View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

S up plem en t

Perspective on interest nates
and
international Monetary Reform
B y J. D e w e y D a a n e
M e m b e r, B o a rd o f G o v e rn o r s o f th e F e d e ra l R e s e r v e S y s te m




Federal R eserve B ank of Ph ilad elp h ia

May, 1967




PERSPECTIVE ON INTEREST RATES AND
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REFORM
By J. Dewey Daane
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

(EDITOR’S NOTE: Mr. J. Dewey Daane, member of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System addressed the Municipal Bond Club of Philadelphia on Wednesday, May 3, 1967. In response
to numerous requests, his remarks are being reproduced in this special supplement.)
I am very pleased to have the opportunity to
address this distinguished group, including many
of my good friends and mentors, like Karl Bopp
and George Kneass, with whom I have been
associated for many years.
Although George Kneass, along with your
President “ Jack” Dempsey, twisted my arm to
make some comments on interest rates as well as
on international monetary reform, I am sure none
of us realized that I would be speaking at a time
when the books were still open on a Treasury
financing and also, of particular importance to
this group, bidding in process for the Common­
wealth of Pennsylvania Turnpike bonds. Thus
I do wish to emphasize at the outset that I am
not, and I hope understandably so, not going to
forecast— or even attempt to—the future of inter­
est rates, or the future of Federal Reserve policy.
Nor will I be releasing these remarks publicly at
this point, not because I will be saying anything
either startling or super secret, about either
domestic or international developments, but
simply because, as all of you know, when a
Treasury financing is in process the Federal
Reserve normally follows what is euphemistically




called an “ even keel” policy. And in my opinion,
“ even keel” might well be redefined to include no
public speeches by Federal Reserve Board Gov­
ernors! The market deserves at least that much
surcease from the flow of words!
I do, however, want to begin by making a few
observations as to the economics of interest rates.
Art Okun, one of the members of the President’s
Council of Economic Advisers, sometimes says
that what we are, or should be, concerned with is
not “ old” economics or “ new” economics but
“ good” economics. And today I thought I might
take this opportunity to outline what I consider
to he “ good” economics regarding interest rates.
First of all, interest rates do not have a sepa­
rate, autonomous, identity apart from the avail­
ability of funds and the demands upon that
availability. The idea that interest rates can be
varied by voice or fiat, in contradiction to under­
lying market forces, ignores this very funda­
mental fact that interest rates are not independent
of, but tied integrally to, the supply and demand
for funds. To complain that there must be a
better way of allocating funds than via interest
rates simply means that one wishes to substitute
3

arbitrary judgments and a controlled rationing
process for market forces. This is surely some­
thing I would not want to see and I am sure you
would not either. The implications of this point
in the recent and current setting are, I hope,
clear; it is not only preferable but clearly more
realistic to rely on competitive market forces to
adjust interest rates—within the framework of
reserve availability—rather than to attempt to
adjust rates through concerted changes in ceil­
ings by regulatory authorities.
Second, and related to this, the Federal Reserve
is not the primary determinant of interest rates,
either in terms of rate levels or changes in rates.
It is true that Federal Reserve policy affects
interest rates (among other things) but—and
this is an important qualification that frequently
is overlooked—the range within which the Sys­
tem can influence interest rates as part of a policy
of promoting sustainable economic growth is
very much determined by the basic economic
environment, by expectations regarding the out­
look for that environment, and by the actual
supplies and demands for funds that reflect both
the environment and its prospects. The System
can only add or subtract a marginal, albeit impor­
tant, fraction to the basic equation.
To be sure, since the System is inevitably
always a part of the demand and supply, we must
always be conscious of, and have some concept
of, where the initial impact of our actions supply­
ing or subtracting reserves may impinge. For
example, there may be times when, in the light of
continuing balance of payments strains alongside
inadequate domestic economic growth, it is advis­
able to tailor System reserve supplying operations
in such a way as to minimize downward pres­
sures on short term rates.
A practical illustration of the point I have
been making—that interest rates are basically
determined by market forces and cannot be
determined by fiat or legislation—is suggested by
4




