View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Timing and Tools of Federal Reserve Policy
The Paper Industry is Like That . . .




Tim in g and Tools of Federal Reserve Policy
. . . In the 1960’s the Federal Reserve tried to improve the timing of policy
changes and experimented with new uses of the tools of monetary control.
The Paper Industry is Like That . . .
. . . There are easier ways of making money hut perhaps none so diverse and
fascinating as papermaking.

B U S IN E S S REVIEW is produced in th e D e p a rtm e n t of R esearch. Evan B. A ld e rfer is E d ito rial C o n s u lta n t. D onald R.
H ulm es prepared th e la y o u t and artw o rk. The a u thors w ill be glad to receive c o m m e n ts on th e ir a rticles.
R equests fo r a d d itio n a l copies should be addressed to B ank and Public R elations, Federal R eserve B ank of P h ilad elp h ia,
P hilad elph ia, P ennsylvania 1 9 1 0 1 .




TIMING AND TOOLS OF
FEDERAL RESERVE
POLICY
by Karl R. Bopp*

As bankers, you are fully aware that we have
had some rapid-fire and rather novel changes in
monetary policy during the past year. During the
first ten months of 1966, in the face of an ex­
cessively rapid economic expansion that was gen­
erating strong upward pressures on prices, oper­
ations were conducted with a view toward mod­
erating the growth of money and credit which
resulted in the high interest rates and scarce
credit mentioned by President Bracken. Then in
November 1966, when the pace of the expansion
moderated and inflationary pressures began to re­
cede, monetary policy shifted promptly toward
encouraging flows of money and credit.
These sharp movements in monetary policy
within a short time demonstrate how quickly it
can respond to changing economic conditions.
They also show that as we increased our knowl­
edge of the workings of the economy and of mone­
tary policy, we have tried to improve the timing
of policy changes and have experimented with
new uses of the tools of monetary control.
Since events of the past year highlight these
changes in the conduct of monetary policy, I
take this opportunity to point out some of them to
you. I shall first discuss some of the factors that
have influenced the timing of changes in general
monetary policy and then turn to some of the
modifications we have made in the use of specific
tools.
* Mr. Bopp, President of the Federal Reserve Bank oj
Philadelphia, gave this talk at the 73rd Annual Conven­
tion of the Pennsylvania Bankers Association, Atlantic
City, May 22, 1967.




TIMING OF FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY
Wesley Mitchell wrote his pioneering book on
business cycles over 50 years ago. Among the
factors to which he drew attention as being ini­
mical to achievement of steady advances in pro­
duction and employment were the financial panics
that had at times severely disrupted the economy.
One of the main reasons the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem was established was to help avoid the sharp
monetary contractions and liquidity freezes that
had precipitated or accentuated economic down­
turns in the past.
Soon after its inception, however, the Federal
Reserve saw that it had a responsibility to do
more than serve passively as a lender of last re­
sort in order to prevent financial crises. It began
to foster monetary conditions that would stimu­
late the pace of business activity when it was de­
pressed and moderate it when the economy was
expanding. That is, it began early to use the
business cycle as the general framework to guide
it in its conduct of monetary policy.
The rationale, and I am greatly over simplify­
ing, went something like this. When business
activity declines, unemployment rises and income
falls. Consequently, monetary policy should be ex­
pansive in order to stimulate production, em­
ployment and income. But as economic activity
expands and prices tend to rise, monetary policy
should become restrictive.
Peaks in economic activity were signals indi­
cating that monetary policy should begin to move
toward ease, and troughs were signals indicating

3

busin e ss r e v ie w

that monetary policy should begin to move toward
restriction.
Now, as I say, this is an oversimplification. The
problem of determining policy has always been
much more complicated than this. All signals
seldom point in the same direction. Often the
Federal Reserve can achieve one objective only
at the expense of another. For example, massive
international gold flows in the 1930’s and the
huge Government financing needs in the 1940’s
led the Federal Reserve to pursue policies at times
that were not what they would have been if it had
been trying solely to moderate cyclical fluctua­
tions in the economy. Nevertheless, with due re­
gard to these qualifications, changes in the phase
of the business cycle—peaks and troughs—ob­
viously have been important considerations in­
fluencing the timing of policy changes.
Let me apply this principle to the 1950’s to
show what I mean.

moved toward ease.
The trough was reached in April 1958, just
nine months after the previous peak. The Federal
Reserve was again able to recognize the turning
point with a lag of only three months and, as be­
fore, immediately decided to reverse the direction
of monetary policy.
It is clear from this brief overview of the 1950’s
that the business cycle did exert a large influence
on the timing of policy changes. The peak in
1953 was the main exception, and in that case
disruption of Government securities markets
played a large part in the early move toward
ease. More generally the pattern was that as soon
as the Federal Reserve recognized a cyclical turn­
ing point, it reversed the direction of policy in
order to stimulate the economy during recessions
and moderate the pace of advance during ex­
pansions.
Timing in the 1960’s

