View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA

business rerieu*

r

i

SELECTIV E
CREDIT
POLICIES:
Should Their
Role Be Expanded?

L




A
1975

ABOUT THIS ISSUE. . .
Selective credit policies have periodically been embraced by policymakers and their
constituents to achieve a wide variety of objectives. Frequently the goals sought have
been laudable. But all too often advocates have moved ahead without the kind of
guidance that can be provided by systematic economic research. In large part this was
because of a marked lack of such research. It was with this lack in mind that the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia undertook a major and ongoing project to investigate
credit-allocation techniques.
I n this issue we summarize the conclusions to come out of the first phase of the project
(the technical papers appear in Ira Kaminow and James M. O'Brien, eds., Studies in Selec­
tive Credit Policies, [Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 1975]). Perhaps the overriding
conclusion emerging from this summary is that the current state of scientific knowledge
concerning the issues surrounding selective credit policies is simply inadequate to make
any confident assessment of their impacts at this time.
In the work currently underway we hope to provide more positive answers concerning
the effects of selective credit policies. It is possible that this work could indicate a useful
social role for credit policies. But given the large degree of uncertainty that now exists, it is
difficult to endorse current credit-allocation proposals. However sympathetic one may
be with the social goals of those who are for allocating credit, the economic underpin­
nings need a great deal more study before such policies can be pronounced reliable.

David P. Eastburn
President,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

BUSINESS REVIEW is produced in the Department of Research. Editorial assistance is provided
by Robert Ritchie, Associate Editor. Ronald B. Williams is Art Director and Manager, Graphic
Services. The authors will be glad to receive comments on their articles.

Requests for additional copies should be addressed to Public Information, Federal
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
of of St. Louis
Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19105. Phone: (215) 574-6115.
Federal Reserve Bank

Reserve Bank

Selective Credit Policies:
Should Their Role
Be Expanded?*
example, large corporate borrowers are al­
leged to get “preferential treatment" in credit
markets while small businessmen or
municipalities are squeezed out.
Selective credit policies (also called selec­
tive credit controls or credit-allocation
policies) are frequently proposed as a solu­
tion. These policies would encourage
“favored" uses of credit and discourage
others through incentives and penalties. For
example, more credit could be made
available for home buyers or local
governments through subsidies and less for
“ unproductive" ventures by taxing such
loans. In the U. S., we already have a number
of credit support programs aimed at housing,
municipal services, education, agriculture,
exports, and other activities which involve
several billion dollars in subsidies each year.1

Using credit to build a business, buy a
house, or bring home a new car is part of the
American way of life. The importance of this
tradition has spurred the concern of Congress
and others (such as housing interests, small
business associations, and women's
groups) about who gets credit, when, and in
what amounts. The most recent worry in some
policymaking circles is that credit markets
keep certain sectors of our economy from
receiving the share of credit they deserve, es­
pecially during periods of tight money. For

*This article was prepared by Ira Kaminow and James
M. O ’Brien. It is based on a research project on selective
credit controls sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia. For the specific studies undertaken in this
project, see Ira Kaminow and James M. O'Brien, eds.,
Studies in Selective Credit Policies (Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia, 1975). Summaries of the individual
studies are presented in Appendix 2 of this article. To ob­
tain copies of the volume, see notice on page 23.

’With respect to the costs only of Federal credit
programs, see Murray L. Weidenbaum, “ Subsidies in
Federal Credit Programs,” in U. S., Congress, Joint
Economic Committee, The Economics of Federal Subsi­
dy Programs, 92d Cong., 2d sess., 8 May 1972, part 1, pp.
106-19.

The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia is interested
in the issue of selective credit controls because of their
current popularity and the System’s long history of in­
volvement with certain credit policies. (See Appendix 1.)




3

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

markets may fall short for several reasons, ac­
cording to proponents of credit policies. First,
the markets are not competitive enough to
ensure that the mix of goods and services
society values most will be produced. Second,
partly because of the first reason, during
bouts of "tight money" credit markets
squeeze out the "wrong" borrowers. And,
third, our product markets "underproduce"
certain goods that generate additional public
benefits.
Are Credit Markets Competitive Enough to
Do Their Job? In a free market economy
credit goes to the borrower who uses it most
profitably. If markets are competitive, the
most profitable uses are likely to coincide
with those society values. (Although the
coincidence of profitability and socially
valuable uses requires more than com­
petitive markets.)
In a noncompetitive environment, how­
ever, this may not be the case. Some propo­
nents of selective credit policies claim that
there is a serious lack of competition in the
banking industry and perhaps in other finan­
cial markets as well.2 They argue that banks
*
maintain special relationships with large cor­
porations who receive preferential (“ prime")
rates, while small businesses and individuals
pay higher interest rates. On occasion, small
borrowers will not be able to get credit
regardless of the rate they are willing to pay.
Recently this kind of argument has received
a good deal of discussion in the debate con­
cerning "redlining" — a procedure whereby
lending institutions allegedly refuse to ex­
tend credit for housing or urban renewal in
certain geographical areas. Slums and socalled declining neighborhoods are alleged
to be particularly affected by the redlining
process. Selective credit policies are often

Is further Government intervention in credit
markets warranted?
Whether credit-allocation policies should
be expanded hinges on the answers to three
questions: Will shifting resources into
different products or sectors of the economy
via credit policies produce gains for society?
Are credit policies able to reallocate real
resources in order to achieve such gains?
What is it going to cost society to implement
these programs?
In evaluating what we do know about the
effects of credit-allocation proposals, the
overwhelming conclusion emerges that at
present we are very far from satisfactory
answers to the first two questions. Moreover,
while the analysis did not specifically focus on
the third question about costs, there is little
doubt that society will bear some burden in
implementing credit controls. On this basis,
expanding Government's role in credit
markets would be a major gamble with the
odds of "winning" highly uncertain.
SOCIAL BENEFITS FROM ALTERING CREDIT
MARKETS?
Selective credit programs are ultimately
aimed at improving the lot of society. In a
broad sense these policies presumably have
objectives such as equality of opportunity,
social stability, reduction in the inequality of
income, and more efficient use of resources
in our economy. Many proponents of creditallocation programs argue that the current
mix of output in the U.S. economy fails to
contribute to the achievement of these goals.
Others focus on who gets the output, rather
than the goods themselves, and make a
similar kind of case. If this logic is valid, the
solution seems obvious: change the mix of
goods and servicesthe economy grinds out or
the mix of individuals receiving them.
Clearly the case for selective credit policies
depends on whether the economy turns out
the "appropriate" mix of goods and services
and distributes them to the "right" in­
dividuals to achieve the broad goals. Credit



2
See, for example, Lester C. Thurow, “ Proposals for
Rechanneling Funds to Meet Social Priorities,” in Policies
for a More Competitive Financial System: A Review of
the Report of the President's Commission on Financial
Structure and Regulation, Conference Series No. 8
(Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1972), pp. 177-89.

