View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

S i

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

ISSN 0007-7011

M AY-JU N E 1978
aalllll&IllliP! i

th e Cost
ZWTmTdL

2S

&

Uniformity
in
Assessment




MAY/JUNE 1978

ESTIMATING THE COST
OF YOUR BANK’S FUNDS
Ronald D. W atson
. . . The cost of the next available dollar, not
the last one, is the right basis for figuring
bank profit margins.
UNIFORMITY IN ASSESSMENT:
HIGH ON THE LIST
OF PROPERTY TAX REFORMS
Nonna A. N oto

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
100 North S ixth Street
(on Independence Mall)
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106

The B U SIN E SS REVIEW is published by
the Department of Research every other
month. It is edited by John J. Mulhern, and
artwork is directed by Ronald B. Williams.
The REVIEW is available without charge.
Please send subscription orders, changes
of address, and requests for additional
copies to the Department of Public Services
at the above address or telephone (215) 5746115. Editorial communications should be
sent to the Department of Research at the
same address, or telephone (215) 574-6418.
* * * * *
The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
is part of the Federal Reserve System —a
System which includes twelve regional




. . . Nonuniform administration and prefer­
ential exemptions can lead to inefficiencies
and inequities in the property tax system.
Greater uniformity in assessment practices
could reduce some of the defects.

banks located throughout the nation as well
as the Board of Governors in Washington.
The Federal Reserve System was estab­
lished by Congress in 1913 primarily to
manage the nation’s monetary affairs. Sup­
porting functions include clearing checks,
providing coin and currency to the banking
system, acting as banker for the Federal
g ov ern m en t, su p erv isin g co m m ercial
banks, and enforcing consumer credit pro­
tection laws. In keeping with the Federal
Reserve Act, the System is an agency of the
Congress, independent adm inistratively of
the Executive Branch, and insulated from
partisan political pressures. The Federal
Reserve is self-supporting and regularly
makes payments to the United States
Treasury from its operating surpluses.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Estimating the Cost
of Your Bank’s Funds
By R onald D. Watson*
By the time Franklin National Bank finally
succumbed in 1974, it had been assured an
honored spot in modern banking theory as
the textbook example of how not to run a
bank. One of Franklin’s weaknesses was the
incorrect method its management used to
estimate the cost of the bank’s funds.1 Dur­
ing a period of high interest rates, the bank
consistently underestimated the cost of rais­
ing money. In fact, the cost of the money that
Franklin borrowed to invest was higher than
the return on the investments it was making.
Most bankers are far more sensitive to this
problem than Franklin’s management was,
but being aware of how important it is to

know the cost of money and being able to
make an accurate estimate of that cost are
two very different things. Making good cost
estimates takes time and requires a thorough
understanding of how investors make their
decisions. Further, these estimates must re­
flect current conditions in the money markets
instead of being based on costs in the past;
and they must take account of the effect that
the bank’s choice of a capital structure may
have on its cost of funds. Getting an accurate
estimate of the cost of funds poses some
tough computational problems, but there
isn’t any other way to find out what rate of
return is required to make a profit.

*Ronald D. Watson is Research Officer, Economist,
and Assistant Secretary at the Philadelphia Fed, where
he has served since 1971. Holder of an M .B.A . from
Cornell and a D .B.A . from Indiana, he specializes in
finance, banking, and business.
■^Sanford Rose, “What Really Went Wrong at Frank­
lin N ational,” Fortune (October 1974), p. 118.

THE OLD WAY:
HISTORICAL AVERAGE COSTS
In the past, the most common method of
estimating the cost of a bank’s funds was to
add together all the net expenses (interest,
reserve requirements, and other expenses




3

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1978

a bank should compare the expected return
from an investment with the current cost of
obtaining the money needed to finance that
investment. If the return (in the long run)
from a new loan or security doesn’t exceed
the probable cost of financing that asset
while the bank owns it, the bank would do
better not to acquire it.2 The added amount
that would be brought in by lending one more
unit of money to a borrower is the m arginal
revenue. The added amount that would be
paid out to procure one more unit of loanable
funds is the m arginal cost.
The use of current information in making
the cost of funds estimates is extremely
important. The cost of a bank’s funds nor­
mally will change as market interest rates
move. Some cost changes, as for CDs and
Federal funds, will be highly visible, while
others, as for demand deposits and savings
accounts, will not be so obvious. The banker
must keep abreast of both. As interest rates
rise, a banker will find that other financial
institutions will compete more vigorously for
these funds, and the depositors themselves
will make an effort to shift into the more
lucrative investments. To attract and hold
these monies a bank may have to step up its
advertising, resort to premiums, and expand
its menu of depositor services. The result
will be a higher cost to the bank for funds
from these sources.
Less obvious will be the rising cost of
equity funds—the bank’s common stock.
The target rate that a bank’s management
sets for returns to shareholders should be
adjusted to reflect any changes in yields on
other long-term investments. Investors who
have the alternative of investing in long-term
bonds at 8 or 9 percent with little risk must
expect to receive more than that from an
investment in common stock, or they will
stay with the safer security. When long-term

less service charge income] of borrowing
current funds and divide the total by the
amount being borrowed. This gave an histori­
cal estimate of the average return that had to
be earned on assets acquired with these
funds for the bank to break even in its
investment activities. If the shareholders
were to receive a return on the funds they
supplied, a profit margin had to be added to
this basic historical cost of funds estimate
(see Appendix].
But historical costs can be extremely un­
reliable as a pricing guide if conditions are
changing over time. When interest rates are
rising, the average cost of funds already
obtained will be below the cost of replacing
those funds by new borrowing, and the bank
may accept new investments it should reject.
When rates are dropping, the historical cost
of funds will be higher than replacement
costs, and the bank may be led to set too high
a standard for new investments, passing up
opportunities to make profits. Historical esti­
mates can be unreliable also when a bank’s
capital structure is changing. If a bank’s debt
is increasing faster than its equity, for ex­
ample, it may come to be regarded as a riskier
operation, and this perception of added risk
may raise the cost of the bank’s funds from
all sources. It’s because of drawbacks such
as these that bankers have turned from his­
torical cost estimates to some basic economic
principles for generating cost estimates.
THE NEW WAY: A BIT OF THEORY
The theory behind this new cost estimating
method starts from a reasonable premise—
that bank managers should make investment
decisions which make the bank more profit­
able. This theory rationalizes the rules of
thumb that many bankers actually use when
they look at profitability—rules such as add­
ing in a desired long-term profit margin as
they try to gauge the expected cost of funds
over time.

2Statement of the MC = MR principle is intentionally
very general, so that complications such as tied-product
returns and discounted future benefits can be accom­
modated within the definition.