Timing in the 1950’s
In the 1950’s this country had two distinct cycles
in economic activity.
Economic activity reached a peak in July 1953.
In June 1953, partly in response to unsettled
conditions in the Government securities markets,
the Federal Reserve changed monetary policy
and began to move toward ease.
This downswing in economic activity con­
tinued until August 1954. Because of lags in col­
lection of data and difficulties of interpreting
them, the Federal Reserve did not recognize the
trough until November, or three months later. As
soon as it did, however, it reversed direction and
began to move toward restriction.
The next peak occurred in July 1957. Again it
took the Federal Reserve three months to recog­
nize that the turning point had been reached; but
once it did, it reversed monetary policy and

4




The timing of policy changes in the 1960’s has
been different. Policy has been eased before cyc­
lical peaks and was not tightened until long after
the only trough we have had.
The Federal Reserve began to ease in March
1960, two months before the peak in the business
cycle. At the time, no recession was expected. In­
stead, this policy change was made primarily to
reverse a declining trend in the money supply in
order to accommodate and stimulate economic
growth.
The economy reached a trough in February
1961. This time the Federal Reserve was able to
recognize it with a lag of only two months, but
did not regard it as a signal to begin to tighten
monetary policy. The Federal Reserve waited un­
til October 1961, six months after it recognized
the trough, before making policy slightly less ex­
pansive and it was not until 1965 that it really

b usin e ss rev iew

began to be restrictive.
Following extreme restraint in most of 1966,
the Federal Reserve shifted direction again in
November. So far as we know now, we have no
cyclical peak with which to compare the timing
of this move. But we do know that policy was
shifted in response to a decline in the rate of eco­
nomic growth with no suggestion that a recession
was imminent.
Reasons for change
Two factors account for differences in the timing
of policy in the 1950’s and 1960’s.
First, the economic environment was substan­
tially different in the two periods. Prices rose
persistently and rapidly throughout most of the
1950’s. In order to combat this, the Federal Re­
serve began to tighten policy as soon as it recog­
nized the onset of an economic expansion, and
continued to do so until a peak had been reached.
Price increases cause personal hardships and
inequities, and are a major stumbling block in the
way of achieving sustained economic growth and
a suitable balance-of-payments position. Mone­
tary policy, therefore, had to do all it could to
moderate the upward price pressures that charac­
terized this period.
In contrast, until 1965 and 1966 the period
since 1960 was characterized by unusual price
stability at both the wholesale and retail levels.
And unlike experience in the 1950’s when un­
employment tended to fall rapidly as the pace of
economic activity picked up, in the 1960’s it
moved much more sluggishly. Lack of price pres­
sures permitted monetary policy to ease before
peaks in economic activity in order to stimulate
economic growth. It also permitted policy to re­
main easy well after the trough in order to com­
bat excessively high rates of unemployment.
A second factor accounting for the different




timing is an increased alertness to the dynamics
of the business cycle.
Wesley Mitchell made clear that what we call
the business cycle is really an average of many
different economic events, each of which follows
its own pattern over time.
Each firm, industry, and sector in the economy
is faced with different forces of demand. At any
given time, some products and services will be in
great demand; others will be subject to declining
demand. While one sector of the economy is ex­
panding, another may be contracting. During the
expansion phase of the business cycle more sec­
tors are expanding than are contracting; during
the contraction phase more sectors are contract­
ing than are expanding.
In a dynamic economy, some firms are hiring
additional workers while other firms are laying
off. Similarily, some firms are increasing prices,
while other firms are lowering them. The levels of
aggregate employment and average prices will de­
pend on the net effect of all these labor and price
adj ustments.
This concept, of course, is not new. But it takes
on added significance as we constantly raise the
standards of performance demanded of the eco­
nomy. I am very skeptical of statements that the
business cycle is dead, but I do believe we have
become increasingly intolerant of it. If the cycle
is ever to be vanquished, therefore, public policy
must be increasingly alert to the dynamics of the
cycle. It must, as economists say, disaggregate
overall movements in the economy.
The Federal Reserve has, I think, come closer
to doing this in the 1960’s than it did in the
1950’s. The signals to ease have become, not the
peak in the business cycle, but unacceptable in­
creases in unemployment and declines in the rate
of growth. The signals to begin to tighten mone­
tary policy, rather than simply the trough in the

