The New Thrift Act: Mending the Safety Net

Richard W. Lang & Timothy G. Schiller

New Regulatory Structure
Treasury Department
Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
— No major change in duties
Office of Thrift Supervision
— Charters federal S&Ls
— Establishes S&L regulations
— Supervises both federal and state-chartered S&Ls, and S&L holding companies

FDIC
— FDIC's Board of Directors expanded from 3 to 5 members and will include the
Director of the Office of Thrift Supervision
Bank Insurance Fund (BIF — same as original FDIC fund)
— Insures deposits of commercial and savings banks
— Manages assets and liabilities of insolvent banks
Savings Association Insurance Fund (SAIF — replaces FSLIC)
— Insures deposits of S&Ls
— Manages assets and liabilities of insolvent S&Ls after 1992
FSLIC Resolution Fund
— Manages the remaining assets and liabilities of some 200 S&Ls taken over by the
FSLIC prior to 1989
R esolution Trust O versight Board

— Oversees the Resolution Trust Corporation
— Chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury. Includes the Federal Reserve Board Chairman,
the Secretary of Housing and Urban Development, and two others appointed by the
President
Resolution Trust Corporation (managed by the FDIC)
— Manages the assets and liabilities of S&Ls that become insolvent between 1989
and August 1992
— Can use $50 billion that will be raised by the Treasury and the Resolution Funding
Corporation to resolve S&L problems
— Ceases to operate after 1996, when its responsibilities are shifted to the FDIC's Savings
Association Insurance Fund
Resolution Funding Corporation
— Issues up to $30 billion of long-term bonds to finance the activities of the Resolution Trust
Corporation

Federal Housing Finance Board
— Oversees the 12 regional Federal Home Loan Banks
Federal Home Loan Banks
— Lend (make advances) to member institutions, which may include banks and credit unions
as well as S&Ls

Federal Reserve
— No major change in duties




5

BUSINESS REVIEW

after its sponsors), the new law banned secur­
ities underwriting by national banks and
deposit-taking by securities underwriters.
Concern about the losses incurred by de­
positors led Congress to include in this law a
section establishing the Federal Deposit Insur­
ance Corporation. The FDIC insured bank
deposits up to $5,000, with initial funds pro­
vided by the Treasury and the Federal Reserve
Banks. The law provided for ongoing funding
of the FDIC by assessing each bank a premium
based on the amount of its insured deposits. By
1935, about 98 percent of all commercial bank
deposits in the country were insured.
Savings and loan associations were not left
out of the safety net. The Federal Home Loan
Bank Act of 1932 established a regional system
of Home Loan Banks to issue bonds and use the
proceeds to supply liquidity to S&Ls by mak­
ing loans (advances) to them. Congress fol­
lowed with deposit insurance for S&Ls that
were members of the FHLB System, creating
the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Cor­
poration in 1934. Like the FDIC, both the
Federal Home Loan Banks and the FSLIC ini­
tially received funds from the Treasury, but
eventually became self-financing.
Extending the Safety Net
Deposit insurance for both banks and thrifts
was raised to $20,000 per depositor in 1969,
and failures were rare. Indeed, Rep. Wright
Patman, then Chairman of the House Banking
Committee, wondered publicly whether the
low incidence of failures indicated that regula­
tors were preserving banks by preventing
competition.
The FDIC did try to keep most banking
offices open— not to prevent competition, but
to protect depositors and reduce costs to the
insurance fund. Under the purchase-andassumption method of dealing with failing banks,
the FDIC provided financial assistance to a
healthy bank that purchased the assets and
assumed the liabilities of a failing bank. In­
Digitized for 6FRASER


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

stead of closing the bank and paying off only
insured depositors, the FDIC effectively pro­
tected all depositors. The FSLIC took a similar
approach.
Over time, the limit on deposit-insurance
coverage was increased—to $40,000 in 1974
and to its current level of $100,000 by the De­
pository Institutions Deregulation and Mone­
tary Control Act of 1980. This Act also made
the Fed's discount-window lending available
to all banks, S&Ls, and credit unions having
transactions accounts or nonpersonal time
deposits, and levied reserve requirements on
these same institutions.
Mending the Safety Net
During the 1980s the number of bank fail­
ures and insolvent thrifts increased sharply.
Earnings problems for S&Ls had begun in the
late 1970s, when inflation drove short-term
interest rates and S&Ls' cost of funds above the
interest rates these institutions were earning
on their portfolios of mortgages. These prob­
lems continued in the 1980s, even after infla­
tion and interest rates subsided, because S&Ls'
cost of funds still remained high compared to
their low-yielding, long-term mortgages. The
deregulation of deposit interest rates and the
expansion of S&Ls' powers into such areas as
direct real estate investments, commercial lend­
ing, and high-yield junk bonds did not reverse
the deteriorating trend for S&L losses as some
had hoped. Also, problems with agricultural
and energy loans caused losses for both banks
and thrifts in several regions of the country.
And as the energy sector continued to deterio­
rate in the Southwest, real estate values in the
area plunged, adding to loan losses.
Because deposit-insurance premiums are
assessed at a flat rate based only on the level of
an institution's deposits, not on the riskiness of
the bank or S&L, the deposit-insurance system
did not provide an incentive for a troubled
institution to avoid risk. In fact, since regula­
tors followed a policy of "forbearance" in the
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The New Thrift Act: Mending the Safety Net

early 1980s by not enforcing strict capital re­
quirements on many troubled S&Ls, there was
actually an incentive for these institutions to
take on more risk. A risky venture might pay
off and bolster earnings. If it didn't, the de­
posit-insurance fund would be the one taking
the loss.
Estimated losses at the insolvent thrifts
eventually outstripped the size of the FSLIC's
resources. The FSLIC's inability to meet its
liabilities, as well as the first-ever operating
loss for the FDIC in 1988, challenged the viabil­
ity of the deposit-insurance system. In 1987,
Congress passed a $10.8 billion recapitaliza­
tion of the FSLIC, but this amount proved
inadequate to handle mounting thrift in­
solvencies. In February 1989 the Administra­
tion proposed major legislation to deal with the
S&L problem, and President Bush signed the
Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and
Enforcement Act (FIRREA) in August. The
new Act:
1. Provides funding for the regulatory authorities
to sell or close insolvent S&Ls. Managed by the
FDIC, the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC)
will receive $50 billion to close or sell ailing
S&Ls: $20 billion borrowed by the Treasury
and $30 billion borrowed by the Resolution
Funding Corporation, the financing arm of
the RTC. The total cost over 10 years for
closing or selling all insolvent S&Ls (includ­
ing interest on borrowed funds) is estimated
by several analysts to be over $160 billion,
with the majority of the cost being paid by
the government.
2. Restructures and strengthens the deposit-insur­
ance funds for both S&Ls and banks. The FSLIC
is replaced by the Savings Association In­
surance Fund (SAIF), now under the FDIC's
control. The banks' insurance fund is re­
named the Bank Insurance Fund (BIF), sepa­
rate from the SAIF. Deposit-insurance pre­
miums for both S&Ls and banks are raised



Richard W. Lang & Timothy G. Schiller

from their current levels, with S&Ls' premi­
ums higher than banks' until 1998. These
increases are expected to replenish the two
insurance funds over the next 10 years.
3. Restructures the regulatory framework of the
financial system. The Act abolishes the Fed­
eral Home Loan Bank Board. Its job of
setting regulations and chartering federal
S&Ls will be performed by the new Office of
Thrift Supervision (OTS), which will be part
of the Treasury. The regional Federal Home
Loan Banks will be managed by a new agency,
the Federal Housing Finance Board, whose
members will include the Secretary of Hous­
ing and Urban Development. S&L examina­
tions will be handled by the OTS rather than
the FHLBs. As with banks, S&Ls' chartering
and deposit insurance now will be regulated
by separate agencies.
4. Tightens restrictions on S&Ls' activities and
raises their capital standards to increase the
thrift industry's safety and soundness. Capital
standards for S&Ls will be raised to levels
no less stringent than those for national
banks. The Act also tightens restrictions on
S&Ls' lending and investments—including
investments in junk bonds, the size of loans
made to one borrower, the extent of transac­
tions with affiliates, the equity investments
that can be made by state-chartered S&Ls,
and the use of brokered deposits by S&Ls
not meeting the new capital standards.
5. Encourages S&Ls to focus on their more tradi­
tional role as mortgage lenders. In addition to
tightening the restrictions on S&Ls' activi­
ties, the Act redefines "qualified thrift lender"
as one holding 70 percent or more of its port­
folio in housing-related assets. These assets
include mortgage loans, home-equity loans,
and mortgage-backed securities. This QTL
provision takes effect on July 1, 1991; until
then, the current 60 percent QTL test ap­
7

BUSINESS REVIEW

plies. If an S&L fails to meet the QTL test, it
will be ineligible for further advances from
FHL Banks and will be subject to bank-like
restrictions. If it then fails to meet the QTL
test within three years, it must repay its
FHLB advances.
6. Reduces the differences in regulatory treatment
of S&Ls and banks. The structure of their
regulatory agencies is now similar, and even­
tually so will be their insurance premiums,
capital standards, and supervisory treat­
ment. S&Ls now may take demand deposits
from any commercial business, just as banks
do. Banks and credit unions can become
members of the Federal Home Loan Bank
System and obtain advances from the FHL
Banks if they have invested 10 percent of
their assets in residential mortgage loans,
although FHLBs must give preference to
members meeting the QTL test. The Federal
Reserve is directed to permit bank holding
companies to acquire healthy S&Ls. And an
S&L may convert to a bank charter or be
merged with a bank subsidiary of a holding
company, although there are exit and entry
fees that must be paid to switch deposit
insurance from SAIF to BIF.
7. Increases the enforcement powers of the regula­
tory agencies and the penalties for banking-law
violations. For its costs of closing a failed or
failing insured institution, the FDIC can obtain
reimbursements from other insured institu­
tions owned by the same parent company; it
also is empowered to act more swiftly in
suspending or revoking an institution's
deposit insurance. Regulators are given
more leeway in issuing cease-and-desist
orders to banks and S&Ls. Civil and crimi­
nal penalties for violating banking laws are
increased and may be applied to a broader
range of individuals involved with deposi­
tory institutions.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

