View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

0
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
IS S N 00 07-70 11




NOVEMBER-DECEMBER

1977

and
Commodity Agreements:
The Haves vs.
The Have-Nots?

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

WHY BANKERS ARE CONCERNED ABOUT
NOW ACCOUNTS
H ow ard K een
. . . NOW accounts may not be a picnic for
commercial bankers, but they aren’t likely to
be as damaging as many bankers fear.
COMMODITY AGREEMENTS: THE HAVES
VS. THE HAVE-NOTS?
Ja n ice M oulton W esterfield

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
100 North S ixth Street
(on Independence Mall)
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106

The B U SIN E SS REVIEW is published by
the Department of Research every other
month. It is edited by John J. Mulhern, and
artwork is directed by Ronald B. Williams.
The REVIEW is available without charge.
Please send subscription orders, changes
of address, and requests for additional
copies to the Department of Public Services
at the above address or telephone (215) 5746115. Editorial communications should be
sent to the Department of Research at the
same address, or telephone (215) 574-6418.

The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
is part of the Federal Reserve System —a
System which includes twelve regional




. . . The developing countries want agree­
ments that will give them higher-than-market
prices for the raw materials they export. The
author suggests that these agreements might
not produce the expected benefits and pro­
poses other ways to encourage economic de­
velopment.

banks located throughout the nation as well
as the Board of Governors in Washington.
The Federal Reserve System was estab­
lished by Congress in 1913 primarily to
manage the nation’s monetary affairs. Sup­
porting functions include clearing checks,
providing coin and currency to the banking
system, acting as banker for the Federal
g ov ern m en t, su p e rv isin g co m m ercial
banks, and enforcing consumer credit pro­
tection laws. In keeping with the Federal
Reserve Act, the System is an agency of the
Congress, independent adm inistratively of
the Executive Branch, and insulated from
partisan political pressures. The Federal
Reserve is self-supporting and regularly
makes payments to the United States
Treasury from its operating surpluses.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Why Bankers
Are Concerned
About
NOW Accounts
By Howard Keen*
If your local banker seems a bit pre­
occupied these days, don’t be surprised.
Chances are he’s concerned that the competi­
tive world as he’s known it may be coming to
an end. In that world, the law gave com­
mercial banks a near monopoly on checking
accounts. But pressure for reform may intro­
duce a change in America’s financial system
which would sweep away the checking
monopoly.
This change is the authorization of nego­
tiable order of withdrawal (NOW) accounts
for commercial banks and other financial
institutions throughout the country. NOW
accounts are interest-bearing checking ac­
counts for nonbusiness depositors. They cur­
rently are authorized in New England, and
proposals in Congress would extend them
nationwide.

Advocates of NOW accounts claim that
consumers will benefit from them, but bank­
ers worry that these gains will be at their
expense. A look at how NOW accounts might
affect commercial banks reveals why bankers
are showing this concern, and why some are
showing more than others. It also suggests,
however, that NOW accounts may not be the
disaster that many bankers fear.
BATTLING FOR BUCKS
NOW accounts are sure to affect competi­
tion for family funds. Households ordinarily
keep funds they want to have readily avail­
able in three basic forms—currency, check­
ing accounts, and savings accounts. The
three together come to about $1 trillion—a
tidy sum. Currency and checking accounts
are most convenient for making payments,
but they have their drawbacks. Carrying
large sums of cash can be risky, and funds
that are held as cash or in checking accounts

*The author, an Economist at the Philadelphia Fed,
specializes in banking and regional business conditions.




3

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

BUSINESS REVIEW

earn no explicit interest.i By contrast, a
savings account may be less convenient for
making payments but it produces interest
income for its owner; and it’s relatively safe.
How family funds are divided among these
forms depends on the tradeoffs people make
among safety, convenience, and interest in­
come. If, for example, it became much easier
to switch funds from savings to currency or
checking accounts, we would expect to see
more funds held in savings accounts and less
in currency and checking. Thus, in effect,

currency competes against savings and check­
ing accounts for household funds.
Commercial Banks and Their Rivals. Dif­
ferent fin an cial institutions also compete for
household funds. Savings accounts, for ex­
ample, can be held both at commercial banks
and at thrift institutions such as mutual
savings banks (MSBs), savings and loans
(S&Ls), and credit unions (CUs). With some
exceptions, checking accounts can be held
only at commercial banks, but there is a host
of commercial banks to choose from. Thus,
in trying to attract funds into checking ac­
counts or savings accounts, commercial bank­
ers face competition on two fronts. First, they
compete as a group against currency and
against savings accounts at thrifts. Second,
they compete among themselves for the de-

iFor an analysis of the comparative advantages of
currency and checking accounts, see Donald L. Kohn,
“Currency Movements in the United States,” Monthly
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, April
1976, pp.3-8.

HOW CONSUMERS MIGHT GAIN FROM NOWs
NOW accounts might bring several benefits to consumers.
First, consumers could hold a checking-type account at many more financial institutions than
they can now. And this wider choice could save them time and effort. Being able to bank at a thrift
located around the corner instead of at the nearest commercial bank 10 blocks away makes more
time available for other activities. Even where banks and thrifts were equally convenient,
consumers could avoid the costs involved in switching funds from savings to checking—as they
must do now if they want to earn interest on their spendable funds. By offering a savings and
checking account rolled into one, NOW accounts could save consumers the time, hassle, and
monetary costs of this kind of transaction.
Further, consumers could gain more from the payment of explicit cash interest than from implicit
interest in the form of banking services. As more and more banking services are provided to
depositors, they tend to get less additional benefit from further increments of these services. Cash,
however, can be used to purchase other, preferred goods and services. The total value that
depositors receive could be higher if interest payments were substituted for some banking services.
Consumers could benefit also from the more intense competition of financial institutions that
NOWs would permit. These gains are likely to be larger during the intitial phase of NOW accounts
when banks and thrifts are trying to establish their market shares. Even after market shares
stabilize, however, competition could result in consumers’ receiving more for their funds than
before.
It’s likely that opportunities for gains would be different for different consumers. Depositors pay
no taxes on banking services as they do on cash interest received, and this tax difference can affect
the comparative values that consumers attach to these two forms of payment. The higher the
depositor’s marginal tax rate, the less attractive is payment in cash. At the same time, it’s possible
that some customers might end up paying more under NOWs than before. Depositors who are
accustomed to write a lot of checks while holding low balances, for example, could find that
continuing to do so would cost them more in service charges than they receive in interest.




