View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

r:;; Business
t Review
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
May •June 1996




ISSN 0007-7011

Looking Ahead:
Leading Indexes for
Pennsylvania and
New Jersey
Theodore M . Crone &
Kevin J. Bahyak

Inflation Forecasts
H ow Good Are They?
Dean Cronshore

Business
Review
The BUSINESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. It is
edited by Sarah Burke. Artwork is designed
and produced by Dianne Hallowell under the
direction of Ronald B. Williams. The views
expressed here are not necessarily those of this
Reserve Bank or of the Federal Reserve System.
SUBSCRIPTIONS. Single-copy subscriptions
fo r individuals are available without charge. Insti­
tutional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
BACK ISSUES. Back issues are available free o f
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may
order up to 50 copies by submitting requests on
institutional letterhead; other orders are limited to I
copy per request. Microform copies are available fo r
purchase from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb
Road, Ann Arbor, MI 48106.
REPRODUCTION. Perm ission must be
obtained to reprint portions o f articles or whole
articles. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.
Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes o f address, and requests to reprint to
Publications, Federal Reserve Bank o f Philadelphia,
Department o f R esearch and Statistics, Ten
Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574,
or telephone (215) 574-6428. Please direct editorial
communications to the same address, or telephone
(215) 574-3805.




MAY/JUNE 1996

LOOKING AHEAD:
LEADING INDEXES FOR
PENNSYLVANIA AND NEW JERSEY
Theodore M. Crone and Kevin Babyak
Many policymakers and business persons
are interested not only in the course of the
national economy but also in the prospects
for their region’s economy. Since 1994, the
Philadelphia Fed has published monthly
indexes of coincident indicators for the
states in the Third Federal Reserve
District. A natural complement would be
a set of leading indexes. In this article, Ted
Crone and Kevin Babyak introduce lead­
ing indexes for the two largest states in the
District— Pennsylvania and New Jersey.
INFLATION FORECASTS:
HOW GOOD ARE THEY?
Dean Croushore
Forecasts of inflation affect decision-mak­
ing in many segments of the economy. But
in the early 1980s, economists found that
forecasts in surveys taken over the past 20
years systematically underpredicted infla­
tion. As a result, many economists stopped
paying attention to forecasts. However,
they may have abandoned them too
quickly. In this article, Dean Croushore
takes a closer look at survey forecasts and,
after considering some relevant factors,
concludes that inflation forecasts may not
be as bad as you think.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes
For Pennsylvania and New Jersey
Theodore M . Crone* and Kevin J. Babyak*

larly look for any sign of a change in the direc­
tion of the overall economy. Prudent budget
directors will reduce their revenue projections
when they see indications of a slowdown in the

*Ted Crone is vice president in charge of the Regional Eco­
nomics section of the Philadelphia Fed's Research Depart­
ment. At the time this article was being prepared, Kevin
Babyak was a research support analyst at the Federal Re­
serve Bank of Philadelphia. He is currently an assistant con­
troller for the City of Philadelphia. The authors thank Tom
Stark for invaluable assistance in developing the models to
estimate the leading indexes.




economy. Likewise, prudent business manag­
ers will take steps to curtail their inventories.
In these attempts to anticipate general business
conditions, people look for signals about the
economy.
One signal of the future course of the na­
tional economy is the traditional composite in­
dex of leading indicators, now published by the
Conference Board but maintained for many
years by the U.S. Department of Commerce.
Recently, the National Bureau of Economic Re­
search (NBER) began publishing an alternative
leading index, developed as part of its project
on cyclical indicators. Both these indexes are
3

BUSIN ESS REVIEW

meant to foreshadow the direction of the na­
tional economy six to nine months ahead.1
Many policymakers and business persons,
however, are interested not only in the course
of the national economy but also in the course
of their region's economy. Since 1994 the Fed­
eral Reserve Bank of Philadelphia has pub­
lished monthly indexes of coincident indicators
for the three states in the Third Federal Reserve
District (see the 1994 article by Crone). These
indexes reveal that state recessions do not nec­
essarily coincide with national recessions.
Therefore, a natural complement to the coinci­
dent indexes would be a set of leading indexes
for the states. This article introduces leading
indexes for the two largest states in the Dis­
trict—Pennsylvania and New Jersey—based on
the methodology of the NBER's new alterna­
tive index for the nation. They are the first state
indexes to be developed using this methodol­
ogy.1
2
LEADING INDEXES
OF THE NATIONAL ECONOMY
The origins of the current leading indexes
for the nation go back to the late 1930s when
Wesley Mitchell and Arthur Burns drew up a
list of 71 statistical series that they considered
to be reliable indicators of economic recover­
ies. The list was later extended to include lead­
ing indicators of recessions. Lists of coincident
and lagging indicators were developed as well.
These lists were periodically revised, and over
time, the individual indicators were combined
to construct composite indexes intended to

1The index of leading indicators formerly maintained
by the Department of Commerce has been published by
the Conference Board since late 1995. We will refer to it as
the traditional leading index.
2In the late 1970s and early 1980s, the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia published a leading index for the
Philadelphia region using the Commerce Department's
methodology (see Anthony Rufolo's article).


4


MAY/JUNE 1996

summarize the information in the individual
indicators and give an overall assessment of the
economy. Both the identification of individual
indicators and the development of composite
indexes have been part of a broader effort to
explain business cycles, which Burns and
Mitchell described as "a type of fluctuation
found in the aggregate economic activity of
nations that organize their work mainly in busi­
ness enterprises: a cycle consists of expansions
occurring at about the same time in many eco­
nomic activities, followed by similarly general
recessions, contractions, and revivals which
merge into the expansion phase of the next
cycle— ; in duration business cycles vary from
more than one year to ten or twelve years; they
are not divisible into shorter cycles . . . [that
exhibit swings in economic activity of similar]
amplitudes."
From a List of Indicators to a Composite In­
dex. The early development of composite in­
dexes was based on the notion that there is a
set of indicators that reflects the current state
of the economy, a set that reflects the future state
of the economy, and a set that reflects past eco­
nomic activity. Once researchers identified and
categorized individual cyclical indicators as
coincident, leading, or lagging, the next step
was to combine at least some of those indica­
tors into single composite indexes. Since busi­
ness cycles are defined as broad-based contrac­
tions and expansions, combinations of indica­
tors or composite indexes are generally better
at tracking the cycles than any single indicator
(see the article by Geoffrey Moore). But which
indicators should be included in each compos­
ite index? And should they all be given the
same weight in forming the composite index?3

3To help answer these questions Geoffrey Moore and
Julius Shiskin developed an explicit scoring system to gauge
the value of the individual series as indicators of the busi­
ness cycle. They considered such factors as how large a
portion of the economy is reflected in the series, how much
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes for Pennsylvania and New Jersey

The components of the traditional compos­
ite index of leading indicators and the weights
assigned to them have changed over the years.
Currently, the index is constructed from 11 com­
ponents (Table 1). As in the case of the coinci­
dent and lagging indexes, changes in the lead­
ing index are calculated as a weighted average
of the monthly changes in each of the compo­
nents. The current weights for the monthly
changes in the components of the index are pri­
marily designed to keep the more volatile se­
ries from dominating month-to-month move­
ments in the index.4
the series fluctuates with the cycle, how large and how fre­
quent revisions to the series are, and how promptly the data
for the series are available.
Moore and Shiskin used their
scores not only to draw up short
and long lists of indicators but
also to weight the indicators in
constructing composite indexes.