Matching Added Costs With Added Rev­
enues. To obtain the largest profit available,




4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

historical costs is relatively easy, figuring
out the full cost of a new dollar of funds is
another matter—especially if it’s necessary
to estimate the impact that using various
sources of funds will have on the cost of
other sources.

interest rates rise 1 or 2 percentage points,
the return to common shareholders must
move by a similar amount. In a competitive
money market, the bank’s shareholders al­
ways will have investment options that offer
the current market rates. Even though a bank
may not be selling a brand new stock issue in
this high-rate environment, it still must aim
to earn the competitive rate for its current
owners. If it doesn’t, the owners would be
better off to instruct management to pay the
maximum dividend possible. The stock­
holders then could use the extra dividends to
make investments elsewhere at the higher
prevailing rates.

MARGINAL COST
ESTIMATION METHODS
Two basic options are available to the
banker who is trying to make a marginal cost
estimate. One is to identify the source of
funds that the bank currently is using to raise
new money. Once this source is identified,
an estimate might be made of the cost of
raising another block of these funds. This
estimate of the marginal cost of a single
source will serve as the hurdle rate—the
minimum required rate of return—for any
new investment of average riskiness. The
other strategy is to estimate the marginal cost
of each of the sources being employed within
the bank. By weighting the cost of new
dollars drawn from each source by the
amount to be raised from that source, bankers
can construct a weighted average of marginal
costs. The second method sounds more com­
plex, but it has some advantages over the
first that make it worth considering.

When New Costs Don’t Match Old. The
decision on a new investment should be
made on the basis of the cost of new money.
Even if a bank were lucky enough to obtain a
large pool of funds at rates that are below
current market levels, shareholders, who
bear the risk of loss, should be the benefi­
ciaries of this good fortune. If historical costs
are used to set current loan rates, the benefits
of having these relatively cheap funds will be
transferred to the borrowers rather than
being retained for the common stockholders.
If circumstances were reversed, it’s unlikely
that borrowers would be willing to pay high
interest rates on loans from a bank which had
unusually high average costs. The fact that
the bank had the misfortune of being stuck
with large amounts of funds acquired when
rates were very high wouldn’t matter if
cheaper sources were available elsewhere.
Regardless of costs or the effect on profits
available for stockholders, bankers can’t
charge borrowers a rate that is much higher
than rates available elsewhere. So historical
costs should not be considered in making
today’s investment decisions. Rather, the
cost of an additional dollar of funds should
be compared with the return that will be
realized when that additional dollar is in­
vested. So much for the theory.
But how should an estimate of the marginal
cost of funds be made? Although averaging




The Marginal Cost of a Single Source.
The most straightforward approach is to
determine which source of funds the bank
wants to use, compute its marginal cost, and
use that estimate as the hurdle rate. Presum­
ably, the source selected will be the cheapest
one available to the bank. For example, if
CDs are the source a banker turns to, the cost
of additional dollars borrowed in that market
is the relevant marginal cost. The interest
rate on CDs is easy enough to determine, but
this rate is only part of the real marginal cost
of these funds.
Suppose a bank—for example, the hypo­
thetical Ninth National Bank—wants to bor­
row $1 million for expansion. If it turns to
the CD market and pays 7 percent, that in­
terest rate is the base for the bank’s cost
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1978

whose funds are covered by deposit insurance
probably won’t care. But the holders of big
deposits and CDs might, because they are not
fully insured, and their concern could cause
them to shift their funds to another bank or
demand a higher return from Ninth National.
In either case, the bank’s cost to attract and
hold such deposits is likely to rise.
The same thing will occur with the capital
note holders and the common stockholders.
When they sense that risks are increasing,
they’ll seek a higher return on their invest­
ments. The ones that presently own these
securities can’t automatically start charging
the bank a higher rate for funds that already
have been committed, but investors will
demand a higher return for any new invested
funds. The bank will be obliged to increase
its earnings and ultimately its dividends to
stockholders in order to compensate them
for their higher risk. If it doesn’t, the interests
of the current shareholders will be harmed,
and that would be inconsistent with manage­
ment’s obligation to run the bank in a way
which enhances the shareholders’ wealth
(see THE SINGLE MARGINAL SOURCE
CALCULATION).

calculations. But the job of estimating the
marginal cost of this source is just beginning.
The bank will incur a small cost in acquiring
and repaying this money, and that cost should
be included in the estimate. Also, there will
be a reserve requirement against this source
of funds (currently 1 percent to 6 percent,
depending on term to maturity);3 any obliga­
tion to keep a portion of the borrowed money
in the form of idle cash raises the effective
cost of the funds. These adjustments to the
basic interest cost are relatively easy to
make.
A much more difficult adjustment to the
cost is the one required to compensate sup­
pliers of other sources of funds for the added
risk created by this new borrowing. Ninth
National’s leverage—its ratio of debt to equi­
ty -w ill be increased by the addition of more
CD funds. Since higher leverage produces
more risk for the bank, other creditors and
shareholders may not be as willing to continue
supplying Ninth National with funds at the
same interest rates as before. Depositors
3See “Member Bank Reserve Requirements,” Federal
Reserve Bulletin, August 1977, A9.

THE SINGLE MARGINAL SOURCE CALCULATION
Suppose the management of Ninth National is looking for another $100 and wants to raise the
money by issuing CDs. It will be obliged to pay the going market interest rate for funds (say, 7
percent). It must then add to this amount several surcharges which raise the effective rate. The cost
of reserve requirements on the CD funds might, for example, be 3 percent (annualized), the cost to
acquire such funds 0.5 percent (annualized), and the cost of servicing the funds 0.3 percent
(annualized). Using the formula

[

(interest rate + servicing costs + acquisiton costs + insurance)!

------------------------------------------------------------------------------ I -

(1 - reserve requirement)
J
the explicit cost of the CD funds is found to be 0.0804 or about 8 percent.
This is only part of the job. Since the bank now is being more heavily financed with short-term
borrowed funds, the risk is greater. Both the other suppliers of borrowed funds and the shareholders
may wish to raise the cost of future funds they provide for this bank. This additional indirect cost
must be added to the explicit cost estimate. Suppose that raising $100 of new CD funds created $.20
in added costs for other sources of funds. The real marginal cost of the CD funds would be estimated
as their explicit cost plus the risk spillover cost:
marginal cost = 8.04 percent + 0.2 percent = 8.24 percent.
Failure to include all of these costs other than interest in the estimate will lead to a hurdle rate for
new investments that understates the real cost of new funds.