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

against other bidders. And by helping to keep
costs down, the restrictions may have given a
boost to bank profits.

posits that households might decide to hold
at commercial banks.
Nature of Checking Account Competition.
The law has given commercial banks an
inside track in the competition for household
funds. Most of the money Americans spend
is spent by check, and commercial banks
have been nearly the only institutions allowed
to provide the checks. Their monopoly on
checking accounts has made it easier for
them to attract nonchecking deposits, because
it’s more convenient for the consumer of bank
services to handle all his transactions at one
institution. Only those who can afford the
inconvenience are likely to be won over by
the higher maximum interest rate allowed on
savings at thrifts.23
But while banking is competitive, it’s also
regulated, and so bankers can’t compete
freely. They’re barred, for example, from
paying interest on checking accounts, and
they have to cope with interest-rate ceilings
on savings accounts. Thus about the only
way they can compete is by providing more
services, such as free or subsidized checking,
to their customers. These services cost the
banker something, and in many cases his
costs are greater than the service charges that
depositors pay. So an inducement is being
paid for checking account dollars, but it’s in
the form of banking services rather than
cash .3
Nonetheless, the restrictions on entry into
this checking account market may have al­
lowed some banks to attract funds at a lower
average cost than if they had to compete

WHAT NOWs COULD DO
NOW accounts, as authorized in New
England and as proposed in Congress for the
rest of the country, are considered in law to
be savings accounts.4 But the negotiable
orders of withdrawal are, in essence, checks,
so that for all practical purposes, NOWs are
interest-bearing checking accounts. Under
the proposals to legalize the extension of
these accounts nationwide, all depository
institutions could offer what amounts to a
checking account, and commercial banks,
as well as the rest, would be allowed to pay
interest on these accounts. Since these pro­
posals would eliminate the checking account
monopoly as well as the prohibition against
paying interest on checking accounts, it’s
likely that commercial banks would feel
some impact. As it turns out, bank profits
could be affected by NOW accounts in sever­
al ways.
NOWs Could Cut Bank Costs . . . One of
the key features of NOW accounts—permis­
sion to pay interest on checking accounts—
might tend to lower the costs of some banks.
Why? Because banks probably can attract a
certain volume of funds at a lower cost if
they can pay for them with interest in cash
than if they have to pay for them with
banking services alone. The reason is that, at
some point, paying interest becomes cheaper
than providing bank services.
As the depositor is provided more and
more of a service, the value to him of each
further bit of the service goes down. People
may find it valuable, for example, to receive
a statement every month which lists their
deposits and checks written. But getting a

^^Regulations on passbook savings accounts, for ex­
ample, set the ceiling a quarter of a percentage point
higher at MSBs and S&Ls than at commercial banks.
CUs are subject to different regulations which permit
even higher rates to be paid.
3For a discussion of this implicit interest, see John H.
Boyd, “Household Demand For Checking Account
Money,” Journal ol Monetary Economics 2 (1976), pp.
81-98, and James M. O'Brien, “Interest Ban on Demand
Deposits: Victim of the Profit Motive?” Business Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, August 1972, pp.
13-19.




4 Since reserve requirements are lower for savings
than for checking, this legal classification of NOW
accounts will reduce the reserves that banks are required
to hold.
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

statement every three weeks, then every
two, and then every week, probably would
be of little value to most depositors. By the
same token, many customers would find the
extension of closing time from six o’clock to
seven o’clock a useful added attraction But
each further hour tacked on probably would
be valued less than the last. This charac­
teristic—that each added unit of a service
contributes less to total consumer satisfac­
tion—is not unique to banking. In fact, it
holds after some point in all kinds of business.
Further, after some level of services is
reached, the bank will have to spend more
than a dollar to give depositors extra services
which they will value at a dollar. As the bank
uses more and more resources to provide
banking services, and as the cost for each
additional unit of service rises, it becomes
increasingly expensive for the banker to
attract checking account funds or to hold on
to them in the face of added competition.
Thus a bank may find that it can retain or
attract depositors at a lower cost if it pays for
funds with interest rather than with more
and more services. In short, having the
option of paying depositors with cash rather
than with banking services may be a valuable
weapon for banks in their competitive strug­
gle for funds.5

BOX 1

SOME ALTERNATIVES
TO CHECKING ACCOUNTS
AT COMMERCIAL BANKS
The following are the most frequently
discussed thrift institution alternatives to
commercial bank checking accounts:
Payment of bills
by direct transfer
of funds out of
thrift savings ac­
counts. In pre­
authorized
ver­
sion, thrifts auto­
matically pay bills
on regular basis af­
ter initial authori­
zation by consum­
ers. In telephone
version, consum­
ers telephone thrifts
each time a pay­
ment is desired.

The road to lower costs, however, is not
without its potholes. In fact, bankers could
find that NOWs tended to inflate costs.
In the first place, banks can’t realize the
benefits of paying cash interest overnight or
by standing pat. If banks which are providing
services at no charge to depositors hope to
attract the same amount of funds at a lower
cost, they must do two things. In addition to
paying their depositors explicit interest, they
must institute an appropriate charge for

Off-Premise
Electronic Terminals — Deposit and with­
draw! from thrift
savings account at
off-site location.
In some cases, con­
sumers can make
direct
transfers
from own to mer­
chants’ accounts.
Share Drafts
— Check-like pay­
ment from credit
union deposit or
share accounts.
Checking Accounts —Traditional check­
ing account trans­
actions (noninter­
est-bearing NOWs—
NINOWs).

5Tax considerations can play a role in the way that
depositors value cash and services. The fact that no
taxes are levied on services would make this form of
payment more attractive to depositors than it would be
otherwise.

services they previously provided for free.
But discovering the right combination of
interest rates and charges may take time.

. . . But NOWs Also Could B oost Costs.