4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

of competitive restrictions and consequent
distortion of credit flows appear mainly
related to Government credit regulations
currently in force. In particular, prohibiting
interest on demand deposits and setting
interest-rate ceilings on time and savings
deposits inhibit depository institutions in
competing for the savings of households.
These interest restrictions also discriminate
against small savers for whom time and
savings deposits constitute a major form of
saving.
Furthermore, the argument continues,
credit markets can be competitive and still
allow such things as "prime" borrowers.4The
reason isthese phenomena may simply repre­
sent efficient responses by lenders toward
risk. Large corporate borrowers may get
"prime" rates because there is less chance of
default on the loan or because they are
regular customers with large deposit accounts
who provide some stability to the bank's long­
term earnings prospects. Borrowers with low
incomes or with whom the lender is less ac­
quainted may represent a higher credit risk.
To compensate for this additional risk, a
higher interest rate must be charged. Where
the likelihood of default on the loan is quite
substantial, lenders may be reluctant to ex­
tend credit at any rate since the return they
anticipate will be quite small or perhaps even
negative. According to this view, it is less ob­
vious that financial markets are not doing the
job they're designed to do—rationing
society's savings more favorably to highreturn/low-risk investment projects and less
favorably to low-return/high-risk ventures.5
On the whole, arguments concerning the
existence of credit market imperfections
provide little support for credit-allocation

proposed to redress these kinds of credit
market "imperfections/'
Many economists, however, might resist
this argument on grounds that credit markets
are far from noncompetitive and riddled with
imperfections. In contrast to most foreign
countries, the U.S. has a myriad of highly
developed credit markets, each possessing a
relatively large number of lenders. It is
reasonable to expect such a system to be
characterized by a high degree of competi­
tion, and there is little hard evidence to
suggest that competition is substantially lack­
ing in U. S. credit markets.3 In fact, evidence
3Some would argue that although there are a large
number of banks, they are really segmented into geo­
graphically defined markets where some areas would
have only a “few” banks. Without considering the validi­
ty of this argument, there is still little evidence to suggest
that geographical restrictions on competitive lending
behavior have or would produce pervasive biases against
any particular set of borrowers, such as small businesses
or home buyers. There has also been some tendency to
cite oligopolistic lending practices among large banks to
help explain loan rate rigidities and the customer
relationship. (See Thurow, “ Proposals for Channeling
Funds to Meet Social Priorities,” op. cit., pp. 177-89;
Donald R. Hodgman, “The Deposit Relationship and
Commercial Bank Investment Behavior,” Review of
Economics and Statistics 42 [1961]: 257-68; Edward J. Kane
and Burton G. Malkiel, “ Bank Portfolio Allocation,
Deposit Variability, and the Availability Doctrine,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 79 [1965]: 125; and
Dwight Jaffee and Franco Modigliani, “A Theory and Test
of Credit Rationing,” American Economic Review 59
[1969]: 851-72.) However, this citation would seem to be
more of a casual suggestion than resulting from any
serious presentation of theory or evidence to support the
position. The analytical models developed to explain
credit rationing and customer relationships generally are
quite compatible with a high degree of atomistic-type
lending behavior (albeit with regulatory constraints and
long-run profit concerns). Moreover, the observation of
loan rate sluggishness and “ price leadership” (a bank in­
itiating a loan rate change later followed by others) may
reflect competitive market behavior under demand un­
certainty and disequilibrium rather than the oligopolistic
pricing procedure that is often suggested. See Edmund S.
Phelps et al., Microeconomic Foundations for Employ­
ment and Inflation Theory (New York: W. W. Norton and
Company, 1970) and Kenneth J. Arrow, “Toward a Theory
of Price Adjustment,” Moses Abramovitz, ed., The
Allocation of Economic Resources (Stanford, Calif.: Stan­
ford University Press, 1959), pp. 41-51.



4This point plus others that provide a basis for question­
ing the credit-market imperfection arguments are
presented in detail in Ira Kaminow and James M. O ’Brien,
“ Issues in Selective Credit Policies: An Evaluative Essay,”
Kaminow and O ’Brien, eds., Studies in Selective Credit
Policies, pp. 6-10.
5Some advocates of selective credit controls agree that
credit markets are efficient but object to the impact of ef­
ficiency on different groups (see Box 1).

5

NOVEMBER 1975

BUSINESS REVIEW

Box 1

SELECTIVE CREDIT CONTROLS AND THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME
Selective credit controls are envisioned by some proponents as a tool for reducing the
large degree of inequality in the distribution of income in the U. S. At first glance, deter­
mining the effects of credit policies on peoples' incomes seems pretty simple. If we sub­
sidize mortgage interest costs, the mortgagee comes out ahead. If we tax business loans,
the businessman sees his income cut. But this is only a very rough first approximation. As
home buyers respond by trying to get more mortgages, this will tend to raise mortgage in­
terest rates. The home buyer sees his mortgage subsidy quite plainly (such as a deduction
of interest costs from his taxable income) but is perhaps less aware that, because of the
subsidy, he's paying a higher mortgage rate. Thus, some of his gain may actually be shifted
to the mortgage lender. And it's not just the mortgage lender who might get some of the
subsidy. The increased demand for houses can force up home prices and people who sell
or build houses may gain too. Thus, the income gain to the mortgagee as a result of the
subsidy is further eroded.
The income ramifications of selective credit policies do not end here. Controls placed
on one market will have "spillover effects" on other markets. If mortgage rates go up, this
might also cause consumer loan rates to rise, for there will be less money available for
consumer loans as lenders switch to higher yielding mortages. The mortgage borrower
would be getting some benefit from the subsidy while the user of consumer credit would
be taking a loss. All this makes it doubly difficult to estimate the effects of credit policies
on the distribution of income. Whether a person finally comes out ahead or behind will
depend not only on whether he buys a home, but on the other assets and goods he buys
or the types of debt he incurs.
It is this "shifting” of a subsidy or tax from one credit instrument to others and to goods
and services which makes it difficult to pin down the effects of credit policies on peoples'
incomes. The state of the art in economics and statistics is not advanced enough to
measure the shifting as it actually works itself out. As a consequence, economists have
mostly trained their sights only on the initial income effects of credit policies on the credit
category actually being subsidized or taxed.
Most concern about the initial income incidence of selective credit policies has
centered around various mortgage subsidies and the incometax exemption on municipal
bond interest.* On the whole, these selective credit subsidies seem to benefit mainly
those in the upper half of the income scale. This appears to be the result of the way the
programs are designed and the ownership distribution of assets and debts that are in­
volved. It is the more affluent individual who, because of his relatively high-income tax
bracket, has the most to gain from the municipal bond income-tax exemption or the tax
*The housing subsidy studies include the deduction from taxable income of mortgage interest costs (or the
exemption from taxes of implicit income from housing ownership), mortgage-guarantee programs, and the
regulation of deposit interest rates. They exclude tne housing credit subsidies specifically designed for lowincome families.




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

deductibility of mortgage interest costs. It is also the more affluent who tend to buy more
expensive homes and, consequently, take out larger mortgages.
On the basis of these findings, we shouldn't jump to the conclusion that selective credit
policies will necessarily have a regressive effect on the distribution of income. If credit
policies were aimed at different types or uses of credit they might show a different in­
cidence pattern. Consumer credit, for example, is more heavily used by lower-income
groups than upper-income groups. With a subsidy to this credit category, lower-income
families might fare better. Even redesigning some of our mortgage and municipal bond
programs might render a more favorable incidence impact—for example, if the size of the
subsidy did not grow with the individual’s income-tax bracket.** Although we should still
keep in mind that, regardless of design, the difficulty of measuring the degree of "shift­
ing” of credit subsidies or taxes likely will still leave their ultimate income distribution
effects with a good deal of uncertainty.***

**With respect to the incidence conclusions concerning mortgage subsidies, we should not attempt any hasty
extrapolations of the effects on the ownership of housing. Selective credit policies affect a person’s income by
altering his income from assets and labor. An individual’s propensity to purchase a home will depend not only
on his income but on his responsiveness to mortgage rates. It is conceivable that while wealthier families receive
a large share of mortgage subsidies, less-wealthy families are more induced to become homeowners.
***lt can be expected that credit policies specificially aimed at low-income groups will be more likely to have
favorable income-distribution effects on those groups. However, the subsidy-shifting problem will remain even
with those policies. Furthermore, credit policies aimed at low-incomefamilies will have another drawback over
more direct income-distribution policies in that they are limited to those willing or able to use the subsidized
form of credit.