Theodore M. Crone and Kevin J. Babyak

How well does this leading index lead? A lead­
ing index can be evaluated either by how well
it predicts turning points in the business cycle
or by how well it predicts actual changes in
some economic indicator at all points in the
cycle (see Gary Gorton's article). The most fre­
quent use of the traditional leading index, how­
ever, has been to predict turning points in the
business cycle, especially economic downturns
or recessions.
Several different rules of thumb have been
applied to the leading index to determine
whether it is signaling a recession. As Gorton
points out, these rules of thumb are inherently
arbitrary, but the most common rule is that three
successive declines in the index forecast a re­

TABLE 1

Components of the
Traditional Leading Index

4A standardized change is
calculated for each component
by dividing this month's change
in the series by the average size
of monthly changes over a his­
torical period. For example, be­
tween 1978 and 1989 the aver­
age absolute percentage change
in hours worked by production
workers in manufacturing was
0.42. If the actual change in the
most recent month was only
0.21, or one-half the historical
average, the stand ard ized
change w ould be 0.5. The
monthly change in the compos­
ite index is a weighted average
of
these
"stan d ard ized
changes" in the components.
The weight is adjusted so that a
1 percent change (or one unit
change) in each of the compo­
nents results in a 1 percent
change in the composite index.
The current formulas for calcu­
lating the index can be found in
the article by George Green and
Barry Beckman.




• Average weekly hours of production workers in manufacturing
• Average weekly initial claims for unemployment insurance
• Manufacturers new orders in constant dollars for consumer goods
and materials industries
• Index of vendor performance
• Contracts and orders for plant and equipment in constant dollars
• Index of new private housing units authorized by local building
permits
• Manufacturers unfilled orders for durable goods in constant dol­
lars
• Sensitive materials prices
• Index of stock prices, S&P 500 common stocks
• Money supply (M2) in constant dollars
• Index of consumer expectations compiled by the University of Michi­
gan Research Center

5

BUSINESS REVIEW

cession within the next nine months. By this
rule the traditional index has successfully pre­
dicted eight of the nine U.S. recessions since
1948, with leads of two to eight months.5 But it
has also given seven false signals. Once the
economy is in a recession, the traditional lead­
ing index has generally been slow to signal a
recovery using the popular three-month rule.
Only three times in the last nine recessions has
the index recorded three successive increases
before the official beginning of the recovery.6
The record of the traditional leading index
has not been perfect, but it has been helpful in
predicting recessions. Questions are frequently
raised, however, about how the index is con­
structed. A major issue is how the weights for
the components are determined (see Vance
M artin's article). While the current weights
adjust for the volatility of the various compo­
nents, they do not reflect differences in how
broadly the indicators represent the economy
or of how consistent they have been in leading
recessions or recoveries. Also, as their names
suggest, the index of leading indicators ought
to lead the index of coincident indicators. And
although the same methodology is used to con­
struct the traditional coincident and leading
indexes, no statistical technique is employed to
ensure that the leading index actually "leads"
the coincident index (see the article by Green
and Beckman).
A Forecasting Approach to a Leading In­
dex. In the late 1980s under the auspices of the
NBER, James Stock and Mark Watson devel­
oped an alternative leading index that attempts
to respond to some of the questions raised about
5The failure was for the 1990-91 recession. Three de­
clines in the leading index did occur between May and July
1989, one year before the onset of the 1990-91 recession.
But we do not consider this to be a true recession signal,
since the index later recorded three successive increases
before the recession actually began.
6In four other cases the leading index registered its sec­
ond successive increase in the month the recession ended.




MAY/JUNE 1996

the traditional index (see the 1994 article by
Crone). In essence, their leading index is a sta­
tistical forecast of future economic conditions.
The weights assigned to the various compo­
nents of the index are not set arbitrarily but are
determined by how well each component helps
predict future conditions.
As a first step in their effort to develop alter­
native measures of the business cycle, Stock and
Watson developed a new index o f coincident in­
dicators for the economy. With one slight modi­
fication this index includes the same series as
the traditional one. The major difference be­
tween the two lies in the method by which they
are constructed. Rather than use some average
of the monthly changes in the individual coin­
cident indicators, Stock and Watson use a mod­
ern time-series technique known as dynamic
factor analysis to estimate what they term the
"unobserved state of the economy." This esti­
mated "state of the economy" is their alterna­
tive coincident index, and the implicit weights
for the individual components are determined
in the process of estimating their model. In prac­
tice, the historical pattern of Stock and Watson's
new coincident index differs little from the pat­
tern of the traditional coincident index. Both
tend to reach their peaks and troughs at or very
near the NBER Dating Committee's official
peaks and troughs of U.S. business cycles. But
Stock and Watson's coincident index provides
the basis for their leading index.
Stock and Watson's new leading index differs
from its traditional counterpart in more ways
than their coincident index does. First, the list
of individual indicators Stock and Watson use
to construct their leading index varies substan­
tially from the traditional list (Table 2). Their
leading index is constructed from their coinci­
dent index and seven other indicators, only two
of which appear in the list of 11 leading indica­
tors used to construct the traditional index.
More important than the differences in the
lists of individual leading indicators is the dif­
ference in Stock and Watson's methodology.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes for Pennsylvania and New jersey