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

And during the transition, bankers may be
spending more, rather than less, to attract the
same amount of funds.
Further, removal of the ban on cash interest
could heat up the battle for funds. Banks
would be able to compete by offering interest
as well as services. If each bank in the
market were to pay only cash and to provide
no free services, it’s possible that the costs of
each and every bank would fall. But the
individual banker can’t be sure that his rivals
will do as he does. And the actions of his
rivals can affect his profits. A banker who
decides to continue offering free services
and paying no interest while his rivals offer
both services and interest may have to revise
his decision rather quickly to avoid losing
deposits. Thus his profits, as well as those of
his rivals, might turn out to be less than if
every bank paid only cash interest.
So removal of the ban on cash interest,
while providing an opportunity for lower
costs, also provides an opportunity for rival
banks to offer more for deposits. No banker
would intentionally offer a package that
would cut into his profits, but his rivals could
offer a package that would do the job for
him. It’s possible that banks may compete
away some profits because each and every
banker wants to protect himself against the
possibility of losing even greater profits.
And while there is no way to tell with any
precision to what degree this might occur,
the mere prospect that it might is enough to
worry many bankers.
Finally, because NOWs would allow thrifts
to offer checking account services to con­
sumers, it would be easier than before for
these institutions to compete with commer­
cial banks for funds.6* More competition
would bring about an increased demand for

BOX 2

HOW W IDESPREAD IS
THE AUTHORITY TO OFFER
CHECK-LIKE SERVICES?*
Preauthorized
Bill-Paying
Telephone
Bill-Paying

Federally chartered
S&Ls nationwide.
S&Ls in 8 states
and D. C.; MSBs
in 9 states.

Off-Premise
Electronic
Terminals

r

Federally chartered
S&Ls nationwide;
S&Ls in 20 states;
MSBs in 10 states;
Federally chartered
CUs in 10 states.
— Federally chartered
Share Drafts
CUs nationwide;
CUs in 27 states.
Checking Accounts — S&Ls in 6 states;
MSBs in 12 states;
CUs in 3 states.

’ Establishment of the authority for these
services does not guarantee that they actually
are being offered at the present time.
SOURCE: American Bankers Association press
release of June 14. 1977.
U/'Uv I g A

these funds and thus higher interest rates
paid to checking account customers (Boxes
1 , 2) .

6 NOW accounts do not provide the only opportunity
for thrifts to offer checking account services. Changes
in payments technology along with regulatory rulings
and interpretations already have given thrifts the author­
ity to enter what was exclusively a commercial bank
domain.




In short, commercial banks could feel the
effects of NOW accounts in several ways.
These might raise but also might lower the
average cost of funds to bankers. Unless the
efficiency benefits of paying depositors with
7

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/BECEMBER 1977

cash outweighed any higher costs brought
about by increased competition, the average
cost of funds to commercial banks would
rise.

more to lose from NOW accounts. All things
considered, these banks pay less for personal
funds than they would if the market were
highly competitive. This helps keep costs
down and gives them larger profits. The
greater are a bank’s profits that arise from
paying less than competitive rates for these
funds, the greater are the profits that might
be eliminated through additional competition.
Thus banks in less competitive deposit mar­
kets have more to lose from additional com­
petition than do banks where competition is
stronger. Although the degree of competi­
tion can vary greatly among the local markets,
banking markets in areas with larger popula­
tions tend as a rule to be more competitive
than those in areas with smaller popula­
tions.8 Overall, then, smaller banks in less
populated areas have more at stake when it
comes to NOW accounts. This does not mean
that banks with these characteristics are
guaranteed a worse time than other banks.9
Nevertheless, having more at stake is enough
reason for added concern over an uncertain
outcome.

SOME BANKS HAVE MORE AT STAKE
Bankers have no way to predict the net im­
pact of NOW accounts with any precision.
But with the competitive rules of the game
changing, no prudent banker can avoid being
concerned to some degree. And on top of
this, there are certain conditions that make
some bankers more apprehensive than others.
Sources of Funds Make a Difference.
Since NOW accounts apply to nonbusiness
deposits only, banks that rely to a greater
extent on households for their sources of
funds would be affected more by changes in
costs for these deposits. The greater the
percentage of total funds that comes from
households, the greater any impact of NOW
accounts on bank costs.
Smaller banks typically rely more on these
household sources. According to a 1976
Federal Reserve survey, nonbusiness check­
ing account funds made up 41 percent of the
total at small banks, 37 percent at medium­
sized banks, and 25 percent at larger banks.
A similar pattern holds for the ratio of house­
hold checking deposits to total deposits.7
Because of this heavier reliance on nonbusi­
ness deposits, many smaller banks would
experience a bigger percentage change in
costs than larger banks. The heavier this
reliance, the greater the impact on a bank’s
total cost of funds from a change in the cost
of nonbusiness deposits. On average, then,
smaller banks stand to gain or lose more from
NOW accounts than do larger banks.
Degree of Competition Matters, Too. Banks
that face little competition for household
funds under the current system also have

8 See “Recent Changes in the Structure of Commercial
Banking,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, March 1970, pp.
195-210.
9 Profits are affected by the demand for loans and by
the aggressiveness of competing institutions as well as
by costs. All things considered, the more inelastic is the
demand for loans, the less will be the reduction in
profits from some given increase in costs, At the same
time, a bank’s cost of funds will be pushed up less, the
less aggressive are competing institutions in offering
NOW accounts. For an analysis of the decision to offer
NOW accounts by MSBs as well as by commercial
banks, see Donald Basch, “The Diffusion of NOW
Accounts in Massachusetts,” New England Economic
Review, November/December 1976, pp. 20-30. As
Basch’s analysis shows, predicting the behavior of
financial institutions is no easy task. There is another
feature of less competitive markets, however, that
could make the road rougher for commercial banks. It’s
possible, for example, that entry by thrifts may be
encouraged by lower rates paid to depositors by com­
mercial banks. Since these rates would be lower in less
competitive deposit markets, banks in these markets
may feel stiffer competition from thrifts.

7See Functional Cost Analysis: 1976 Average Banks,
p. 7.6, and “The Impact of the Payment of Interest on
Demand Deposits,” Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, January 31, 1977, p. 48.