some of the disparate rate movements that have
occurred in recent weeks. As you all know, the
System began easing policy last fall and has con­
tinued on an “ ease” course ever since—most
recently reaffirmed by the discount rate reduction
of a few weeks ago. There has been no change in
our policy objectives of combatting weakening
tendencies in the economy, or promoting renewed
expansion, to the extent a monetary policy of
ease can do so. Despite continuance of this policy
of ease, however, and its reflection in greater
reserve availability and rapid credit expansion,
some interest rates have once again firmed
markedly and widely differing patterns of rate
behavior have emerged in specific sectors of the
market.
To recall, quickly, recent rate developments
with which you are all familiar, yields on some
new and recently offered corporate and municipal
bonds have advanced as much as 30 basis points
in the past few weeks, reflecting a rash of syndi­
cate terminations, the generally slow reception
accorded many recent new issues even at currently
higher yields, the still congested state of under­
writers’ inventories, and the heavy volume of
offerings still to come on the forward calendar.
To illustrate, reoffering yields on new AA-rated
electric utility bonds with five-year call protection
have advanced to a new 1967 high of 5.60 per
cent. This is 22 basis points above the end of
March level, and some 55 basis points above the
low reached at the end of January. This rise from
the 1967 low has erased more than half of the
earlier overall decline from the 1966 high of
6.05 per cent reached at the peak of market
tensions last August.
The sharpness of this recent advance in bond
yields has reflected the interaction of several
major influences:
At the beginning of April underwriters of
both corporate and municipal securities held
substantial unsold balances of recently offered

new issues which they had taken on at declining
interest rates in the expectation of being able to
resell to investors at still lower rates—following
the anticipated cut in the discount rate, and after
some expected moderation in new issue volume
from the hectic March pace.
Following the discount rate cut in early April,
however, these earlier expectations of further
interest rate declines began to be called in ques­
tion. Market opinions on the business outlook for
the second half of the year were suddenly
strengthened by the unexpectedly favorable busi­
ness news, and by the reports of likely further
escalation of the war in Vietnam. At the same
time, large further additions to the new issue
calendar— in both the corporate and municipal
markets—made it look as if there would be no
significant respite from business and state and
local government demands on capital markets—
at least through the second quarter.
Given these changed conditions, underwriters
terminated syndicates and sought to liquidate
their holdings of older issues in order to be in a
position to participate in new offerings at higher
rates. But shifting expectations on the business
and interest rate outlook, the heavy volume of
current security offerings, and further additions
to the forward calendar of future offerings all
continued to maintain upward pressures on rates.
Thus, despite their efforts to trim inventories,
underwriters have continued to end up with size­
able holdings—particularly in the municipal
market where inventories are in near record
volume.
The particular catalyst that has triggered this
mix of influences is, of course, the growing expec­
tations that business is strengthening, and the
resultant view that the cyclical down-swing in
long-term rates may have ended. In these circum­
stances investors have become reluctant buyers,
waiting to see if the heavy forward supply will
force rates higher; underwriters have pressed to




try to liquidate positions; and some borrowers
in both corporate and municipal markets have
apparently accelerated their borrowing plans in
an effort to satisfy their needs before an antici­
pated further change in market conditions.
Speaking more generally, we now seem to be
living through a period of a whole sequence of
reactions to the strains of last summer, strains
from which you as market participants and we as
monetary authorities have, I hope, learned a num­
ber of lessons. And one reflection is evident in
the emphasis placed on restoring liquidity as the
first, and quite natural, reaction to the easier
availability of money against the background of
last year’s developments. For example, this is
evident in the changed behavior of bank
demand, in turn in part reflecting unwillingness
to seek larger inflows of CD money. Thus, de­
spite the substantial shift in Federal Reserve
posture—as noted in the shift from average net
borrowed reserves of $430 million last October
to a recent average of well above $200 million
free reserves— active bidding for shorter term
Treasury bills and shorter term municipals has
contrasted with conditions in the long-term
markets which at times have been characterized
as “ nothing” markets.
Thus, while the disparate rate movements re­
main an interest phenomenon, they are an under­
standable by-product of the concern that devel­
oped, and of the shift in expectations, which has
meant a differing pattern of rate changes as
between short and long term securities. As I said
at the outset, I am not trying to offer a full blown
theoretical or practical explanation so as to
pretend to identify and predict the course of
interest rates, but simply to highlight that current
developments serve once again to underscore the
truism that the market is bigger than any of us
and that market expectations and related actions
are, more often than not, all important.
What has occurred represents, in part, the
5