5

busin e ss re v ie w

business cycle, have become unsustainable rates
of growth, increases in the price level, and
so on.
While these signals do not always point in the
same direction at the same time and trade-offs
have to be made, the important point is that
policy changes are more directly related to the
policy goals themselves rather than to the peaks
and troughs in the business cycle.
Stabilization of the business cycle, after all, is
not a goal by itself. We are concerned with
achieving full as well as stable employment, and
rising as well as stable rates of production. Con­
sequently, shifts in monetary policy should be
geared directly to the degree of achievement of
each policy goal—that is, to changes in the rate
of unemployment, the level of prices, the rate of
economic growth, and the degree of disequili­
brium in the balance of payments.
NEW USES OF OLD TOOLS
Along with changes in the timing of policy ac­
tions, there have been changes in the use of the
tools of monetary policy.
You are familiar with the way the Federal Re­
serve has traditionally used open market opera­
tions and changes in reserve requirements and the
discount rate either individually or in combina­
tion to achieve a given degree of restraint or ease.
To restrain, securities have been sold, reserve
requirements raised, or the discount rate in­
creased. To ease, the System has purchased
securities, lowered reserve requirements, or drop­
ped the discount rate.
Different emphasis has been placed on each of
these tools at different times, but until recently
they were generally used only to influence total
flows of money and credit through the economy.
Last year, a new dimension was added and they
were used to influence sectoral flows as well.

6




Sectoral flows in 1966
It became clear as monetary conditions tightened
in 1966 that markets for mortgages and munici­
pal securities had to carry a disproportionate
share of the burden of restriction while business
loans were expanding at an unsustainable pace.
The problem in the mortgage market was due
in part to the difficulty savings and loan associa­
tions and mutual savings banks had in attracting
and holding deposit and share accounts. They are
limited in their ability to increase the rates they
pay to savers because the bulk of their assets are
of fixed yield and turn over slowly. Consequently,
as market rates rose, savers channeled an in­
creasing proportion of their funds directly into
market instruments rather than into these finan­
cial institutions. At the same time, commercial
banks raised the rates they were willing to pay
on time deposits and some funds that might
otherwise have gone to nonbank financial inter­
mediaries went instead to commercial banks.
These two factors sharply curtailed the ability of
savings and loan associations and mutual savings
banks to invest in new mortgages. Since they are
typically heavy suppliers of funds to this market,
the availability of mortgage funds was severely
reduced. Home builders were forced to bear a
relatively large part of the burden of monetary
restriction.
The problem in the market for municipals was
different. While commercial banks were better
able to compete for the saver’s dollar than were
most nonbank financial institutions, they still
experienced demands for their funds that greatly
outpaced their ability to attract deposits. Requests
for business loans were particularly heavy. In an
attempt to satisfy some of these burgeoning de­
mands for credit, banks liquidated large amounts
of municipals. Since they are ordinarily heavy
purchasers of these securities, this liquidation re­

b usin e ss re v ie w

suited in the steep run-up in interest rates on these
issues. Either because of legal constraints, the
forces of custom, or the exercise of judgment, some
state and local governments were unable or unwill­
ing to borrow at these high rates. In addition,
there was some question as to whether or not some
issues could have been sold even if the borrowers
had been willing to incur high interest costs.
Federal Reserve response
The Federal Reserve was concerned that moves to
restrict the overall flows of money and credit were
impinging heavily on the markets for mortgages
and municipal securities while business loans
continued to advance too rapidly. Yet inflationary
conditions in the economy and large deficits in
the balance of payments clearly warranted a
policy of general monetary restraint during most
of 1966. The Federal Reserve, therefore, decided
to use its ability to alter reserve requirements and
set maximum rates on time deposits to try to
correct some of these sectoral imbalances.
In response to the difficulties in the mortgage
market, the Federal Reserve first refined its use
of changes in reserve requirements. Instead of in­
creasing the requirements against a whole class
of deposits as it had done in the past, differential
reserve requirements were introduced against
specific types of time deposits. In June and again
in August, requirements against time deposits
other than savings accounts in excess of $5 mil­
lion were increased, first to 5 and then to 6 per
cent. It was hoped that this would better enable
savings and loan associations, mutual savings
banks, and smaller commercial banks to attract
deposits. With the higher propensity of these in­
stitutions to invest in mortgages and other types
of nonbusiness loans, this would ease conditions
in the mortgage market and moderate the pace of
business spending.