8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

that chose not to offer NOWs and experi­
enced a runoff of deposits, were particularly
hard hit. Out of 226 banks in the two states,
16 were in the former group and 15 in the
latter. Another study examined the 22 Massa­
chusetts banks with negative earnings in 1976
and concluded that these negative earnings
were not explained by the percentage of total
deposits in NOW accounts.
In short, it appears that while some banks
have had a lot of adjusting to do, NOWs over­
all have not severely damaged the position of
commercial banks in New England.
NOWs in the Rest of the U.S. While bank­
ers may not find complete reassurance in the
estimated impact of NOWs in New England,
there are reasons to believe that banks in the
rest of the country may not find the going as
rough.
For one thing, bankers have the New
England experience to learn from. And if the
learning that comes from the inevitable trial
and error is costly, then bankers in the rest of
the U .S. may be able to avoid some costly
mistakes. One lesson, for example, is that
the pricing of NOW accounts is of prime
importance. Whether NOW accounts are
profitable or unprofitable can depend upon
the pricing package that bankers devise. A
comparison of banks in Massachusetts in
1976 showed that banks that offered NOWs
with service charges had average earnings
rates almost double those of banks not offer­
ing NOWs. A third group—the one with
banks offering free NOWs—had the lowest.
Banks do not have to pay depositors more for
their funds than banks can earn on them, and
the proper pricing structure can help banks
avoid losing money.
Another lesson from New England is that
the transition period described earlier may
not last more than a few years. In M assa­
chusetts and New Hampshire, aggressive
competition for NOWs was beginning to
ease a bit less than two years after the
introduction of NOWs. And with the New
England experience to learn from, it may be
shorter elsewhere.

LESSONS AND PROSPECTS
Although nationwide NOWs could make
life tougher for some bankers, it’s difficult to
predict just how much tougher. Against the
opportunity for more intense competition and
its likely impact on bank costs is the prospect
of a gain in efficiency from paying depositors
with cash. Moreover, what bankers do in
terms of charging for services and how aggres­
sively thrifts enter the market for NOWs will
have an important bearing on the outcome.
NOWs in New England. Commercial banks
and thrifts (except CUs) have had the authority
to offer NOW accounts in Massachusetts
and New Hampshire since 1974 and in the
rest of New England since 1976. Several
studies have been done to try to estimate the
impact of NOW accounts on commercial
banks there. For the most part, these studies
have focused on Massachusetts and New
Hampshire, since NOWs have been author­
ized in these two states for the longest time.
It’s been estimated, for example, that for
all banks in these two states, NOW accounts
reduced after-tax earnings by about two and
a half percent in 1974 and by a little over
eight percent in 1 9 7 5 .10 Within this aggre­
gate group of banks, however, were some
that experienced larger percentage declines
in earnings. One group of banks with low
earnings to begin with, and another group

10 For estimates of the impact of NOW accounts on all
commercial banks in Massachusetts and New Hamp­
shire, see John Paulus, Effects of “NOW” Accounts on
Costs and Earnings of Commercial Banks in 1974-75,
Staff Study No. 88, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, 1976. Estimates of the impact on
particular groups of banks are given in Ralph C. Kimball,
“Impacts of NOW Accounts and Thrift Institution
Competition on Selected Small Commercial Banks in
Massachusetts and New Hampshire, 1974-75,” New
England Economic Review, January/February 1977, pp.
22-38. See also U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee
on Financial Institutions of the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, NOW Accounts, Federal
Reserve Membership, and Related Issues: Hearings on
S.1664, S.1665, S.1666, S.1667, S.1668, S.1669, and
S.1873, 95th Cong., 1st sess., 20, 21, 22, and 23 June
1977, pp, 1124-1133.




9

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

A stronger position in the competition
with thrifts likewise may ease the cost pres­
sures on bankers. There is some evidence on
depositor loyalty which suggests that many
depositors may prefer to hold a NOW account
at an institution they’ve dealt with in the past.
Although thrifts have an interest-ceiling
advantage on savings, locational convenience
and a wider menu of financial services still
are strong selling points for commercial
banks. If customers stay loyal, then current
shares of savings may indicate how competi­
tive banks might be in the struggle for NOW
accounts. In New England at the end of 1975,
banks held only 20 percent of savings deposits
and of time deposits totaling $100,000 or
less, while thrifts held 80 percent. Nationally,
however, banks are in a stronger competitive
position, with 45 percent of the total compared
to 55 percent for thrifts.11
Proposals now before Congress (S. 2055 and
H.R. 8981] also could serve to ease the
earnings pressure that commercial banks
might feel from NOW accounts. One pro­
posal is for the Fed to pay interest on required
reserves, and a second would allow reduc­
tions in the required reserve ratio on certain
checking and savings deposits. While non­
member banks in many states have the op­
portunity to hold their required reserves in
earning assets, member banks do not. Pay­
ment of interest on reserves and reductions
in required reserve ratios would provide
added revenue to these banks which could
help offset any increase in costs.
A third proposal is designed expressly to
help ease cost pressures during the initial
phase of NOW accounts. It calls for maxi­
mum interest rates on NOW accounts equal
to the maximum allowed on passbook savings
at commercial banks. The proposal allows,
however, for the interest rate ceiling on
NOWs to be set below this maximum and
then to rise gradually over a period of several
years. Such a gradual phase-in procedure

would reduce the likelihood of sharp increases
in the cost of funds and would give bankers a
little breathing room in their search for a
desirable pricing plan. A final provision calls
for the NOW account package to take effect
one year after it is signed into law, and this
delay would give bankers additional time to
gear up for NOW accounts. Each of these
proposals represents another advantage that
bankers around the country would have that
their New England counterparts did not.
BANKERS’ CONCERNS IN PERSPECTIVE
After examining the ways that NOW accounts
could affect commercial banks, it seems safe
to say that bankers have solid reasons for
concern over these new accounts. They are
faced with the prospect of paying interest
where they paid none explicitly before as
well as with the prospect of added competi­
tion for funds. Understandably, bankers are
worried that all of this will mean higher costs
for them.
But several advantages of financial reform
could help offset the cost pressures from
added competition. Paying interest in cash
can be more efficient than paying in the form
of bank services. And with an appropriate
pricing plan, paying cash interest actually
could lower bank costs. Moreover, the initial
phase of NOW accounts may be easier than
many bankers think. Bankers have the New
England experience with NOWs as a guide­
line, they may be in a stronger competitive
position with thrifts than banks in New
England, and they might enjoy the benefit of
a gradual phase-in of interest ceilings on
NOWs. At the same time, member banks may
begin to earn interest on required reserves.
All of this could help mitigate any higher
costs that banks might feel from NOW ac­
counts. Banks in Massachusetts and New
Hampshire didn’t have any of these advan­
tages, but most of them have fared reason­
ably well.
In short, while NOW accounts may not be
a picnic for bankers, neither are they likely to
be as damaging as many bankers fear.

H “The Impact of the Payment of Interest,” p. 47.