6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

In any event, it should be clear that the
impact which heavy use of one source of
funding has on the cost of other sources
should be included in any analysis of the cost
of marginal funds. This risk spillover cost is
very difficult to measure, but it must be
included in the calculation. Accordingly, the
cost of new CD money can be found only
after considering the direct interest cost, any
acquisition and servicing costs, reserve re­
quirements, and risk spillover costs.4
The same principles apply to estimating
the cost of demand and time deposits (han­
dling, acquisition, reserve requirement, and
deposit insurance costs are likely to be high­
er than for CDs) or capital notes (risk spill­
over may raise the cost of the bank’s CDs and
uninsured deposits as well as the cost of its
common stock). Similarly, the nominal, before-tax cost of new common stock may

overstate its real cost because it will have the
effect of reducing overall risk and is likely to
lower the net cost of other debt sources.
Averaging All Marginal Costs. The other
approach to calculating a bank’s marginal
cost is to presume that the institution will be
financed during the next few months in
pretty much the same way as it’s being fi­
nanced now. Checking and savings accounts
will open and close and the bank will expe­
rience deposits and withdrawals. But as long
as advertising doesn’t diminish and services
don’t deteriorate, total dollars from each
retail source will change only gradually. The
bank will wind up paying the going rate to
hold funds from each of these sources.
Similarly, market rates (plus associated costs)
will be paid for any CDs sold even if they are
simply replacements for maturing issues.
Finally, the bank will have to pay competi­
tive returns for capital if it expects to keep
access to these sources of funds. In short, the
mix of sources doesn’t change and the bank
must pay current rates for each source used
(see THE AVERAGE OF MARGINAL
COSTS CALCULATION).

4 A more technical explanation of this calculation can
be found in Ronald D. Watson, "The Marginal Cost of
Funds Concept in Banking,” Research Paper No. 19,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, January 1977;
reprinted with revisions in the Journ al o f B an k Research
8 (Autumn 1977), pp. 136-147.

THE AVERAGE OF MARGINAL COSTS CALCULATION
Since figuring out the risk spillover costs is very difficult, the banker might prefer to calculate his
explicit marginal costs for each source of funds and average those estimates to find out what the
entire pool of funds presently is costing. Suppose that the bank is structured as follows;

Demand deposits
Time deposits
CDs
Capital notes
Common stock

Added Dollars

Explicit Cost*

$30
40
10
10
10

.05
.07
.08
.09
.22

$8.20

$100

Then Ninth National’s estimate would be: marginal cost =
‘ With acquisition, servicing, and reserve costs included.




$1.50
2.80
.80
.90
2.20

7

---- 1— = 0.082 = 8.2 percent.

$ 100.00

MAY/JUNE 1978

BUSINESS REVIEW

If Ninth National is trying to calculate the
overall cost of this pool of funds, it will need
an estimate of the marginal cost of each
source employed. That estimate must include
any explicit interest payments, acquisition
and servicing costs, deposit insurance, and
reserve requirements. Such a calculation
will be straightforward for CDs and capital
notes but very difficult for demand and time
deposits (even if the bank has a reliable cost
accounting system). Estimating the percent­
age of the advertising budget that goes to
keeping demand deposit levels steady or the
additional advertising that would be required
to increase time and savings deposits by a
few percent is a very uncertain undertaking.
At best it will involve a substantial amount of
informed judgment.
When management is satisfied with these
marginal cost estimates, an overall average
can be calculated by multiplying each esti­
mate by the fraction of the bank’s funds that
will be raised from this source in the near
future. The weighted average will indicate
the cost to the bank of buying the funds that
will be used for investments or loans made
during that time and it will serve as a mini­
mum target rate of return for a new invest­
ment of average risk.
For all its complexity, this estimate has an
advantage over the single-source cost esti­
mate. With the weighted average approach
there is no need to try to calculate the impact
that risk spillovers have on the cost of other
sources. The present level of the bank’s
leverage risk already is reflected in the prices
of its liabilities and equity securities. If the
composition of the pool of funds doesn’t
change, the risks aren’t going to change
significantly. The risk spillover that each
source of funds creates for the other sources
is neutralized in this pooling process and
need not be estimated separately. As a result,
estimates of the current marginal cost of
each source, averaged across all sources,
will provide a correct estimate of the bank’s
pool of funds without further risk adjust­
ments.




CHOOSE YOUR POISON
Both of the cost estimation methods just
described have pitfalls. Calculating the mar­
ginal cost of a single source such as CDs
looks easy. The interest rate is known and
the reserve and handling costs are measur­
able. But estimating the size of the risk
spillover adjustment that should be added to
the other costs to get the real marginal cost is
very difficult.
In addition, one of the basic principles of
economic theory is that businesses should
tap each source of funds until the cost of the
next dollar raised from that source is the
same as the cost of a dollar from each other
available source. That’s the way to maximize
profit, since it keeps money costs as low as
possible. If a bank concentrates its attention
on the cost of just one source, it may lose
sight of the availability of funds from other
sources that are cheaper.
Computing a weighted average of marginal
costs keeps a banker looking at all of his
costs simultaneously. Estimating the margi­
nal cost of the bank’s demand and time
deposits remains a sticky problem, but the
uncertainties of calculating risk spillover
adjustments are avoided. This method will
not provide the manager with the informa­
tion needed to balance the marginal cost of
one source against the marginal cost of
another. For that he needs a marginal cost
estimate that includes the risk spillover ad­
justment for each type of funds used. But the
banker doesn’t have to worry about risk spill­
over adjustments when he uses this method.
He may not be getting the cheapest mix of
funds, especially if he has overlooked a
relatively cheap source; but he will be getting
an accurate estimate of the cost of the pool of
funds he’s using. In this he has an advantage
over his counterpart who computes the mar­
ginal cost of a single source but then con­
tinues to raise funds from all of the available
sources. If the real marginal costs of each
source are not really equal, use of the singlesource technique will produce a faulty esti­
mate.
8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

same answer. If they do, you have a cost of
funds estimate. If they don’t, you had better
try to figure out why. Do you need better data
about your costs? Is the bank being financed
with too expensive a mix of sources? Are the
institution’s costs under both calculations
higher than previously thought? Has the
bank been adding new business at a loss
rather than a profit?
The exercise may be frustrating. It may be
disturbing. But a sharp banker has to go
through it if he’s to do a first-rate job of
managing profits.

A Sensible Procedure. Both processes
produce the right answer when used correct­
ly. And both are difficult to use correctly.
The best approach is to remember that both
methods can give the right answer. Calculate
the bank’s cost of funds both ways. Use a
sharp pencil. Analyze the cost estimates
employed. Think about the effect that lever­
age risk has on the cost of various sources of
funds. Analyze what you’re really paying for
demand deposits.
If both methods can give a correct answer,
the calculations you make should give the

For Appendix, see overleaf. . .




9

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1978

APPENDIX

AN EXAMPLE OF HISTORICAL AVERAGE COST
CALCULATIONS
Consider the case of the hypothetical Ninth National Bank. This bank gets its funds from demand
and time deposits, CDs, subordinated capital notes, and common stock (see BALANCE SHEET).
The full cost of each source of funds (interest and servicing cost of all funds obtained from that
source) is indicated in parentheses.