Theodore M. Crone and Kevin /. Babyak

effect of each indicator on
the composite leading in­
Variables Used to Construct
dex is statistically deter­
mined in the process of
Stock and Watson's Leading Index
estimating the forecast.
How well does this new
• Stock and Watson's Coincident Index
index forecast recessions?
Stock and Watson's lead­
• Index of new private housing units authorized by local building
permits*
ing index is available
only from 1960. The U.S.
• Manufacturers unfilled orders for durable goods in constant dol­
economy experienced a
lars*
recession that year and
has suffered five others
• Part-time work in nonagricultural industries because of lack of full­
since then. How well did
time work
this new index signal the
• Trade weighted nominal exchange rate between the U.S. dollar and
past five recessions?
the currencies of the U.K., West Germany, France, Italy, and Japan
Since Stock and Watson's
leading index is a fore­
• Yield on 10-year Treasury bonds
casted change in eco­
nomic activity, a negative
• Spread between the yields on 10-year Treasury bonds and one-year
value of their index is
Treasury notes.
analogous to a decline in
• Spread between the interest rates on six-month commercial paper
the traditional index. If
and six-month Treasury bills
we apply the rule of three
consecutive negatives to
Stock and Watson's lead­
*Also in the list of indicators for the traditional leading index.
ing index, it forecasts
four of the five U.S. reces­
Rather than constructing a leading index from sions since the end of 1960 with leads of two to
some average change in the individual indica­ six months. Like the traditional index, Stock and
tors, Stock and Watson tie their leading index Watson's would not have forecast the 1990-91
more closely to their coincident index. If the recession using the rule of three consecutive
coincident index truly reflects the state of the negatives.7 But the Stock and Watson leading
economy, a good forecast of the change in the index would have resulted in only one false
coincident index should make a good leading recession signal since 1960 while the traditional
index. Therefore, Stock and Watson use past
changes in their coincident index as well as a
7Stock and Watson do not consider any absolute num­
number of other variables that have historically
ber of negatives in their leading index as a recession signal.
led the business cycle to forecast the change in Rather, they estimate a separate probability of being in re­
the coincident index over the next six months. cession in six months based on the components of their co­
This forecasted six-month change in the coin­ incident and leading indexes. But their recession probabil­
cident index becomes their leading index. To ity index also failed to forecast the 1990-91 recession. The
estimated probability of recession did not exceed 10 per­
produce the forecast they use a common timecent in the nine months prior to that recession. In the nine
series technique called vector autoregression, months prior to each of the four previous recessions, the
or VAR (see The Basics o f VAR Forecasts). The estimated probability reached 77 percent or higher.



TABLE 2

7

BUSIN ESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1996

The Basics of VAR Forecasts
Vector autoregression (VAR) forecasts are based on the notion that in properly chosen sets (vec­
tors) of economic variables there are fundamental patterns among the variables (see the 1992 article
by Crone). These fundamental patterns can sometimes be obscured by occasional deviations, and the
purpose of the VAR system is to uncover the basic pattern by estimating a system of equations in
which each variable is related to past values of itself and all the other variables in the system. In a
simple two-variable model of housing starts and mortgage interest rates, for example, the two equa­
tions to be estimated would be
Starts, = a0 + a, Starts, + a2 Starts, 2 . . . + b, Rates,, + b2 Rates, 2 . . . + es,
Rates, = g0 + g, Rates, j + g2 Rates, 2 . . . + h, Starts,, + h2 Starts, 2 . . . + eR
,
Once the coefficients a, b, g, and h have been estimated from historical data, forecasts can be gener­
ated by successively calculating values for starts and rates one period ahead.
Of course, the quality of the forecast will depend on choosing the proper variables for estimating a
stable underlying pattern. One cannot, however, increase the number of variables or the number of
lags on the variables arbitrarily in the hope of increasing the accuracy of the forecasts. Trying to
estimate too many coefficients with a limited amount of historical data will cause the occasional past
deviations from the fundamental pattern to be incorporated into the estimates of the coefficients.
Forecasts from such an estimated model will reflect past one-time deviations as well as the true fun­
damental pattern. Most model builders overcome this difficulty by limiting the number of variables
and lags included in the system based on their prior understanding of how certain variables affect
others in the economy. For a more technical discussion of VAR models, see Thomas Sargent.

index produced six false signals since then.
Thus, over the period for which it is available,
the Stock and Watson index foreshadows the
same number of recessions as the traditional
index but produces considerably fewer false
signals (see Figures 1 and 2). Like the tradi­
tional index, Stock and Watson's leading index
is less helpful in predicting recoveries than in
predicting recessions. Using a rule of three
consecutive increases, Stock and Watson's in­
dex would have predicted two of the last five
national recoveries.
LEADING INDEXES FOR THE STATES
Since we have previously constructed coin­
cident or current economic activity indexes for
Pennsylvania and New Jersey, we can use Stock
and Watson's methodology to construct lead­
ing indexes for those two states.8Like Stock and
Watson's national leading index, our state in­
dexes are forecasts of the change in the state's
8



current activity index. We chose a nine-month
forecast to produce an index with a reasonable
lead time.9 In other words, our leading index is
8We followed Stock and Watson's methodology in con­
structing the current economic activity indexes for the states.
For a description of the methodology and a list of the vari­
ables used to construct the coincident indexes, see the 1994
article by Crone. We also constructed a coincident index
for Delaware, but we were not successful in constructing a
leading index for that state because we found no set of vari­
ables to adequately predict the state's coincident index.
There is more month-to-month variability in Delaware's co­
incident index than in the indexes for Pennsylvania and
New Jersey, so changes in Delaware's coincident index are
more difficult to forecast.
9We also experimented with a six-month forecast, but
the nine-month horizon produced a slightly better lead time
for some recessions without introducing any more false sig­
nals. The longer the forecast horizon, the longer is the po­
tential lead time. The advantage of a longer lead time, how­
ever, must be weighed against the disadvantage of a less
accurate forecast.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Theodore M. Crone and Kevin J. Babyak

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes fo r Pennsylvania and New Jersey

FIGURE 1

Traditional Leading Index

60

62

64

66

68

70

72

74

76

78

80

82

84

86

88

90

92

94

96

90

92

94

96

FIGURE 2

Stock and Watson Leading Index

60

62

64

66

68

70

72

74

76

78

80

82

84

86

88

Note: Shaded areas represent national recessions.

a forecast of the total change in the coincident
index over the next nine months. Among the
variables used in the traditional index or in
Stock and Watson's index, only three are avail­
able at the state level— average hours worked



in manufacturing, housing permits, and initial
unemployment claims. Our basic model for the
leading indexes includes past changes in hous­
ing permits and initial unemployment claims
for the states plus past changes in the coinci­
9

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE1996

dent index.1 It does not include average hours
0
worked as a separate variable because this vari­
able is a component of the current activity in­
dexes for Pennsylvania and New Jersey and
past changes in these indexes are already in­
cluded in the models for the leading indexes.
We expanded these basic models by adding
some interest-rate and regional variables that
im proved the accu racy o f the forecasts w ith ­

out diminishing their ability to signal recessions
or without increasing the number of false sig­
nals. We found that adding the spread between
the six-month commercial-paper rate and the
six-month Treasury-bill rate improved our ba­
sic forecast model for New Jersey.1 For Penn­
1
sylvania, the forecast was improved by adding
the spread between the yield on 10-year Trea­
sury bonds and one-year Treasury notes.