policies at this time. However, additional
evidence needs to be gathered before
rendering a verdict on this issue.

best possible job when credit is tight. In fact,
the appearance of "arbitrary” allocation may
be nothing more nor less than credit markets
doing their job of allocating scarce credit for
the most urgent uses. For example, mortgage
flows slow, they argue, because postponing
the purchase of a new house rather than post­
poning the purchase of food, clothing, or a
new car is easier. This doesn’t mean that food,
clothing, or cars are more important than
houses, only that houses that wear out slowly
can be made to "do” for another year or two.
Moreover, free marketeers argue that if there
is a problem it is more likely a result of too
much Government interference, not too
little.
In particular, one of the reasons credit flows
are altered during periods of “tight money”
stems from the existence of legal ceilings on
the interest rates that can be paid on certain

Offsetting the Effects of Tight Money. It is
often argued that selective credit policies
should be used to help the sectors that are
squeezed by tight credit. Advocates of this
view underscore the urgency of such action
when tight credit is brought on by restrictive
monetary policy. Here they argue that
because such a policy often makes it tough for
some credit demanders, selective credit
programs should be instituted to help those
bearing the heaviest burden.
But not everyone agrees that selective
credit policies are the answer (see Box 2). Op­
ponents of the policies argue that just as
smoothly functioning markets allocate credit
best when things are going well, they do the



7

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

Box 2

SELECTIVE CREDIT POLICIES AND
ECONOM IC STABILIZATION GOALS
A number of economists have suggested that the frequency of tight credit periods
might be reduced by relying less on monetary policy for stabilizing the economy and
more on fiscal policy (increasing the size of the Government's budget surplus) to slow
down an overexpanding economy. While this seems like a good idea at first, the plan also
has some significant drawbacks. For one thing, there is good reason to believe that both
monetary and fiscal policy are useful for economic stabilization.* If we decide at the out­
set to hold back on the use of one (in this case monetary policy), we may have to make
some sacrifices of our stabilization goals—full employment and price stability. Another
problem in switching emphasis from monetary to fiscal policy is that the latter also has
sectoral impacts. Cutting Government expenditures or increasing taxes will hurt some
sectors and some people more than others. How do we decide between the adverse im­
pacts of restrictive monetary policy and those of restrictive fiscal policy?
Still another solution sometimes suggested is the use of selective credit controls to help
achieve full employment and price stability. This would supposedly make it possible to
rely less heavily on both monetary and fiscal policy. However, there is a serious question
about how effective selective credit policies could be in reducing inflation or unemploy­
ment. Selective credit policies will primarily, and at best, shift credit from one use or
economic sector to another. Restricting credit for purchasing products whose prices
have been rising at a relatively rapid pace may make more credit available for other uses
but, in so doing, increase the prices of these products. At most, the effects may be on the
relative prices of goods and services rather than on the overall level of prices. Extensive
experiences with the use of selective credit controls for purposes of price stability in a
number of West European countries offer little support for the effectiveness of credit
controls in curbing inflation.**
A somewhat analogous result may also occur in attempting to use credit policies to
stimulate areas of relatively high unemployment. Shifting creditto an industry with an un­
employment problem and, consequently, away from other industries may also shift the
unemployment problem to the latter. Of course, it is possible that the offset may not be
perfect, and some net gains might result. But it might also be possible that the offset could
be more than 100 percent, resulting in a net loss. Thus, before attempting any such
policies, it would be desirable to have some research on what might be expected and
which industries might be appropriate for such policies.
*Of course, even if both are useful, it is possible that currently they are not being used in the best possible
combination for promoting economic stability. For an analysis of this issue, see R.M. Young, “The Distribution
of Stabilization Policy: A Possible Role for Structural Instruments,” Kaminowand O ’Brien, eds., Studies in Selec­
tive Credit Policies, pp. 217-31.
**See Donald R. Hodgman, National Monetary Policies and International Monetary Cooperation (Boston:
Little, Brown and Company, 1974).




8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

decision-making. In theory, credit-allocation
policies might be a useful tool for en­
couraging markets to produce more of these
goods—and, consequently, less of others.
In practice, however, social scientists have
no well-developed criterion for defining the
links between goods and social benefits. Con­
sequently, there is likely to be much subjec­
tivity involved in specifying what social
benefits, if any, can be derived from particular
goods. For example, it is sometimes suggested
that widespread ownership of housing will
make for greater social stability.7 Others,
however, may ask why it is that this alleged
social benefit is unique to housing ownership
and not characteristic of other assets.
As long as Government stands ready tosupport worthwhile undertakings, there will be
no shortgage of claims that particular projects
will produce important social benefits. Some
way needs to be found to select from the
numerous competing proposals that alleged­
ly yield social benefits. If rational decisions are
to be made, then spelling out the nature of
the alleged benefits, their links to the par­
ticular priority items of concern and the an­
ticipated costs, therefore, is called for.8
*
Unfortunately, most proposals for selective
credit measures are vague in these areas. The
claims of social benefits tend to be general,
the linkage between the priority item and the
benefits uncertain, and the expected costs
not well-defined. For example, some of the
proposals have suggested we need more of
this or that type of investment—say, more
housing at the expense of less corporate
investment—without saying how this will
serve our social goals of efficiency, equal op­
portunity, and so forth. Other proposals
suggest numerous social objectives will be

types of loans. Besides the ceilings on interest
rates that can be paid on time and saving
deposits at most financial institutions, state
and local governments often set ceilings on
rates for mortgage loans and for bonds they
issue. Consequently, when interest rates on
marketable securities (such as U. S. Treasury
bills or private commercial paper) rise, funds
flow in the direction of these instruments and
away from those whose yields cannot rise
because of legal ceilings (savings deposits,
mortgages, and municipal bonds). Many
economists have argued that interest-rate
ceilings are an important cause of distorted
credit flows during bouts of tight money.
Consequently, the argument goes, it would
be better to combat the problem first by
removing the regulations before attempting
to saddle credit markets with still another set
of regulatory interferences.
However, as appealing as the "free market"
answer might be to some, it has special
problems in the context of tight credit and
business cycles. Even if all Government
regulations and other impediments to free
markets are removed, markets will be ef­
ficient only if they are in a state of
equilibrium. But the very nature of economic
cycles, and hence tight money policies, is that
markets are not in equilibrium. So, we can't
be confident that free markets will allocate
credit efficiently during tight-money periods.
Whether this presents a cyclical role for selec­
tive credit policies is an open and important
issue.6
Social Benefits: Which Goods? Most
economists agree that some goods produce
social benefits which the market does not
adequately take into account. For example,
some suggest that education is one such
good. While obviously benefiting the in­
dividual "purchaser,” it may also yield extra
benefits to society since an informed pop­
ulace may be more efficient in political

7See, for example, David Laidler, “ Income Tax Incen­
tives for Owner-Occupied Housing,” Arnold C.
Harberger and Martin J. Bailey, eds., The Taxation of In­
come from Capital (Washington: The Brookings In­
stitution, 1969), p. 53.
8A more detailed presentation of this view is developed
in Kaminow and O ’Brien, op. cit., pp. 3-6.

6For elaboration of this point, see Kaminow and
O ’Brien, op. cit., pp. 10-15.



