View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Business
Review
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
July-August 1991




ISSN 0007-7011

Business
Review

The BUSINESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. It is
edited by Patricia Egner. Artwork is designed
and produced by Dianne Hallowell under the
direction of Ronald B. Williams. The views
expressed here are not necessarily those of this
Reserve Bank or of the Federal Reserve System.
SUBSCRIPTIONS. Single-copy subscriptions
for individuals are available without charge. Insti­
tutional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
BACK ISSUES. Back issues are available free of
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may
order up to 50 copies by submitting requests on
institutional letterhead; other orders are limited to 1
copy per request. Microform copies are available for
purchase from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb
Road, Ann Arbor, MI 48106.
REPRO D U CTIO N . Perm ission must be
obtained to reprint portions of articles or whole
articles. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.
Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes of address, and requests to reprint to
Publications, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Department of Research, Ten Independence Mall,
Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574, or telephone (215)
574-6428. Please direct editorial communications
to the same address, or telephone (215) 574-3805.

Digitized for 2FRASER


JULY/AUGUST 1991

IS ACCESS TO CENTER CITY
STILL VALUABLE?
Richard Voith
If "location, location, location" is really all
that important to house values, then what
makes one residential location more at­
tractive than another? One answer is
accessibility to jobs, shopping, and
recreation—amenities usually found in
the downtown of a city. But with subur­
ban employment and shopping centers
proliferating, is access to center city still
as valuable as it used to be?

LESSONS ON LENDING AND
BORROWING IN HARD TIMES
Leonard I. Nakamura
Problem loans and highly leveraged trans­
actions have brought home a truth about
lending that is easily forgotten in good
times: loans sometimes fail, with sad con­
sequences for both borrower and lender.
In truth, seizing the collateral of insolvent
debtors often harms the lender as much as
the borrower. How can lenders ensure
repayment by borrowers and yet avoid
being too conservative in hard times?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is Access to Center City
Still Valuable?
Richard Voith*
1 he old real estate adage—that the three
most important factors in house value are "lo­
cation, location, and location"—may be an ex­
aggeration. Nevertheless, prices for similar
houses vary greatly within metropolitan areas
and even more so across metropolitan areas.
What makes one location more attractive than
another?
Some studies have emphasized amenities
and the efficiency of local government as im­
portant determinants of where people choose
^Richard Voith is a Senior Economist in the Urban and
Regional Section of the Philadelphia Fed's Research Depart­
ment.




to live and how much their houses are worth.
Another major factor, however, is accessibility
to employment, shopping, and recreation. And
because people prefer to live in neighborhoods
convenient to employment and everyday ac­
tivities, houses in these areas command higher
prices.
Although we often hear about "accessible"
neighborhoods, accessibility is not an easy thing
to measure. Before the rapid growth of the
suburbs, a city's central business district (CBD)
was the focal point of a region's economic
activity. Accordingly, economists' early mod­
els of residential location tended to define ac­
cessibility in terms of distance from the CBD.
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

But suburbanization changed all that, requir­
ing us to reconsider what makes one location
more accessible than another.
Since people can work, shop, and find enter­
tainment in any number of employment cen­
ters, a neighborhood's accessibility depends
not just on how close it is to those various
centers, but on the quality of transportation to
and from them. Even if close to an employment
center, a residential area may not be perceived
as accessible if transportation to that center is
poor. Another complicating factor is that dif­
ferent neighborhoods may be convenient to
employment and recreation centers that are not
equally attractive. A house within easy com­
mute to a center with a large number of highwage jobs is likely to be more valuable than a
house nearby a center with relatively low wages.
And since a locale's accessibility and nearby
attractions may be greatly affected by eco­
nomic development and transportation poli­
cies, it is important to know how much acces­
sibility affects people's location choices.
EARLY MODELS
OF RESIDENTIAL LOCATION
Urban economists first addressed how ac­
cessibility influences residential locations and
land values by making some simplifying as­
sumptions. The most important was that busi­
nesses concentrated in the CBD because being
close to one another increased productivity.1
These productivity increases associated with a
CBD location were termed "agglomeration
economies."2 The only concentration of em­

'For a detailed discussion of the monocentric model, see
Edwin S. Mills, "An Aggregative Model of Resource Alloca­
tion in a Metropolitan Area," American Economic Review 47
(1967) pp. 197-210, or Richard F. Muth, Cities and Housing:
The Spatial Pattern o f Urban Residential Land Use (University
of Chicago Press, 1969).
2See Gerald Carlino, "Productivity in Cities: Does City
Size Matter?" this Business Review (November/December