From the Philadelphia Fed's Business Out­
look Survey of manufacturers we also have
some regional variables that correspond to com­
ponents of the national leading indexes, namely,
new orders, unfilled orders, and delivery time
(vendor performance).1 Neither the regional
2
variable for new orders nor the one for unfilled
orders improved the performance of the lead­
ing indexes for the states. But the Pennsylva­
nia model was improved by adding the diffu­
sion index for delivery time from the Philadel­
phia Fed's survey. This diffusion index is the
difference between the percentage of respon­
dents reporting an increase in delivery time and
the percentage reporting a decrease. (For a com­
plete list of variables in the state models, see
Table 3.)
Figures 3 and 4 present the leading indexes
for Pennsylvania and New Jersey from Janu­
ary 1973 to the present.1 Our leading indexes
3

10Because of the high month-to-month variability in the
data on housing permits, we smoothed the data by taking
a six-month moving average.

12The firms in this survey are located in eastern Penn­
sylvania, southern New Jersey, and Delaware.

11Improvement in the forecast was measured by the re­
duction in the average root mean squared error of the fore­
cast for the nine-month-ahead change in the state's eco­
nomic activity index.

13Because some of the data were not available prior to
1972 and our models used a number of lags in the data, we
were not able to construct leading indexes for the states prior
to 1973.

TABLE 3

Variables Used to Construct Leading Indexes for the States
Pennsylvania

New Jersey

The Philadelphia Fed's Economic Activity
Index for Pennsylvania

The Philadelphia Fed's Economic Activity
Index for New Jersey

Housing units authorized by local building
permits

Housing units authorized by local building
permits

State initial unemployment claims

State initial unemployment claims

Spread between the yields on 10-year Treasury
bonds and one-year Treasury notes

Spread between the rates on six-month
commercial paper and six-month Treasury
bills

Diffusion index for vendor delivery time from
the Philadelphia Fed's Business Outlook
Survey
10



FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes fo r Pennsylvania and New Jersey

are the predicted nine-month growth rates for
each state's current activity index based on
these final models (see Appendix). Any posi-

Theodore M. Crone and Kevin J. Babyak

tive value of the state index is a prediction of a
cumulative increase in activity over the next
nine months; any negative value is a predic-

FIGURE 3

Pennsylvania Leading Index
Index

FIGURE 4

New Jersey Leading Index

Shaded areas represent state recessions.




BUSINESS REVIEW

tion of a cumulative decrease in activity.
How Well Have These State Indexes Per­
formed? The rationale for developing leading
indexes for the states is based on the notion that
recessions in the states do not necessarily coin­
cide with national recessions. Using the cur­
rent economic activity index developed in 1994,
we identified dates for four recessions in Penn­

MAY/JUNE1996

nal, and the New Jersey index two. The record
of the state indexes is only slightly less accu­
rate than the record of the national Stock and
Watson index, which would have given no false
signals since 1973 but would have missed call­
ing the most recent recession. Like the national
indexes, these state indexes are not as reliable
in signaling the end of recessions. Using the

sy lv an ia and N ew Je rse y b etw ee n 1973 and

th ree-m onth rule P en n sy lv an ia's lead ing index

1994.1 How well would the leading indexes for
4
the two states have forecast those recessions?
If we use the rule that three successive nega­
tive readings of the index signal a recession,
Pennsylvania's leading index has predicted all
four of the state recessions since 1973, with
leads of 5 months or more. The index also gave
a false signal last year when it was negative for
seven consecutive months. Pennsylvania's
economy was very weak in 1995, but it did not
suffer a recession.
New Jersey's leading index has also pre­
dicted all four of that state's recessions since
1973, with leads of one to seven months. New
Jersey's index has given two false recession sig­
nals, one at the beginning of 1979 and one at
the end of 1987. Both of these false signals oc­
curred a little more than a year before the onset
of the next recession. Thus, in the last 23 years,
the new leading indexes for the states would
have predicted all four recessions in Pennsyl­
vania and New Jersey. In addition, the Penn­
sylvania index would have given one false sig­

would have predicted recovery from two of the
state's four recessions since 1973; New Jersey's
index would have predicted recovery from only
one of four.
At the end of 1995 the economies of both
Pennsylvania and New Jersey were growing at
a slower rate than the national average. A
record-breaking snow storm in January 1996
reduced economic activity at the beginning of
the year. New Jersey's leading index remained
positive through the period, forecasting no re­
cession this year. Pennsylvania's index was
negative in January 1996 but turned positive
again in February; so it too is not signaling a
recession this year.

14State recessions are dated from the peak to the trough
of the state's current activity index in any business cycle. A
decline in the index was recognized as a recession only if
the cumulative decline was at least four times the average
absolute monthly change in the index. Using these criteria,
we marked with bars the state recessions in Figures 3 and
4. With two exceptions these recession dates are within three
months of the cyclical peaks and troughs of employment in
each of the two states.

Digitized 1 2 FRASER
for


CONCLUSION
Although they do not have a perfect record,
leading indexes of the national economy have
been helpful in foreshadowing turning points,
especially economic downturns. The limited
data available at the state and regional level and
their greater volatility make it more difficult to
construct leading indexes for the states. Despite
these difficulties, we have been able to construct
leading indexes for Pennsylvania and New Jer­
sey. These indexes have been rather successful
in predicting downturns in the state economies
over the past 23 years. Because there have been
few business cycles over that time, however, a
longer history will be necessary before we can
make a full evaluation of these leading indexes
for Pennsylvania and New Jersey.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Theodore M. Crone and Kevin ). Babyak

Looking Ahead: Leading Indexes for Pennsylvania and New Jersey

Appendix

Model Specifications for the State Indexes
Like Stock and Watson we used vector autoregression models to construct our leading indexes for
the states. The Pennsylvania model contained five equations, and the New Jersey model, four. All
the variables except the diffusion indexes and the interest rate spreads are expressed in log difference
form, i.e., AlnX( = lnXt - lnXM. We applied some of the same restrictions that Stock and Watson used
in their model. For example, the equation for each variable except the one for the changes in the
state's economic activity index contained only one lag of itself and one lag of each of the other vari­
ables. Also, the equation for the change in the state's economic activity index contained four lags of
the change in that index and a varying number of lags on the other variables. We used a commonly
accepted statistical procedure to determine the number of lags for these other variables (see Akaike).
We show the resulting equations forecasting the change in the economic activity index for Penn­
sylvania and New Jersey.
Pennsylvania