NINTH NATIONAL BANK BALANCE SHEET
Cash and due
Investments
Loans

Total

$100
300
600

$1000

Demand deposits
Time deposits
CDs
Capital notes
Common stock

(4%)
(6%)
(6%)
(8%)
(20%)

Total

$300
400
100
100
100
$1000

Since management wants to insure that the shareholders’ funds earn a return of 20 percent (10
percent after taxes if the tax rate is 50 percent), it must include this profit objective in its average cost
of funds estimate.
.04
.06
.06
.08
.20

Demand deposits
Time deposits
CDs
Capital notes
Common stock

x
x
x
x
x

$300
400
100
100
100

$1000

Cost of funds =

$70

$1000

= $12
= 24
= 6
= 8
= 20 (before taxes)
$70

0.07 = 7.0 percent.

Only if Ninth National is able to average a 7-percent return on all invested funds will it be able to pay
shareholders that target 10-percent return (after taxes).
Most banks would have little trouble computing this breakeven return, and it would appear to
solve the problem of estimating a cost of funds which could be used as a minimum required rate of
return (hurdle rate) for new investment decisions. But, this will work only when interest rates are
perfectly steady. Otherwise, using actual average costs to set the hurdle rate for new investments
will give the wrong answer.




10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

As an illustration, suppose that the inflation rate increases, and one consequence of this change is
a jump in interest rates on most securities. For simplicity, let’s say that all rates go up 1 percentage
point. The cost of replacing all Ninth National’s deposits, CDs, and capital funds might now be:
Demand deposits
Time deposits
CDs
Capital notes
Common stock

5%
7%
7%
9%
11% (after taxes).

The weighted average cost of a new pool of funds would be over 8 percent rather than the 7 percent
that Ninth National has been paying for its funds. What happens if the bank continues to use that
historical cost hurdle rate of 7 percent?
One thing that will happen is that Ninth National might be tempted to take on new loans and
investments that yield only 71/2 percent. If the bank invests in a $100 bond that yields 71/2 percent,
it will be earning $7.50 per year. But as long as the composition of the bank’s sources of funds doesn’t
change, the cost of new funds acquired to make that investment is:
Demand deposits
Time deposits
CDs
Capital notes
Common stock

.05
.07
.07
.09
.22

$30 ==$1.50
40 == 2.80
X
10 == .70
X
10 == .90
X
10 == 2.20
$100 $8.10.

X

X

Since shareholders are the last to be paid, this shortfall will come out of their part of the bank’s
income:
$7.50
-5.90
1.60
-.80
$.80

income
cost of debt sources
earnings before taxes
taxes
earnings after taxes.

$.80
Return on new shareholder equity = --------- =0.08 = 8 percent.
$ 10.00

This return is not high enough to pay shareholders the return of 11 percent (after taxes) that they
expect from their investment in the bank’s stock. The ones that are dissatisfied will want to sell their
stock and its price will be forced downward. All of the shareholders will be worse off because of the
incorrect investment decision.




ll

F ro m th e
P h ilad elp h ia F e d ...

A Banker’s Day

This new pamphlet, which describes the range of decisions a modern banker has to make, is
available without charge from the Department of Public Services, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, 100 North Sixth Street, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Uniformity in Assessment:
High on the List
of Property Tax Reforms
By N onna A. N oto *
The results are inequity (equals are not treated
equally) and inefficiency (property costs do
not accurately reflect underlying demand
and supply considerations). While a move
toward greater uniformity would produce
hardship in some cases, many tax experts
favor dealing with such cases by direct aid
rather than by imposing the costs of nonuni­
formity of the assessment system on property
taxpayers as a whole. But the precise costs
and benefits of both direct aid and exemptions
remain to be determined.
The mechanisms for achieving greater uni­
formity are available. Legislatures can use
methods other than nonuniform assessments
to respond to different groups. And modern
computer technology can improve the admin­
istration and efficiency of America’s property
tax system.

In recent years, dramatic increases in prop­
erty values and higher costs for local gov­
ernment services, including education, have
driven property tax bills sharply upward. As
the dollar amounts claimed by taxes have
grown, many property owners around the
country have come to question whether they
are paying more than their fair share.
Most states have laws on the books that
require all properties to be assessed for tax
purposes at the same percentage of their
market value, at least within the same taxing
jurisdiction. But these laws often are not
accompanied by procedures for attaining the
legislated goal. And many states have legis­
lated exemptions that offer preferential tax
treatment to individuals in certain groups.
The consequence of not living up to one of
the basic tenets of “good” taxation—unifor­
mity—is a patchwork of uneven tax liabilities.

ASSESSMENT RATIOS
ARE NOT UNIFORM
Uniformity is a long-recognized principle
of public finance and is embodied in many

* Nonna A. Noto, who joined the bank staff in 1974,
holds a Ph.D. from Stanford University. She specializes
in urban economics and public finance.




13

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1978

states’ legislation on assessments. Yet almost
any sample of properties is likely to reveal a
considerable range of assessed-to-marketvalue ratios rather than uniformity.

be assessed at a higher ratio than new ones. 3
And lower value houses may be assessed at a
larger fraction of market value than higher
value ones.
Evidence of identifiable patterns of in­
equality in assessment ratios has turned up in
Philadelphia and other cities, but the patterns
vary from city to city. 4 The overall picture of
the Philadelphia situation is illustrated by
the accompanying map. According to calcu­
lations by the Philadelphia City Finance
Director’s Office, the 1975 citywide average
assessment ratio (on all types of property]
was 40 percent. Average assessment ratios

Clear Evidence. The factual evidence for
nonuniformity is clear both at the local and at
the state level.
Most states, for example, have legislated
partial exemptions for homeowners, senior
citizens, the disabled, and veterans.i And
many organizations have a long history of
total exemption from the property tax.
Churches, private schools, and nonprofit
hospitals and cultural institutions, along with
Federal, state, and local governments, have
been declared exempt from property taxes
under time-honored legal precedents.
Further, some land use classifications are
assessed at lower ratios than others. Vacant
or agricultural land, for example, often is
assessed at a lower ratio than developed
land. And single-family residential property
frequently is assessed at a lower rate than
multifamily residential, commercial, or
industrial property. In a few cases, these
preferential assessment policies have been
articulated in state laws. But in many instances,
they represent local assessment customs.*2
Even within one land use classification,
there may be a systematic bias in assessment
ratios corresponding to such features as the
age or value of property. Older commercial
and industrial properties, for example, may

law require that all types of property be assessed
uniformly. Nonetheless, a statewide sample of 1976
property sales in New Jersey found vacant and residential
land assessed, on average, at 68 percent of sales price
while business property was assessed at 86 percent. A
similar calculation of average assessment ratios in
Philadelphia based on 1975 property sales found private
residential property assessed at 37 percent of sales price
compared to 41 percent for industrial property, 42
percent for vacant property, 45 percent for multifamily
units, and 52 percent for commercial property. See U. S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census,
Property Values S u bject to L o ca l General Property
Taxation in the United States:1973, State and Local
Government Special Studies No. 69 (Washington:
Government Printing Office, 1974), pp. 4-9; State of
New Jersey, Department of the Treasury, Division of
Taxation, Average A ssessm ent/Sales Ratio in N ew jersey
by Taxing District—by Property Class (Trenton:1977),
p.III; City of Philadelphia, O ffice of the Controller, Real
Estate Tax, August 31, 1976, Exhibit IV.