9

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

sought with no attention to their links to the
output mix or possible conflicts among
objectives.9
In sum, the problem with justifying selec­
tive credit policies on the basis of social
benefits is a practical one of identifying
benefits and linking them to a particular goal
and allocation of resources. In an open and
diverse society there will be as much agree­
ment as disagreement on what is socially
beneficial enough to warrant special treat­
ment. These disagreements must be resolved
through the democratic process, but their
resolution should be based on discussions of
how "special treatment'' can advance ul­
timate social objectives. To date, there has
been little public discussion of these issues,
and partly because of this, little evidence that
selective credit policies can advance our
social goals.
CAN SELECTIVE CREDIT POLICIES CHANGE
THE OUTPUT MIX?
Even if it could be shown that reallocating
resources with credit policies could improve
the lot of society, there is still the issue of
whether credit-allocation policies can effec­
tively change the allocation of resources. If
credit-allocation policies are going to be able
to change the mix of output in accord with
"social priorities," then there must be some
link between the tools of policy (taxes, sub­
sidies, quotas, etc.) and the basket of goods
produced in the economy. To find out if such
a link exists, two questions need to be asked:
whether credit-allocation policies can change
the composition of credit successfully, and
whether policy-induced changes in the com9See, for example, the prepared statement of Andrew
F. Brimmer, “The Banking Structure and Monetary
Management,” in U. S., Congress, Senate, Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, Selective Credit
Policies and Wage-Price Stabilization, 92d Cong., 1st
sess., 31 March, 1 and 7 April 1971, pp. 159-73. Also see S.
887, 28 February 1975, as introduced by Senator Richard S.
Schweiker and referred to the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs (see footnote 11 for full
citation).



position of credit will somehow bring about
desired changes in the mix of goods and serv­
ices. If the Federal Government cannot affect
the composition of credit or if changes in
credit flows have no effect on the mix of
goods, then credit-allocation policies will be
unable to satisfy their aims, no matter how at­
tractive the goals might be.
Selective Credit Controls and the Composi­
tion of Credit. There is a wide variety of
techniques that can be used to try to change
credit flows in the economy. (See Appendix 1
for a more detailed description of various
types of credit policies.) These fall into three
broad classes. The first— termed "moral sua­
sion" — involves no explicit coercion. Rather,
an official agency simply provides lenders
with a list of "priority" credit categories, for
example residential mortgages and student
loans. Lenders are then "encouraged" to ex­
tend credit to priority users but there is no
penalty for failing to meet the lending
guidelines. A policy of this type is presently in
effect. In September 1974, the Federal Ad­
visory Council1 issued a list of various types of
0
borrowing that might best serve the publicinterest. The Council encouraged banks to give
special attention to loans to support
homebuilding and capital expansion by
business, for example, while deeming loans
for speculative purposes "unsuitable."
The other two types of selective credit
policies involve some form of coercion. For
example, quotas or ceilings can be applied to
extending different categories of credit. One
current proposal would force banks to extend
at least a third of their loans to “ high-priority"
credit categories, for instance.1*Lenders who
1
fail to heed the Government's decrees would
1
0This is a statutory body of bankers set up to advise the
Federal Reserve Board.
11U. S., Congress, Senate, Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, S. 887: A Bill to Reduce In­
terest Rates and Make Additional Credit Available for Es­
sential Economic Activities, 94th Cong., 1st sess., 28
February 1975.

10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

presumably be punished with fines or other
penalties.
The remaining technique for credit alloca­
tion involves the use of subsidies or taxes on
various types of loans. For example, the
Federal income tax structure currently con­
tains subsidies in the form of tax exemptions
on interest from municipal securities and
deductions from taxable income for interest
paid on home mortgages. Several creditallocation proposals envision a more com­
prehensive program of subsidizing or taxing
different types of credit. One popular
proposal would apply “asset-reserve re­
quirements" to bank loans. Banks would be
required to hold cash reserves which would
vary with the types of loans held. The larger
the share of the bank's loans to high-priority
borrowers, the lower that bank's required
reserves would be. Since required reserves
earn no interest income, this asset-reserve re­
quirement acts like a tax on low-priority lend­
ing. Bankers are not actually forced to make a
given amount of certain kinds of loans as they
would be with a quota; rather, some incen­
tives are provided for them to do so.
In terms of effectiveness, is there any
reason to prefer one kind of selective credit
policy over others? It seems clear at the outset
that moral suasion is unlikely to be a very
effective device. The reason is easy to under­
stand. The lender’s preferred pattern of loans
hardly represents a series of arbitrary choices
on his part. Rather it reflects a conscious
management decision involving profit, risk,
liquidity, and so forth. It seems overly op­
timistic, then, to expect that lenders will
generally sacrifice their own objectives for
the Government's when there is no penalty or
incentive for doing so.1 Thus, some form of
2
coercion or inducement is probably
necessary if selective credit policies are to

have much effect on the allocation of credit.
It might seem at first glance that quotas
would prove a more effective tool than a taxsubsidy scheme since the latter allows in­
dividuals enough flexibility to ignore the in­
centive if they so choose. However, pol­
icymakers can probably get the same degree
of curtailment or expansion in a credit
category with a tax-subsidy scheme as with a
quota by a sufficient dose of the tax or sub­
sidy. In other words, the incentive can be
made sufficiently strong so that few will be
willing to ignore it. Moreover, quotas are
hardly inflexible policy instruments. Judging
from experience, we can expect that as cer­
tain lenders or institutions find themselves
substantially constrained by quotas, the au­
thorities will relax the regulations. This can be
done, for example, by making exceptions to
the rules, by changing the definitions of items
subject to quotas or ceilings, or by relaxing
enforcement of the regulations.
The U. S. experience with interest-rate
ceilings on demand and time deposits pro­
vides some good examples of how regulations
can be changed. As interest rates rose in the
1960s and '70s and the competition for check­
ing accounts increased, the authorities al­
lowed banks to make payments indirectly to
their checking-account customers by
eliminating service charges or giving “free"
gifts for additional deposits.1 During the
3
same period, the authorities not only raised
the maximum interest allowed to be paid on
time and savings deposits as market rates rose,
but they actually eliminated the ceilings on
certain types of time deposits. Thus, the fact
that regulations can be changed means that
quotas can be considered a flexible instru­
ment. Nevertheless, economists usually favor
subsidy-tax schemes over quotas. The reason
is that most economists believe that subsidy-

12Obviously, there are some instances where most in­
dividuals feel so strongly about an issue that they put the
country’s interest ahead of their own—such as helping to
defend one’s country in wartime. However, it seems un­
likely that credit-allocation programs will promote this
degree of enthusiasm in more normal times.

1 These implicit payments have become sufficiently im­
3
portant that some persons have questioned the further
usefulness of the interest ban. See James M. O ’Brien,
“The Interest Ban on Demand Deposits: Victim of the
Profit Motive?” Business Review of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, August 1972, pp. 13-19.




11

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

tax schemes involve less social cost because
individual lenders have more leeway than
with quotas, although both approaches can
be programed to yield the same total result.
Besides deciding on the type of credit
policies to implement, a decision on the type
of lending (or borrowing) to regulate also
must be made. If, say, some lenders of a dis­
favored credit category are not included in
the regulations, the policy will probably
become less effective since borrowers will
tend to switch from the restricted to the un­
restricted source of funds. But even if all
current lenders of some particular type of
credit are covered by controls, the effec­
tiveness of credit-allocation policies is likely
to diminish over time. The reason is that
borrowers and lenders will eventually learn to
exploit loopholes in the regulations despite
their apparent comprehensiveness. In addi­
tion, new credit channels are apt to develop
which will also circumvent the regulations.
Most of the current credit control pro­
posals in the U. S. apply to the commercial
banking system, but there is no reason why
credit policies can’t be applied to other
lenders or borrowers as well. In Western Eu­
rope, for example, governments apply a
variety of selective credit policies to an array
of lenders and borrowers. Credit-allocation
proposals in the U.S. probably tend to focus
on commercial banks because the banking
system would be relatively easy to regulate—
banks are already subject to a large amount of
Government supervision—and because of
the banking system’s prominence in our
financial structure.
By limiting controls to commercial banks,
however, most proposals have failed to face
the issue of avoidance. There is little ap­
parent consideration given to what will be
done, for example, as nonbank lending
sources fill the gaps created by tighter
regulations on bank lending. Experience in
the U. S. as well as the more extensive ex­
periences of West European economies all
suggest that the problem of evasion of con­
trols can be quite serious.1 In short, the in­
4