New Jersey

4

4

AlnPAI = a + X P;(A/nPAZ)t •

AInNJl = a + £ (3 (A/nNJJ)t ■

7=1

7=1

+ylAlnPermitst_1
3

+X 8k(AlnClaims)t_
k
k=l

+X

+y]AlnPermitst_l
6

+X 5k(AlnClaims)t_
k
k= 1

C (A elivery)^
m D

m
=1

+ £$p(A Spread6)t_
p
p=i

+ X 1 p(ASpreadlO)t_
1
p
p=i

where:
AlnPAI

= log difference of the Pennsylvania current economic activity index,
i.e., AlnPAIt = lnPAI( - lnPAIt ]
= log difference of the New Jersey current economic activity index
AlnNJI
Alnpermits = log difference of the six-month moving average of state housing permits
= log difference of state initial unemployment claims
Alnclaims
= change in the diffusion index for delivery time from the Federal Reserve Bank of
Adelivery
Philadelphia's Business Outlook Survey of manufacturers
AspreadlO = change in the spread between the yields on 10-year Treasury bonds and oneyear Treasury bills
= change in the spread between the interest rates on six-month commercial paper
Aspread6
and six-month Treasury bills.

Since our leading index is the forecasted nine-month change in each state's coincident index, we
follow Stock and Watson in using the R2 between the forecasted nine-month change and the actual
nine-month change as a measure of the "goodness of fit" for the model. For Pennsylvania this R2 is
0.48, and for New Jersey it is 0.42.



13

MAY/JUNE 1996

BUSINESS REVIEW

REFERENCES
Akaike, Hirotugu. "Likelihood of a Model and Information Criteria," Journal o f Econometrics, 16 (1981),
pp. 3-14.
Bums, Arthur F., and Wesley C. Mitchell. Measuring Business Cycles. New York: National Bureau of
E conom ic R esearch, 1946.

Crone, Theodore M. "A Slow Recovery in the Third District," Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review (July/August 1992).
Crone, Theodore M. "New Indexes Track the State of the States," Federal Reserve Bank of Philadel­
phia Business Review (January/February 1994).
Gorton, Gary. "Forecasting with the Index of Leading Indicators," Federal Reserve Bank of Philadel­
phia Business Review (November/December 1982).
Green, George R., and Barry A. Beckman. "Business Cycle Indicators: Upcoming Revision of the
Composite Indexes," Survey o f Current Business (October 1993).
Martin, Vance L. "Derivation of a Leading Index for the United States Using Kalman Filters," Review
o f Economics and Statistics, 72 (1990) pp. 657-63.
Mitchell, Wesley C., and Arthur Burns. "Statistical Indicators of Cyclical Revivals," New York: NBER
Bulletin No. 69,1938.
Moore, Geoffrey H. Statistical Indicators o f Cyclical Revivals and Recessions. Occasional Paper 31. NY:
National Bureau of Economic Research, 1950.
Moore, Geoffrey H., and Julius Shiskin. Indicators o f Business Expansions and Contractions. NY: Na­
tional Bureau of Economic Research, 1967.
Rufolo, Anthony M. "An Index of Leading Indicators for the Philadelphia Region," Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (March/April 1979).
Sargent, Thomas J. "Estimating Vector Autoregressions Using Methods Not Based on Explicit Eco­
nomic Theories," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (Summer 1979).
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. "New Indexes of Coincident and Leading Economic Indica­
tors," NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1989), pp. 351-94.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. "A Probability Model of the Coincident Economic Indicators,"
in Geoffrey Moore and K. Lahiri, eds., The Leading Economic Indicators: New Approaches and
Forecasting Records. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.


14


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Inflation Forecasts:
How Good Are They?

F

J L orecasts of inflation are important because
they affect many economic decisions. Inves­
tors need good inflation forecasts, since the re­
turns to stocks and bonds depend on what hap­
pens to inflation. Businesses need inflation fore­
casts to price their goods and plan production.
H om eow ners' decisions about refinancing
mortgage loans also depend on what they think
will happen to inflation.
*Dean Croushore is an assistant vice president in charge
of the Macroeconomics Section in the Philadelphia Fed's
Research Department.




Dean Croushore*
In the early 1980s, economists tested the in­
flation forecasts in surveys taken over the pre­
vious 20 years and found that the forecasts sys­
tematically underpredicted inflation. But eco­
nomic theory suggests that this shouldn't hap­
pen. To some extent, forecasters' livelihoods
depend on how well they forecast, so they have
a strong incentive to avoid such systematic
mistakes. Faced with evidence that forecasters
make systematic errors, economists suggested
that either those who surveyed the forecasters
weren't collecting the proper data or forecast­
ers were irrational in their beliefs about infla­
15

BUSIN ESS REVIEW

tion. As a result, many economists stopped pay­
ing attention to the forecast surveys.
If we look at the data on actual inflation and
the forecasts of inflation, the problem with the
forecasts is clear. In the mid-1970s, and again
in the late 1970s, inflation increased dramati­
cally, rising to much higher levels than were
forecast. But that doesn't mean that the fore­
casters w eren 't d oing the b est they could using

the available information. Major increases in
oil prices because of political events in the
Middle East made the job of accurately fore­
casting inflation impossible. When oil prices
rose, inflation rose sharply as well. Given that
no one anticipated these huge increases in oil
prices, it isn't surprising that the inflation fore­
casts underpredicted inflation. Another prob­
lem for forecasters was that, before 1973-74,
they had never faced such a large increase in
oil prices, so they didn't know how inflation
would respond.
So economists may have been too rash in
abandoning the surveys of forecasters. The key
question is this: does adding data from the
1980s and early 1990s suggest that the forecasts
are better than when we just looked at data from
the 1970s and before? The answer is yes: the
forecasts are much better when you look at the
entire period through 1994. One interpretation
is simply that the sharp rise in oil prices caused
a period of inflation underprediction; inflation
forecasts are generally good otherwise. And
it's understandable that forecasters facing such
a huge economic shock w eren't sure what
would happen.
But the forecasts aren't perfect. Forecasters
don't seem to account properly for changes in
monetary policy. When inflation is increasing
and the Federal Reserve raises short-term in­
terest rates, the forecasts suggest that inflation
will stop rising much more quickly than it ac­
tually does. Systematic errors such as these sug­
gest that while inflation forecasts are correct on
average, forecasters are inefficient in their use
of information about monetary policy. These er­