The second thing the Federal Reserve did to
help even out the burden of its restrictive mone­
tary policy was to give real bite to Regulation Q.
Always in the past when interest rates on time and
savings deposits bumped against the ceilings es­
tablished under Regulation Q, the ceilings had
been increased. This was not true in 1966. In
July the maximum rate on multiple-maturity
time deposits of 90 days or more was reduced
from 5 !/2 to 5 per cent and for maturities of less
than 90 days the ceiling was reduced to 4 per
cent. In September the Federal Reserve used its
newly acquired power to flexibly regulate maxi­
mum rates on time and savings deposits to drop
the rate ceiling for time deposits other than sav­
ings deposits of under $100,000 from 5i/2 to 5
per cent.
Meanwhile, the Federal Reserve maintained the
ceiling on other time deposits even though many
banks were paying rates near or at that rate and
market rates had risen even higher.
These adjustments under Regulation Q were
intended to help maintain competitive balance
among financial institutions and thereby prevent
excessive and disruptive rate competition and
help take some of the pressure off the mortgage
market. The result was a big net decline in large
denomination certificates of deposit after August
1966, a slower growth in bank credit from Sep­
tember to November, and hopefully a more bal­
anced distribution of the effects of monetary
restriction among the various financial institu­
tions and sectors of the economy.
In direct response to the excessive expansion
of business loans and difficulties in the market
for municipal securities, the presidents of the
Federal Reserve Banks sent a letter to all member
banks on September 1 requesting that they mod­
erate their expansion of business loans and re­
frain from further liquidation of municipal se­

7

b usin e ss r e v ie w

curities. The promise of adequate accommodation
at the discount window was held out to those
complying banks which needed such help to
smooth over the period of adjustment. At the
same time, the discount officers at each Reserve
Bank began to hold regular telephone conferences
to ensure uniform administration of the discount
window throughout the country. These efforts
marked a milestone in the Federal Reserve’s use
of moral suasion and discount policy to influence
flows of money and credit.
Reason for sectoral approach
The Federal Reserve is concerned about flows of
funds to different sectors of the economy as well
as about the total volume of money and credit
because it is concerned about the specific effects
of monetary policy. Just as there is need to dis­
aggregate broad economic movements and look
at each policy goal individually in deciding
when to change monetary policy, there is need to
disaggregate the effects of monetary policy to
see how it should be changed. Because of institu­
tional, legal or other market rigidities, the stimu­
lus or restriction resulting from monetary policy
may at times produce sectoral imbalances that
threaten sustained growth of the economy. The
Federal Reserve has a duty to try to prevent such
imbalances from damaging the general health of
the economy.
Experience last year demonstrated that there
may be times when growth and stability of the
overall economy call for particular attention to
developments in parts of the economy. In such
conditions, it may be necessary to employ the
tools of policy differently than usual. In most
circumstances, however, use of general instru­
ments can be directed toward the total flow of
money and credit without trying to influence di­
rectly where these funds go or how they are used.

8




IMPLICATIONS
I have noted some highlights of recent modifica­
tions in the timing of changes in monetary poli­
cy and in the Federal Reserve’s use of the tools of
monetary control. What do they imply about fu­
ture changes in monetary policy? There are four
main conclusions I should like to draw.
First, the Federal Reserve will continue when
possible to ease monetary policy when the econo­
my slows down rather than waiting for a reces­
sion. Such easing should not be interpreted as
indicating that we are forecasting a recession.
The business cycle may not be dead, but there
may be times when the rate of growth will slow
down without being followed by large declines in
production and employment. That happened in
1962 and also may describe what has happened
recently. Under such circumstances, if you inter­
pret an easing of monetary policy as a sign that
a recession is close at hand, you might well adopt
policies yourselves and recommend to your bor­
rowers that they adopt policies that are not in
your best interest or theirs.
Second, when production and employment are
at depressed levels, even though business activity
is increasing, you can expect monetary policy to
follow a stimulative policy as long as possible.
Business cycle troughs will not themselves signal
a shift in policy.
Third, we will continue to be alert to the sec­
toral as well as the total flows of money and cred­
it. Hopefully, the market will function effectively
so that there will be few occasions when sectoral
imbalances will develop that will require us to
deviate from our usual practice of making only
general changes in monetary policy.
Fourth, with respect to both the timing and
tools of monetary policy, it is clear that we still
have a lot to learn about the economy and the ef­
fects of monetary policy on it. We are trying to

b u sin e ss re v ie w

learn more. We currently have studies under way
appraising the discount mechanism, studying the
Government securities market, and investigating
the linkages between monetary policy and real
economic activity. As these and other studies
are completed, they will likely lead to further
modifications in the way we formulate and exe­

cute policy. Consequently, the changes in the
procedures I have described here are not the
end of the story. They are simply part of a
continuing effort on our part to see that
monetary policy makes its maximum contribu­
tion to the achievement of the nation’s economic
objectives.