8. Encourages the development of low-income
housing and strengthens the Community Rein­
vestment Act's role in the banking and S&L
industries. Regulatory agencies' evaluations
of CRA performance by banks and S&Ls
must be made public. The Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act now covers all mortgage
lenders with assets of more than $10 million
and requires expanded reporting of com­
pleted applications by income, race, and
sex. Each FHL Bank must establish a pro­
gram to provide funding to member institu­
tions for CRA-type activities, and subsi­
dized funding for low-income housing. In
two years, FHLB advances will be made
only if borrowing institutions meet certain
community investment standards established
by the Federal Housing Finance Board.
The new Act will mean dramatic changes for
the financial industry, affecting S&Ls and banks
alike. As the Resolution Trust Corporation
sells or closes sick thrifts, more consolidation
of firms will occur, reinforcing a trend for S&Ls
and banks already begun by increased compe­
tition and expanded interstate banking.
While the FIRREA makes major changes in
the safety net, Congress still plans to examine
the net more closely. In particular, Congress
held initial hearings in September on one of the
major unresolved issues in the pricing of de­
posit insurance: whether the current system of
flat-rate deposit-insurance premiums should
be changed to one that takes into account the
different levels of risk each bank or thrift im­
poses on the deposit-insurance funds. The
FIRREA also requires the FDIC and the Treas­
ury to study the feasibility of risk-based premi­
ums and to report back to Congress within 18
months of FIRREA's enactment. If the practi­
cal difficulties of designing risk-based depositinsurance premiums can be overcome, such
premiums would be one way in which the
safety net could be reinforced further.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Unequal Subsidies
in Highway Investment:
What Are the Consequences?
Richard Voith*
The automobile's rise to dominance has
changed the face of virtually every metropoli­
tan area in the United States. With automobiles
came highways that dramatically extended the
boundaries of attractive places to live and work.
For people with cars, it was no longer necessary
to live in the city in order to work there, and
increasingly, businesses found it advantageous
to locate in less congested suburban areas as

* Richard Voith is a Senior Economist in the Urban
and Regional Section of the Philadelphia Fed's Research
Department.




well. Thus, people and jobs have become more
dispersed throughout metropolitan areas, of­
ten following developments in the highway
transportation system.
The way for ubiquitous automobile travel
and for attendant changes in regional develop­
ment was paved not just by expenditures on
cars and trucks, but also by billions of dollars of
public investment in the highway transporta­
tion system. This public investment has been
financed, in part, by taxes levied on motorists
using the highway. These taxes, or "user fees,"
are the prices motorists pay to use the highway
system.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

BUSINESS REVIEW

User fees, however, fail to cover the high­
way system's total construction, maintenance,
and operating costs. Nearly $454 billion in
general tax revenues has supplemented high­
way user fees in the 1956-86 period, represent­
ing about 32 percent of the total investment.1
The share of total highway expenditures cov­
ered by user fees has fluctuated considerably
over the period and in 1986 stood at 61 percent
(see graph below). Though user fees cover
about 68 percent of the highway system's costs
on average, the degree of subsidy for a particu­
lar highway may be considerably more (or less)
than the average. And the price a motorist
pays to use a highway often diverges from the
actual cost he imposes, contributing to high­

way congestion and inefficient patterns of
regional development.
Highway subsidies not only foster increased
travel and congestion, but they change the rela­
tive attractiveness of localities within a metro­
politan area. An area traversed by a new
highway tends to become more attractive be­
cause its transportation is improved without
the residents, who get to use the highway,
having to bear the full costs of the construction.
Some localities will benefit economically from
highway subsidies, but others, especially the
older, more densely populated city centers,
may suffer.

WHAT SHOULD THE MOTORIST PAY?
Encouraged by low user fees, more motor­
ists are traveling longer distances than ever
f ig u r e s are in 1986 constant dollars. In 1986, highway
before. According to U.S. Census figures, the
subsidies were $24.5 billion, or 39 percent of the total pub­
percentage of work-commuting trips by car
lic expenditure. Calculated from Highway Statistics (annual
increased from 69.5 percent in 1960 to 85.9
series, 1956-87), U.S. Department of Transportation, Fed­
percent in 1980, and the average length of a
eral Highway Administration, Table HF-10.
commuting trip in­
creased 18 percent
between 1975 and 1980.
The bulk of the increase
User Fees as a Percentage
in travel has occurred
of Total Expenditures
in suburb-to-suburb
and suburb-to-city
commuting, up 58
percent and 25 percent,
respectively.2
The
increase in suburban
travel is straining the
capacity of the high­
ways that initially fos-




1986

2These data are com ­
piled in Commuting in Amer­
ica, by Alan Pisarski, Eno
Foundation For Transporta­
tion, W estport, CT (1987).
The analysis is based on
data from the U.S. Bureau of
the Census.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Unequal Subsidies in Highway Investment

tered the suburban development. Is this level
of auto travel, and the associated geographic
dispersion, a good use of our resources?
According to economic theory, individuals'
transportation and location decisions would
be efficient if the price paid for transportation
closely matched the costs imposed by the user.3
Though motorists do not pay a fee directly
every time they use a highway, they do pay fees
that are indirectly related to their use of the
highway system.4 The federal Highway Trust
Fund was established in 1956 to finance con­
struction of highways, using revenues from a
tax on gasoline and, to a lesser extent, from
other automobile-related taxes.5 The tax on
gasoline, a user fee, is essentially the price
motorists pay to use the highway system.
General governmental tax revenues augment
highway expenditures, since the revenues from
gasoline taxes have been insufficient to cover
the capital, maintenance, and administration
costs of highway use.6

3For discussion of the economic theory of highway pric­
ing, see Theodore E. Keeler and Kenneth A. Small, "Optimal
Peak-Load Pricing, Investment, and Service Levels on Ur­
ban Expressw ays," Journal of Political Economy (1977) pp. 125.
4Toll roads are an exception. Current federal regula­
tions prohibit tolls on virtually all roads built with federal
aid. There are, however, nine pilot projects that are federalaid toll roads. See Michael Deitch, New Directions of the
Nation's Public Works, Congressional Budget Office (Sep­
tember 1988).
5The federal government actually started taxing gaso­
line in 1932, but the funds were not earmarked specifically
for highway expenditures. Federal expenditures on high­
ways tracked gas-tax revenues fairly closely during the
1932-55 period. States taxed gasoline for highway expendi­
tures much earlier than the federal government; as early as
1916, nearly 30 percent of states' highway expenditures
came from gas-tax revenues. See Michael Deitch, New
Directions o f the Nation's Public Works, Congressional Budget
Office (September 1988).
6State and local governments contribute most of the non­
user-fee revenue for highway expenditures.




Richard Voith

The Costs of Highway Use. Motorists im­
pose two primary types of costs: infrastructure
costs and congestion costs. Infrastructure costs
include the costs of constructing, maintaining,
and operating the highways. Congestion costs
include time lost waiting in traffic, increased
pollution, and reduced fuel efficiency. These
are the costs one motorist imposes on another
by competing for the same highway infrastruc­
ture. Adding another car on an already crowded
road may result in slow travel not only for that
car but for all others on the road.7 Infrastruc­
ture and congestion costs are related, as con­
gestion costs can be reduced in the short run by
more infrastructure investment. Alternatively,
user fees can be raised to reflect congestion
costs, reducing the demand for car travel and
hence the need for additional highways.
The costs of highway use— infrastructure
and congestion—often diverge from the prices
motorists pay through user fees, for three rea­
sons. The most obvious reason is that total user
fees are insufficient to cover the infrastructure
cost of the highway system. The second reason
is that while the federal government collects
user fees from all motorists, many of the expen­
ditures from the Highway Trust Fund are
concentrated on projects that only a fraction of
all motorists use.8 Often, the user fees gener-

7Estimates of the costs of congestion are as high as $5.6
billion per year (in 1981). See Steven A. Morrison, "A Survey
of Road Pricing," Transportation Research 20A (1986) pp. 8797.
8In theory, the federal portion of the gasoline tax should
be used to promote interstate mobility for all U.S. citizens,
while state and local user fees should cover intrastate and
intrametropolitan highway investment. In practice, how­
ever, the federal government's highway investments have
large effects on local comm uting and development pat­
terns, since the Highway Trust Fund provides up to 90
percent of the funds for state and local highway capital
projects. Thus, some federal expenditures have primarily
local effects even though they are paid for by the motorist at
large. A similar problem occurs at the state level, though
less severely since states spend their user fees at home.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

ated from these particular projects cover only a
small part of their infrastructure cost. The
third reason prices and costs diverge is that not
all motorists impose the same costs. Motorists
traveling at peak times impose greater costs
than those traveling at off-peak times. Taken
together, rush-hour highway users cause higher
infrastructure costs because additional lanes
are needed to accommodate them. If peak
highway capacity is inadequate, rush-hour
motorists are likely to impose high congestion
costs on one another. Yet, the price that rushhour motorists pay in user fees is almost the
same that off-peak motorists pay. Each of the
three reasons for the divergence of prices and
costs is easily illustrated.
A Hypothetical Example. Suppose there
are only two cities in the country, Taxtown and
Spendville. Taxtown is an older, compact city
with little open space. Spendville is far less
concentrated, with an abundance of inexpen­
sive open land. Both cities have severe prob­
lems with rush-hour congestion; the costs of
this congestion in lost time and economic activ­
ity are $40 million for each city. Because of the
availability of inexpensive land in Spendville,
it is possible to build a highway there for $30
million that, in the short run, will eliminate the
congestion. In Taxtown, the lack of land and
dense population drive the construction cost of
a new highway up to $50 million. Motorists in
Taxtown and Spendville contribute $20 mil­
lion, $10 million from each city, to the national
Highway Trust Fund through user fees; conse­
quently, neither city can pay for congestionreducing investments from user fees at their
current level.
From a social point of view, the highway in
Spendville should be built, since its benefits
will exceed its costs. That is, the benefits of
reduced congestion ($40 million) exceed the
cost of highway construction ($30 million). The
highway in Taxtown should not be built, since
the construction cost ($50 million) exceeds the
benefit ($40 million). Under the current system
12FRASER
Digitized for