element of reaction to expectations, expectations
that, in my judgment, are unfounded at least in
the sense that the one thing of which I am sure is
that events never repeat themselves in precisely
the same way. But just as significant as the expectational catalyst, however, and not unrelated to
it, has been the actual supply of securities offered
in the various markets. In the market for new
publicly offered corporate bonds it now looks as
if the April calendar will aggregate in excess of
$1.3 billion, which compares with the $1.7 billion
March record. The May calendar already exceeds
$1 billion and some think it may ultimately rise
to $1.5 billion. Similarly, with the June calendar
of scheduled offerings already at $800 million, it
too may ultimately exceed $1 billion. In short,
gross public offerings of corporate bonds for the
first half of 1967 may total nearly $7 billion,
compared with gross offerings of $8 billion in the
entire year 1966. As to new State and local gov­
ernment bonds, offerings in April are estimated
to have exceeded $1 billion for the fourth con­
secutive month. And, as you know all too well,
gross municipal offerings through the end of
April are estimated at $4.7 billion, 15 per cent
larger than in the like period a year ago.
This recital of details as to public offerings is
not intended to sound alarmist over either recent
or prospective resultant rate developments. One
partial offset to the enlarged flow of public offer­
ings has been a drop in private placements. In the
first half of the year these may run around % to
% of a billion dollars below the first half of
1966. And the unprecedented concentration of
public offerings in the first half—not unrelated
either to the repayment of bank debt (reportedly
accounting for over 40 per cent of first quarter
offerings) or to the build-up of liquid asset
positions—suggest a tapering off in corporate
issues of this type sometime later in the year. But
my point here is a simple one, namely that it is
the underlying market forces, including both
6




environment and expectations, that have ac­
counted for these most recent rate developments.
Such underlying forces are real, not illusory,
and if at times the market temporarily overdoes
its adjustment to such pressures, in the long run
they must be adapted to if markets are to remain
free and competitive.
Not so simple at the moment is the picture with
respect to the relationship of the various credit
markets. A major complicating factor in the
analysis of recent credit developments is the
marked change in the role played by banks. In
a sense, it appears as if banks, in a dramatic
about face from their 1961-65 practice, recently
have been borrowing long and lending short. On
the lending side, despite rapid overall credit ex­
pansion, there has been, after adjustment for nor­
mally large tax payments, a reduced rate of growth
in business loans in 1967. Banks obviously have
been engaged in restoring portfolio liquidity, as
reflected in the large increase in security holdings
—about $9 billion—in the last five months. As to
sources of funds, total time and savings deposits
at banks rose sharply from last fall and were the
major source of funds used to rebuild liquidity.
The increase was particularly rapid until midFebruary, with over one-half of the increase
coming from large denomination negotiable CD’s.
Since February, however, both CD and total time
and savings inflows have moderated; all of the
growth in CD’s in this latter period appears to
have occurred at banks outside New York City.
This slower growth in CD’s at the larger banks
reflects, it seems to me, two main factors. First,
the continued increase in time deposits other
than negotiable CD’s and the turnaround in
savings deposits have served to maintain a rapid
inflow of funds without the use of large CD’s.
Second, with loan demands requiring a smaller
share of deposit growth, with security portfolios
rising, and with declining market yields on the
short-term assets banks were acquiring, the need