4


JULY/AUGUST 1991

ployment was in the CBD, giving rise to the
term "monocentric region." Other common
assumptions were that transportation costs per
mile to the CBD were equal from anywhere
within the metropolitan area, and that only
transportation costs for work trips were impor­
tant. These assumptions implied that the travel
costs associated with any location were deter­
mined solely by its distance to the CBD.
Given these assumptions, economists ana­
lyzed how people trade off commuting costs
with what they are willing to pay for housing.
They drew three conclusions: 1) the value of
land should fall as distance from the CBD
increases; 2) population density should fall as
distance from the CBD increases; and 3) people
choose residential locations that minimize total
commute time in the region.
Not surprisingly, the monocentric model
predicts higher prices for land close to the CBD,
which in turn leads to higher house prices for
otherwise identical houses. Consumers can
avoid some of the costs of commuting by living
closer to the CBD, but in doing so, they bid up
the prices of houses such that the higher house
price just offsets the commuting savings. A
direct consequence is higher land costs for
locales closer to the CBD and lower land costs
for more distant locations. Accordingly, people
living closer to the CBD own smaller houses
than residents of more distant, less expensive
areas. This leads to the second major conclu­
sion of the monocentric model— that popula­
tion density declines with distance from the
CBD. Finally, the predicted pattern of declin­
ing house prices and less density with distance
from the CBD results in the optimal amount of

1987). This assumption did not preclude employment scat­
tered in the suburban areas. Of course, the downside of
agglomeration is congestion, and if a locale becomes too
congested, productivity may decline. Firms locating out­
side the CBD forfeit the agglomeration economies, but could
realize a benefit by lowering their workers' commuting
costs, allowing the suburban firms to offer a lower wage.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is Access to Center City Still Valuable?

commuting. That is, given house prices and
commuting costs, no two households could
exchange locations and both be better off.
How do these predictions correspond to the
real world? Although there is evidence that
residential density declines with distance from
the CBD, there is little consistent evidence that
house values fall as well.3 Also, residential
distances from the CBD and the associated
level of com m uting predicted by the
monocentric model are much lower than that
actually observed. In other words, people tend
to live farther away from the CBD than would
be expected given the trade-off between house
prices and commuting costs to the CBD. Some
authors argue there is a great deal of "wasteful"
commuting, suggesting that the underlying
notion that people make residential-location
decisions based on a trade-off between com­
muting and housing costs is fundamentally
flawed.4 After all, people may want to be near
amenities not available in the CBD and thus
may be willing to pay more to locate farther
from the CBD. Others suggest that the concept
is correct, but that the assumptions about the
metropolitan areas are wrong.5

3The density predictions are consistent with the
monocentric model, since much of the housing stock in
older cities was constructed when the model's assumptions
were more consistent with the actual metropolitan struc­
ture. House prices can adjust much faster than the stock of
housing, so the failure of the monocentric model should be
observed first in its predictions regarding prices. Examples
of recent studies finding either a positive relationship or no
relationship between distance from the CBD and house
value include D.M. Blackley and J.R. Follain, "Tests of
Locational Equilibrium in the Standard Urban Model,"
Land Economics 63 (1987) pp. 46-61; M.L. Cropper and P.L.
Gordon, "Wasteful Commuting: A Re-examination," Jour­
nal o f Urban Economics 29 (1991) pp. 2-13; and E.J. Heikkila et
al., "What Happened to the CBD-Distance Gradient? Val­
ues in a Poly-centric City," Environment and Planning 21
(1989) pp. 221-32.
4Bruce W. Hamilton, "Wasteful Commuting," Journal of
Political Economy 90 (1982) pp. 1035-53.




Richard Voith

IMPROVING THE SIMPLIFIED MODEL
Though the monocentric model is a useful
starting point for examining residential-loca­
tion choices, its basic assumptions are less real­
istic today than when the model was first pro­
posed. Most metropolitan areas have not just
a CBD but many suburban employment cen­
ters, and these centers can differ from the CBD
in several ways. High-quality automobile trans­
portation to suburban centers is almost univer­
sally available, while public transportation to
these centers is poor at best. Generally depen­
dent on the automobile for access, these centers
are less dense in their development, which
lowers their potential for agglomeration econo­
mies. On the other hand, most CBDs are
accessible by public transportation and by au­
tomobile, though usually at a higher cost than
are the suburban sites. Public transportation
allows higher-density development in the CBD
than in most suburban centers, increasing the
potential for agglomeration economies. Though
most suburban neighborhoods have high-qual­
ity auto access to suburban employment cen­
ters, not all have high-quality public transpor­
tation to the CBD.
More complicated models that consider sub­
urban employment centers and differences in
public transportation services do not lead to
simple conclusions about the relationship be­
tween distance from the CBD and house value
and residential density. These models predict
that people "sort" themselves into residential
communities that are convenient to specific
employment locations. Communities conve­
nient to an employment center—the CBD, for
example— should have a disproportionately
high percentage of their residents working in
that center. Over time, this sorting process
should result in people choosing employment

5See, for example, Michelle J. White, "Urban Commut­
ing Journeys Are Not 'W asteful,'" Journal of Political Economy
96 (1988a) pp. 1097-110.