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

of financing, user fees from Spendville and
Taxtown ($20 million, by way of the national
Highway Trust Fund) would be allocated to
build the highway in Spendville. (The transfer
of funds from Taxtown to Spendville is called
a cross-subsidy.) Moreover, an additional $10
million in general tax revenue would be re­
quired to build the Spendville highway. (This
additional $10 million in general tax revenue is
a non-user-fee subsidy.)9
The subsidies for Spendville's highway
provided by the general taxpayer and the
motorists in Taxtown affect more than just
Spendville's transportation system. Because
two-thirds of the cost of Spendville's highway
investment is subsidized, it is likely to be a
more attractive place to live and work, as its
transportation has been improved without its
residents having to bear the full cost. Addi­
tionally, the highway subsidies would encour­
age more geographic dispersion in Spendville
and, in the long run, more travel that would
partly offset the benefits of increased highway
capacity.
The residents of Taxtown, on the other hand,
still pay user fees but derive no benefit from the
highway investment. From a social perspec­
tive, it would be both more equitable and more
efficient to increase user fees in Spendville by
$20 million and eliminate the general revenue
subsidy and the cross-subsidy.10
The Importance of Fine-Tuning User Fees.
Now let's examine some possible consequences
9The actual distribution of federal highway funds is
quite complex. Some highway trust funds are allocated by
formula, while others, including the interstate highway sys­
tem, are allocated on a project-by-project basis.
10Note that there may be instances when it is more
efficient for cities to jointly fund a project— if the project has
benefits for both cities. Additionally, sometimes projects
should be funded from general revenues. If the overall
benefits of a project outweigh what users are willing to pay
because of positive externalities, there is a good rationale for
subsidies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Unequal Subsidies in Highway Investment

of increasing user fees in Spendville. Just in­
creasing user fees to cover the costs of the new
highway would likely reduce the demand for
highway travel and, hence, reduce congestion.
With the reduced travel, a less ambitious, less
expensive new highway might suffice to elimi­
nate the remaining congestion. Now suppose
that user fees are increased only for rush-hour
motorists, since these motorists impose the
highest costs. This would reduce travel de­
mand when its costs are highest, partly by
shifting travel to periods when the road is
underused. The reduction in peak travel would
lessen the need for new highway construction
while keeping user fees low for those motorists
imposing only small costs.
But what of the congestion in Taxtown?
Suppose congestion in Taxtown could be elimi­
nated by improved public transportation cost­
ing $35 million. This investment in public
transportation improvement should be made,
since the benefits of reduced automobile con­
gestion ($40 million) outweigh the costs of
improved public transportation ($35 million).
However, highway user fees probably would
not be used for public transportation invest­
ment, even though it is socially desirable.11
Financing for public transportation would have
to come from a combination of public-transit
user fees and general revenue subsidies, even
though automobile users directly benefit be­
cause overall congestion would be reduced.12*
It would be more efficient to increase highway
user fees and invest them in public transporta­
tion than either build the highway for $50
11Highway user fees are generally earmarked solely for
highway investments, though there are some exceptions.
For example, 1 cent of the 1982 5-cent hike in federal gaso­
line taxes is dedicated to public transportation. See the
Highway Revenue Act of 1982.
12The only justification for subsidizing public transpor­
tation in this case is that it benefits riders and motorists
alike. If no benefits accrued to nonriders, it would not be
efficient to subsidize public transportation.




Richard Voith

million or do nothing and endure the conges­
tion cost. In this case, limiting the use of
motorists' user fees to highway investments is
against the interest of the motorist.
By fine-tuning user fees to more accurately
reflect the costs imposed, and by investing user
fees where they make the greatest contribution
to mobility, it is possible to reduce congestion
and the quantity of new infrastructure needed.
In our example, Spendville might be able to
have both low average user fees and low con­
gestion without subsidies from general tax­
payers and cross-subsidies from motorists in
Taxtown. Taxtown's residents would be better
off raising user fees and investing in public
transportation. In either case, if pricing is
ignored, new highways designed to reduce
congestion are bound to become congested
themselves, since the low price will attract
users until congestion costs offset the benefits.
DISTORTIONS DUE
TO UNEQUAL SUBSIDIES
While the example of Taxtown and Spendville
is purely hypothetical, it mirrors what actually
occurs in the pricing of and investment in our
highway system. The extent to which travel
and location decisions are distorted from the
most efficient ones depends, in part, on how far
prices diverge from the true costs of highway
use. The degree to which the highway user is
subsidized on average will affect the attrac­
tiveness of the automobile relative to other
transportation alternatives, as well as the level
of total travel and, in the long run, the extent of
geographic dispersion. Unequal subsidies for
individual highway projects will distort the
relative attractiveness of locations for indi­
viduals and businesses, regardless of the aver­
age level of subsidy. Thus when examining the
extent of highway subsidies, it is useful to go
beyond their average level and examine those
for individual highway projects.
Individual Highway Subsidies. Subsidies
for individual highways may differ widely
13

BUSINESS REVIEW

from the average subsidy. It is not necessarily
true that users of any particular highway will
pay the 1986 average of 61 percent of highway
infrastructure costs. Some areas will generate
more user fees than are spent, while others will
spend more than are generated. Just as in
Taxtown and Spendville, those making use of
highway investment may not be financing the
total investment through user fees.
For any project, several factors affect the
share of the infrastructure costs covered by
highway user fees. On the cost side, expenses
increase with the number of lanes needed, the
quality of the roadway, the cost of acquiring
land, and the complexity of the project. For
example, expressways through densely popu­
lated urban areas often are complex and have
high land-acquisition costs. In the case of new
highways, costs are often higher as special
amenities, such as sound barriers, are built into
the design of the highway to minimize its nega­
tive impacts on the communities it passes
through.13 On the revenue side, user fees in­
crease proportionately with travel so that the
most heavily traveled roads generate the most
revenue. Urban highways thus tend to gener­
ate more user fees than rural expressways.
The subsidy level for any particular project
depends on the interaction of factors affecting
costs and revenues. A rural highway may be
relatively inexpensive to construct but traffic
may be low, resulting in low user fees, and
hence the highway may be heavily subsidized.
The pattern of traffic demand affects the level
of subsidy for a project in another way. Peak
travel levels determine the number of lanes
needed for a highway and hence the cost, but
the total user fees depend only on total traffic.

13Some claim that the costs of these amenities often out­
weigh the environmental benefits. See Jose A. GomezIbanez, "The Federal Role in Urban Transportation," in
American Domestic Priorities, John M. Quigley and Daniel L.
Rubinfeld, eds., University of California Press, Berkeley
(1985) p. 205.

14FRASER
Digitized for


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

So if traffic is very heavy at rush hours but light
at other times during the day, the highway
built for heavy peak traffic will require higher
subsidies than if demand were smooth through­
out the day.
Some Real-World Examples. To get a handle
on the extent to which user fees and highway
infrastructure costs diverge, we examined 13
major highway construction projects— six in
Pennsylvania, six in Maryland, and one in New
Jersey. (See Tables 1 and 2 for a description of
each project, listed in order from the most
highly subsidized on a per-car basis to the least
subsidized.) The projects, ranging in cost from
$97 million to $581 million, include completely
new highways and reconstructions of existing
highways. The cost per mile of construction
varies widely, from a low of $6.8 million per
mile to a high of $133.3 million per mile. For all
but one project, current and future travel levels
are shown in Table 1.u The current daily usage
varies from 9,200 cars per day to 127,600 cars
per day. The projected daily usage ranges from
26,000 to 133,800 cars per day.
For each project, yearly costs, yearly userfee revenue, and subsidy have been calculated
and are shown in Table 2.1415 (For method of cal-

14The current levels refer either to the number of cars per
day using the highway when it is initially opened, or, if it is
a reconstruction or expansion, to the traffic level prior to the
project. The projected level of travel is the number of cars
per day expected by the states' departments of transporta­
tion when the transportation and land-use patterns have
evolved around the highway. The years in which the
projected travel levels are reached are not the same for each
project.
15The cost figures include only the opportunity cost of
capital and depreciation, and no allowance for mainte­
nance, law enforcement, administration, or externalities
such as pollution and personal injury from highway acci­
dents. The revenue figures include only gasoline taxes, both
state and federal, and assume that, without the investment,
there would be zero user-fee revenue. On balance, the
estimates of subsidy (costs-revenue) are likely to be under­
estimated.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Richard Voith

Unequal Subsidies in Highway Investment

TABLE 1

Project
Blue
US48
US220
1279
178
197
MD100
Vine
RTE29
168
US50
168
176

State
PA
MD
PA
PA
PA
MD
MD
PA
NJ
MD
MD
MD
PA

Urban,
Suburban,
or Rural

Capital
Cost
($ million)