16


MAY/JUNE 1996

rors could arise because forecasters don't do
their jobs well, because the economy is too com­
plicated and changes too frequently, because it
takes tim e to learn about changes in the
economy, or because monetary policy isn't fully
credible.
FORECASTS SHOULD BE UNBIASED
The econom ic theory of rational expectations
implies that forecasts for inflation should meet
two criteria: (1) they must be unbiased, that is,
forecast errors (actual inflation minus the fore­
cast) must average out to zero over time; and
(2) they must be efficient, that is, forecasters must
use all the relevant information at their disposal
in forming forecasts.
Forecasts are unbiased if, when you look at
the data on inflation and on inflation forecasts
over a long period, positive and negative er­
rors cancel each other out. But a look at actual
inflation compared with expected inflation (as
estimated from the Livingston Survey of econo­
mists from 1956 through 1979) shows a prob­
lem (Figure l) .1If the inflation forecasts are cor­
rect on average, they should be located sym­
metrically around the 45-degree line drawn in
the figure. As you can see, the points tend to be
above that line—actual inflation has usually
been higher than expected inflation. These fore­
casts are biased because they show a system­
atic underprediction of inflation.
Many formal statistical studies of the data
available in the early 1980s also suggested that
forecasts were biased.2This discovery, with sta­
tistical support behind it, persuaded economists

1The Livingston Survey, which collects economists' fore­
casts of inflation and other economic variables twice a year,
has been in existence since 1946. For more information on
the Livingston Survey, which is conducted by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, see the article by Herb Tay­
lor. John Carlson discusses some statistical problems in
using the survey. The figure shows the mean forecasts of
CPI inflation over the 14 months following each survey,
compared with actual inflation over those 14 months.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Inflation Forecasts: How Good Are They?

Dean Croushore

FIGURE 1

Actual and Expected Inflation
Livingston Survey 1956H1 to 1979H2
A ctual

Expected
that there must be something wrong with sur­
veys of inflation expectations. Some economists
believed that people didn't have a strong
enough incentive to respond accurately to the
surveys, because they weren't being paid to

2These studies include those by Stephen Figlewski and
Paul Wachtel; Edward Gramlich; Eugene Fama and Michael
Gibbons; and Michael Bryan and William Gavin. For a re­
view of the issues and the statistical results, see the article
by G.S. Maddala. Technically, a biased forecast isn't neces­
sarily worse than an unbiased forecast, if the bias is small
and if the biased forecast has smaller errors, on average.
But the bias found in these studies was quite large.




supply their fore­
casts, and they
m ade their fore­
casts anonymously.
An
altern ativ e
view was that the
people being sur­
veyed weren't very
good at forecasting
in flation because
they had no reason
to be good at doing
so; their livelihoods
didn't depend on
their inflation fore­
casts. As one par­
ticipant suggested,
the ben efits of
working on a joke
for the speech he
was about to give
were greater than
the benefits from a
slight refinement in
his inflation fore­
cast.

INFLATION
AND THE OIL
SHOCK
Economists had
become interested in testing people's expecta­
tions about inflation at the worst possible time.
In 1973 and 1974, the price of oil rose dramati­
cally on world markets in response to a sharp
reduction in supply from the Arabian penin­
sula, catching everyone by surprise. As a result,
inflation in the United States and many other
countries rose sharply, and the forecasts of in­
flation looked very bad (Figure 2).2The oil-price
3

3A s before, the data in this figure are the mean responses
from the Livingston Survey for the 14-month-ahead fore­
cast of CPI inflation.
17

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1996

FIGURE 2

Actual and Expected Inflation
Livingston Survey
Percent

Note: "Expected" is the inflation forecast for the year following the forecast date;
"Actual" is the actual inflation rate over that period.

shock of 1973-74 was followed by another one
in 1978-79, which is also apparent in the figure.
The two oil-price shocks were unexpected.
But compounding the problem was the fact that
people didn't know how the economy would
respond. Would the oil price increases cause a
recession in the United States? Would inflation
rise permanently or temporarily and by how
much? How would monetary policy respond?
We know now that the sharp increases in oil
prices led directly to a large increase in inflaDigitized for 18
FRASER


tion, but at the
time, no one knew
what would hap­
pen.4 Since these
were the first epi­
sodes of their kind
in U.S. history, it
isn't surprising that
the
fo recasters
d id n 't do a very
good job in forming
inflation expecta­
tions.
FORECASTS
LOOK BETTER
TODAY
If we add the in­
flation data since
1980 to the chart,
the forecasts look
much better (Fig­
ure 3). There ap­
pears to have been
some overpredic­
tion of inflation in
the early 1980s and
again in the early
1990s, but these er­
rors are m uch
smaller than the er­
rors in the 1970s.5
Formal statisti­
cal tests on the

4CPI inflation rose from just over 3 percent in 1972 to
almost 9 percent in 1973 and over 12 percent in 1974. In the
second oil shock, inflation rose from just under 7 percent in
1977 to 9 percent in 1978, then to about 13 percent in 1979
and 1980.
5The error in a forecast is defined as the actual inflation
rate over the period minus the forecast of the inflation rate
over the period. If forecasts are good, forecast errors should
be fairly small, and the plotted points should be close to the
45-degree line in the figure.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Inflation Forecasts: How Good Are They?

d ata, w hich are
id en tical to the
ones econ om ists
perform ed in the
early 1980s, show
m u c h -im p ro v e d
performance.6 The
forecasts no longer
show any bias. In
the figu re, the
poin ts are fairly
symmetric around
the 45-degree line.
W h at's m ore,
this result holds up
when we look at
data from other
surveys of forecasts
or data other than
the CPI in flation
rate. W e've done
the same statistical
tests using the Sur­
vey of Professional
Forecasters (Figure
4) and the Univer­
sity of M ichigan
Survey of Consum­
ers (Figure 5).7 The
expected inflation
variable in the fig­

Dean Croushore

FIGURE 3

Actual and Expected Inflation
Livingston Survey 1956H1 to 1994H2
Actual

6In this analysis, we add data from the 1980s and 1990s
to the original data from the 1950s through the 1970s. A
similar figure for just the 1980s and 1990s shows a very
impressive forecast pattern, with very small differences be­
tween actual and expected inflation. The formal results,
which are based on regression analysis, are available from
the author upon request.
7See my 1993 article for a detailed description of the
Survey of Professional Forecasters, which began in 1968.
See the article by Nicholas Noble and Windsor Fields for
more details on the University of Michigan Survey of Con­
sumers, which, in 1969, began to collect inflation forecasts
once a quarter.