5

BUSINESS REVIEW

and residential locations that minimize the
region's total commuting burden. Recent stud­
ies provide strong evidence for this sorting
behavior. In fact, if differences in the quality of
the transportation system and the multicentered
nature of regions are taken into account, there
is little evidence of "wasteful" commuting.6
But what are the implications for house
values? Certainly house prices are no longer
strictly linked to their distance from the CBD.
Since there are many smaller, similar suburban
employment centers, all with relatively good
highways and parking, a suburban residential
location is likely to be convenient to at least one
employment center. A house far from the CBD
may not be highly valuable to a CBD worker,
but it might be highly attractive to a suburban
worker. Though one might expect some differ­
ences in house prices based on distances from
suburban centers, these differences are likely to
be small and difficult to observe, requiring
detailed geographic and transportation data
that are seldom available.
Still likely, though, is that higher house val­
ues would be observed for locations having
commuting advantages to high-wage employ­
ment centers not duplicated elsewhere.7 One
such advantage is the availability of high-qual­
ity public transportation to the CBD. If the CBD
has higher-wage employment, differences in
the availability and quality of public transpor­
tation across suburban neighborhoods could
cause differences in suburban house values. In
communities with good public transportation,
higher house values should go hand in hand
with a greater fraction of the labor force em-

^ e e White (1988a).
7Note that higher wages can be sustained only if the
employment center is more productive. Frequently, this
higher productivity depends on the employment center's
accessibility to a large, high-quality labor force and agglom­
eration economies associated with concentrations of busi­
nesses.

Digitized for6 FRASER


JULY/AUGUST 1991

ployed in the CBD and with lower auto owner­
ship, as people substitute public transportation
for cars.
The extent of residential sorting is important
to consider when evaluating policy changes
that affect accessibility. Policymakers should
take into account not only how a policy change
would affect the existing population, but also
w hat changes in p opu lation the p olicy w ould

induce. A policy that dramatically affects the
accessibility of a residential area or the produc­
tivity of a commercial area could have much
larger impacts than expected.
For example, suppose a public transit au­
thority alters its prices or service quality. This
will immediately change the demand for its
services and ultimately affect accessibility as
well. Over time, people will decide to relocate,
which magnifies the initial impact of the policy.
These sorting impacts may be larger than the
direct im pacts, even tu ally affectin g a
community's size and house values.8
THE PHILADELPHIA EXAMPLE
The Philadelphia metropolitan area is an
excellent case study for examining the issues
raised by urban models. The Philadelphia
region, having multiple employment centers, is
fairly decentralized, yet it has a large CBD that
has grown along with the suburban subcenters
in the 1980s.9 The location and commuting

8For example, Richard Voith, in "The Long-Run Elastic­
ity of Demand for Commuter Rail Transportation," Journal
o f Urban Economics (1991), has estimated that the long-term
effects on transportation demand of changing price and
quality can be more than twice as large as the short-term
effects. A highly readable discussion of these issues is
provided by Voith in "Commuter Rail Ridership: The Long
and the Short Haul," this Business Review (November/December 1987).
9The Philadelphia CBD is defined as the area bounded
by the Schuylkill and Delaware rivers and Vine and South
streets.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is Access to Center City Still Valuable?

patterns were examined for evidence of sorting
and its effects on residential location, car own­
ership, and house values.10 Though general
evidence is provided on the importance of
sorting throughout the metropolitan area, the
focus is on where CBD workers live, the role of
the suburban commuter rail system in their
choice of neighborhood, and the system's ef­
fects on car ownership and house values.11
Geography and Transportation. Accord­
ing to the 1980 Census, about 55 percent of the
2.2 million people in the Philadelphia metro­
politan area labor force lived in the suburban
Pennsylvania counties of Bucks, Chester, Dela­
ware, and Montgomery and in Camden County,
New Jersey.12 The extent of employment decen­
tralization in the region is evident. Only 4.6
percent of the suburban labor force works in the
CBD, and fully 17 percent of the suburban
census tracts have no residents working in the
CBD. Still, the CBD has maintained its impor­
tance in the regional economy. Some suburban
census tracts have as many as 22 percent of their
labor force working in the CBD. The CBD's
share of the region's total employment has been
almost constant at 10 percent in the years from
1976 to 1986. However, while suburban em­
ployment grew tremendously over the period,
the rest of the city did not prosper.13