Suburban
Rural
Rural
Urban
Urb/Suburban
Suburban
Suburban
Urban
Suburban
Suburban
Suburban
Suburban
Urb/Suburban

581
202
97
405
384
364
197
200
253
204
103
158
200

Miles

Current
Cars Per
Day

Projected
Cars Per
Day

21.5
22.1
11.0
16.0
30.0
20.9
12.4
1.5
13.5
10.2
15.2
9.8
17.7

64,000
9,200
17,000
45,000
35,000
43,822
21,581
70,000
86,667
75,229
28,923
46,510
127,600

75,000
26,000
NA*
74,000
64,000
72,597
49,935
120,000
131,185
105,490
47,148
89,176
133,800

Notes: Gas tax (state + federal in $ /g a l): M aryland=.275; Pennsylvania=.21; New Jersey=.195; U.S.=.9. Quarterly
Summary of Federal, State, and Local Tax Revenue, Bureau of the Census, GT-88-Q3.
Sources: State Report on Transportation Vol. II, Maryland Department of Transportation, FY1988 - FY1993; New Jersey
State Department of Transportation (Regional Office); Pennsylvania State Department of Transportation (Regional
Offices).
^Projected value not available.

culation, see Calculating Cost and Revenues, p.l7.)
According to these calculations, none of the
projects generates sufficient user fees to cover
the infrastructure investment. In fact, based on
the current travel-usage figures, user fees cover
54 percent of the investment at best and 2.5
percent at worst. On a per-car basis, the sub­
sidy ranges from $0.16 to $4.50 for every car
using the highway. On a vehicle-mile-traveled
basis, the subsidy ranges from less than 1 cent
per vehicle mile to 41 cents per vehicle mile.
Based on projected travel, these figures range
from 0.8 cents to 23 cents per vehicle mile.16 All
16These figures do not take into account the higher sub­
sidies accruing in years prior to the traffic reaching the pro­
jected level.




of these highway projects are very highly
subsidized— some because their costs of con­
struction are very high and others because the
total travel, and hence user fees, is low.
Three Philadelphia-area Projects. Let's take
a closer look at three projects, all in the Phila­
delphia metropolitan area. The most expen­
sive project—1476, commonly known as the
Blue Route—is a completely new highway cut­
ting through suburban Philadelphia. This high­
way is highly subsidized, by over $41 million
per year (8 cents per vehicle mile traveled, or
$1.47 per car), because it has a relatively high
construction cost on a per-mile basis ($27 mil­
lion per mile) and because the traffic level
(75,000 cars per day) is not that high. The most
expensive project on a per-mile basis is the Vine
15

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

BUSINESS REVIEW

TABLE 2

Project
Blue
US48
US220
1279
178
197
MD100
Vine
RTE29
168
US50
168
176

Yearly GasTax Revenue
($ million)
Current Projected
5.27
1.02
0.72
2.76
4.02
4.60
1.34
0.40
4.16
3.85
2.21
2.29
8.66

6.18
2.88
NA*
4.54
7.36
7.61
3.11
0.69
6.30
5.40
3.60
4.39
9.08

Total
Yearly
Cost
($ million)
46.35
16.12
7.74
32.31
30.63
29.04
15.74
15.95
20.18
16.31
8.20
12.59
15.95

Yearly
Subsidy
($ million)
Current Projected
41.07
15.10
7.02
29.55
26.61
24.44
14.40
15.55
16.02
12.46
5.99
10.30
7.30

40.17
13.24
NA*
27.77
23.27
21.42
12.63
15.26
13.88
10.91
4.60
8.20
6.88

Subsidy
Per Car
($ million)
Current Projected
1.76
4.50
1.13
1.80
2.08
1.53
1.83
0.61
0.51
0.45
0.57
0.61
0.16

1.47
1.39
NAa*
1.03
1.00
0.81
0.69
0.35
0.29
0.28
0.27
0.25
0.14

Notes: Yearly Revenue = Tax * (M iles/M PG) * (C ars/D ay) * 365
Total Yearly Cost = (Int. Rate * Capital C o st)/(l-exp (- Int. Rate * Capital Life))
Yearly Subsidy = Yearly Cost - Yearly Revenue
Subsidy/Car = Yearly S u b sid y /(C ars/D ay * 365)
Assumed miles per gallon: 20
Assumed capital life: 30 years
Assumed interest rate: 7 percent
aRanked by current subsidy per car.
■^Projected values not available.

Street Expressway, running through the heart of
Philadelphia. This project is almost five times
as expensive on a per-mile basis than the Blue
Route, but its projected subsidy per vehicle
mile is a little more than three times as great
because of the heavy traffic volume (120,000
cars per day).17

17This project is very expensive because part of the high­
way runs underground for aesthetic and environmental
reasons.

16




The 176 (Schuykill Expressway) reconstruc­
tion project in the Philadelphia metropolitan
area is, by far, the least subsidized project. It
has relatively low construction costs per mile—
primarily because no additional land needed
to be acquired for reconstruction. Addition­
ally, the highway has very high traffic volumes
of 133,800 cars per day. The projected subsidy
on a per-mile basis for this project is less than 1
cent per mile, or 14 cents for each car using the
expressway.
Each of these projects is likely to have a
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Unequal Subsidies in Highway Investment

different impact on the pattern of regional
development in metropolitan Philadelphia. Since
the 176 reconstruction serves the same area at
close to the same capacity as the original high­

Richard Voith

way, it probably will have little impact on new
development. Rather, it should facilitate the
continued economic health of the areas it has
historically served. The effect of the Vine Street

Calculating Cost and Revenues
To calculate subsidies for a highway project, we compare the yearly costs of the highway with the
yearly revenue from user fees. In computing the yearly cost of a highway project, we need to estimate
the opportunity cost of the capital invested in the project, the rate at which the highway depreciates,
the maintenance and operating costs, and the costs of adverse side effects from the highway, such as
increased pollution. To calculate user fees, we need to know how many cars will use the road, how
much gas they will use, and what the gasoline tax rate is.
Consider highway costs first. What is the opportunity cost of capital? It is the amount of money
one could make by not spending the money on the highway project, but rather by investing it in some
risk-free asset like a Treasury bill. For example, the opportunity cost of capital for the $581 million
spent on the Blue Route, assuming a 7 percent interest rate, is .07 times $581 million, or $41 million
a year. The highway does not last forever, so we must take into account how much the highway
depreciates each year. For our calculations, we assume that the highway lasts 30 years and that the
asset delivers the same service flow throughout the life of the highway. Given these assumptions,
coupled with a 7 percent rate of interest, the yearly expense for the Blue Route is $46.35 million.* The
yearly expense increases with the level of interest rate assumed; the assumed interest rate of 7 percent
is less than current long-term rates, which are about 8 percent, so our cost estimate is conservative.
Also, since we ignore all other costs, such as maintenance and pollution costs, our cost estimates are
lower than the true costs.
To calculate the user fees generated by motorists, we use estimates of the number of cars using the
highway, then assume that the average car gets 20 miles to the gallon and that it travels the entire
length of the highway. The yearly revenue equals the gasoline tax multiplied by number of gallons
consumed by each car on the highway times the number of cars using the highway each year. Using
the Blue Route as an example, total gasoline taxes in Pennsylvania are 21 cents per gallon, the highway
length is 21.5 miles, and the expected number of cars per day at the outset is 64,000, or 23.4 million
cars per year. This gives total revenues of $5.27 million per year. An implicit assumption in this
calculation is that all travel on the highway is new travel— that is, it is travel that would not have
occurred without the highway. Because this assumption is unlikely to be true, the estimate is likely
to overstate the new user fees resulting from the project.
Subsidies are the difference between yearly costs and yearly revenues. In the case of the Blue
Route, these amount to $41.1 million initially. Because costs are probably underestimated and
revenues are probably overestimated, the subsidy figure may be too low.

*The formula for calculating the annual opportunity plus depreciation costs is: (r x k) / (1 - exp(-r x L)), where
r is the interest rate, k is the total capital cost, and L is the useful life of the highway. Note that r x k is the opportunity
cost, and the depreciation cost is the difference between the yearly cost and the yearly opportunity cost. For a
discussion of this calculation, see Theodore Keeler and John S. Ying, "Measuring the Benefits of a Large Public
Investment," Journal of Public Economics (1988) pp. 69-85.




17

BUSINESS REVIEW

Expressway, despite its high subsidy level, is
uncertain; it is unclear whether it will serve
primarily as a bypass for suburb-to-suburb
travel or whether it will improve access and
extend the boundaries of the central business
district. Finally, the Blue Route is likely to have
large effects on regional development, since it
provides access to a large area that formerly
had no interstate highway access. Whether its
large subsidy will be offset by reduced conges­
tion and by new economic development (as
opposed to shifts in the location of develop­
ment) is an open question.
DO WE INVEST IN HIGHWAYS
EFFICIENTLY?
Just because a highway does not generate
sufficient revenue under the current mecha­
nism of pricing does not mean that the high­
way should not be built. The decision to
build—and the type of road to be built—depends
on the social costs and benefits of the highway.
The benefits include the time saved from re­
duced congestion and the new economic activ­
ity spawned by the highway. For example, the
Blue Route, though highly subsidized, may be
a good investment if the time savings plus net
benefits to nonusers, such as new economic de­
velopment, are greater than the subsidy. But in
this case, those deriving the benefit from in­
creased local economic development should
help pay the cost of the investment.
If a highway's costs are not borne by those

Digitized18for FRASER


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

deriving the benefits, motorists have too large
an incentive for travel, and local jurisdictions
have an incentive to undertake projects that
provide some benefits but not enough to justify
the costs. Also, it is easier for localities to
undertake a project that simply shifts develop­
ment from one area to another. In the case of
the Blue Route, for example, there will likely be
significant economic development in the area it
serves. But how much of this development
would have occurred anyway, only in a differ­
ent location, had the large subsidy not existed?
Our analysis indicates that all of the large
highway projects considered are highly subsi­
dized and that the subsidy levels of the 13
projects vary considerably. While many of
these projects may be worthwhile from a social
point of view, the obvious beneficiaries are not
paying the full cost. We can assume that for
each project there are some benefits enjoyed by
nonusers to justify a subsidy, but there is little
indication that the different subsidy levels are
in any way related to the benefits to nonusers.
It is also likely that the large subsidy levels are
not matched by benefits to nonusers and there­
fore encourage too much auto travel and too
much dispersion of economic activity. The
best way to ensure efficient transportation and
location decisions is to make those imposing
the costs or deriving the benefits—whether
motorists or local communities seeking
development—pay for the investment.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country:
Causes, Prospects, and
Policy Implications
Stephen A. Meyer*
One and a quarter trillion dollars—that is
roughly the value of claims on the United
States accumulated by foreigners from 1982
through 1988. Their purchases of U.S. assets
far exceeded U.S. residents' purchases of for­
eign assets, turning the United States into a net
foreign debtor in 1985. By the end of 1988,
foreign ownership of assets in the U.S. ex­
ceeded our ownership of foreign assets by
about $530 billion.