THE RARER INDUSTRY
IS LIKE THAT...
by Evan B. Alderfer

Big, widely scattered, forest-anchored, marketoriented, highly diversified, largely integrated,
highly mechanized, overcapacity prone, mergerminded, and relentlessly competitive. There are
easier ways of making money, but papermaking is
fascinating.
Most paper is made out of trees. There are
many kind of trees and many kinds of paper made
in many different mills in many different places
for many different markets and ultimate use. Di­
versity is the one word that best describes the
industry. Two words might be better—diversity
diversified.
Diversity of uses
Diversity runs riot with respect to the kinds and
uses of paper. Newspapers, books, and magazines
probably come to mind first; but as carriers of
written communications, paper also serves in
thousands of business forms, legal documents,
catalogues, directories, hand bills—and what an
insatiable appetite for paper E.D.P. systems have!
In the handling of goods, paper and paper­




board perform a protective function—as in wrap­
ping paper, bags, sacks, boxes, cartons, drums,
and containers of almost endless variety. In the
construction industry, building paper and build­
ing board are used extensively for insulation and
roofing. Paper is indispensable in modern hy­
giene and sanitation, as attested by the use of dis­
posable cups, plates, napkins, tissue, towels, and
hospital supplies.
And miscellaneous paper products include such
heterogeneities as carbon paper, cigarette paper,
handbags, tickertape, confetti, waxpaper, wall­
paper, photographic paper, and now ladies’
dresses. A complete list of paper products is said
to run over 12,000 items, and annual consumption
of paper in the United States is in excess of a
quarter-ton per capita. We are the world’s most
prodigal users of paper.
Stature and structure
The paper industry, in the broadest sense, is ap­
proximately 5,000 manufacturing establishments,
about 680,000 workers, and production in 1966

9

busin e ss re v ie w

was over 46 million tons of paper products. Total
billing for the products that left shipping plat­
forms came to $22 billion. As such, papermaking
is one of our larger industries. The dollar figure
cited, however, involves considerable double
counting when, for example, the pulp maker sells
his product to the papermaker who sells his pro­
duct to the converter who performs final “ value
adding” operations for the ultimate consumer.
This article is confined primarily to pulp and
paper manufacture and only incidentally to the
conversion of paper into consumer goods such as
drinking cups, envelopes, and party knickknackery made by so-called “paper converters.”
The industry’s output, summarized in the table,
falls into two major classes: paper and paperboard. Technically, nine-thousandths of an inch
(0.009) thickness is the dividing line between
thin sheeting called paper and the thicker prod­
ucts designated paperboard, and the tonnage of
the two is roughly equal. Of considerably smaller

PRODUCTION OF PAPER AND
INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION
Index 1957-59= 100

10




U.S. Paper and Paperboard Production, 1966
P ao e r
.............................. .........................
P rin tin g .................................. ............
C o a rse ..................................... ............
T is s u e ..................................... ............
Fine .......................................... ............
N e w sp rin t .............................. ............
S p e c ia l in d u stria l ............... ............
P ap erbo ard
..............................
................. ............
C o n tain e rb o ard
B o xboard ................................ ............
O ther ....................................... ............
C o n stru ctio n ..............................
B u ild in g pa p e r .................... ............
B u ild in g board .................... ............
To tal ....................

T h o u sa n d
to n s
20,200
6,489
4,713
3,002
2,637
2,198
1,161
22,624
13,517
6,345
2,762
3,717
1,516
2,201
46,541

S o u rce : A m e rica n P ap er In stitu te.

tonnage is a third class—construction paper—
which consists largely of roofing felts, floor cov­
ering, and insulating board.
Paper and paperboard each fall into the sev­
eral subdivisions as indicated. Printing paper is
the type used for books, magazines, pamphlets,
envelopes, and tablets. Coarse paper is used for
shipping sacks, bags, wrapping, Kraft, and
grease-proof paper. Tissue includes napkins,
towel and sanitary papers generally; fine embraces
writing paper, cover and text papers. Most of the
newsprint goes to newspaper publishers; but the
tonnage seems unbelievably small as you recall
how a copy of the Sunday New York Times
weighs you down. The joker is that we import
three times as much newsprint from Canada as
we produce at home. Special industrial is paper
for tags, tabulating cards, filter and absorbent
paper, and such like. The large tonnage of con­
tainer board should occasion no surprise in view
of the fact that cardboard cartons have just about
backed wooden boxes off the American scene.
Moreover, the widespread use of paperboard in
commerce and industry may explain in large part
why the production of paper so closely parallels

b u sin e ss re v ie w

the Federal Reserve Board’s index of industrial
production, as shown in the chart.

beating, the pulp reduced to a slurry—a sort of
puree of cellulose—is ready for the second stage,
papermaking.

Capitalistic aspects

The Fourdrinier, on which most paper is made,
is a mammoth piece of machinery a city block
in length, full of moving parts and astonishment.
A continuous stream of slurry cascading on the
machine at the wet end is rapidly relieved of its
moisture, and from the dry end of the machine
the felted fibers emerge as a continuous sheet of
paper 18 to 20 feet wide, at speeds up to almost
60 miles an hour depending on the type of paper
being made. The machine may cost $13 million to
buy and install, but it can be operated by a crew
of seven men.