10See Richard Voith, "Transportation, Sorting, and House
Values in the Philadelphia Metropolitan Area," Journal of
the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association
(forthcoming), for a detailed description of the analysis.
1’The analysis is based on 1980 Census data. These data
are still useful because the issues examined reflect long-run
location choices. The factors affecting these choices, espe­
cially the transportation system and the CBD's relative
importance to the region, have changed little in the last 10
years.
12The Philadelphia metropolitan area also includes
Burlington and Gloucester counties in New Jersey. We did
not examine these counties because they do not have com­
muter rail service.




Richard Voith

The transportation system in the Philadel­
phia area has not changed dramatically in the
last 20 years, though the highway system has
improved progressively. But these improve­
ments have barely kept pace with the increase
in auto travel due to the region's decentraliza­
tion.
The commuter rail system, now operated by
the Southeastern Pennsylvania Transportation
Authority (SEPTA), has been a fixture on the
Pennsylvania side of the Philadelphia region
for most of the century. The Port Authority of
Pennsylvania and New Jersey (PATCO) has
provided commuter rail service in Camden
County, New Jersey, since 1968. The primary
function of both systems is to bring suburban
commuters to downtown Philadelphia. De­
spite recent interest in "reverse commuting,"
these systems are generally not competitive
with the automobile for commuting to subur­
ban employment. With 137 stations combined,
they provide service to a large number of sub­
urban communities. Over 42 percent of the
suburban census tracts have access to com­
muter rail transportation (Figure 1), but the
quality of commuter rail service differs consid­
erably across communities.
How Long Do Philadelphians Commute to
Work? A powerful piece of evidence for sort­
ing in the Philadelphia region is that average
reported commuting times differ very little
across residential locations.14 People have the
opportunity to work at an employment center

13See Anita Summers and Peter D. Linneman, "Patterns
and Processes of Urban Employment Decentralization in
the U.S., 1976-1986," Wharton Real Estate Center Working
Paper 75, University of Pennsylvania (1990). CBD employ­
ment grew about 10.5 percent, but overall employment in
the city of Philadelphia fell over 6 percent. Suburban
employment rose 33 percent.
14The commuting data are based on the 1980 U.S. Cen­
sus.

7

JULY/AUGUST 1991

BUSINESS REVIEW

FIGURE 1

Commuter Rail Transportation in the Delaware Valley
Quakertown
BUCKS
COUNTY

Doylestown

Pottstown

Newtown
>ter

Lansdali

CHESTER
COUNTY

West Trenton
Trenton

Norristown

BURLINGTON
COUNTY
DELAWARE

Marcus Hook
Wilmington

Lindenwold
GLOUCESTER
COUNTY

CAMDEN
COUNTY

Note: Dashed lines indicate services discontinued since 1980.

that is relatively close, regardless of how far
their house is from the CBD, and they choose to
do so. People in tracts far from the CBD tend to
commute the same amount of time as those
close to the CBD. Average commute time in the
region is about 23 minutes; this figure is re­
markably consistent across counties, ranging
from a low of 22 minutes in Chester and Mont­
gomery counties to a high of 25 minutes in
Delaware County (Figure 2). This contrasts
with the dramatic differences in highway com­
mute times to the CBD across counties, which
vary from a low of 36 minutes in Camden
County to a high of 77 minutes in Chester
County. Even though the average highway
commute time from Chester County to the CBD
Digitized for
8 FRASER


is more than twice that of Camden County,
residents of Chester and Camden counties
spend nearly the same average time commut­
ing. It appears that people choose to live in
locations relatively close to their work places,
and that virtually all suburban residential loca­
tions are convenient to at least some form of
employment.
Where CBD Workers Live. Since people
choose to live close to their jobs or to seek jobs
close to their homes, those having jobs in the
CBD should be concentrated in areas from
which CBD commuting is relatively less costly.
For any location, the greater its accessibility to
the CBD, the higher the fraction of its residents
that should work in the CBD. And more resiFEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is Access to Center City Still Valuable?