“Stephen A. M eyer is Vice President and Associate
Director of Research at the Federal Reserve Bank of Phila­
delphia.




Our growing status as a net debtor has
raised various concerns. A major one is that
future generations of Americans may face
lowered living standards because they will be
forced to service the foreign debt we have
accumulated. A second concern is that our
large foreign debt might bring the U.S. very
high inflation rates in the future, like those
experienced recently by some of the world's
debtor nations.
To assess the validity of these concerns, we
first need to understand the economic factors
that generated large net capital inflows into the
United States. That understanding will enable
us to analyze the implications for future living
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

standards and inflation. We also will be able to
evaluate the prospects for reversing our posi­
tion as a net debtor and weigh the role eco­
nomic policies can play in that process. (See
Glossary, pp. 30-31, for definitions of terms that
appear above and elsewhere in this article.)

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

LARGE CURRENT ACCOUNT DEFICITS
MADE THE U.S. A NET DEBTOR
A direct link exists between the current
account balance and international capital flows.
Understanding that link is critical to under­
standing how the U.S. became a net debtor.

What Does It Mean to Be a Net-Debtor Country?
There is widespread confusion about what the Commerce Department's figures mean when they
show that the U.S. is a net foreign debtor. Technically, those figures show that foreigners' ownership
of claims on the U.S. (including land, buildings, firms, stocks, bonds, and other financial instruments)
exceeds U.S. residents' ownership of claims on foreign countries. The important point here is that all
foreign assets and liabilities are included in this calculation, not just debt instruments.
About 30 percent of U.S. foreign "debt" is accounted for by foreign ownership of stock issued by
U.S. corporations and by foreign direct investments in the United States (such as foreign-owned land,
office buildings, and manufacturing and distribution facilities in the United States). For example,
automobile factories built in the U.S. by Japanese auto companies show up in the official figures as
foreign claims on the United States. Corporate stocks and direct investments account for nearly the
same percentage of U.S. claims on foreigners.
That some of our foreign assets and "debts" are actually real investments matters for three reasons.
First, direct investments produce goods and services in the U.S. and thereby generate the stream of
dividends or profits that are paid to foreigners. In the process, direct investments generate output and
employment in the U.S., benefiting residents as well as nonresidents. Second, while direct invest­
ments generate a stream of profits or dividends that flow to their owners, direct investments do not
normally require a contractually fixed stream of payments to foreigners (such as are required by
interest payments on a bond). Instead, foreign direct investments in the U.S. pay high returns when
profits are strong in the U.S. and lower returns when profits are weak. In effect, we pay more to
foreigners when we can best afford to. Third, direct investments are valued at their "book value"
(historical acquisition cost) in the official figures, unlike financial instruments, which usually are
valued at their current market value. Using book value results in a large understatement of the true
value of foreign direct investments owned by U.S. residents, but a much smaller understatement of
the true value of foreign-owned direct investments in the United States. Thus, valuing foreign direct
investments at their book value results in a large overstatement of the true size of the U.S. net-debtor
position. These three points argue that the true burden that will arise from the need to service our
foreign "debts" is likely to be smaller than estimates based on official Commerce Department figures
seem to suggest.
Making these and other technical adjustments to the official figures suggests that the U.S. netforeign-liability position was at least $350 billion smaller at the end of 1987 than the official figures
show.* Despite the ambiguities in the official figures, however, it is clear that the balance between U.S.
claims on foreigners and U.S. liabilities to foreigners has changed dramatically during the 1980s.
From a large net-foreign-asset position in 1982, the U.S. almost certainly shifted to a net-foreignliability position at the end of 1988.
*For a discussion of these issues and other measurement problems in the official statistics, and also for corrected
estimates of U.S. foreign assets and liabilities, see Michael Ulan and William G. Dewald, "Deflating U.S. Twin
Deficits and the Net International Investment Position," Planning and Economic Analysis Staff Working Paper 12
(Bureau of Economic and Business Affairs, U.S. Department of State, 1989).

Digitized 20
for FRASER


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

Stephen A. Meyer

When the U.S. imports more than it exports
and runs a current account deficit, as it has
each year since 1982, our receipts from abroad
fall short of our payments to foreigners. To
finance the excess of foreign payments over
receipts, the U.S. must borrow from foreigners
or sell assets to them. In each case, financial
capital flows into the United States. At the
same time, either our liabilities to foreigners
rise or our holdings of foreign assets decline, so
our net foreign asset position declines.1*
Current Account Deficits and Matching
Capital Inflows Reflected Macroeconomic
Imbalances. Fundamentally, the large capital
inflows into the U.S. during the 1980s resulted
from a shortfall of national saving relative to
the demand for funds to finance real invest-

1A standard source for information on the U.S. trade and
current account balances, and on the foreign assets and
liabilities of the U.S., is the Survey o f Current Business, pub­
lished monthly by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S.
Department of Commerce. The March, June, September,
and December issues contain detailed information on the
U.S. current account balance and its components. The June
issue also includes details on foreign assets and liabilities of
the United States.

merit in buildings, equipment, structures, and
inventories. The excess of investment spend­
ing over national saving was financed by an
inflow of capital from abroad.
National saving (the sum of personal sav­
ing, business saving, and government saving)
declined as a share of GNP during the 1980s.
National saving declined from 16.2 percent of
GNP in 1980 and 17 percent in 1981 to a little
more than 12 percent in 1987 before rising
somewhat in 1988. Business saving did not
decline relative to GNP; it was just about the
same share of GNP in 1987 and 1988 as in 1980
and was higher between 1981 and 1986. But
personal saving fell from about 5 percent of
GNP at the beginning of the 1980s to less than
2.5 percent in 1987. And government dissaving
in the form of budget deficits (for all levels of
government combined) grew from a little more
than 1 percent of GNP to an average of almost
3.5 percent in 1982 through 1986, then declined
in 1987 and 1988. Thus, about half of the
decline in national saving relative to GNP was
caused by falling personal saving rates and
about half by rising government budget defi­
cits.

TABLE 1

Personal and Government Saving Fell Relative to GNP
While Investment Rose

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988

Investment
Spending
(% of GNP)

National
Saving
(% of GNP)

16.0
16.9
14.1
14.8
17.6
16.0
15.6
15.5
15.4

16.2
17.0
14.1
13.6
13.5
13.3
12.4
12.2
13.2




Business

National Saving
(% of GNP)
Personal

Government

12.5
12.8
12.7
13.6
13.5
13.4
12.9
12.4
12.2

5.0
5.2
4.9
3.8
4.4
3.1
3.0
2.3
3.0

-1.3
- 1.0
-3.5
-3.8
-2.8
-3.3
-3.4
-2.4
-2.0

21

BUSINESS REVIEW

While the national saving rate fell, invest­
ment spending rebounded from its 1982 low as
the economy recovered from recession. Invest­
ment spending grew especially strongly in 1983
and 1984, rising to 17.6 percent of GNP, then
fell back to about 15.8 percent of GNP from
1985 through 1988. The resulting imbalance
between investment spending and national
saving has exceeded $100 billion each year
since 1984, generating the need for a capital
inflow from abroad.2
The large current account deficits and match­
ing deterioration in the U.S. net-foreign-debt
position also reflected a decline in the interna­
tional competitiveness of U.S. firms from 1980
to 1985, most of which was caused by the more
than 50 percent increase in the value of the
dollar during that period. That rise in the
dollar's value, which has since been reversed,
meant that firms in the U.S. could buy various
goods abroad and import them into the U.S. at
a lower cost than they would incur by produc­
ing the goods here. The resulting increase in
U.S. imports, and the accompanying decline in
exports, accounts for most of the growth in our
current account deficit.
The imbalance between national saving and
investment was an important cause of the dol­
lar's appreciation. The shortfall of national
saving relative to investment spending helped
drive up real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates
in the United States. The rise in real interest
rates, in turn, contributed to the rise in the
dollar's value that reduced U.S. international
competitiveness. The interplay between these

2Data on U.S. national income and product, including
saving and investment spending, are available monthly in
the Survey of Current Business. Those data show that per­
sonal saving has been declining as a share of GNP since the
mid-1970s, when it peaked at 6.5 percent. For more detail on
the behavior of private and government saving in the U.S.,
see Behzad Diba, "Private-Sector Decisions and the U.S.
Trade Deficit," this Business Review (Septem ber/O ctober
1988).