genuity of the regulated has proved stiff com­
petition for that of the regulators.
The Composition of Credit and the Mix of
Output. The next link in the credit-allocation
chain is how the mix of goods and services
produced will change whenever a new tax or
subsidy on credit is established or an old
quota is repealed. Presently much uncertainty
prevails on how altered credit flows will affect
the output mix of the economy.
Consider first the issue of how changing the
credit mix with a tax-subsidy scheme will
affect the pattern of goods people want to
buy. Suppose, for example, the Government
tries to curb production of refrigerators by
imposing a tax law that makes it more expen­
sive to obtain “ refrigerator loans.” The idea,
of course, is to cut down on the demand for
refrigerators by making it more expensive to
finance them with credit. Whether this policy
will “work” hinges on several factors. First, it
depends on the willingness of potential
refrigerator buyers to alter their buying plans.
If there is no other way to obtain refrigeration
services, buyers may be willing to bear the
higher cost of refrigerator loans. Of course,
the tax rate could become so high that con­
sumers would eventually take to building “ ice
houses.” As a general rule, however, the
harder it is to find a “substitute” good for the
product subject to controls, the less effective
controls will be.1*
5
Second, the effects of controls on spending
14Regarding the U.S. experience with regulating stock
market credit, see James M. O'Brien, “ Federal Regulation
of Stock Market Credit: A Need for Reconsideration,”
Business Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, July/August 1974, pp. 23-33. With respect to
experiences in Western Europe, see Donald R. Hodgman,
National Monetary Policies and International Coopera­
tion (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1974).
15For a detailed analysis of the analytical conditions
determining the effectiveness of credit-allocation
policies, see D.C. Rao and Ira Kaminow,“ SelectiveCredit
Controls and the Real Investment Mix: A General
Equilibrium Approach,” Kaminow and O ’Brien, eds.,
Studies in Selective Credit Policies, pp. 173-95.

12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

that supports the view that credit controls can
affect their buying choices.1 But the evidence
7
is too incomplete to predict the ultimate
effects on the output mix with much con­
fidence.1
8
In sum, the success of credit-allocation
programs will depend critically on how the
output mix is affected. The key question is
not, for example, whether the volume of
mortgage loans has increased, but how much
has the quantity of housing increased as a
result of selective credit policies? Even if we
know that subsidized mortgages are used
only to buy houses, this is not enough to
deem a credit-allocation program a success.
For example, some people may be sub­
stituting subsidized financing for nonsubsidized loans — that is, using subsidies to
finance home purchases that they would have
made even if the subsidy program had not
been in effect. If this is the case for a large
number of home buyers, then the stock of
housing would be little affected by a subsidy
program.1
9

for refrigerators will depend on the ease with
which people can switch to alternative
sources of finance to avoid paying the higher
cost of “ refrigerator loans.” For example,
refrigerator buyers may decide to buy more
clothes on credit and make a smaller down
payment on a new car, then use cash to buy a
refrigerator. Their total credit purchases are
the same, but they have avoided an expensive
refrigerator loan. If many people behave this
way, refrigerator demand may fall little even
though the use of “ refrigerator loans” could
fall substantially. Thus, the easier it is to find
substitute financing for the goods to be
purchased, the less effective controls will be.
Third, even if a tax on refrigerator loans
effectively discourages demand, producers
must still be willing to respond by bringing
fewer refrigerators to the appliance market.
If, for example, producers expect controls to
be short-lived or if they find it very difficult to
switch to production of other kinds of goods,
production may fall little. The main effect of
the controls then would be a reduced price of
refrigerators rather than fewer refrigerators.1
6
There are clearly, then, several possibilities
for “slippages” to make controls less effective
than their initial design would suggest. The
quantitative importance of these slippages
can be determined only by carrying out many
statistical tests to find out what the substitu­
tion possibilities are among goods and among
sources of finance. To date, little direct
evidence has been produced which bears on
these issues. There is, however, some indirect
evidence on peoples' substitution tendencies

17For a review of this literature, see part 1 in Kaminow
and O'Brien, e d s Studies in Selective Credit Policies, es­
pecially William L. Silber, “ Selective Credit Policies: A
Survey,” pp. 95-120. In part 2 see John H. Wood, “ Some
Effects of Bank Credit Restrictions on the Short-Term
Behavior of Large Firms,” pp. 147-70; and James M.
O ’Brien, “ Household Asset Substitution and the Effec­
tiveness of Selective Credit Policies,” pp. 197-215.
1 The incompleteness of the evidence is discussed in
8
Kaminow and O ’Brien, op. cit., pp. 19-23.
1 The importance of the linkage between the mix of
9
credit and the mix of output suggests an alternative ap­
proach to reallocating resources favored by many
economists. This is the use of fiscal measures such as sub­
sidizing or directly taxing goods whose production is to
be encouraged or discouraged rather than subsidizing or
taxing credit used to buy the goods. A detailed considera­
tion of the fiscal approach to resource reallocation is
beyond the scope of this article. However, it can be noted
that economists often favor this method over credit
policies because its effectiveness does not depend on the
linkages between the mix of credit and the mix of output.
There are, however, other factors, some common to
those of credit policies, which must be considered when
evaluating the policies effects on the output mix.
Moreover, the appropriateness of this approach versus

16ln fact, the issue is even more complex than outlined
above. The reason is that once producers and consumers
respond to controls by adjusting their behavior in the
refrigerator market, their actions will have some impact
in other markets. If people increase their demands for
other kinds of appliances,.the price of these goods will
rise. This may create a tendency for consumers eventually
to revert to buying refrigerators and reduce the overall
effectiveness of the control policy. To date, economists
know very little about the magnitude of these kinds of
feedback effects from one market to another and this
makes it quite difficult to predict the effectiveness of
controls.




13

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

CREDIT ALLOCATION: IS A LARGER ROLE
DESIRABLE?
Selective credit policies have long been in­
tuitively appealing. If buying stocks with too
much credit is bad and owning a home is
good, then limit the amount of credit for
financing equity purchases and subsidize
mortgages. Selective credit controls are direct
and get the job done, or do they? What we do
know about credit controls suggests they may
not be as straightforward or get the job done
as readily as might appear at first glance. More
important, what we do know about them is
dwarfed by what we don't know.
At present there is considerable doubt that
redirecting credit flows will improve society's
welfare. Current arguments for creditallocation policies have done little more than
enunciate actual or perceived social short­
comings of our credit and product markets
without actually demonstrating that credit
policies are a desirable response. Yet, in some
cases the nature of the social problem itself
hasn't been spelled out. In other cases, where
social benefits are suggested, there is no in­
dication of the linkage between resource
reallocation with credit policies and these
benefits. Nor has there been any attempt at
relating credit-allocation policies to the
achievement of social goals in general. Even if
a policy yielded some social benefits, it could
very well be at the expense of others.
Next comes the issue of the ability of selec­
tive credit policies to reallocate resources.