Expected
ure for the Survey of Professional Forecasters
is the mean of the survey participants' forecasts
of the GNP implicit price deflator (GDP defla­
tor after 1991) over the next year, which is com­
pared to actual inflation over the next year; for
the Michigan survey it is the mean of the sur­
vey participants' forecasts of the CPI inflation
rate over the next year, which is compared to
actual inflation over the next year. Though these
surveys differ in the types of people respond­
ing to the survey and the type of inflation vari­
able being forecast, there is no apparent bias in
the figures, a finding supported by formal sta­
tistical tests.
19

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1996

biased , there is
some evidence that
they are inefficient.
Actual and Expected Inflation
The term inefficient
Survey of Professional Forecasters 1968Q4 to 1994Q4
applies to forecasts
that could be im ­
Actual
proved by using
additional informa­
tion. That is, fore­
casters could have
done a better job at
forecasting if they
had used all the
data available to
them in the right
way. My research
with Larry Ball of
Johns
H opkins
U n iv ersity
has
found that forecast­
ers do not use infor­
mation about mon­
etary policy in the
best way possible.8
Our research sug­
gests that when in­
flatio n is risin g,
leading the Federal
Reserve to tighten
m onetary policy,
Expected
forecasters under­
estimate the degree
to which inflation
So it appears that the bias found in earlier continues to rise even after the Fed has taken
studies of the surveys of inflation forecasts was action. Forecasters thus seem to assume that
largely due to the oil-price shocks in the 1970s. tight monetary policy will have a more imme­
Those shocks made all forecasts of inflation look diate impact on inflation than is actually the
bad. Still, these forecasts may have been the best case.
In our research, we examine the correlation
possible forecasts of inflation at the time; people
should realize that unpredictable shocks some­ between the inflation forecast error (that is, the
times occur.
FIGURE 4

BUT FORECASTS
MAY STILL BE INEFFICIENT
Even though the forecasts appear to be un­

20


8Detailed results can be found in our 1995 working pa­
per. Frederick Joutz, as well as John Schroeter and Scott
Smith, also found that forecasters don't use information
about monetary policy efficiently.
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Dean Croushore

Inflation Forecasts: Hoiv Good Are They?

FIGURE 5

Actual and Expected Inflation
Michigan Survey 1969Q1 to 1994Q4
A ctual

tionship, which can
be seen in a plot of
the data (Figure 6).
In this figure, we've
shown the inflation
forecast error from
the Survey of Pro­
fessional Forecast­
ers plotted against
the change in the
federal funds rate.
You can see that
there is a positive
relation sh ip b e­
tw een the tw o—
w hen m onetary
policy is tightening,
actu al in flation
tends to be higher
than expected infla­
tion. And when
m on etary policy is

0

2

4

6
Expected

actual inflation rate over the next year minus
the expected inflation rate) and the change in
the federal funds rate (our measure of monetary
policy) over the past year. If the forecasters are
efficient in using information about monetary
policy, there should be no relationship between
the forecast error and the annual change in the
federal funds rate; otherwise the forecasters
should have used the relationship between the
forecast error and the change in the federal
funds rate to produce an improved forecast. But
our formal statistical tests show a positive rela­



easing, actual infla­
tion tends to be less
than expected infla­
tion.
The solid line
shown in the figure
is the line through
8
10
12
the points of the
figure that fits the
data best.
As
shown by the line,
an increase of one percentage point in the fed­
eral funds rate over the past year is associated
with an increase in the forecast error of 0.32
percentage point, on average.
Further investigation of this result shows
that the forecasters' errors lie in the timing of
the response of inflation to monetary policy, not
in the magnitude. That is, the forecasters are
right about the size of the effect that tighter
monetary policy has in reducing inflation, but
their forecasts suggest that inflation will re­
spond to monetary policy quickly. In fact, it
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1996

ing this procedure
over the last six
years of the period
Inflation Forecast Errors and
we study w ould
Monetary Policy
have lowered fore­
Survey of Professional Forecasters 1968Q4 to 1994Q4
cast errors roughly
20 percent.9 For ex­
ample, after the fed­
eral funds rate de­
clined 2.4 percent­
age points in 1992,
the forecasters pre­
dicted inflation in
the GDP deflator of
2.87 percent, but a
b etter
forecast
could have been
made by predicting
inflation of 2.87 (2.4 x .32), or 2.10
percent. Actual in­
flation for the GDP
deflator turned out
to be 2.13 percent,
so the m odified
fo recast
would
have been m uch
better.
This relationship
-8
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
betw een inflation
forecast errors and
Change in Federal Funds Rate
past changes in
M onetary Policy
m onetary policy
--------- Easing
T ig h ten in g -------- ►
also appears when
we use the L iv­
ingston Survey or
takes longer for monetary policy to work than the University of Michigan Survey of Consum­
the forecasters think.
An improved inflation forecast can be de­
vised by using the information from Figure 6.
9Technically, the root mean squared forecast error is 17
To get a new inflation forecast, take the aver­ percent lower, while the mean absolute error is 24 percent
age survey forecast for inflation (in the GDP lower. The root mean squared forecast error is found by
taking the square of the forecast error at each date, calculat­
deflator) over the coming year and add to it an
ing the average of these squared values, and taking the
amount equal to 0.32 times the change in the square root. The mean absolute error is found by taking the
federal funds rate over the past year. Follow­ average of the absolute values of the forecast errors.
Digitized for 2 2
FRASER


FIGURE 6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Inflation Forecasts: How Good Are They?

ers as the basis for expected inflation. This sug­
gests that forecasters could use information
about monetary policy to make better forecasts.
In particular, forecasters would need to make
sure that their inflation forecasts reflected the
proper timing of changes in inflation caused by
recent movements in monetary policy.
EXPLAINING FORECAST INEFFICIENCY
Why do inflation forecasts suffer from inef­
ficiency? Don't forecasters have the incentive
to provide optimal forecasts? If so, how can
forecast errors be persistently related to mon­
etary policy measures? You might think that if
forecasters continually made mistakes in their
inflation forecasts, they would realize they were
doing so and would correct those errors. So the
real question is: why don't forecasters make
adjustments so that they produce not only bet­
ter forecasts but also ones that are efficient with
respect to monetary policy? There are a num­
ber of possible explanations for why forecast
errors may persist, but no convincing explana­
tions for why the forecasts are inefficient in the
first place.
One possible explanation for the failure of
forecasters to improve their forecasts is simply
that forecasters don't do their jobs well. That
is, they must not have enough incentive to form
completely rational expectations of inflation,
perhaps because their inflation forecasts aren't
that important to them. It's possible that, ex­
cept for the few forecasters whose forecasts of
inflation are used by traders to buy and sell
bonds and thus have a lot of money riding on
them, the forecasters in the survey may not care
about inflation very much. If their forecasts are
wrong, it doesn't hurt them.
Another possible explanation for why fore­
cast errors may persist is that the m acro­
economy is very complicated, and no one has a
complete understanding of how it works. The
Phillips curve (which relates inflation to the
unemployment rate) was thought to be a great
model of inflation until the 1970s, when it failed