O

t

4
Preferential tax treatment can take the form of a
reduction in the assessed value of the residence (an
exemption in the traditional sense), a deduction from
the tax payment otherwise due, or a tax rebate check.
All three approaches accomplish the same result of
lowering the effective property tax rate paid by certain
property owners.

Investigating assessments in Boston in the early
1970s, Andrew Hamer learned from the Boston Asses­
sor’s Office that while recently constructed office prop­
erty was assessed on average at 30 percent of market
value, older office structures were assessed at 50 percent;
for industrial properties, recently constructed space
was assessed at 35 percent, remodeled space at 45
percent, and older space at 50 percent. See his Industrial
Exodus from Central City (Lexington, M ass.: D.C.
Heath and Company, 1973), p. 46.

2Apart from the now widespread agricultural and
open space exemptions, only eight states have made
legal provisions for different land use categories to be
assessed or taxed at different rates. Tennessee law, for
example, provides that farm and residential property is
to be assessed at 25 percent of market value, industrial
and commercial property at 40 percent, and public
utilities at 55 percent. Both New Jersey and Pennsylvania

4 In some cities, high-value properties appear to be
targeted for higher-than-average assessment ratios. But
Philadelphia and Baltimore have been singled out by
two separate studies as cities which impose noticeably
higher assessment ratios on properties of lower value
and properties in blighted or declining neighborhoods.
See George Peterson, ed., P roperty T ax R eform (Wash­
ington: The Urban Institute, 1973), pp. 29-31, 110-111.




14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

ASSESSMENT RATIOS DIFFER
AMONG PHILADELPHIA
NEIGHBORHOODS




Ratio of Assessed Value to Sales Price
(aggregate ratio by ward, 1975).
below 40%
40% to 50%
above 50%
SOURCE: City of Philadelphia, Office of the
Controller, R eal Estate Tax, August 31,1976,
Exhibit III.

15

MAY/JUNE 1978

BUSINESS REVIEW

effective rates, even though the same millage
rate shows up on their tax bills (see MILLAGE
VERSU S EFFECTIVE RATE).

for city wards, however, ranged from 29
percent to 66 percent. Based on these figures,
it appears that wards with assessment ratios
higher than the official target of 50 percent
are located mainly in the predominantly
black neighborhoods of North and West
Philadelphia, which have low and declining
property values. Further, the wards with
below-average assessments appear to be
clustered in the growing Northeast and the
stable neighborhoods of Northwest and South
Philadelphia. Independent research on assess­
ment inequality in Philadelphia shows similar
results. 5
Not all differences in official assessment
ratios impose uneven burdens on taxpayers.
The fact, for example, that the Philadelphia
assessor aims for a 50-percent assessment
ratio while the assessor in neighboring
Montgomery County strives for a 17-percent
ratio is not necessarily evidence of nonuni­
formity. As long as all property owners in a
taxing jurisdiction are assessed in the same
way, they all will be paying taxes in propor­
tion to market value.6 But when properties
within the same taxing jurisdiction are as­
sessed at different fractions of their market
value, then they are subject to different

MILLAGE VERSUS
EFFECTIVE RATE
In comparing property tax burdens, many
taxpayers think first of the millage rate—the
amount levied per thousand dollars of a prop­
erty’s assessed value. If every property were
assessed at its full market value, the millage
would tell the whole story. But although most
states require full-value assessment, many
taxing jurisdictions actually use a certain
percentage of full value for computing tax
bills. With different assessment ratios, the
same millage rates may translate into widely
disparate tax bills. Thus if two houses with
market values of $50,000 both are situated in
districts that tax at 20 mills but one is
assessed at full value while the other is
assessed at 50 percent, their annual tax
bills—at $1,000 and $500 respectively—will
differ by $500. So to get a standard for
comparison, the right thing to do is to divide
the market value into the total tax bill. This
gives the effective tax rate. In the example,
these rates are 2 percent and 1 percent.
Looking at official millage rates alone would
not have revealed this difference in tax bur­
dens.

5 A detailed analysis of assessment inequality in
Philadelphia found strong statistical evidence that
assessment ratios tend to be larger for lower value
houses than for higher value ones and higher for houses
located in black and low-income neighborhoods than
elsewhere in the city. See Robert H. Edelstein, “The
Equity of the Real Estate Property Tax: An Empirical
Examination of the City of Philadelphia” (Philadelphia:
Rodney L. White Center for Financial Research, The
Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1976).

Where do differences in assessment ratios
come from? Some are traceable to the inade­
quacy of current assessment systems to
standardized measure of taxable property value. Market
value per pupil (in Pennsylvania) or equalized assessed
value per pupil (in New Jersey) is used in the formula
which determines the amount of state aid to local school
districts. New Jersey also uses this assessment ratio in
the formula which allocates property tax relief to
individual property owners from state income tax
revenues. In the homestead exemption formula, the
assessment or equalization ratio is used to convert the
assessed value of an individual residence into an equalized
house value (similar to market value) and the millage
rate into an equalized (or effective) tax rate. If state aid
were distributed on the basis of unadjusted measures,
more aid would go to school districts and property
owners in places with lower-than-average assessment
ratios than would be justified by a standardized compar­
ison.

6 But local variations in assessment ratios would
interfere with efforts to levy a uniform countywide or
statewide property tax. And discrepancies in assessment
ratios across cities and school districts have complicated
the task of constructing state revenue-sharing formulas
based on local property tax effort or property wealth
factors. Pennsylvania and New Jersey, along with many
other states outside the Third District, calculate assessment-to-sales ratios for all jurisdictions in the state on
the basis of individual property transactions and assess­
ment records. The state estimated assessment ratio is
used to convert locally reported assessed value into a




16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

their equity and efficiency preferences. One
important weakness is in property appraisal,
including the initial appraisal of the parcel
and its subsequent reappraisal in light of real
estate market trends and physical condition.
Poor appraisal and infrequent reassessment
are serious impediments to uniformity in
assessment (see APPRAISING MARKET
VALUE).

appraise property accurately and to keep up
with changing patterns of market value. And
some reflect policy decisions to tax certain
kinds of property more heavily than others.
One Cause: Assessment Procedures.
While discretionary policies reflect the col­
lective wisdom of the voters, procedural
defects result in unwanted distortions of