10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Commodity
Agreements:
The Haves vs.
the Have-Nots?
By Janice Moulton Westerfield*
The industrialized nations soon may be
transferring more of their wealth when they
buy raw materials. Even now, the develop­
ing countries are trying to arrange interna­
tional agreements which would raise the
prices of 19 basic commodities and stabilize
them at higher-than-market levels.
In the past, commodity agreements have
been limited to a single resource, such as tin
or coffee. The present push toward a blanket
agreement covering many commodities comes
from countries that are rich in raw materials
but haven’t developed the industrial base to
turn them into finished goods. These coun­
tries are dissatisfied with having their econo­
mies depend on the actions of the market­
place. Moreover, they watched the OPEC

cartel pile up huge revenues from oil, and
they would like to use commodity agreements
to emulate OPEC’s earning performance.
Spokesmen for the developing countries
claim that commodity agreements would
guarantee the industrialized nations access
to raw materials and at the same time promote
economic development and the redistribution
of wealth. Representatives of the developed
countries reply that letting market forces
operate would produce the largest output for
everyone while intervention in commodity
markets will lead to economic waste and
misallocation of resources. Thus the issues
raised by commodity agreements concern
both the size and the manner of income
transfers from the have countries to the havenots. The developed countries, because of
their interest in maintaining harmonious re­
lations, are likely to go along part way. But
they will continue to seek more efficient
ways to expand trade and to improve condi­
tions in the developing countries.

‘ Janice M. Westerfield, who joined the bank in 1973
and received her Ph.D. from the University of Pennsyl­
vania the following year, writes frequently on inter­
national finance and trade.




11

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

WHAT ARE ICAs?
There’s nothing new about attempts to
stabilize commodity prices. What is new is
the fervor with which the developing nations
are urging their case for commodity agree­
ments as the preferred method of transferring
income.
International commodity agreements (ICAs]
have certain features in common. Their mem­
bership includes both producing and con­
suming countries. (The OPEC cartel, for
example, is not an ICA because consumer
countries do not participate.] They have
certain stated objectives, such as stabilizing
prices, assuring adequate supplies to con­
sumers, and promoting the economic develop­
ment of the producers. A typical statement
of objectives can be found in the coffee
agreement: “to achieve a reasonable balance
between world supply and demand on a basis
which will assure adequate supplies of coffee
at fair prices to consumers and markets for
coffee at remunerative prices to producers
[and] to avoid excessive fluctuations in levels
of world supplies, stocks and prices which
are harmful to both producers and con­
sumers.”! Finally, an ICA is administered by
a central council which represents the mem­
bers.
ICAs fall into three kinds—quota, buffer
stock, and multilateral purchase arrange­
ment. A quota arrangement, such as the
coffee agreement or sugar agreement, speci­
fies quantities to be exported by each pro­
ducer. B u ffer sto ck s (inventories of com­
modities] may be used alone or in conjunction
with a quota system, as with tin. The buffer
stock system attempts to stabilize prices by
buying up the commodity when the price
nears an agreed-upon floor and selling the
commodity when the price approaches the
ceiling. The third type of agreement—a multi­
lateral contract such as the wheat agreement—
sets up ranges of intervention for commodity
prices. Consumer countries agree to purchase

certain amounts of the commodity at no less
than the minimum price while producer
countries agree to sell certain amounts at no
more than the maximum price. The market
mechanism functions between these limits.
The wider the price range, the closer the
system approximates a free market; the nar­
rower the range, the more the system ap­
proaches a quota system with guaranteed
prices. (For a history and analysis of the tin
agreement, see Box.]
These three kinds of agreements have a
strong attraction for the developing countries,
especially because of the way these countries
perceive their own position in the international
trading arena.
HOW THE DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
SEE IT
The developing countries are interested in
having international economic relations work
more in their favor, and high on their list is
the stabilization of their export earnings.
Many of the developing countries depend
heavily on export earnings from one or two
commodities. When prices for these com­
modities fluctuate, ongoing economic develop­
ment programs become hard to sustain, and
long-range efforts become more difficult to
plan.
These countries argue not only that their
trade position is disadvantageous but also
that it is deteriorating. They claim that because
the ratio of export prices to import prices—
the terms of trade—has declined over time,
their traditional exports now buy fewer im­
ports from the developed countries. In order
to prevent further slippage, they’ve proposed
that raw material prices be indexed to prices
of manufactured goods. That way, the prices
of the raw materials they export would keep
pace with the prices of manufactured imports.
Along with stabilization of export earnings
and improvement in the terms of trade, the
developing countries are looking for easier
access to the markets and technology of their
industrialized trading partners. Access to
these potentially large markets currently is

international Coffee Agreement 1976, p. 2.




12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

BOX

INTERNATIONAL TIN AGREEMENT
Some form of international control of tin production has been in effect for over 50 years. Initially,
only the producing nations were parties to the agreement. Several attempts were made by the
members to include the consuming nations, but none was successful until the early 1950s, when
the U. S. stopped buying tin for its strategic stockpiles.* This withdrawal from the market and the
resulting price decline helped spur negotiations for a new agreement. The First International Tin
Agreement became effective in July 1956 for five years. Subsequent agreements, also of five years’
duration, were negotiated, and the U. S. became a member of the Fifth Agreement.
The main objective of the agreement has been to adjust world production and consumption of tin
so as to “prevent excessive fluctuations in the price and export earnings of tin.” The central
provisions to attain these goals—buffer stocks and export controls—have remained unchanged.
The International Tin Council administers the buffer stock operations to maintain prices within a
target zone. When prices reach the floor of the target zone, the Council buys tin until the market
price rises above this level or the funds are exhausted. When prices approach the ceiling, tin stocks
are sold as long as the stocks last. Buffer stocks are considered the first line of defense; export quotas
are held in reserve for situations that the buffer stock can’t control. Export quotas can be tightened to
shore up the floor price, and penalties can be imposed on countries that exceed their export quotas.
These controls have been operative about one-quarter of the time.
The tin agreements have been quite successful in maintaining the floor price. Only once, in
September 1958, has the price fallen below the floor level. And that price decline was caused mainly
by sales of tin by the U .S.S.R., a nonmember. Maintaining the ceiling price has been more difficult.
Ceiling prices were exceeded in 1961, 1963-66, and in the 1970s, and they would have been broken
more often if they had not been raised. In recent years, the buffer stocks were exhausted, export
quotas were suspended, and prices still remained above the ceiling of the target zone. The buffer
stock was doubled in the Fifth Agreement, which became effective provisionally in July 1976.
Though the agreements may have contributed somewhat to a more stable tin price, average prices
probably have been higher than they would have been without the agreements.
‘ Through the years, critics have objected that the price was set so high that even mines with high production
costs were able to operate at a profit. High prices also stimulated the search for substitutes. Shortly after World
War II, new methods of tin plating, food storage (freezing), and competition from aluminum and synthetic
products all acted to dampen demand.

restricted by quotas, tariffs, and other barriers.
Actually, many developing countries are
guaranteed access on a basis of equality—for
example, at the same tariff level—with other
nations. 2 But they want more than just equal

access; they want free entry for the products
of their fledgling industries. Preferential treatby the rules of the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade. One important exception is the customs union,
which may reduce or eliminate all trade barriers for
members. A second is the Generalized System of Prefer­
ences which the U.S. implemented in January 1976.
This program grants duty-free entry to selected imports
from eligible developing countries, subject to quantity
restrictions.