and desire to seek large CD’s aggressively has
tended to wane at most banks. Thus, in the last
two months or so, banks lowered their marketable
CD rates sharply, to levels that reduced appreci­
ably the level of CD yields relative to competing
financial assets—including the CD yield in the
secondary market. With rates at levels indicating
that banks clearly were no longer anxious to
attract large CD’s, outstandings rose by only
$800 million from mid-February to the end of
March. Over the first three weeks of April—with
CD offering rates 10 to 30 basis points below
secondary market yields on CD’s—outstandings
declined by almost $600 million—almost threefourths of which occurred over the tax week. Last
week, offering rates were generally unchanged
and outstandings at banks in New York declined
an additional $27 million. And despite the reduc­
tion in outstanding CD’s, New York banks, on
balance, continued to repay Euro-dollars in April.
This reference to Euro-dollars leads me to com­
ment that, just as in the case of the domestic
sphere, international rate relationships also
primarily reflect changes in basic environmental
economic conditions and expectations along with
monetary policy moves, and these relationships
correspondingly shift with these internal devel­
opments in individual countries. All of this is by
way of saying that the spread of downward
central bank rate adjustments since January was
a to-be-expected response to the changing avail­
ability and demands for funds already in process
before last year end, as many European econo­
mies also began to experience a slowdown in
economic activity. The resultant international
flows of funds, reflecting the variety of changes in
availability and rates here and abroad is, I be­
lieve, well known. Looking back, most marked
was last year’s inflow into the United States of
around $ 2 ^ billion from foreign branches of
U.S. banks—leading in turn to a small surplus in
our balance of payments on an official settle­




ments basis for the year 1966. Before year end
1966 we began to see those funds flow out again
—perhaps to the extent of nearly $1 billion by
early February. Following two months of little
or no movement, in April there was a moderate
outflow again. All of this would indicate that the
published statistic for the U.S. balance of pay­
ments deficit on an official settlements basis
could hardly be expected to look very favorable
in the first quarter or first half of 1967. As to our
other principal payments balance measure—the
overall liquidity basis—it is more difficult to sort
out and anticipate possible results. One can, how­
ever, suggest that it is a matter of striking a bal­
ance between offsetting developments on current
and capital account. Trade developments thus far
this year point to an encouragingly larger trade
surplus. On the other hand, some deterioration is
expected in military expenditures and in the net
capital outflow.
The balance of payments problem—however it
may turn out to appear statistically in the first
quarter—remains a serious one. And here I would
like to clear up any remaining confusion as to
the relationship of our balance of payments
problem to our current efforts to bring the search
for an international money to supplement gold
and dollars to a successful conclusion.
The plain fact is that there is no real connection
between our current balance of payments financ­
ing problem and the problem of creating a new
international reserve asset to provide a supple­
ment to gold and reserve currencies. There is
simply no international liquidity escape route
from the hard road of restoring equilibrium in
our balance of payments. And I would submit
that the continuing and increasingly comprehen­
sive efforts made to reduce the U.S. balance of
payments deficit in themselves serve as a denial
of the asserted escapism. Furthermore, the modest
amount of reserve assets that would accrue to
the United States under any plan, as well as the
7

delay in actual creation of new assets in any
realistic timetable, underscores the irrelevance to
current deficits.
In plain fact, it is simply inconceivable that
the United States could go on running significant
deficits on the basis of our share in any new
reserve asset creation. Moreover, so far as the
immediate situation is concerned, I can see no
prospect that the many remaining preliminaries
can be completed, and actual reserve creation
initiated, before 1969 or 1970. So neither the
Europeans who are skeptical of our motives, nor
the Americans who have indulged in wishful
thinking, should be misled concerning the real
nature of our genuine interest in reserve creation
as a fundamental improvement necessary for the
international monetary system, not as a crutch
for the United States.
Then why are we searching for ways and
means of deliberately creating, for the first time,
an international money? The answer is relatively
simple—it is because there will not be enough of
the existing kinds of reserve assets to go around.
The present sources of increases in international
reserves are, it is generally conceded, likely to
prove inadequate over the years ahead and global
reserve shortages could have deflationary effects
and lead to restrictive external policies that could
only serve to reduce growth of world trade and
of the world economy. The world needs the
assurance that the traditional reserve assets, gold
and reserve currencies, can and will be supple­
mented by a new reserve asset as needed to meet
future requirements.
To illustrate, during the past decade, roughly,
the increase in world reserves has averaged close
to $2 billion a year. If one excludes the United
States which has experienced a substantial de­
cline in reserves, reserve growth of the rest of the
world has averaged nearer to S3 billion a year.
But analysis of trends in the principal components
of that reserve growth point to the likelihood of
8