Here the problem is less philosophical and
more one of nuts and bolts. The evidence to
date is not totally pessimistic but not en­
couraging either.Experience suggests that it
may be difficult to keep credit policies from
being exploited, not necessarily because
regulators are inefficient, but because lenders
and borrowers can be expected to use their
ingenuity to find ways to evade the rules. It is
also to be expected that there will be “slip­
pages" between altering credit flows and
changing the mix of real output. More
mortgages because of mortgage subsidies do
not necessarily mean more housing than
otherwise would have been the case. The
magnitude of these slippages is largely
unknown.
On the benefit side, then, there are some
significant philosphical hurdles about what is
“ best" for society as well as some serious
practical problems of how to achieve desired
ends. On the cost side, there are unknowns as
well. Totaling the salaries of those who en­
force credit controls is relatively easy. Total­
ing the costs to the private sector of com­
pliance with or avoidance of the regulations is
more difficult. Moreover, there is almost a
total lack of knowledge about the social
welfare costs of altering individual choices, as
well as the political “costs" of increased
Government interference.
So, the case now for a larger role for selec­
tive credit controls is less than convincing.
The benefits are elusive and, even if defined,
difficult to achieve, and the costs of im­
plementation may be sizeable. Therefore,
the justification for additional selective credit
co n tro ls, given the current state of
knowledge, must rest more on “ hunch" than
any systematic analysis.

credit policies will depend on the ultimate objectives be­
ing served. In any event, it is important to rememberthat
the desirability of credit policies rests not only on
whether the policies do their job but how they perform
relative to alternative approaches such as fiscal policy.




14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Appendix 1
A CLASSIFICATION OF CREDIT POLICIES*
Explanation and Examples

Classifications
A. On Lenders
1. Portfolio restrictions

This type of policy would apply mainly to finan­
cial institutions requiring (or persuading) them
to hold certain types of assets. A current exam­
ple is that savings and loan associations are
limited mainly to holdingonly U.S. Government
securities, mortgages, and home improvement
loans.

2. “Special” reserve requirements

There are at least several possible forms. One
example is the current suggestion that the
Federal Reserve System impose “asset-reserve
requirements” on bank lending (see text for an
explanation). Another is that “ high-priority”
loans could be used by financial institutions to
meet legal reserve requirements on their
liabilities. Reserve requirements are currently
not used for credit-allocation purposes in the
U.S., although they are employed in West Euro­
pean countries.**

3. Other subsidies (taxes) to lenders
making certain types of loans

This policy could take many forms. One form
currently in practice is the exemption from in­
come taxes of interest earned on municipal
securities. Another example would be special
access to the Federal Reserve’s lending facilities
to banks making certain priority loans (such as
the September 1966 “ letter” from the Federal
Reserve System to banks). This practice of credit
allocation has been much more common and
formalized in Western Europe than in the U.S.

*This classification scheme is adapted from William L. Silber, “ Selective Credit Policies: A Survey/' Kaminow
and O'Brien, eds., Studies in Selective Credit Policies, p. 101. For a detailed classification of credit policies
applicable to the residential mortgage market and housing, see Jack M. Guttentag, “Selective Credit Controls
on Residential Mortgage Credit,’’ Kaminow and O'Brien, eds., op. cit., pp. 38-40.
**For a more detailed review of West European uses of selective credit controls, see James M. O ’Brien, “ Cen­
tral Banking across the Atlantic: Another Dimension,’’ Business Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, May 1975, pp. 3-12.




15

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

B. On Borrowers

1. Subsidies (taxes) to certain kinds of
borrowers

There are also many forms that this policy might
take. Some could involve one way or another of
reducing the income-tax liabilities of certain
borrowers.*** Other examples are provided by
current Federal credit programs. One form is
direct low-interest loans by the Federal Govern­
ment such as those made by the Rural Elec­

trification Administration, the Department
of Housing and Urban Development, the
Export-Import Bank, etc. Another form is
interest-subsidy payments to those ob­
taining private loans. Current examples are
subsidies paid on college housing loans
and academic facility loans.****
Borrowers would haye to get permission from
some governmental committee in order to issue
bonds on the open market. This is not practiced
in the U.S. but is used in West European coun­
tries to guarantee favorable treatment in the
capital market to high-priority borrowers.

2. Capital issues committee

C. On Instruments
The Federal Reserve System has had a long
history of administering credit policies, as
directed by Congress, to affect interest rates and
other credit terms of several types of debt in­
struments. These include interest-rate ceilings
on deposits of commercial banks, and down
payment and collateral requirements on loans
to purchase stock since the early 1930s. They
also include the regulation of (noninterest)
terms on consumer loans during World War II,
1948-49, and the Korean War as well as
mortgages during the Korean War. Moreover,
some state governments set maximum interest
rates on mortgages, consumer loans, and
municipal securities. These various ceilings
have been largely used ostensibly to protect
borrowers and lenders. However, the ex­
periences associated with the two wars and in­
tervening period were concerned with curbing
consumer durable and home buying.

1. Interest-rate ceilings and controls over
other terms of credit

***For a more detailed discussion of this type of policy, see Rudolph G. Penner, “ Taxation and the Allocation
of Credit," Kaminow and O ’Brien, op. cit., pp. 76-78.
****For a more detailed review of Federal credit programs and their importance, see Murray L. Weidenbaum,
“ Subsidies in Federal Credit Programs,” in U.S., Congress, Joint Economic Committee, The Economics of
Federal Subsidy Programs, 92d Cong., 2d sess., 8 May 1972, part 1, pp. 106-19.




16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

2. Changing the characteristics of certain
types of loans

Some credit programs have been aimed at
reducing the riskiness of certain favored
categories of loans, particularly residential
mortgages. Both the Federal Housing Ad­
ministration and the Veterans Administration
make mortgage insurance available to qualified
borrowers. Also, the Federal National Mortgage
Association maintains a “secondary" market in
mortgages and Federal Home Loan Banks make
loans to savings and loan associations. These in­
stitutions help reduce the riskiness of mortgage
lending by making it possible for savings and
loan associations to obtain funds or liquidate
mortgages in order to meet current commit­
ments. The Federal Home Loan Bank Board has
its liabilities guaranteed by the Federal Govern­
ment and both financial institutions have
backup-borrowing capability at the U.S.
Treasury.

Appendix 2
SUMMARIES OF INDIVIDUAL STUDIES*
Ira Kaminow and James M. O'Brien: “Issues in Selective
Credit Policies: An Evaluative Essay"
This essay uses the perspective provided by the other contributions to the book and other studies
to examine and organize the issues surrounding selective credit policies. These issues are split into
three groups — the ultimate social goals that selective credit policies are supposed to serve, the
effectiveness of such policies in achieving the more proximate aim of resource reallocation, and
their impacts on the distribution of income.
Ultimate goals that can be discerned from arguments for credit-allocation policies include a more
socially desirable mix of output, correcting for Pareto-type imperfections in credit markets and
offsetting the sectoral impacts of restrictive monetary policy. Arguments germane to these goals are
examined in terms of social benefits to be gained from employing selective credit policies.
Arguments for the use of selective credit policies must also depend on their ability to affect the
allocation of resources. Reviewing analyses dealing with this issue reveals different, but not
necessarily incompatible, views on the modus operandi. Different views of how the process works
color opinions on the type of evidence deemed relevant and sometimes the likely effectiveness of
credit policies. Nonetheless, there seems to be some agreement that available evidence on the
whole does not run counter to the notion that credit policies can effectively reallocate resources.
However, the evidence is also mostly indirect and very incomplete.
Income-incidence impacts of credit policies have received less attention from economists than
their ability to reallocate resources. Research in this area has been limited to a partial equilibrium
analysis of some of our current credit subsidies. Although the incidence conclusions are still of in­
terest the work largely fails to come to grips with the important issue of the shifting potential of
credit subsidies and taxes.
*These summaries were prepared by Ira Kaminow and James M. O'Brien. The individual studies appear in Ira
Kaminow and James M. O ’Brien, eds., Studies in Selective Credit Policies (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
1975). To obtain copies of this volume, see notice on page 23.