APPRAISING MARKET VALUE
Appraising property accurately requires a great deal of informed professional judgment. The
local or county assessor frequently calls upon more than one of the following popular appraisal
methods for assistance in estimating a property’s fair market value.
The simplest method of appraising the market value of a property is to use its most recent selling
price as a guide. But the assessor must be alert to conditions that may make the selling price an
inaccurate indicator of fair market value. For example, the assessor may have to adjust the observed
selling price to reflect what price the property would bring in an arm’s length transaction rather than
an exchange on especially favorable terms such as a sale between relatives or business partners or a
forced liquidation. He may have to discount the selling price to allow for the inclusion of personal
property such as residential appliances or business equipment in the transaction. Or he may need to
increase the selling price to correct for special financing arrangements, such as the assumption of a
mortgage.
Estimating the value of a property which has not sold recently is accomplished most easily via
market comparison. The assessor can take an observed selling price as a standard and estimate the
market value of similar properties by adjusting the price upward to reflect, say, the presence of an
extra bedroom or bathroom or downward to reflect a deteriorated physical condition or a smallerthan-average lot.
The task of assigning a fair market value is more complicated for unusual properties or those that
change hands infrequently. Mansions, apartment houses, industrial plants, and office buildings all
are likely to possess the troublesome characteristics of being unique and seldom sold. Appraisers
rely on two main techniques for setting a value on such properties. One, known as the incomemultiplier approach, converts the rental income generated by a property (net of operating expenses)
into an estimated market value for the property. The net property income is multiplied by a factor
which is based on the capitalization rate. The other approach estimates the replacem ent cost of a
property by using tables of building costs plus an estimate of land value.
The income-multiplier and replacement-cost approaches have difficulty accounting for physical
depreciation and calculating the impact of changes in demand or supply on the price of property.
Further, the capitalization and cost factors used in these methods can become outdated quickly in an
inflationary environment. Still, the replacement-cost approach is the basic technique used by the
private mass appraisal firms which are hired by small assessment jurisdictions to conduct
reappraisals. Evidence of the inadequacy of the estimates made by these firms in the past has
focused attention on the need for local assessors to validate the property value estimates made by
mass appraisal firms and even for the states to regulate and certify those firms.*
* New Jersey has established procedures whereby the Director of the State Division of Taxation sets standards
and qualifications for private appraisal firms and must approve all contracts for reappraisals made with such
firms by local assessors. The state also must certify all local assessors.
Pennsylvania’s State Tax Equalization Board (STEB) currently is prohibited from monitoring county real
estate assessments. Legislation is being considered, however, which would permit STEB to provide technical
assistance to local assessors and to set uniformity standards for public assessments and private appraisals.




17

MAY/JUNE 1978

BUSINESS REVIEW

Two trends have made the already difficult
task of achieving accurate appraisals and
equal assessment ratios even harder. One is
the overall inflation in the real estate market.
The other is the tendency of some property
values, most notably in certain central city
neighborhoods, to rise less rapidly than
others—or even to decline.
As inflation in property values during the
1970s has far outrun increases in assessed
valuation, average assessment ratios have
declined. Even when all property values are
rising at the same rate, more recently reas­
sessed properties tend to have higher assessedto-market-value ratios and higher effective
tax rates. This inequality is compounded
when some properties increase in value more
rapidly than others. With infrequent reas­
sessments (or an unwillingness to reassess
downward), average assessment ratios in
declining neighborhoods tend to rise in
comparison to those in the rest of the juris­
diction.
Nonuniform assessment patterns are found
not only in homogeneous jurisdictions but
also in counties that cover both urban and
suburban districts. Such nonuniformity has
been alleged in a class action suit against the
Board of Assessment Appeals in Berks
County, Pennsylvania. Homeowners in a
predominantly nonwhite neighborhood of
the old central city of Reading charge that
they are being discriminated against because
their assessment ratios are higher than those
for properties located in the predominantly
white areas of the county. The suit claims
that, because the Board does not reassess all
properties in the county annually, current
assessments fail to reflect the decline in
property values in the nonwhite areas of the
county and the increase in values in the
white neighborhoods.7
Thus much of the observed difference in
assessment ratios stems from inadequacies
in the assessment system which keep it from

responding to changes in market value. In
essence, procedural defects are inadvertently—
and unnecessarily—distorting the allocation
of the property tax burden.
Another Cause: Preferential Tax Treat­
ment. Some nonuniformity in assessment
ratios, however, is a direct reflection of
society’s preferences. There are many who,
though they favor uniformity in principle,
would permit some nonuniformity in order
to achieve certain outcomes—for example,
preserving open space or providing financial
relief to senior citizens. But to those who
favor strict application of the uniformity
principle, it isn’t clear that these aims are
best achieved by a system of tax preferences.
Cases of preferential tax treatment are
common, and they often correspond to pat­
terns of property ownership or property use.
One such tax preference is the exemption for
agricultural land and open space. It has been
argued that taxing open space or farm land at
the full value of its most productive alter­
native use would force current owners to sell
or develop the land in order to generate
sufficient income to pay the tax. This argu­
ment has been used successfully in many
areas of the country, and now 37 states have
established property tax relief provisions for
undeveloped land.
Exem ptions for elderly and low -in com e
homeowners have been defended by similar
arguments. People are likely to have purchased
property in the past on the assumption that
their property taxes, like their mortgage
payments, would remain stable. With rapidly
rising real estate values and the growth of
public service costs, this expectation has
been disappointed. And proponents of
exemptions argue that homeowners whose
incomes now are low or fixed shouldn’t be
pressured into selling their property as they
might be if it were taxed at its market value.
Both the open space exemption and the
homeowner exemption act as tax shelters for
capital gains produced by increases in the
value of property. The upshot is that the

7 Garrett v. Bamford 538 F.2d 63 (3rd Cir. 1976].




18

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

less highly taxed property a higher price),
most of the subsidy effect of exemptions may
be lost as property values are bid up in
response to favorable tax treatment.9 Also,
because the property tax abatement represents
only a small part of the total costs of a
project, the tax concession may not have
much influence at all on private investment
decisions. If property tax abatement pro­
grams in fact do little to encourage economic
development, they may turn out to be a net
drain on the public treasury, according to
opponents of this approach.
Another variety of preferential treatment
—one alternative to direct regulation of land
use—is the graded tax, which is designed to
favor certain forms of land development.
Most jurisdictions levy the same property
tax rate on the assessed value of both land
and improvements. Taxing them at different
rates can affect the patterns of development
by altering the incentives for investment.
Raising or lowering the tax rate on im­
provements can influence not only the total
price to the buyer, because of tax capital­
ization, but also the supply of improvements.
If the tax on improvements is relatively low,
for example, more improvements will be
built and higher density construction will be

costs associated with land or housing may
not be borne fully by the owners. Thus
opponents of exemptions have argued that
individuals who can’t afford the liabilities on
their property may need to admit that they
are overhoused or that their property invest­
ments aren’t paying their keep. If society’s
aim is to help property owners maintain their
holdings, they say, then methods other than
tax exemptions may be preferable. Resolving
the debate in a rational way requires an
appreciation of the costs and benefits of
these other methods, such as land use regula­
tion and direct subsidies to the poor and
elderly. But more needs to be known about
the costs and benefits of these other methods.
Exemptions have been extended to busi­
nesses as well as to individuals. Communities
that are trying to attract nonresidential prop­
erty users sometimes offer assessment
exemptions as a form of economic d ev elop ­
m ent subsidy. They may use tax abatements
running for as long as ten years to encourage
the rehabilitation and redevelopment of
deteriorated neighborhoods. The city of
Wilmington, Delaware, for example, offers
abatements both for new construction and
for improvements to existing buildings. These
policies apply to residential, industrial, and
commercial development anywhere within
the city limits. And a 1971 Pennsylvania law
permits local jurisdictions to enact exemptions
for increases in assessed value which are
attributable to improvements made on resi­
dential property in deteriorated neighbor­
hoods. 8
This subsidy technique reflects the belief
that the tax revenue forgone in the short run,
and the attendant public service costs imposed
by the new occupants, will be more than
offset in the long run by revenue from higher
property values and a broadened income tax
base. Some have argued, however, that
because of tax capitalization (a more highly
taxed property brings a lower price, and a