future difficulties. Taking new gold first, there
has been very little addition to international
reserves from this source in recent years—per­
haps 200 to 300 million dollars a year. And, last
year there was actually a net drain from monetary
reserves into nonmonetary uses— reflecting in­
creased industrial uses associated with space,
jewelry, etc., and, undoubtedly, continued specu­
lative demand. So gold alone does not seem to
provide the answer to the need for growth in
international reserves as we look ahead. What
about dollars—or about some other currency
performing this function? Again, there are clear
indications that growth in foreign official dollar
balances alone, or in combination with new gold,
cannot meet these prospective needs. For sub­
stantial dollar growth could mean continued
overly large official settlements deficits in the
U.S. balance of payments to provide such an
outflow. Yet, such deficits—unless accompanied
by net increases in U.S. reserve assets—are
clearly undesirable, for they can only serve to
weaken the value of the dollar and lead more and
more to an unwillingness of foreign monetary
authorities to accept, or at least to hold, such
dollars in their reserves. In the past two years,
monetary authorities of the major industrial
countries have, in fact, not added to official dol­
lar holdings in their reserves. Instead, as most of
you know, there has been a substantial conversion
of dollars into gold and, although mainly reflect­
ing the policy and actions of one country, this
results in a corresponding reduction in total
international reserves. The why of our search,
therefore, is the strong evidence that the supply
of reserves from traditional sources—mainly
gold and dollars—will not be enough to meet
growing needs.
As to any other national currency filling the
breach, apart from the special role of sterling,
all major countries have made clear their unwill­
ingness and inability to accept the burdens of a

reserve currency country. Thus it is only prudent
to look elsewhere—and it is this prudent look
that has been, and is, called “contingency plan­
ning” for reserve asset creation.
Finally, it may be asked, where is the search
taking place and what are the prospects for suc­
cess? The where question is the easiest to answer,
but not the least important, for it sets the stage
for at least one of the key issues remaining,
namely, how the decision-making process, in
terms of both the establishment of a plan to
create assets and its activation, will be deter­
mined. Speaking generally, the search for ways
and means of deliberately creating reserve assets
to supplement gold and reserve currencies in the
international monetary system has been going on
for several years, most meaningfully in two
forums—which have' now been joined in this
effort—the so-called Deputies of the Group of
Ten (the deputies to the finance ministers and
central bank governors of the ten leading indus­
trial countries) and the International Monetary
Fund itself for, as Managing Director Pierre
Paul Schweitzer has often said, “ international
liquidity is the business of the Fund.”
Beginning last fall these two groups joined
efforts and a series of joint meetings of the
Deputies of the Ten and Executive Directors of
the IMF has been held, the first in Washington
at the end of November, 1966; the second, in
London near the end of January, 1967; the third,
again in Washington last week; and a fourth and
final meeting scheduled for Paris in mid-June.
Against the background of all the efforts to date
and of these most recent joint meetings, what can
be said as to the progress made and hopes for
the future?
The answer here is not such a simple one be­
cause it involves the current negotiations and a
number of still unresolved issues. But I believe
that it is fair to state that great progress has
been made. Consider the broad, and important,




areas of agreement:
First of all, there is now a unanimous con­
sensus on working ahead toward the establish­
ment of a plan for deliberately creating reserve
assets to provide for adequate secular growth in
reserves.
Second, it is generally agreed that the creation
of such reserves should be designed to meet the
global needs of all Fund members, not the
balance of payments needs of any individual
country. And there is agreement, too, that reserve
creation should not be linked to development
assistance.
Third, there also seems to be general support
for the principle of universality—that is, that any
asset created will be distributed to, and available
for use by, all countries not just a privileged few.
The consensus on this score seems to lean toward
distribution to all member countries of the Inter­
national Monetary Fund according to a generally
objective formula such as IMF quotas. No clear
view has yet emerged as to the relation of uni­
versality and decision making but here, too,
gratifying progress has been made in discussing
and exploring the possibilities.
Fourth, as to the more specific and technical
questions of the nature and form of the new
asset it is now also generally recognized that the
two principal types of reserve assets that have
been discussed—one a new reserve unit and the
other a new drawing right claim on the Fund—
can be made nearly identical in technical prop­
erties. But there are important questions remain­
ing as to the precise construction of an uncondi­
tional reserve asset that will clearly and effec­
tively serve as a true supplement to gold and
dollars. Those favoring a reserve unit approach
point out that it can more readily do just that.
But apart from, although not unrelated to, the
question of the choice of approaches a number of
important issues remain to be resolved:
First, the question of decision making with
9