Papermaking requires an abundance of capital
for machinery and other facilities because trees,
the principal raw material, must first be broken
down into pulp and, second, the pulp must be
built up into paper.
Most pulping is done either mechanically or
chemically. Groundwood pulp, made by pressing
logs against high-speed grindstones, produces
pulp with short fibers and without removing the
lignin which tends to make paper brittle and turn
yellow with age. Groundwood pulp goes into
newsprint, building, wrapping, and other kinds of
paper where quality is not at a premium.
Chemical pulp is made by processing wood
chips with certain chemicals in enormous “ pres­
sure cookers” that dissolve the lignin and other
impurities which are drained away and leave
practically pure long-fibered cellulose. Old-fash­
ioned batch-type digesters are now being replaced
by modern units of larger size that operate con­
tinuously. After much washing, screening, and




This sketchy sketch of the technology is enough
to show that even a one-Fourdrinier papermaker
needs considerable capital. Moreover, for reasons
of economy, most papermakers also make their
own pulp, the production of which takes yet more
capital. A recent financial statement of a onemachine paper company shows an investment of
$16 million in fixed asets (property, plant, and
equipment before depreciation) and net sales of
$16 million. That relationship—a sunken dollar
for every sales dollar—is fairly typical of the
paper business.
As paper companies go
A paper company with annual sales of $16 million
is a small concern as paper companies go. Even a
company with sales of $100 million is not a big
company, for there are others much bigger. For
example, Georgia-Pacific, Mead, and KimberlyClark have sales over $500 million each; Crown
Zellerbach and Weyerhaeuser tower still higher,
and International Paper Company with annual
sales well over a billion dollars is the industry’s
giant. Thus it is apparent that with respect to cor­
porate stature, paper companies come in all sizes.

11

b u sin e ss r e v ie w

A one- or two-machine paper company is most
likely to specialize in one line such as boxboard,
or printing paper, and all of its facilities are gen­
erally confined to one site—usually on a stream,
for pulp and papermaking take a lot of water. A
large company may engage in several or almost
all major lines of paper, and some companies are
completely integrated from ownership of timberlands to and including a broad spectrum of fin­
ished paper products.
One company with sales in excess of $100
million and formerly one of the largest producers
of newsprint has broadened its lines to include
linerboard and groundwood specialty printing
paper, so that newsprint now accounts for only
one-third of its sales.
Another company approaching the half-billiondollar class tells its stockholders that it “ is a
forest products company —not a paper company,
not a lumber company, nor a plywood company.”
It is all three.
A still larger company with annual sales well
in excess of a half-billion dollars owns or con­
trols close to 4 million acres of timberland, oper­
ates 16 pulp, paper, and board mills; 12 bag
plants, 26 container mills, 10 folding carton
plants, 10 flexible packaging plants, and 20 other
converting plants plus sawmills, plywood and
other woodworking mills, and four chemical
plants. These properties are distributed in more
than half the states from Maine to Hawaii. No
one product contributed over 18 per cent to the
sales dollar in 1965, as the table shows.
With such product diversification the company
makes maximum use of its forest resources. For
example, at one of its Western plants peeler logs
are made into veneer sheets, sawlogs into lumber,
smaller logs and veneer cores into studs, mill
residues into chips for pulping, sawdust and
planer shavings into fuel for powerplant boilers,

12




P ercent
_______ Item _______________________________________ of sa le s
C o rru gate d boxes .......................................................
F o ld in g and set-up bo xes .....................................
K raft, paper, and p ape rbo ard ..............................
P rin tin g and fine p a p e rs ........................................
F le xib le p a c k a g in g ....................................................
In d u stria l and co n su m e r b a g s ..............................
G la s s in e and g re a se p ro o f p a p e rs .......................
En ve lo pe s, paper p late s, e tc..................................
Lu m b e r and plyw ood ...............................................
O ther p ro d u cts ............................................................

18%
5
17
12
10
10
4
7
9
8
100%

and bark into garden mulch.
Acquistion of timberland has become a wide­
spread policy throughout the paper industry,
which is now the country’s largest industrial
holder of commercial forest land. Of course the
distinction between pulp and paper ownerships
and holdings of other forest industries is becom­
ing less and less meaningful as the production of
pulp, lumber, veneer, particle board, and other
wood products has become more closely inte­
grated with large companies. Whether they start­
ed out as paper companies and branched out into
lumbering or originally lumber concerns that
went into papermaking, they manage their forests
on a sustained-yield basis which includes exten­
sive programs for reforestation through planting,
seeding, and disease control. Intensively managed
young forests produce far more than natural ma­
ture forests. Only about 25 per cent of the pulpwood consumed by the industry is cut from com­
pany-owned land; the rest is obtained from
farmers and from Government lands.
Where paper mills go
Pulp and paper mills are large-volume operations,
so their habitat is close to timber and water re­
sources. The Southern States have 39 per cent of
the country’s commercial forest land and nearly
half the timber growth. The region has already
attracted a large segment of the industry and con­