2The most-favored-nation clause extends tariff reduc­
tions granted to one country to all other countries with
which the first exchanges most-favored-nation treatment.
This approach has been used for commodities covered




13

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

BUSINESS REVIEW

ment is required, they claim, if they are to
compete with developed countries that al­
ready have well-established customs unions
and other arrangements for trading their
goods.
The developing countries look to interna­
tional commodity agreements as the answer.
ICAs, they believe, would raise the relative
prices of their exports, stabilize those prices,
and enable them to develop their productive
resources. In short, ICAs would start wealth
flowing their way, as, they believe, other
forms of economic assistance have failed to
do.
But outside the developing countries, many
people have doubts about the value of ICAs.
They take a different view of what has been
happening to commodity price stability and
they emphasize the drawbacks of commodity
agreements. They believe that a clearer per­
spective on these matters ought to precede a
decision for or against ICAs.

export price index for manufactured goods
rose from 78 to 213. Since these indexes take
1963 as the base year (= 100], they indicate
that from the base year on, prices of primary
products have outrun prices of industrial
goods. Thus while some countries may face
worsening terms of trade, a close look at the
evidence does not support a case for overall
deterioration. 3
Further, the evidence for price instability
for primary products is far from conclusive.
Most of the primary commodities except
cocoa have seen a lessening of price fluctua­
tions since midcentury. Large groups of
commodities show less price fluctuation in
the third quarter than in the first half of this
century, and the same goes for an important
commodity subgroup.4 But since 1950, primary
commodity prices have fluctuated on average
about 1.5 percent per year more than prices for
manufactured goods.
While overall price instability for primary
products probably has been overstated by
those who favor ICAs, it remains true that
some primary commodities may suffer severe
price fluctuations. And since some nations
may depend on one or two export commodi-

HOW SOUND ARE THE ARGUMENTS
FOR ICAs?
The arguments about price instability and
terms of trade demand special attention, for
they lie at the heart of the developing coun­
tries' case for commodity agreements. It’s
important to know also which are the pro­
ducing and which the consuming nations, as
well as how likely it is that commodity
agreements would accomplish what they’re
designed for.
Movements in Commodity Prices. The
evidence for the terms of trade argument
depends upon the time period chosen. It
appears that over the first half of this century,
commodity prices were trending upward.
During the decade after the Korean War,
prices of most primary products fell while
those of manufactured goods were rising
slightly, but the next decade saw the terms of
trade improve for the developing countries.
Overall from 1950 to 1975, the United Nations
export price index of primary commodities
(excluding oil] rose from 105 to 225 while the




3From 1972 to mid-1974 the U.N. index of export
prices of all primary commodities increased by over 100
percent. The other side of the picture is the sharp decline
in commodity prices observed the following two years
(followed by another price rise in 1976], Nevertheless,
commodity prices in general outstripped manufactured
goods prices from 1972 to 1976. Indexing commodity
prices to manufactured goods prices would have resulted
in smaller revenues for commodity producers.
4The U.N. price index for 22 primary commodities
had an average annual fluctuation of 14.5 percent over
the first half of this century. The average fluctuation
dropped to 4.5 percent for the period 1950-62 and then
rose slightly to about 7.5 percent for the period 1963-75.
The average annual price change for the ten core
commodities (excluding hard fibers) fell from +14.7
percent in the first half-century to +11,3 percent for the
period 1950-75. Dae Yong Choi assisted in calculating
these figures from Instability in Export Markets o f
Underdeveloped Countries (New York: United Nations
Department of Economic Affairs, 1952) and from various
issues of the U. N. Monthly Bulletin o f Statistics.

14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

case to see which countries would benefit
from the higher prices ICAs would bring. It’s
likely that commodity agreements would
make the U .S., the U .S .S .R ., and other
resource-rich developed countries the major
beneficiaries and would bring small benefits
to the developing countries. 6 In short, agree­
ments on large groups of commodities could
give the developing nations the promise of
economic improvement without the return
they expect and end up benefiting mainly the
developed countries.
Are ICAs Workable? Even if the terms of
trade were unfavorable to the developing
countries, and even if the developing coun­
tries were the main commodity producers
and thus the main prospective beneficiaries
of ICAs, these agreements still might not
work out very well. Economic conditions
favorable to commodity agreements are dif­
ficult to maintain over the long haul. Indeed,
a recent M IT study found that commodity
cartels which put through large price hikes
lasted an average of only four to six years. 7
The difficulties are less severe when fewer

ties for a large part of their income, a drop in
the price of either or both may be extremely
troublesome, even if the average price for a
group of primary products holds much more
stable. This lack of diversification in a develop­
ing nation’s economic base may be at the
heart of the drive toward ICAs. It’s likely that
individual commodity price fluctuations could
be reduced much more efficiently in other
ways—for example, by developing markets
that deal in future purchases and sales of
primary commodities. But the developing
countries continue to argue in favor of ICAs,
believing that the terms of trade have deteri­
orated and that primary product prices have
been destabilized overall.
Who Are the Commodity Producers? Fur­
thermore, the division into producers and
consumers of primary commodities is not as
simple as appears at first sight. Consumers
cannot be identified with developed countries
nor producers with developing countries.
OPEC is a revealing example: here the inter­
ests of the developing countries that don’t
produce oil are aligned with those of the
consumer nations. In primary commodities,
the principle producers are the d ev elop ed
countries. In fact, the developed nations
produce about 70 percent of the commodities
under discussion at UNCTAD (United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development) and
account for nearly 50 percent of the exports. 5
The U .S., for instance, leads the world in
cotton exports. Wheat and rice are other
commodities heavily imported by the develop­
ing countries.
Because different countries produce dif­
ferent primary products, perhaps the list of
commodities should be examined case by