9
Buying a property is buying a tax bill. The prospec­
tive buyer who has to look forward to a higher tax bill
won’t be willing to pay as high a purchase price for a
given property. And the savings associated with a lower
tax bill will tend to be capitalized into a higher purchase
price.
The assumption that tax differences are capitalized
has been used to argue against an abrupt change to
uniform assessment: the argument goes that such a
change is unnecessary on equity grounds, since the
combination of tax and purchase price balances out for
everybody. It’s not clear, however, that full capitalization
ever occurs. The evidence suggests that differences in
average effective tax rates from one jurisdiction to
another are capitalized into property values—for
example, in neighboring suburban jurisdictions. But
little evidence is available that different assessment
ratios within a single jurisdiction produce such capital­
ization. Thus the tax-capitalization argument against
uniform assessment doesn’t appear to hold for the city
situation.

8 72 P. S. § § 4711 to 4716.




19

MAY/JUNE 1978

BUSINESS REVIEW

quacies of the appraisal system, procedural
changes are in order. Increased pressure
from citizens outraged by their higher-thanaverage assessments has resulted in the de­
mands of many states to have equalized, if
not full-value, assessment for all property.
Some states have insisted on annual reassess­
ments, and some state legislatures are en­
dorsing state supervision of assessment
practices through personnel training and
procedural guidelines.
Computer technology combined with sta­
tistical analysis has proven to be a valuable
assessor’s tool. It offers the property appraiser
greater accuracy, standardization, and speed
than can be achieved when assessments are
done by hand. Automated mass appraisal
using advanced statistical techniques has
been applied with notable success in several
California counties. The greatest break­
throughs in computerized assessments have
been made with single-family dwellings,
which represent the largest part of most
assessors’ loads. But recently, progress has
been made in applying computer techniques
to the appraisal of apartment properties as
well. In three Pennsylvania counties—
Montgomery, Centre, and Union—the com­
puter help's the assessor appraise a house’s
current value by comparing it to similar
houses that recently have changed hands
(see COMPUTER AIDED A SSESSM EN T).
The laws of many states require property
appraisals and assessments to be updated
annually. But this annual reassessment pro­
vision has been enforced only rarely because,
under traditional assessment procedures, the
cost of conducting an annual reassessment
would have been prohibitive, especially in
large jurisdictions.
Even with computerized mass appraisal
techniques, which have increased the feasi­
bility of conducting annual reassessment,
assessors’ budgets are unlikely to grow enough
to support an annual on-site reappraisal of
every property in their jurisdictions. An
assessor with limited resources thus may
wish to consider whether more uniformity

encouraged. But if the improvements tax is
relatively high, owners will be discouraged
from developing or redeveloping their land.
Changing the tax rate on land can’t have any
effect on its supply, but, through tax capital­
ization, it certainly can cause a change in its
price. The old Pennsylvania cities of Harris­
burg, Pittsburgh, and Scranton have enacted
a graded tax in an effort to spur both construc­
tion of new buildings and rehabilitation of
older structures. 10
In summary, these preferential tax tech­
niques—exemptions, subsidies, and graded
levies—can provide tax relief in certain cases
and can encourage voter-favored land uses.
Some students of public finance argue, how­
ever, that there may be more effective ways
to achieve these aims without sacrificing the
principle of uniformity.
ACHIEVING
MORE UNIFORM ASSESSMENT
Settling on policies to reverse established
assessment practices is no simple task. Any
attempt to make assessment procedures more
accurate and responsive won’t be easy or
inexpensive. And any attempt to eliminate
exemptions and other forms of preferential
tax treatment will touch on the economic
interests of many concerned groups.
Introducing Computer Aided A ssess­
ment Procedures. Where variations in assess­
ment ratios are traceable primarily to inade-

Pennsylvania’s third-class cities may set different
tax rates for land and buildings as long as the rate is
uniform within each classification. Pittsburgh and
Scranton limit the city tax on buildings to one-half the
rate on land. Thus in 1976, Pittsburgh levied a 49.5-mill
tax on land but only a 24.75-mill tax on buildings; in
Scranton the rates were 42 mills on land and 21 mills on
improvements. Harrisburg taxed land at 23 mills and
improvements at 17 mills. The Pennsylvania legislature
is considering making the graded tax a local option for
all jurisdictions. See Carrie Vang, L o ca l T ax M anual
(Harrisburg: Pennsylvania League of Cities, 1977), p.5;
and Pennsylvania Senate Bills 1014 through 1020
(Session of 1977).




20

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

COMPUTER AIDED ASSESSM ENT
The application of computers to property assessment has been based on the market comparison
approach to appraisal. A property is viewed as possessing a set of characteristics, each of which has
a market price. The value of an individual house, for example, is estimated by adjusting the value of
the average house in a neighborhood upward or downward according to the presence or absence of
certain features. If most houses in the neighborhood have three bedrooms, two baths, a 50 by 100
foot lot, were built in 1955, and on average sell for $35,000, for example, having one less bedroom
might reduce the value by $3,000, and having a third bath might raise it by $1,500.
Using a partially computerized approach known as the sort system, the assessor in Pennsylvania’s
Montgomery County describes the basic neighborhood location and structural characteristics of the
property in question to the computer. The sort system makes use of the computer’s ability to glance
rapidly through the computerized records of all parcels in the assessing jurisdiction in order to select
a sample of comparable properties which have sold recently. Using observed selling prices as a
guideline, the assessor judgmentally estimates the market value of each property by adjusting the
average selling price of a house of that type upward to reflect extras in the property in question or
downward to reflect the absence of common features.
In the sort system, the value assigned to these optional house features may be estimated on the
basis of the assessor’s experience. In a more fully computerized system known as multiple
regression analysis, the computer estimates values for these factors by comparing statistically the
recent selling prices and associated features of many similar properties. By pooling information on a
large number of transactions, multiple regression analysis is able to make an accurate estimate of
the average impact on the price of a house that the presence of a certain feature is expected to have.
Then, by adding up these calculated values for a property’s characteristics, the computer
automatically generates an estimate of the current market value of a house. Later, the assessor can
alter the computer-generated appraisal for an individual property if an on-site inspection or
additional information so indicates.
Pennsylvania’s Centre County and Union County use a simplified multiple regression system in
their residential appraisal process. Using information about houses which have sold recently, the
computer estimates a market value per square foot of house based on such considerations as age,
number of stories, presence of a garage, and neighborhood location. This square foot multiplier is
used to estimate the current market value of comparable houses which have not changed hands.