22



NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

factors produced the large current account
deficits and matching capital inflows of the
1980s. Those capital inflows cumulated to
produce our net-foreign-liability position of
$530 billion—almost 11 percent of GNP—at the
end of 1988.3
WILL OUR NET-DEBTOR STATUS REDUCE
OUR FUTURE STANDARD OF LIVING?
Our growing net-debtor status has raised
worries that we will have to transfer to foreign­
ers so much of our future income— in the form
of interest and dividend payments to foreign
owners of claims on the U.S.—that we will end
up with a falling standard of living. Whether
the U.S. faces reduced living standards de­
pends upon how the capital inflows of the
1980s were used—in particular, whether they
financed investment or consumption. And the
answer also depends upon our future savings
behavior.
If Capital Inflows Financed Additional In­
vestment, Our Future Standard of Living Is
Likely to Rise. Additional spending on new
investment in plant and equipment generates
higher output and incomes by making workers
more productive and by creating new jobs.
Only part of the increased output and income
accrues to foreign investors in the form of
interest and dividend payments. The remain­
der of the higher incomes flows to workers in
the U.S. in the form of wages and salaries and
to governments in the U.S. in the form of tax
revenues.
Foreign capital inflows can finance addi­
tional investment either directly or indirectly.
They can finance additional investment di­
rectly if they are used to build new factories,

3A shortfall of national saving relative to desired invest­
ment spending in one country can generate foreign capital
inflows into that country only if other countries' saving
exceeds their investment spending. That has been true for
Germany, Japan, and other countries during the 1980s.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

office buildings, and other structures, or if they
are used to purchase new equipment. Foreign
capital inflows can finance new investment
indirectly if they are used to buy financial
instruments (such as stocks and bonds) from
Americans, who will then be able to use the
funds to finance investment.
But if Capital Inflows Financed Consump­
tion, Our Future Living Standards May Be
Reduced. If the inflow of foreign capital fi­
nanced only current consumption spending,
including consumption by the government,
then we incur future payments to service the
accumulated foreign debt but gain no offset­
ting increase in future incomes. In this case,
our future standard of living will be lower than
it otherwise would have been, but it still may be
higher than today's. Continuing technological
progress and real investment financed by
domestic savings will raise our future stan­
dard of living, unless interest and dividend
payments to foreigners rise more than our
GNP. Thus there is a possibility that foreign
capital inflows could produce a burden on
future generations in the form of a lowered
standard of living, if those capital inflows are
used to finance consumption spending rather
than new investment.
More Than Half of the Capital Inflow Was
Used to Finance Increased Net Investment.
By comparing the net capital inflows during
the 1980s with the increase in the amount of net
investment spending undertaken in the United
States, we can determine how much of the
capital inflows were used, directly or indi­
rectly, to finance additions to the capital stock.
During 1980 and 1981, when there was virtu­
ally no net capital flow, net investment spend­
ing by U.S. businesses averaged about $150
billion per year. From 1984 to 1988 there were
sizable net foreign capital inflows averaging a
little more than $126 billion per year. Net
investment increased to an average of about
$221 billion per year over this period, better
than $70 billion per year higher than in 1980


Stephen A. Meyer

81.4 On average, then, about 55 percent of the
net foreign capital inflow from 1984 to 1988
was used, directly or indirectly, to finance
additional net investment.
There is another way to look at this issue:
although national saving declined from 16.6
percent of GNP in 1980-81 to about 13.2 percent
in 1984-88, net investment was unchanged as a
share of GNP; net investment averaged 5.2
percent of GNP during the earlier period and
also during the latter years. The implication is
that foreign capital inflows allowed the U.S.
capital stock to grow at the same rate from 1984
through 1988 as during 1980 and 1981, despite
the drop in national saving relative to GNP. In

4We omit data for 1982 and 1983 from this comparison
because investment spending w as depressed during those
years as a result of the 1981-82 recession. It would be
misleading to attribute either the drop in investment spend­
ing from 1981 to 1982, or the increase from 1983 to 1984, to
changing foreign capital inflows. If we were to include data
for 1982 and 1983, it would appear that nearly 80 percent of
the foreign capital inflow financed additional net invest­
ment.

TABLE 2

More Than Half
of Net Capital Inflows
Were Used to Finance
Added Investment
Net
Capital Inflow
Per Year
($ billion)

Net
Investment
Spending
Per Year
($ billion)

1980-81

-4.4

150.5

1984-88

126.3

220.9
Increase = 70.4

23

BUSINESS REVIEW

the absence of foreign capital inflows, a drop in
national saving relative to GNP would have to
be accompanied by a drop in investment rela­
tive to GNP. The inflow of capital from abroad
allowed continuing growth in the capital stock,
which is likely to mean rising living standards
in the future. Nevertheless, more of the returns
to that new capital will accrue to foreigners, so
our standard of living will grow less rapidly
than if net investment had been financed by
domestic saving rather than foreign saving.
A simple back-of-the-envelope calculation
will give a feeling for the potential size of this
effect. The ratio of net foreign debt to GNP for
the U.S. was almost 11 percent at the end of
1988. Whether that ratio rises or falls in the
future, and by how much, will be critical in
determining the size of the burden. If that ratio
rises, indicating that our net foreign debt is
growing faster than our GNP, then a rising
share of our total incomes will accrue to for­
eigners.
Projections by various economic forecasting
services of the likely future paths of GNP and
the current account deficit suggest that the
ratio of our net foreign debt to GNP might
gradually rise to 15 percent of GNP, or perhaps
to as much as 20 percent, before it begins to
decline sometime late in the 1990s.5 As a result,
we would need to transfer a rising share of each
year's GNP to foreigners to make the interest
and dividend payments that go with our netdebtor status. The projections indicate that net
interest and dividend payments to foreigners
might peak at as much as 1 percent of GNP.
That is the potential burden of our position as
a net foreign debtor.
We can gain some perspective on the size of
this potential burden by noting that net interest

5These figures, and other numbers cited below, are
based upon long-term economic projections published
during the winter of 1988-89 by D RI/ McGraw-Hill and The
WEFA Group.

Digitized for
24 FRASER


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

and dividend payments to foreigners are pro­
jected to rise from about $4 billion in 1988 to as
much as $90 billion in 10 years' time. But over
the same 10 years our GNP is projected to
roughly double, rising by nearly $5 trillion.
Some of that growth in measured GNP reflects
price increases rather than production of more
goods and services, and some of that growth is
needed to maintain our existing standard of
living as the U.S. population grows. But even
after adjusting for inflation and population
growth, the projections suggest that per capita
real GNP less net interest and dividend pay­
ments to foreigners is likely to grow about 16
percent by 1998.
That is not to say that our growing netforeign-debtor position will have no effect upon
Americans' future living standards, however.
According to these projections, growing net
interest and dividend payments to foreigners
will leave our per capita real income roughly 1
percent lower at the turn of the century than it
would be in the absence of those payments.
Such an effect is small, but noticeable.
While the projections upon which these cal­
culations are based are necessarily subject to
great uncertainty, they do give a feeling for the
size of the future burden of our net-debtor
position. Americans are not likely to face a
lower standard of living than we enjoy today.
Still, our standard of living will grow a little
less quickly as a result of our growing netdebtor position.
WILL OUR FOREIGN DEBT
CAUSE HIGH INFLATION?
While it is unlikely that our growing net
foreign debt will mean a lower standard of
living than we have today, the concern remains
that our net-debtor status might generate strong
inflationary pressures like those in some other
debtor countries. This concern raises two re­
lated questions. First, does the U.S. face the
temptation to generate higher inflation because
doing so could reduce the real value of its
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

foreign debts? And second, if foreigners were
to become unwilling to continue accumulating
claims on the U.S., as has happened with some
other debtor countries, would the result be a
debt crisis that generates high inflation in the
United States?
Can We Inflate Away Our Foreign Debt?
One important difference between the U.S. and
other debtor countries is that much of our
foreign debt is denominated in our own do­
mestic currency while theirs is not. That fact
raises the possibility that the U.S. could inflate
away the real value of its foreign debt by gen­
erating higher domestic inflation so that each
dollar owed to foreigners would buy fewer
U.S. goods.
In assessing this possibility, it is important
to note that it is only fixed-rate, long-term
nominal debt whose real value can be reduced
by higher inflation. That is, the real value of
fixed-income securities with fixed value at
maturity, such as long-term bonds, can be
red u ced by h ig h er inflation. But the real v alue

of shares of stock in U.S. firms and of real assets
such as buildings, factories, or land cannot
reliably be reduced by inflation; their dollar
values tend to rise along with prices of goods
and services. And the real value of short-term
or floating-rate debt cannot be reduced by
higher inflation, because interest rates on such
debt would rise along with the inflation rate,
thereby compensating the holder of such debt
for the higher inflation. Indeed, higher infla­
tion would actually increase the burden of
servicing short-term or floating-rate claims held
by foreigners, because it would quickly raise
the required interest payments on such debt.
Fixed-rate, long-term debt, whose value can
be reduced by higher inflation, accounts for at
most 20 percent of foreign claims on the United
States.6 The bulk of U.S. liabilities to foreigners
t w e n t y percent is almost certainly an overestimate.
Very little data on the maturity structure of foreign claims
on the U.S. are available. The 20 percent figure is an estimate




Stephen A. Meyer

consists of short-term debt, equity, and invest­
ments in real property. Thus, the U.S. cannot
effectively inflate away the real value of its
foreign debt, even though most of that debt is
denominated in U.S. dollars.
That the U.S. cannot inflate away its foreign
debt may not be enough to prevent inflationary
pressures. Some of the world's debtor coun­
tries have suffered very high inflation, even
though their foreign debts are largely floatingrate debt denominated in currencies other than
their own so that their domestic inflation does
not reduce the real value of their foreign debt.
Those episodes of very high inflation seem to
follow or accompany debt crises, in which
foreign lenders become unwilling to continue
accumulating claims on a particular country.
Would the U.S. Face Very High Inflation if
It Could No Longer Borrow From Foreigners?
Although very high inflation seems to be con­
nected with debt crises, episodes of very high
inflation actually have little to do with the
presence of foreign debt, or with debt crises,
per se. Rather, very high inflation reflects a
lack of well-developed internal capital mar­
kets, governments' inability to collect taxes
effectively, and governments' responses to debt
crises.
Many of the world's debtor countries had
large government budget deficits that they
financed mostly by borrowing from foreigners,

derived by treating all U.S. government notes and bonds
plus all U.S. corporate and other bonds held by foreign
official and foreign private investors as long-term, fixedrate claims, and dividing that sum by total foreign claims on
the United States. (Data on foreign holdings of U.S. govern­
ment debt are available in the Treasury Bulletin; data on
foreign ownership of U.S. corporate bonds are given in the
June issue of the Survey o f Current Business.) This method for
estimating how much of foreign claims on the U.S. is fixedrate, long-term debt almost certainly produces an overesti­
mate because much of the stock of U.S. government notes
outstanding at any point in time actually has a fairly short
time remaining to maturity. The rest of foreign claims on the
United States, other than those cited above, are either short­
term or are real assets.