6The developing countries want to improve their eco­
nomic position in relative as well as absolute terms. But
because the developing countries consume a large
portion of the world’s raw materials and export signifi­
cant quantities of manufactured goods, higher com­
modity prices may not improve their net foreign earnings
as much as they hope. The gains anticipated by the
developing countries will be reduced to the extent that
they import costlier raw materials and export relatively
inexpensive manufactured goods. Moreover, because
commodity agreements constrain the total supply of
goods, such agreements may reduce the size of the
economic pie available to be divided.
Nevertheless, because some developing countries
have not been able to diversify their exports, they tend
to be concerned with the prices of only a very few
commodities. A few primary products may generate a
sizable portion of their export earnings while money
spent on imports is spread over a whole basket of goods.
Thus they see it as their interest to concentrate on the
few export prices that have a strong effect on their own
economies.
7 P. L. Eckbo, “OPEC and the Experience of Previous
International Commodity Cartels,” Working Paper No.
75-008WP, MIT Energy Laboratory, August 1975.

^The primary products under discussion at the NorthSouth talks were cocoa, coffee, tea, sugar, jute, cotton,
natural rubber, copper, bananas, iron ore, bauxite,
beef, sisal, vegetable oils, oil seeds, tropical woods,
manganese, phosphate, and zinc. The UNCTAD dis­
cussions cover ten core commodities [the first eight
listed above plus hard fibers and tin) as well as bananas,
iron ore, bauxite, meat, wool, wheat, and rice.




15

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

BUSINESS REVIEW

producers are parties to the agreement be­
cause detecting attempts to cheat and policing
the agreement are simpler then. Reaching a
consensus on barriers to keep competitors
out of the market may be easier, too. But
entry barriers and policing still have to be
taken care of.
One cause of the fragility of commodity
agreements is technological innovation which
leads to the substitution of synthetics for
natural products. Commodity agreements
are effective in keeping prices up only so
long as no cheaper substitutes can be found
for the protected item. When the supply of
natural rubber was restricted in the 1920s,
for example, synthetic rubber was brought
onto the market. And when natural fibers,
such as silk, cotton, and wool, became scarce
or very costly because of war or production
cutbacks, chemical companies produced man­
made fibers to fill the demand. Metals also
have given way to substitution, by cheaper
metals and plastics.
Further, each kind of ICA has its own
characteristic weaknesses. Quota systems
specify amounts to be exported by each
producer. But producers may try to circum­
vent their quotas if they see gains to be made
from increased production and sales. And
reallocation of quotas among producers has
proven difficult. Nor do quotas keep produ­
cers outside the agreement from expanding
their production.
The buffer stock system also has draw­
backs. The main drawback with a buffer
stock is that it may require extensive financ­
ing by member countries to acquire the
commodity and support its price. If the fund
isn’t large enough, buffer stock operations
won’t have much effect on prices. Price
ceilings, especially, have proven hard to
maintain. Further, the market in which the
manager buys and sells the commodity must
be well organized. The establishment of
intervention points—floor and ceiling prices—
requires forecasting a market-clearing price
that anticipates future developments. If pro­
ducers are to receive a net benefit, members




then must negotiate an average price which
is higher than the market-clearing price if
they are to bring about a transfer of income
from consumers to producers.
Other difficulties confront the manager of
a buffer stock. If the floor price is set too
high, producers step up production, especially
if convinced the buffer stock manager will
support the price. In this case, too many
resources will be used in production of the
commodity, and surpluses will result.8 Fur­
ther, a manager must be able to distinguish
short-term fluctuations from long-term trends
in prices. A secular price increase that is
offset continually by sales from the stock­
pile, for example, will deplete the buffer
stock and leave the manager unable to defend
the ceiling price. Even a buffer stock which
exhibits no systematic imbalance in pur­
chases or sales can be costly to operate.
Storage costs, brokerage fees, and general
operating expenses may be sizable.9
Thus, in short, the history and practical
8 Critics argue that commodity agreements are ineffi­
cient mechanisms for allocating resources. If a com­
modity price is supported above the equilibrium price,
high-cost producers will be subsidized. They will respond
by expanding production, and their extra production
will be purchased for the buffer stock. The result will be
a surplus of the commodity—to be stored or destroyed.
Meanwhile, consumers will respond to the artificially
high prices by buying less and shifting their demand to
substitutes.
Because the developing countries do not appear to
dispute the inefficiencies of commodity agreements, it's
hard to see why they are so adamant about them. It
would be more efficient economically to develop futures
markets in commodities to smooth price fluctuations
and then to transfer wealth to the developing countries
as a separate operation via direct aid or loans.
9A recent study estimated that the maximum initial
capital outlays to establish buffer stocks for eight
agricultural commodities would be $8.3 billion. This
estimate assumes buffer stocks large enough to keep
price fluctuations within 10 percent of the target level.
Pooling the capital outlays for the buffer stocks would
reduce the amount of capital required if the commodity
prices tend to move independently of one another. For
further discussion see P. A. MacAvoy and D. L. McNicol,
“Commodity Agreements and the New International
Economic Order,” Council of Economic Advisers, June
1976.
16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

the commodity would be sold. But the integra­
tion of the individual commodity agreements
has not been agreed upon. One approach
would have the common fund lend money to
individual commodity councils which would
own and trade the stocks. Then the common
fund, through the commodity councils, could
channel money received from sales of one
commodity into purchases of other commodi­
ties for the buffer stocks.
Both economic and political considerations,
as well as humanitarian ones, appear to
dictate some sort of an affirmative response
to the developing countries’ pleas for aid. The
developed nations already have sunk huge
investments into the developing countries,
and they want those investments to be pro­
ductive. Maintaining harmonious relations
is likely to discourage nationalization and to
forestall boycotts and other obstacles to
mutually beneficial trade. Further, the Third
World countries vastly outnumber the devel­
oped countries, and their growing political
power makes them a force to be reckoned
with. The question is what sort of response is
most appropriate.