17

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

Specific suggestions for orienting future research emerge from the evaluation. These deal with a
need to (1) move away from the casualness that currently permeates most discussions of the objec­
tives of selective credit policies, (2) develop analyses bearing directly on the issues and depending
less heavily on work in other areas of economics that is sometimes inappropriate or of limited use,
and (3) give greater recognition to the general equilibrium or disequilibrium and dynamic setting in
which credit-allocation policies will operate.
Finally, from the perspective of the evaluation, the implications for extending credit-allocation
policies beyond what is currently in existence appear negative. There seems no clear indication that
credit policies might improve economic efficiency or otherwise produce social benefits. Indeed,
there is little basisforeven rejecting the possibility that such policies would be socially detrimental.

Jack M. Guttentag: “Selective Credit Controls
on Residential Mortgage Credit”
The application of selective credit policies to affect mortgage flows is reviewed in this study. The
first part of the study is concerned with various selective credit techniques which have actually been
used or have been suggested for use in influencing mortgage flows to housing. These various
techniques are classified and discussed. A special emphasis is given to analyzing the role of “max­
imum terms” — legal interest-rate ceilings, maturities, and loan-to-value ratios — as applied to
mortgages.
The second part of the study uses the discussion of credit control techniques in evaluating five
suggested objectives of selective credit controls for influencing mortgage credit: reduction of
aggregate demand, correction of maladjustments in the housing sector, maintenance of structural
stability in the economy in the face of unusually disruptive shifts in demand, increase of resources to
housing, and achievement of a more equal distribution of housing among different income groups.
Some conclusions are reached regarding these various objectives. For example, it is argued that in
correcting for maladjustments in the mortgage and housing sectors (particularly mortgage and
housing downturns) the preferred approach would be to stimulate mortgage credit and housing by
reducing Federal deficit spending. Credit policies aimed at restricting corporate borrowing would
be the next-best solution.
The objective of maintaining some form of structural stability in the economy would require a
broad-based system of credit-allocation policies. Devising such a system of controls that would be
effective, but not require extensive administrative interference in financial markets merits serious
investigation. In using credit policies to affect a shifting of resources to housing, there is a strong
need to study the importance of credit terms on the long-term demand for housing. Current
attempts to measure the effects of credit terms on housing demand capture some mix of temporary
and permanent effects. Finally, it can be argued that mortgage credit terms have the strongest im­
pact on the housing demand of low-income groups. However, the impacts that legal restrictions on
mortgage terms have on the distribution of housing ownership among different income groups
have not been adequately analyzed and require additional research.

Rudolph G. Penner: “Taxation and
the Allocation of Credit”
This study focuses on tax legislation that is aimed at reducing credit flows in order to change the
mix of production. Attention is first given to specifying the economic variables which determine the




18

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

cost of capital to the investor and how capital costs are affected by different forms of subsidies and
taxes. Various forms of subsidies and tax concessions are examined. The latter include the invest­
ment tax credit, depreciation allowances, deduction of interest from taxable income, and changes
in the income tax rate. One conclusion is that interest subsidies or penalties are likely to be more
equitable and efficient than tax credits and concessions. Moreover, since outright subsidies are a
budget outlay they have another advantage over tax concessions as thesubsidy element in the latter
are often hidden and difficult to estimate. Among the different tax approaches, credits are deemed
generally more desirable than other types of concessions because they tend to be more equitable
and cost the Government less for a given impact.
Attention is also given to affecting the interest rate paid by borrowers through tax schemes
applied to assets in lenders' portfolios. Using a mean-variance approach, definitive results of the
effects of taxes on the demand for "risky" versus “safe" assets are difficult to obtain a priori. Several
possible results are discussed under different portfolio behavior assumptions and different tax
policies.
Given the effect of a selective credit policy on the cost of capital, the impact on real investment
will depend on the firm’s response. In reviewing studies on this issue, a middle-of-the-road conclu­
sion appears to be that changes in the cost of capital significantly affect investment demand but with
a relatively long lag, as compared with, say, sales. Finally, it is emphasized that there are several
possibly important “slippages" between changing the composition of credit and changing the mix
of output. Thus, if the objective is to change the mix of output, it is likely to be done more effectively
by subsidizing or taxing the outputs directly rather than through credit subsidies or taxes.

William L. Silber: “Selective Credit Policies: A Survey”
The degree of substitutability among financial market instruments by borrowers and lenders is
crucial in determining whether a selective credit policy can affect the allocation of resources or
redirect financial flows. Much of this essay examines these substitutability relationships. The discus­
sion first focuses on the substitutability conditions required for credit policies to alter the output or
credit mix, according to whether the policies are applied to lenders, borrowers, or more directly to
the assets themselves.
With respect to these conditions, a review of empirical work on asset substitutability indicates a
general lack of research on the efficacy of selective credit policies. What information is available, in­
cluding indirect and piecemeal evidence, does not generally refute the hypothesis that credit
policies can have desired effects on the composition of credit and possibly real output. However,
several caveats are advanced. One is that the impacts of the policies may be much stronger on credit
flows than on real resource allocation. Another is that the effectiveness of the policies is likely to
diminish over time. And, finally, the piecemeal nature of most of the evidence, plus a number of
possibly significant technical problems, suggests that any conclusions should be held with a good
deal of reservation.
One aspect of the efficacy issue that has received some study is that of the effects of Federal Home
Loan Bank advances to savings and loan associations and mortgage purchases by the Federal
National Mortgage Association. Both programs have been important in recent years. Somewhat
surprisingly, the studies indicate that the impact of FHLB advances on the mortgage and residential
construction markets might be quite large while the impact of FNMA purchases appears neglible.
However, the studies of these programs are still very few. Furthermore, some serious problems in
estimating the policies' effects emphasize that the results should not yet be taken at face value.
Concluding the survey is a brief review of arguments for and against credit policies on the
grounds o f their equity and efficiency in reallocating resources. Several points emerge from the
review. One is the need for a normative theory of the incidence of stabilization policy so that




19

BUSINESS REVIEW

NOVEMBER 1975

policymakers will have a standard for judging whether the incidence of countercyclical policy
should, or can, be offset by selective credit policies. Another point is that opponents of selective
credit policies have most often stressed their interference with the efficiency of our financial
system. The implication is that credit policies may not be particularly appropriate for reallocating
resources unless the source of the resource allocation problem is a malfunction in our credit
markets.

Paul F. Smith: "A Review of the Theoretical and Administrative
History of Consumer Credit Controls”
Debate over the need and desirability of consumer credit controls has ensued for many years.
Historically the arguments have revolved around consumer credit and economic stability: the im­
pact of cycles in consumer credit on overall economic stability, the effectiveness of traditional
monetary policy in dampening excessive increases in consumer credit, and the ability to alter
aggregate credit expansion effectively with consumer credit policies. Definitive answers to these
issues are still lacking, but recent arguments and some statistical work suggest that the cyclical
behavior of consumer credit may, if anything, tend to dampen general swings in economic activity.
Recent studies also indicate that consumer credit is sensitive to traditional monetary policies.
However, there is a dearth of statistical research toward resolving the debate on the ability of con­
sumer credit controls to affect total credit.
Another important issue is whether consumer credit controls can be expected to influence con­
sumer buying. Studies of the relation between consumer credit terms and durable buying generally
indicate that the latter is sensitive to the former. This offers some support for the effectiveness of
consumer credit policies since these policies would attempt to affect consumer purchases through
changes in the terms on consumer credit.
Some further insight into the potential effectiveness of consumer credit policies can be obtained
through studies of experiences with controls during and following World War II and during the
Korean War. At least on a superficial level, these experiences suggest that consumer credit controls
can restrain consumer durable purchases. They also suggest some significant problems in the ad­
ministration of the controls, particularly as borrowers and lenders attempt to evade them. None­
theless, more study is needed before any firm conclusions can be reached on the effectiveness of
consumer credit policies from these experiences. Credit controls were imposed during special
times along with other controls, and there is little evidence on what the situation would have been
without them.