25

BUSINESS REVIEW

especially from international banks and multi­
lateral organizations. After issuing so much
foreign debt that lenders became unwilling to
provide additional funds, or became unwilling
to provide as large a flow of new lending as in
earlier years, many of those countries found
that their domestic capital markets could not
absorb enough new debt to finance ongoing
government budget deficits as large as those
previously financed by borrowing from for­
eigners. Policymakers in those countries then
faced a choice between reducing government
spending, raising taxes to finance that spend­
ing, or simply printing new money to finance
the excess of government spending over reve­
nues. Those governments that printed money
to finance continuing budget deficits gener­
ated high inflation.7 On the other hand, those
7For a more thorough discussion of these problems, with
details of particular countries' experiences, see Thomas J.
Sargent, "The Ends of Four Big Inflations," in Robert Hall

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

debtor countries that responded to the reduced
availability of foreign funds by reducing their
budget deficits, thereby avoiding rapid growth
of their money supplies, did not experience
rapid inflation.
Thus, it is not foreign debt per se, or even the
inability to issue new foreign debt, that causes
high inflation in debtor countries. Rather, it is
continuing rapid expansion of the money sup­
ply, usually to finance large government budget
deficits, that causes high inflation.
Should we expect our government budget
deficits to generate high inflation in the United
States? In applying the lesson from those debtor
countries that have experienced very high in­
flation, there are three points to bear in mind.
First, the U.S. has well-developed domestic

(ed.), Inflation, NBER and University of Chicago Press
(1982), and also Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer,
"Stopping Hyperinflations Past and Present," NBER W ork­
ing Paper #1810 (1986).

Comparing the U.S. to High-Inflation Debtor Countries
While foreign claims on the U.S. are large, they are much smaller relative to the size of our economy
than is true for those debtor countries that have suffered very high inflation. More importantly, the
growth rate of the money supply in the United States is much, much lower than in high-inflation
debtor countries.
In most of the debtor countries that have experienced very high inflation, large and continuing
government budget deficits caused a large shortfall of domestic saving relative to investment
spending. That shortfall was financed primarily by borrowing abroad. Accordingly, those countries
accumulated very large foreign debts relative to their GNP and foreigners eventually became
unwilling to continue lending at the same pace.
The size of the foreign debt was not itself the cause of high inflation, however. Nor was foreigners'
reluctance to continue lending the cause of high inflation. Rather it was governments' response to the
reduced availability of foreign funds that was critical. When foreigners became unwilling to continue
lending to the same extent, some governments responded by creating large amounts of new money
to finance continuing large budget deficits. Those governments that did so generated high inflation.
Comparing the U.S. to Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Peru, and South Korea makes the point clear. In
contrast to the United States, the first four of these debtor countries have experienced very high
inflation because their governments generated very rapid growth of their money supplies.
South Korea, too, has a large foreign debt relative to the size of its economy; its government,
however, did not allow very rapid money growth. Thus South Korea, like the United States, did not
experience high inflation. The difference in monetary policy, not in the level of foreign debt, is what
separates debtor countries that experienced high inflation from those that did not.

26 FRASER
Digitized for


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

Stephen A. Meyer

financial markets. The U.S. government has
had no difficulty financing its deficits by issu­
ing debt in these markets, although some of
that debt has been purchased by foreigners.
And no such difficulty is likely to arise as long
as investors perceive that the U.S. budget defi­
cit will shrink further relative to GNP.
Second, the shortfall of national saving rela­
tive to investment has been much smaller over
the past 15 years for the U.S. than for the major
debtor countries that have experienced very
high inflation. As a result, the foreign debt of
the U.S. is much smaller relative to our GNP
than is the case for those countries. And the
money supply has grown much less rapidly in
the United States than in those countries.
Third, the U.S. Treasury cannot finance its
deficit by printing new money. The power to
issue new money in the U.S. is vested in the
Federal Reserve System, which is prohibited
by law from issuing new money to purchase

newly issued debt directly from the U.S. Treas­
ury.8 Thus we should not expect budget defi­
cits to generate very high growth rates of the
money supply or very high inflation in the
United States. Still, the inflationary experience
of many debtor countries makes clear the
importance of conducting monetary policy so
as to avoid very rapid growth of the money
supply, even when government deficits put
pressure on financial markets.

8There is a minor exception (contained in 31 United
States Code, section 5301; act of September 13, 1982) that
allows the Federal Reserve to buy up to $3 billion of securi­
ties directly from the U.S. Treasury when the President of
the United States declares an economic emergency. This
amount is tiny relative to the roughly $230 billion of govern­
ment securities that the Federal Reserve System held during
the summ er of 1989 — securities that were acquired in the
open market during the normal course of monetary policy
operations.

Large Foreign Debts Need Not Mean High Inflation

Total external debt
(public and private)
as % of GNP (1986)
Avg. saving shortfall
(I - S) as % of GNP
(1973-80)
(1980-86)
Average money growth
(broad money: M2)
(% per year, 1980-86)
Average inflation
(% per year, 1980-86)

Argentina

Bolivia

Brazil

Peru

S. Korea

U.S.

59

103

43

62

47

22

0.6
4.7

6.8
8.7

4.6
3.3

4.3
4.4

6.0
3.0

302

643

176

101

18

9

326

684

157

100

5

4

0.0
1.5

Sources: World Development Report 1988 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1988);

Survey of Current Business, June 1988 (U.S. Department of Comm erce, Washington, D.C.)




27

BUSINESS REVIEW

Continued Increases in Net Foreign Debt
Might Lead to Slightly Higher Inflation. Al­
though the buildup of foreign claims on the
U.S. is unlikely to generate high inflation, fu­
ture debt increases might contribute to mod­
estly higher inflation for several years. Theo­
retical models of exchange-rate behavior sug­
gest that if U.S. current account deficits do not
shrink and our net-foreign-debtor position
continues to grow rapidly as a result, then the
dollar would tend to depreciate gradually over
time. Such gradual but continuing deprecia­
tion would be expected to make inflation as
measured by the Consumer Price Index a little
higher than it would be otherwise. The reason
is that the dollar's depreciation would contrib­
ute to rising prices for imports and for import
substitutes produced domestically.
WHAT ARE THE PROSPECTS FOR
REVERSING OUR NET-DEBTOR STATUS?
We have seen that the costs of our netdebtor status, whether it affects our future
living standards or inflation, are likely to be
small. Still, a long-run economic perspective
suggests that it may be desirable for the U.S. to
eventually reverse its net-debtor position and
return to being a net foreign creditor.
When large numbers of those in the "baby
boom" generation begin to retire, roughly 25 to
30 years from now, they will need a large stock
of assets—domestic or foreign—upon which to
draw in order to finance their consumption
during retirement. Americans can accumulate
such a stock of assets by saving more to finance
more domestic investment, or by saving more
and using the funds to lend to foreigners or buy
assets from foreigners. Those foreign assets
can later be sold back, in exchange for the
goods that members of the baby-boom genera­
tion will want to consume during their retire­
ment. Such behavior by individuals would
imply that the U.S. would need to accumulate
a positive net-foreign-asset position—a posi­
tion that would eventually be drawn down to
28 FRASER
Digitized for


NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

finance imports of consumer goods after the
baby-boom generation retires.
Reducing Our Net-Debtor Position Will
Require National Saving to Exceed Invest­
ment Spending. We saw earlier that the for­
eign capital inflows that produced our netdebtor status reflected a shortfall of national
saving relative to investment. To reduce our
net-foreign-debt position, we must generate
capital outflows either to repay foreign debt or
to acquire foreign assets. To generate capital
outflows, national saving must exceed invest­
ment in the United States. Are there forces at
work in the U.S. economy that will raise na­
tional saving relative to investment spending?
Recall that national saving is composed of
personal saving, business saving, and govern­
ment saving in the form of budget surpluses.
Both personal saving and government saving
seem likely to rise in the future.
The U.S. Personal Saving Rate Should Rise
Over the Next 20 Years. Historical evidence
clearly indicates that the bulk of personal sav­
ing in the U.S. is done by people 45 to 64 years
old. During the past 20 years, the share of the
U.S. population in that age group has fallen to
a low of about 18.5 percent, and personal sav­
ing as a share of GNP has fallen too. The U.S.
Census Bureau projects that as the baby-boom
generation grows older, the share of those aged
45 to 64 is likely to grow to about 23 percent of
the population by the year 2000 and then rise
still further. Thus, the U.S. personal saving
rate is likely to rise over time, contributing to a
rise in national saving relative to GNP. How
much personal saving will rise is not known,
however.
Government Saving Is Likely to Increase
Too. Large government budget deficits, espe­
cially at the federal level, as well as a declining
personal saving rate, contributed to the decline
in national saving relative to GNP during the
1980s. While large federal budget deficits were
to be expected when the U.S. economy was in
recession from 1980 to 1982 (because recesFEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