economics of commodity agreements justify
only modest hopes for their success. More­
over, there is no conclusive evidence avail­
able for the alleged deterioration in commodity
price stability and in the terms of trade.
CURRENT STATUS OF ICAs
In light of these facts, it is not surprising
that negotiators for the developed countries
have shown some reluctance toward the ICA
proposals. At the recent North-South talks in
Paris, for example, the 27 participant coun­
tries could agree on only 20 of 41 subjects
under discussion, according to their joint
communique. The developed countries clearly
haven’t bought the argument that commodity
agreements will provide consumers with ready
access to supplies at reasonable prices.
Most developed countries, and especially
the U. S., are reluctant to endorse the ideology
behind the ICAs. TheU .S. position has shifted
from vaguely favorable to cool and back
again over the years. In 1961, President
Kennedy pledged that the U. S. was ready to
examine commodity market difficulties on a
case-by-case basis. But not much was agreed
upon until President Carter started the ball
rolling again by stating in New York that the
U. S. was “willing to consider with a positive
and open attitude, the negotiation of agree­
ments to stabilize commodity prices, including
the establishment of a common fund . . . .”
Since then, at the Conference on Interna­
tional Economic Cooperation (CIEC) in Paris,
the U .S. has agreed to the principle of a
common fund to support commodity prices.
Further negotiations are scheduled for the
current UNCTAD meeting (November 1977).
The common fund, indeed, has been the
main stumbling block in these negotiations.
The developing countries have argued for a
$6-billion fund to stabilize the prices of the
19 primary commodities. Basically, this com­
mon fund would be used to establish a buffer
stock for each commodity. Under this system,
when the price of a commodity threatened to
fall below the floor, the commodity would be
purchased; when the price reached the ceiling,




OTHER WAYS TO TRANSFER WEALTH
Perhaps all the rhetoric about commodities
has obscured the real issue—income redistri­
bution towards the poorer developing coun­
tries. Many people believe that it should be
possible to transfer wealth to these countries
in a way which avoids the pitfalls of price
supports—unwanted surpluses, artificially
high prices, and misallocation of resources
that may accompany interference with the
pricing mechanism.
One alternative favored by the U .S. is to
expand the IM F Compensatory Financing
Facility. This IMF facility already is available
to member countries suffering from balanceof-payments deficits. It’s role could be extended
to provide larger drawing rights for member
countries that have shortfalls in export earn­
ings from primary products.
To the extent that the economic malaise of
the developing countries stems from price
17

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1977

BUSINESS REVIEW

instabilities caused by lack of diversification
rather than from an overall, long-term deteri­
oration in the terms of trade, a balance-ofpayments financing facility may provide the
remedy. Another alternative, advocated by
the Europeans, would be to expand the
Stabex program of the European Community.
At present, Stabex is a half-billion-dollar
fund which provides support for export earn­
ings from several basic commodities and is
available to some 50 countries associated
with the EC. Other options include expanding
loans from the World Bank and other interna­
tional institutions.
Direct aid to the developing countries may
be extended through either foreign aid or
special action funds. Back in 1968 at the
Delhi session of UNCTAD, the industrial
countries accepted the goal that 1 percent of
their GNP be devoted to aid through public
and private transfers. This goal was reiterated
as part of the Paris agreement when the
industrial countries agreed to work toward a
target rate of 0.7 percent of a country’s GNP
as direct aid. Countries like Canada and
Sweden agreed to write off the debt of
certain distressed countries to the tune of
$254 million. The participating countries
also agreed upon a special action fund to
help the poorest countries.io

A PEEK AT THE FUTURE
Policymakers in the developed countries
have accepted the premise that they must
share more of their countries’ wealth with
the developing nations. But both the extent
and the method of redistribution are far from
settled. They definitely do not want raw
material prices indexed to prices of manu­
factured goods. They may, however, go part
way toward preserving and increasing the
purchasing power of other countries. So, for
example, they are willing to allow entry of
some goods imported from the developing
countries on a preferential basis. Similarly,
they are ready to commit funds to develop­
ment projects, as long as those projects are
well laid out. It’s likely, then, that the devel­
oped countries will pledge some further aid,
even if it’s less than the 1 percent of GNP
demanded by the developing countries.
As new pressures for commodity agree­
ments are brought to bear, most of the
developed countries will accept limited inter­
ference with the pricing mechanism because
they think they have no choice. But over the
long haul, they can be expected to push for
alternative forms of aid—forms that preserve
the efficiencies and economic growth that
market forces can foster.

10The U. S. pledged $345 million to the special action
fund, a sum which needs Congressional approval to be
effective by fiscal year 1978. The European Community

pledged $385 million, Japan $114 million, Canada $51
million, Sweden $29 million, Switzerland $26 million,
Australia $18 million, and Spain $2 million.




18

NEW From the

Philadelphia FED...

ECONOMIC M AN
vs. SOCIAL MAN

AND O TH ER TALKS
By David P. Eastburn
Copies of this new publication are available without charge from the Department of
Public Services, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 100 North Sixth Street, Philadelphia,
Pennsylvania 19106.
_______




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA
BUSIN ESS REVIEW • CONTENTS 1 9 7 7
agl

l■ :
l

|:

ig ill

H Sm I

JANUARY/FEBRUARY

JULY/AUGUST

John J. Seater, “Coping With Unemploy­
ment
Anthony M. Rufolo, “Local Government
Wages and Services: How Much Should
Citizens Pay?”
Table of Contents 1976
Annual Operations and Executive Changes

Donald J. Mullineaux, “Inflation Expec­
tations in the U.S.: A Brief Anatomy”
Helen F. Peters, “The Mortgage Market:
A Place for Ceilings?”
The Fed in Print
SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER

•

MARCH/APRIL

Nonna A. Noto, “The Economics of
muting in a Higher Cost World”
Nariman Behravesh, "The World 1
Cycle: Is It Here To Stay?”

Nonna A. Noto and Donald L.
"Philadelphia’s Fiscal Story: The City and
the Schools”

BOB

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER
MAY/JUNE
Jam es M. O’Brien, “A Case for Market
Interest Rates”
Stewart Schw ab and John J. Seater, “The
Unemployment Rate: Time to Give It a
.. 1
Rest?”
^

^

amasmmmamm

on Independence M all
100 North Sixth Street
Philadelphia, Pa. 19106




a m B

Howard Keen, “Why Bankers Are Con­
cerned About NOW Accounts”
Janice M. Westerfield, “Commodity AgreeI
ments The Haves vs. the Have-Nots?”
Table of Contents

i§ '

v ii

.. S

§s

!1977
_

_

Ltufta : .

.......................