John H. Wood: “Some Effects of Bank Credit Restrictions
on the Short-Term Behavior of Large Firms”
A popular argument for selective credit policies is the need to curb corporate credit demands
and, possibly, production during periods of high interest rates and economic booms. An important
question has been whether these objectives could be achieved by restricting bank lending to cor­
porations. In this contribution an analytical model is developed to get at some of the main issues.
These issues concern the ability of corporations to avoid controls by using alternative sources of
finance or altering the timing of their borrowing and production patterns. The effectiveness of both
anticipated and unanticipated bank lending restrictions are analyzed.
Corporations are assumed to maximize profit over a multi-(four) period horizon. The firm’s in­
puts are labor and capital. Production is divided between sales and inventories. Allowance is also
made for "compensating balances" and credit is obtained by issuing long- and short-term securities
as well as through bank borrowing (also short-term). Within this framework, the effects of a single­




20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

period ceiling on bank loans to corporations are analyzed. The impacts on the output and credit
patterns are generally shown to depend on the elasticities of alternative forms of finance,
economies of scale in production, the costs of carrying inventories, and the prices of inputs and
outputs.
Some of the specific results indicate that, except in limited cases, unanticipated credit restrictions
have a greater effect on curbing corporations' total credit demands and production than do an­
ticipated controls during the restriction period. Changes in financing patterns may also be quite
different in the two cases. However, even in the case of anticipated credit restrictions, there
appears little danger that firms will be able to escape the effects of the controls. On this basis, an­
ticipated controls might be preferable to unanticipated forms of credit restrictions. Anticipated
controls are more likely to avoid credit crunches and rapid shifts in production and unemployment,
while still having a curtailing effect on the credit demands and production of large firms.

D. C. Rao and Ira Kaminow: “Selective Credit Controls and the Real
Investment Mix: A General Equilibrium Approach”
An important issue in judging the merits of credit-allocation policies is whether they can
predictably alter the real investment mix where there exists a diversity of financial instruments
that are substitutable in the portfolios of borrowers and lenders. This issue is investigated here using
a general equilibrium framework. The model consists of a system of asset-market clearing
equations for "deposits,” "mortgages,” "bonds,” "housing capital,” and “other capital” and issubject to the usual Walrasian constraint. All assets are assumed gross substitutes in households' and in­
termediaries' portfolios, and borrowers finance housing and other capital investment with
mortgages and bonds. A selective credit policy consists of applying asset-reserve requirements to
intermediaries’ holdings of mortgages and bonds (but the effects of the policy apply to any instru­
ment operating on the intermediaries' asset demands).
The policy’s objective is to encourage housing investment relative to other capital. Success is
determined by whether the policy’s general equilibrium effects lower the required rate of return
on housing and raise it on other capital. The conditions for success which are derived state essential­
ly that the degree of substitution among holdings of different typec of real capital is low and that the
demand for each type of capital is more sensitive to the rate on one financial instrument than the
other. It is also shown that the total effect of the policy on the required rate of return on real capital
can be divided into the policy impact on the behavior of the financial sector and the response of the
nonfinancial sectors to changes in interest rates.
Major conclusions with policy implications include the following: (1) Where there is no dis­
intermediation and all intermediaries are subject to credit controls, there will be little chance of
failure. (2) Where all intermediaries are not covered, the magnitudes of the effects on the real rates
of return will be reduced but the plausibility of success is still high. (3) However, where there are
"open” markets and disintermediation is possible, the asset-reserve plan could fail to have the
desired effect. In this situation, determining the likelihood of success requires careful empirical in­
vestigation. (4) Finally, regardless of any ambiguities in the real investment mix, the policies will
have the impact on interest rates that policymakers would generally anticipate.

James M. O'Brien: “Household Asset Substitution and
the Effectiveness of Selective Credit Policies”
This study deals with the general question of the ability of credit-allocation policies to alter the
mix of real investment. Its particular focus is the role played by the financial asset behavior of




21

NOVEMBER 1975

BUSINESS REVIEW

households. Relevant aspects of this behavior can be characterized by the following propositions:
(1) Applying a credit policy uniformly either to all borrowers or lenders utilizing a particular finan­
cial instrument will more effectively alter the use of this instrument the more willing are households
to substitute this for other financial assets. (2) If the policy is applied to only financial intermediaries,
the substitutability condition for households is essentially reversed.
To determine which substitutability conditions are likely to be more realistic, an empirical in­
vestigation of household asset substitution is conducted across a range of nine financial assets—
three kinds of deposits, savings bonds, marketable bonds, corporate stock, life insurance reserves,
mutual funds, and “other assets.” An attempt is made to employ a technique developed by Henri
Theil and others which involved the use of estimated covariances among commodities to deter­
mine their substitutability. Asset and other data used in the present study come from the 1962
Survey of Financial Characteristics of Consumers (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System).
The major empirical finding is that households’ asset-preference functions appear to be ap­
proximately additive. The implies that the relative substitutability of financial assets can be ap­
proximated by the assets’ relative wealth elasticities. Estimates of the wealth elasticities exhibited a
tendency for “fixed-price” assets to be wealth inelastic and “variable-price” assets to be wealth
elastic, although all elasticities were not very far from “one.”
The finding of an additive preference function also provides a basis for arguing that, among the
assets studied, asset substitution is likely to be low. The policy implications cut several ways. To the
extent that credit policies are applied directly to financial assets purchased by households, their
effectiveness would be relatively small. However, if the policies applied only to institutional asset
purchasers, there may be relatively little offset substitution by households. Of course, these im­
plications apply only to the asset categories studied here. Within a given category, asset substitution
could be expected to be greater.

R. M. Young: “The Distribution of Stabilization Responsibility:
A Possible Role for Structural Instruments”
A common assumption in discussions of stabilization goals is that a tradeoff exists between
monetary and fiscal policy in producing economic stability. This presumption has become the basis
of current arguments over a need to rely more heavily on fiscal and less on monetary policy in
achieving economic stability because of the adverse side effects of the latter. The present study ex­
amines this issue and suggests a possible role for “structural” instruments such as selective credit
policies either to affect this tradeoff or to alter the degree of economicstability achievable with the
traditional macro tools.
The mode of analysis rests on a simplestabilization model wheretheobjectiveof policy concerns
the variance of some measure of economic activity, such as Gross National Product, and the macro­
policy tools may be viewed as the variances in fiscal and monetary policy. Within the context of this
model, it is first shown that if the objective of the macro tools is to minimize the variability of GNP,
there is a unique solution for each policy variable. Hence, there is no tradeoff among policy tools. If,
however, policymakers engage in satisficing and attempt only to achieve, say, a target level of
economic stability, then a tradeoff may well exist and debates on this issue become more
meaningful.
This alternative view of a target level of economic stability and the stabilization model employed
suggests a role for “structural” instruments somewhat different from the often-suggested role of
directly helping to increase (the maximum amount of) economic stability. Illustrations are used to
show how a structural instrument, such as selective credit controls, can alter the relations between
the monetary and fiscal tools and the measure of economicstability. Thus, for any given target level
of economic stability, credit policies or other “structural” instruments might be used to alter the
tradeoff locus between the macro tools. From this alteration, it may be possible to obtain a mix of
fiscal and monetary policies more in keeping with the totality of policymakers’ goals.




22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

AVAILABLE UPON REQUEST - ■ ■

S T U D IE S
IN
S E LE C T IV E
C R E D IT
P O L IC IE S
edited by
Ira Kami now
Jam es M. O ’Brien
Single copy free. Additional copies $2 each. Requests should be addressed
to Studies in Selective Credit Policies, Department of Research, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Philadelphia, PA 19105. Checks should be
made payable to the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.




23

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PENNSYLVANIA 10105

business review
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PA. 19105