Dean Croushore

miserably. Nobody knew ahead of time that the
oil-price shocks in the 1970s would raise infla­
tion so much. And the most popular theoreti­
cal models of the economy today seem far too
abstract to use in forecasting. As a result, it isn't
surprising that forecasting inflation is difficult.
Related to our lack of understanding of ex­
actly how the economy works is the fact that it
takes tim e for econom ists to learn about
changes in the economy. They don't see trends
emerging right away; it takes time for the data
to come in and for economists to realize that
the relationship between economic variables
has changed. For example, in the late 1980s, the
Federal Reserve developed a model of inflation
called P* (pronounced P-star), which related the
money supply (measured by M2) to the price
level for the GNP deflator. But the changes in
the demand for money that occurred in the
early 1990s altered the relationship between M2
and inflation. As a result, the model no longer
provided good forecasts. For example, it pre­
dicted a large reduction in inflation in the 199395 period, but inflation didn't decline nearly as
much as predicted.
Another possible explanation for the ineffi­
ciency of inflation forecasts concerns the cred­
ibility of monetary policy. In the early 1980s,
people had doubts about how serious the Fed­
eral Reserve was about fighting inflation. They
thought the Fed might allow inflation to drift
upward, rather than keeping inflation at 4 per­
cent or less. That may be why forecasters per­
sistently overpredicted inflation in the mid1980s. So, clearly some degree of inefficiency
in forecasting inflation may be due to uncer­
tainties about monetary policy.
Credibility may also have played a role in
the early 1990s. Again, forecasters kept predict­
ing a rise in CPI inflation from about 3 percent
to about 3.5 percent. The overprediction was
small, but it persisted for several years. This
persistence may have resulted from a combi­
nation of doubts about the Fed's commitment
to low inflation and the lack of a good macro­
23

BUSINESS REVIEW

economic model of inflation, since monetary
aggregates (M l, M2, M3) seemed to have lost
their predictive power.
While these explanations may help us un­
derstand why forecasters have difficulty in fore­
casting inflation and perhaps also why they
don't adjust their forecasts to better use the in­
formation about monetary policy, they don't tell
us why the forecast errors are systematically
related to monetary policy in the first place.

Digitized for 4
2 FRASER


MAY/JUNE 1996

CONCLUSION
Surveys of inflation forecasts have had a bad
reputation. Based on statistical tests in the early
1980s, economists had doubts about how ac­
curate the forecasts were. But that was largely
the effect of the oil-price shocks in the 1970s. If
we look at the data today, the forecasts look
much better. Nonetheless, there appears to be
some inefficiency in the forecasts with respect
to their relationship to monetary policy.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Inflation Forecasts: Hoiv Good Are They?

Dean Croushore

REFERENCES
Ball, Laurence, and Dean Croushore. "Expectations and the Effects of Monetary Policy,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper No. 95-22, October 1995.
Bryan, Michael F., and William T. Gavin. "Models of Inflation Expectations Formation: A
Comparison of Household and Economist Forecasts," Journal o f Money, Credit, and
Banking 18 (November 1986), pp. 539-43.
Carlson, John A. "A Study of Price Forecasts," Annals o f Economic and Social Measurement 6
(Winter 1977), pp. 27-56.
Croushore, Dean. "Introducing: The Survey of Professional Forecasters," Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (November/December 1993), pp. 3-15.
Fama, Eugene F., and Michael R. Gibbons. "A Comparison of Inflation Forecasts," Journal
o f Monetary Economics 13 (May 1984), pp. 327-48.
Figlewski, Stephen, and Paul Wachtel. "The Formation of Inflationary Expectations," Re­
view o f Economics and Statistics 63 (February 1981), pp. 1-10.
Gramlich, Edward M. "Models of Inflation Expectations Formation," Journal o f Money,
Credit, and Banking 15 (May 1983), pp. 155-73.
Joutz, Frederick L. "Informational Efficiency Tests of Quarterly Macroeconometric GNP
Forecasts from 1976 to 1985," Managerial and Decision Economics 9 (1988), pp. 311-30.
Maddala, G.S. "Survey Data on Expectations: What Have We Learnt?" in Marc Nerlove,
ed., Issues in Contemporary Economics, vol. II. Aspects of Macroeconomics and Econo­
metrics. New York: New York University Press, 1991.
Noble, Nicholas R., and T. Windsor Fields. "Testing the Rationality of Inflation Expecta­
tions Derived from Survey Data: A Structure-Based Approach," Southern Economic
Journal 49 (October 1982), pp. 361-73.
Schroeter, John R., and Scott L. Smith. "A Reexamination of the Rationality of the Livingston
Price Expectations," Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking 18 (May 1986), pp. 239-46.
Taylor, Herb. "The Livingston Surveys: A History of Hopes and Fears," Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (January/February 1992), pp. 15-27.




25

Philadelphia/RESEARCH
WORKING PAPERS
The Philadelphia Fed's Research Department occasionally publishes working papers based on
the current research of staff economists. These papers, dealing with virtually all areas within
economics and finance, are intended for the professional researcher. The papers added to the
Working Papers series thus far this year are listed below. To order copies, please send the number
of the item desired, along with your address, to WORKING PAPERS, Department of Research,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 10 Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106. For over­
seas airmail requests only, a $3.00 per copy prepayment is required; please make checks or money
orders payable (in U.S. funds) to the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. A list of all available
papers may be ordered from the same address.

96-1

Mitchell Berlin, Kose John, and Anthony Saunders, "Bank Equity Stakes in Borrowing
Firms and Financial Distress"

96-2

Joseph P. Hughes and Loretta J. Mester, "Bank Capitalization and Cost: Evidence of Scale
Economies in Risk Management and Signaling"

96-3

Tom Stark and Dean Croushore, "Evaluating McCallum's Rule When Monetary Policy
Matters"

96-4

Sherrill Shaffer, "Capital Requirements and Rational Discount Window Borrowing"

96-5

Stephen Morris, "Speculative Investor Behavior and Learning"

96-6

Karen K. Lewis, "Consumption, Stock Returns, and the Gains from International RiskSharing"

96-7

Graciela L. Kaminsky and Karen K. Lewis, "Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Signal
Future Monetary Policy?"

96-8

Satyajit Chatterjee and Dean Corbae, "Money and Finance with Costly Commitment"

96-9

Joseph P. Hughes, William Lang, Loretta J. Mester, and Choon-Geol Moon, "Efficient
Banking Under Interstate Branching"


26


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

FEDERAL
RESERVE BANK OF
PHILADELPHIA
Business Review Ten Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574