b u sin e ss re v ie w

tinues to offer strong inducements. A crop of
Southern pine can be turned over in as little as
17 years; the forests offer easy accessibility for
logging, and nearness to large Eastern markets.
Perhaps the major obstacle to expansion in the
South is the large proportion of its timberland
belonging to small owners, so many of whom do
not practice intensified timber management.
Converting plants are smaller-scale value oper­
ations located in urban areas on the doorsteps of
their markets. In contrast with pulp and paper­
making, converting requires very little capital,
plants take up much less space, and pound-forpound add much more value to the materials
processed.
The Philadelphia Federal Reserve District, a
variegated industrial panorama, is a great con­
sumer of paper products and also a large pro­
ducer. Dispersed throughout the region are more




than 400 paper mills, not counting the country’s
first—built on a tributary of the Wissahickon by
William Rittenhouse in 1690, and still standing
as a museum piece.
Over half of the district’s paper mills are small
establishments in terms of employment but they
turn out a tremendous tonnage of converted
paper products such as bags, envelopes, folding
paperboard boxes, set-up paperboard boxes, sani­
tary food containers, and corrugated shipping
containers—all of which are in great local de­
mand for shipping the products of the area’s
diversified industries to market.
Among the largest producers in the district and
originally established here are Scott Paper, a pio­
neer and leader in sanitary tissue products; and
Glatfelter, a fully integrated manufacturer of
printing and fine paper used in books and busi­
ness forms. Within the district also are branch
plants of big companies headquartered elsewhere,
notably Weyerhaeuser, International Paper, Con­
tainer Corporation, St. Regis, and Owens-Illinois
Glass—a company that makes so many glass con­
tainers that it acquired several paper mills to make
the cartons for packaging the glass products.
Competition
Papermaking has been competitive for years, but
competition today is different and more intensive
because competitors are different and more ex­
pansive. Formerly, competition was restricted
largely to producers in the same general line of
products, but as a result of vertical integration
there is now a score of large companies operating
in the various grade groups of paper and paperboard. Out of this grow intensified competitive
pressures for several reasons.
Practically all of the large integrated com­
panies are already well established in all or
nearly all of the major markets according to

13

b usin e ss re v ie w

companies recently merged to become U. S.
Plywood-Champion Papers, Inc., and thereby
became the second concern to break into the
billion-dollar annual sales class.
The biggest companies, however, are not nec­
essarily the most profitable. If profitability were a
function of size, how could the smaller paper com­
panies survive the competition of their multimillion-dollar competitors? But they do, and fre­
quently show much better records of earnings.
Profits
Although some paper companies issue financial
statements that gladden the hearts of their stock­
holders, profits for the industry as a whole reflect
a growing intensity of competition. Using as a
measuring stick the rates of profits, after taxes,
on stockholders’ equity and plotting the paper
industry’s rank among the country’s 20 major
groups of manufacturing industries show a sur­
prising result. Paper, as the chart indicates,
grade of paper. Moreover, the leading companies
are also seeking greater geographical dispersion
of their markets, mill capacities, and timber
resources across the nation and in foreign
countries. Today’s huge investment costs per ton
of mill capacity make for much larger minimum
economic size mill construction and greater spe­
cialization, so that the pressure for full utiliza­
tion of larger mill capacity increases competition
for markets.
As in other industries, some of the largest
companies have attained their huge size not only
by normal growth but also by merger or consoli­
dation with other concerns. Corporate marriage
is the quickest way to acquire productive capac­
ity in another geographical region or to round
out the product line or to get into a related line
and, incidentally, gain stature overnight. Two

14




HOW PAPER RANKS AMONG THE TWENTY
MAJOR MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
IN PROFIT MAKING*
(Selected Years)
Rank

Source: FTC and SEC.

b u sin e ss rev iew

slipped from second place in 1947 to ninth in
1955, and to the tail end in 1965.
The fact that paper came in last in the 1965
race for profits does not mean that the industry
was unprofitable, for it earned 9.4 per cent on
stockholders’ equity, but 19 other industrial
groups did better. A peculiarity of the industry
which intensifies competition is the tendency
toward overcapacity.
Every so often the industry goes on a stam­
pede of plant expansion. Foreseeing larger mar­
kets, a few concerns build new plants or enlarge
existing mills and, not to be outdone, other com­
panies follow suit. As the additional capacity
goes on stream the industry’s capacity becomes
topheavy and so does its price structure. Then,
hungry for tonnage to get fuller utilization of
capacity, paper men cut prices. With a lower
price structure the industry muddles through a
period of austerity until growing demand again