Stephen A. Meyer

TABLE 3

Demographic Trends
Suggest Personal Saving
Will Rise

1970
1975
1980
1985
1987
1988
1990
1995
2000

Share of
U.S. Population
Ages 45 to 64 (%)

Personal Saving
as Share
of GNP (%)

21.5
20.3
19.1
18.8
18.6
18.7
18.7
20.2
23.0

5.7
6.0
5.0
3.1
2.3
3.0
—
—
—

sions produce lower incomes and profits and
thus lower federal revenues), large budget
deficits now that the economy is at or close to
full employment suggest a need for corrective
policies. Those corrective policies are embod­
ied in the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings deficit
reduction legislation, which commits the U.S.
government to eliminate its budget deficit by
1993. Even if that target is not met fully, the
government budget deficit seems quite likely
to shrink relative to GNP over the next few
years, as it has since 1986.9
Continuing to reduce the budget deficit, or
even running a budget surplus, would raise
national saving relative to investment spend­
ing and thereby help transform current ac­
count deficits and net capital inflows into cur­
rent account surpluses and net capital out­
flows. Such capital outflows will be required if

9Part of the reduction in the federal budget deficit re­
flects the growing surplus of the Social Security trust fund.
That surplus is projected to continue growing at least
through the end of the century, contributing to higher gov­
ernment saving.




we are to reduce our net foreign liabilities and
eventually return to being a net foreign credi­
tor.
One way to reduce the shortfall of national
saving relative to investment spending would
be to reduce investment. Few people would
argue that the U.S. should cut investment spend­
ing, because doing so would reduce our future
standard of living. In addition, the U.S. al­
ready uses a smaller share of its GNP for in­
vestment purposes than do other major indus­
trial countries. If we do not wish to reduce
investment spending relative to GNP, our fo­
cus in eliminating the shortfall of national sav­
ing relative to investment must be on generat­
ing higher savings. Whether national saving
will eventually rise enough to exceed invest­
ment spending, and thereby generate capital
outflows from the U.S., remains an open ques­
tion. Private saving is expected to rise relative
to GNP in coming years, as is government
saving. To close the shortfall of saving relative
to investment without reducing investment as
a share of GNP, national saving's share of GNP
must rise by about 2.2 percentage points from
its level in 1988 (or 2.8 points from its average
level for the years from 1983 through 1988).
Such an increase is possible, but not certain.
THE ROLE OF MONETARY POLICY
While it is clear that fiscal policy can help
reduce or reverse our net-foreign-liability posi­
tion by continuing to reduce the budget deficit,
nothing in the preceding discussion seems to
suggest much of a role for monetary policy. In
fact, monetary policy can play an important
role by promoting sustainable economic growth
and low inflation. Too-rapid growth in the
demand for goods and services in the U.S., and
the attendant rise in inflationary pressures,
would tend to increase our trade and current
account deficits and thus contribute to higher
foreign debt. But a recession, while it would
reduce imports, would tend to increase the
burden of our existing foreign debt because
29

BUSINESS REVIEW

in terest and d ivid end p ay m en ts to fo reig n ­
ers w ould b eco m e a g reater share o f our d i­
m inished G N P.
A n other w ay of stating the role o f m o n e­
tary p olicy— and o f fiscal p o licy as w ell— is
that p o licy m ak ers can p ro m o te an eventu al
redu ction in our net foreig n d ebt by ad opting
p olicies to en su re th at the d o m estic co m p o ­
nents o f d em and for U .S. g ood s and services
(especially co n su m er sp en d in g and g ov ern ­
m ent pu rchases) grow less rap id ly than the

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1989

eco n o m y 's cap acity to p ro d u ce g oo d s and serv ­
ices. By d oin g so, p o licy m ak ers w ould allow
U.S. firm s to m eet g ro w in g exp o rt ord ers w ith ­
out gen eratin g stron ger in flatio n ary p ressu res. If
gov ern m en t d eficits co n tin u e to sh rin k as a sh are
o f G N P , and if p erson al sav in g rates in crease a p ­
preciably as d em o g rap h ic tren d s su gg est, then
the d om estic com p on en ts o f d em an d w ill grow
m ore slow ly; so, in the fu tu re it m ay n o t b e n ec­
essary to use m on etary p o licy to restrain grow th
in d em an d so as to red u ce o u r n et foreig n debt.

GLOSSARY
Current account balance - a broad measure of the difference between the international receipts and
payments that result from transactions with foreigners. It includes the difference between our exports
and imports (the trade balance), and it also includes "factor payments" such as interest and dividends,
and outright gifts such as charitable donations and foreign aid. The U.S. current account balance is
the difference between our receipts from foreigners and our payments to foreigners that result from
all transactions except purchases or sales of assets (whether stocks and bonds and other financial
assets, or real assets such as land and buildings and factories).
Capital inflow into the U.S. - financial capital flows into the United States when residents of the U.S.
borrow abroad or when they sell existing assets to foreigners.
Capital outflow from the U.S. - financial capital flows out of the United States when residents of the
U.S. lend to foreigners or when they buy existing assets from foreigners.
Net capital inflow into the U.S. - the capital inflow from abroad minus the capital outflow.
Foreign claims on the U.S. - the total value of foreign-owned assets in the U.S., including the value
of loans to U.S. residents.
U.S. claims on foreigners - the total value of assets outside of the U.S. that are owned by U.S. residents,
including loans to foreigners.
U.S. net-foreign-asset position - U.S. claims on foreigners minus foreign claims on the United States.
A country with a positive net-foreign-asset position is a "net foreign creditor."
U.S. net-foreign-liability position - foreign claims on the U.S. minus U.S. claims on foreigners. A
country with a positive net-foreign-liability position (and thus a negative net-foreign-asset position)
is a "net foreign debtor." The United States is now a net foreign debtor.


30


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

The U.S. as a Debtor Country

SUMMARY
A look at the causes and implications of the
U.S. becoming a net-debtor country yields four
conclusions. First, our standard of living is
unlikely to decline, although it may grow less
rapidly because of the need to service our
liabilities to foreigners. Second, our net-debtor
status is unlikely to cause very high inflation
rates like those experienced by some of the
world's debtor countries. Third, we can re­
duce, and eventually reverse, our net-debtor

Stephen A. Meyer

position if we save a greater proportion of our
incomes in the future—especially if the babyboom generation saves more as it enters middle
age. And fourth, the government can help if it
continues to reverse the budget deficit as a
share of GNP, and if it chooses monetary and
fiscal policies that promote sustainable, noninflationary economic growth.

Personal saving - that part of households' current after-tax income that is not spent to buy goods and
services. This is the part of current income that is deposited in financial institutions, used to buy
additional financial assets, or otherwise lent out. When we aggregate personal saving for the economy
as a whole, we net out new consumer borrowing from the flow of new saving done by households.
Business saving - that part of businesses' revenues that is not paid out to workers, lenders, suppliers,
or owners. Alternatively, the funds that are retained as cash on hand, deposited in financial
institutions, or lent out. Business saving is comprised largely of retained earnings and depreciation
or amortization allowances.
Government saving - the consolidated government budget surplus for all levels of government.
When governments run a budget surplus they use the excess of revenue over outlays either to retire
debt they had issued previously, or they buy financial assets. When governments run budget deficits,
they dissave and issue new debt or money.
National saving - the sum of personal, business, and government saving. Conceptually, national
saving represents the quantity of funds that can be used to finance domestic investment or that can
be lent to foreigners.
Real investment - the purchase and installation of new machinery and equipment, the construction
or expansion of buildings and structures, and the accumulation of additional inventory.
Net investment - gross (total) investment spending by businesses less an estimate of economic
depreciation. Economic depreciation is the amount of the capital stock that wears out or becomes
useless. Thus net investment is a measure of the amount by which investment spending increases the
stock of capital in the economy.




31

Januaiy/Februaiy

Gerald A. Carlino, "What Can Output Measures Tell Us About Deindustrialization
in the Nation and its Regions?"
Thomas P. Hamer, "A New Regional Economic Indicator: The Mid-Atlantic Manufacturing Index"
March/April

Brian J. Cody, 'International Policy Cooperation: Building a Sound Foundation"
Daxnd Y. Wong, "Stabilizing the Dollar: What Are the Alternatives?"
May/June

Theodore M. Crone, "Office Vacancy Rates: How Should We Interpret Them?"
Loretta J. Mester, "Owners Versus Managers: Who Controls the Bank?"
July/August

Paul S. Calem, "The Community Reinvestment Act: Increased Attention
and a New Policy Statement"
Robert Schweitzer, "How Do Stock Returns React to Special Events?"
September/October

Ben Bemanke, "Is There Too Much Corporate Debt?"
Sherrill Shaffer, "Challenges to Small Banks' Survival"
November/December

Richard W. Lang and Timothy G. Schiller, "The New Thrift Act: Mending the Safety Net"
Richard Voith, "Unequal Subsidies in Highway Investment: What Are the Consequences?"
Stephen A. Meyer, "The U.S. as a Debtor Country: Causes, Prospects, and Policy Implications"

FEDERAL
RESERVE BANKOF
PHILADELPHIA
BUSINESS REVIEW Ten Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574
Address Correction Requested