for the assessment dollar can be obtained by
concentrating efforts on certain neighborhoods
or land uses. The results of assessment ratio
studies can be used to pinpoint the places
that exhibit the greatest divergence from the
average assessment ratio (see Appendix).
Some assessment districts may be too
small to make economical use of computer
technology on their own. These jurisdictions
might consider joining together with others
to support a modernized system or might tap
the technical expertise available at the state




tax equalization board or revenue department.
Sharing appraisal expertise could prove
especially helpful in cases of nonresidential
properties, which don’t lend themselves easily
to standardized mass appraisal techniques.
To the extent that the property tax burden
is distributed inequitably and inefficiently as
a result of appraisal techniques, procedural
improvements can and should be made.
Technically induced nonuniformity does not
reflect voter preferences; rather it reflects a
need for improved assessment methods.
21

BUSINESS REVIEW

MAY/JUNE 1978

move would have to be accompanied by new
programs, on the assumption that society
wishes to continue to assist some of the
people who would lose the tax benefits
afforded by open space exemptions, senior
citizen exemptions, and the like. Thus while
there are gains to be made through uniformity,
there may be costs as well.

Reconsidering Preferential Tax Treat­
ment. There’s a saying that old laws are good
laws. The reasoning behind this maxim is
that people and institutions adjust over time
to the quirks of the law and that any attempt
to iron these quirks out may cause more
hardship than leaving them alone.
Still, many tax experts believe that the
system of tax preferences has grown so
complex and burdensome that at last it must
be realigned. And they see fundamental
efficiency and equity advantages in unifor­
mity. Proponents of Federal income tax
reform have argued, for example, that cur­
tailing exemptions would broaden the tax
base so that the same amount of revenue
could be collected at a lower average tax
rate. They see the net outcome of greater
uniformity as tax relief all around. The same
argument can be made for the property tax—
the greater uniformity that would come from
reducing exemptions would bring general
tax relief.
If enough people decide that they want an
end to tax preferences, uniformity will be
imposed through legislation and regulation.
But just shifting from tax preferences to
uniformity—the mere shift itself—could be a
costly and dislocating venture; and any such

SUMMING UP
The local property tax has been attacked
on many grounds. Critics have called for
fundamental changes in the tax and even for
its abolition. But the property tax remains
the single largest local revenue source for
municipalities and school districts, and it’s
likely to be around for a long time to come.
Thus there may be much to be gained from
making this system as fair and efficient as
possible.
Technological developments have made
regular and frequent assessment a live option
for tax reformers right now. The costs and
benefits already are well known. But the
issue of preferential tax treatment calls for
further examination. Eliminating tax prefer­
ences would bring uniformity nearer, but
whether the benefits would outweigh the
cost remains to be determined.

SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER READING
For a concise introduction to current issues in property tax analysis see Henry J. Aaron, Who Pays
the Property Tax? A N ew View (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1975).
Jerome Dasso’s Computerized Assessment Administration (Chicago: International Association of
Assessing Officers, 1974) is a manager’s guide to computer aided assessments. The technical details
of computerized assessment systems are treated by Albert M. Church and Robert H. Gustafson in
their Statistics and Computers in the Appraisal Process (Chicago: International Association of
Assessing Officers, 1976).
The A ssessor’s H andbook published by the State of Pennsylvania’s Department of Community
Affairs (Harrisburg: 1977) lays out the responsibilities of assessors in Pennsylvania as well as the
standard methods of appraisal and assessment. For a detailed discussion of uniformity measures see
Analyzing Assessment Equity: Techniques for Measuring and Improving the Quality o f Property Tax
Administration (Chicago: International Association of Assessing Officers, 1976).
For a summary of assessment procedures in individual states see The Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations, The Property Tax in a Changing Environment: An Information Report
(Washington: ACIR, 1974).




22

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

APPENDIX
MEASURING ASSESSMENT UNIFORMITY
A statistic commonly used to measure the relative uniformity of assessment ratios is the
coefficient of dispersion (coefficient of deviation). This number expresses the average deviation
from the median (mean) assessment ratio as a fraction of the median (mean) ratio for that sample of
properties. As an illustration, for the five properties listed in the example below, the median
assessment ratio is 0.50 and the coefficient of dispersion is 0.24. Thus in this sample, the average
deviation from the median assessment ratio is 24 percent.
There is no universal standard for measuring the quality of assessment practices. Some assessors
may be faced with conditions, such as dissimilarity in the properties to be assessed and rapidly
changing market values, that make their task unusually difficult. As a rule of thumb for manual
appraisal systems, however, a coefficient of dispersion of 20 has been considered a mark of
acceptable assessment performance, while a coefficient of 10 or below has been viewed as a mark of
excellence. With the application of computerized appraisal using multiple regression analysis,
coefficients of dispersion of 5 or less have been obtained. Only computerized assessments, then,
seem to be approaching the degree of uniformity that would be expected in income tax and sales tax
administration, for example.
A 1971 survey by the U. S. Census of Governments indicates that among the three Third District
states only New Jersey achieved a degree of assessment uniformity higher than the national average.
Eighty percent of the New Jersey areas sampled had coefficients of dispersion less than 20—
compared with 49 percent for the U. S. as a whole. Only 21 percent of the Pennsylvania areas and
none of those in Delaware had coefficients of dispersion under 20. In fact, a fifth of the areas
sampled in Pennsylvania, and a third of those in Delaware, had coefficients of dispersion of 40
percent or more. This compares with none for New Jersey and 9 percent for the U. S. as a whole.

TO CALCULATE THE COEFFICIENT OF DISPERSION
IN A SAMPLE OF PROPERTIES . . .
1.
2.

Compute the assessed-to-market-value ratio.
Find the absolute difference of each ratio from the median.

Assessed Value
(dollars)
16,500
19,000
20,000
29,250
28,000

3.
4.
5.

Market Value = Assessed-to-Market-Value
(dollars)
Ratio (percent)
22,000
27,000
40,000
65,000
70,000

75
70
50 (median)
45
40

Absolute Difference
of Assessed-to-Market-Value
Ratios from Median Ratio
(percent)
25
20
0
5
10

Sum the absolute differences (25 + 20 + 0 + 5 + 10 = 60).
Divide the sum of differences (60) by the number of properties in the sample (5) to get the
average difference (12).
Divide the average difference (12) by the median ratio (50) to get the coefficient of
dispersion (24 percent).




23

on Independence Mall
100 North Sixth Street
Philadelphia, Pa. 19106