catches up with capacity. But, by and by, a new
wave of construction breaks out and the cycle
of resurgence and remorse is repeated.
The industry is at present actively building
additional plant capacity. During each of the
past two years, capacity was increased in excess
of 2 million tons. This year the industry plans
an additional 31/2 million tons capacity and 2.8
million more in 1968. Paper manufacturers feel
that the current expansion is not excessive in
view of the growing domestic demand and the
prospect of increased exports. A deficiency in
European timber resources is almost certain to
stimulate exports of pulp, paper, and paperboard products from this side of the Atlantic.
That’s the way the paper industry is—big,
widely scattered, forest-ancbored, market-orient­
ed. largely integrated, highly mechanized, over­
capacity prone, merger-minded, and relentlessly
competitive.

15

FOR THE RECORD

•

•

i

B U S IN E S S
A

•

/ DEPARTME MT STORE SALES, DIST.

..

>0,SEASO
NALLYAOJ.)

A/V
N

f a c t o r y pa

YROLLS, DIST.

r

(CONSUMER
19571959- 100)PRI CES,

- —

"■ “

PHILA.

?

FACTORY EMPLOYMENT, DIS T.

(1957-1959- 1D
O
)

:

SU M M ARY

Third Federal
Reserve District

United States

Per cent change

Per cent change

April 1967
from
mo.
ago

MANUFACTURING
Production .....................
Electric power consumed
Man-hours, total* ........
Employment, total .........
Wage income* .............
CONSTRUCTION** ...........
COAL PRODUCTION .........
BANKING
(All member banks)
Deposits .........................
Loans ............................
Investments....................
U.S. Govt, securities ....
Other ............................
Check payments***........

APR.
1967

YEAR
AGO

2 YEARS A G O
•Discontinued.

year
ago

4
mos.
1967
from
year
ago

April 1967
from
mo.
ago

o
-

3
0
0
0
+ 16
+ 19

+
+
+
+
+

PRICES
Wholesale.......................
Consumer .......................

2
3
1
2
4
3t

+
+
+
+
+

+
+
+
+

4
2
2
3
6
5

+ 31

+ 1

LO C A L
C H A N G ES
Standard
Metropolitan
Statistical
Areas*

Banking

Employ­
ment

Payrolls

Check
Payments**

Per cent
change
April 1967
from

Per cent
change
April 1967
from

Per cent
change
April 1967
from

Per cent
change
April 1967
from

year
ago

mo.
ago

year
ago

mo.
ago

year
ago

+ 1

+ 2

+ 1

_ 2

-1 2

mo.
ago

year
ago

+ 1

+ 1

mo.
ago
0

Atlantic City ...
- 1
+ 9

2
1
0
4
4
4

0
0

-1 3
+47

+
+
+
+
+
+

6
6
8
2
15
12

0
+ 2

Total
Deposits***

+ 3
Wilmington ....

7 + 6 +
10 + 10 +
5 + 2
4 — 6 16 + 11 +
101 + 8f +

0* + 2f

‘ Production workers only
“ Value of contracts
‘ “ Adjusted for seasonal variation




+ 1
- 1
+ 1
+ 2
-1 6
+58

year
ago

4
mos.
1967
from
year
ago

Manufacturing

-1 1
+ 11

+ 6
+ 7
+ 5
0
+ 12
+ 12

+ 1
+ 3

fl5 SMSA's
^Philadelphia

Trenton ........

+ 3

-

4

Altoona .........

— 1

0

Harrisburg ....

— 2

+ 4

Johnstown ....

0

Lancaster .......

0

Lehigh Valley

0

-

Philadelphia ....

0
1

— 2

Reading ........

-

-

+ 3
+ 4
-

2

-

4

3

-2 3

0
+ 4

1

+ 8

+ 3

+ 16

-

0

0

+ 9

0

+ 8

+ 12

+ 3

+ 12

+ 2

+ 9

+ 1

+ 3
+ 1
+ 2

+ 6

1

— 6

— 2

0

— 1

— 2

+ 4
0

1

+ 1

+ 1

+ 5

+ 3

+ 1

0

+ 3

+ 6

+ 14

+ 1

— 12

-

-

1

+ 1

2

+ 2
+ 2

+ 8
+ 5
+ 10
-4 0

Scranton ........

-

1

+ 3

0

+ 13

+ 2

+ 3

+ 1

+ 7

Wilkes-Barre ...

+

-2

0

+ 4

+ 10

+ 4

+ 14

+ 8

York .............

-

1

+ 4

-2

+ 10

+ 4

+ 19

+ 2
+ 1

+ 5

‘ Not restricted to corporate limits of cities but covers areas of one
or more counties.
“ All commercial banks. Adjusted for seasonal variation.
‘ “ Member banks only. Last Wednesday of the month.