dents will work in the
CBD if the community's
accessibility to other
work sites is poor.
Highway commute
time to the CBD is one
important factor affect­
ing a neighborhood's
convenience to the CBD
and hence its attraction
for CBD workers. A
look at where suburban­
ites work shows how
strongly highway com­
muting time influences
th eir n eighborhood
choice (Figure 3). The
fraction of people work­
ing in the CBD declines
dramatically with high­
way commute time. For
example, the percentage
of M erion resid en ts
working in the CBD,
with Merion being just
a 25-minute drive from
the CBD, is 2.9 times as
large as the percentage
of workers coming from
Paoli, which is 61 min­
utes away by car.
Some differences in
the percentage of work­
ers em ployed in the
CBD may result from
differences in accessibil­
ity to other work sites
rather than in travel time
to the CBD. Consider
two communities, both
with equal commute
times to the CBD; if one
has higher average com­
mute times for all com­
mutes, including those



Richard Voith

FIGURE 2

Average Commute Times by County and
Highway Commute Time to the CBD
Minutes

Bucks

Chester

Delaware

Montgomery

Camden

Source: Average commute time is published by the U.S. Commerce Department's
Bureau of the Census. Highway commute time is compiled by the Delaware Valley
Planning Commission.

FIGURE 3

Percent of the Suburban Labor Force
Working in the CBD and Highway Commute
Time to the CBD
Percent Labor Force
Working in CBD

Minutes to CBD

Source: Based on data from the U.S. Census (1980) and the Delaware Valley Planning
Commission.

9

BUSINESS REVIEW

outside the CBD, then that locale must have
relatively worse accessibility to the non-CBD
employment centers. The data suggest that for
two communities with equal access to the CBD,
increasing travel time to non-CBD employ­
ment centers by five minutes increases the
percentage working in the CBD by 46 percent.
For Philadelphia-area commuters, the rail
system is an important alternative to the auto­
mobile. A major difference between the rail
system and the highway system, however, is
that only some communities have access to the
rail system, and it essentially serves only one
employment destination—the CBD. Not sur­
prisingly, for suburban communities with train
service,15the fraction of the labor force working
in the CBD (5.3 percent) is 29 percent higher
than for census tracts without service (4.1 per­
cent). Part of this difference results from the
fact that tracts with service tend to be closer to
the city. But even with other factors held
constant, the fraction of CBD workers living in
census tracts with service is 15 percent higher.
The availability of the commuter train also
results in fewer purchases of automobiles, even
for households of equal income. Households in
census tracts with train service own 4.5 percent
fewer cars, on average. While this figure ap­
pears small, it actually is quite significant con­
sidering that only 5.3 percent of the labor force
in these tracts commutes to the CBD. Assum­
ing that train service is irrelevant for 90 percent
of the people in a given census tract (and hence
should not affect car ownership), the 4.5 per­
cent reduction overall implies a household carownership rate for the remaining 10 percent of
only 0.97 cars per household, about 60 percent
of the average car-ownership rate.
Housing Prices and the Commuter Rail
System. Does sorting into residential locations

15The designations "with service" and "without ser­
vice" refer not to the communities themselves, but to resi­
dences having rail stations in or nearby their census tracts.


10


JULY/AUGUST 1991

convenient to work result in higher house prices
in neighborhoods with greater accessibility? In
particular, are people willing to pay a premium
to live in residential neighborhoods that have
commuter rail service to the CBD?
Median house values in each of the 678
census tracts in the Philadelphia metropolitan
area were compared using statistical techniques
to adjust for differences in housing quality.16
There was some evidence that houses tend to be
more expensive the farther they are from the
CBD, contrary to the pred iction of the
monocentric urban model.17 But consistent
with the idea that most suburban communities
are convenient to at least one suburban em­
ployment center was the finding that average
commute times are unrelated to house value.
This is not surprising, since sorting has resulted
in similar commuting times throughout the
region.
Even though house prices tend to increase
with distance from the CBD and most residen­
tial locations are equally convenient to some
suburban employment, the accessibility to the
CBD provided by the commuter rail systems
generates significant house value premiums
for residents in neighborhoods with service. In
fact, if we hold constant other factors, such as
highway accessibility and house quality, houses
in areas with train service enjoy premiums of
6.4 percent over those without service. This

16A linear regression model was used in which median
house value was the dependent variable. House value was
a function of its accessibility to the CBD by auto and by train,
as well as to other employment centers. Since the theory is
developed in terms of a standard unit of housing, character­
istics of the housing and neighborhood are included in the
regression to control for differences in attractiveness that
are unrelated to accessibility across tracts.
17House prices may be higher for more distant houses
partly because of larger lots. Unfortunately, data on lot
sizes are not available.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is Access to Center City Still Valuable?

Richard Voith

implies a premium of
FIGURE 4
$5,594 for train ser­
vice.18
House-Value Premiums
The house-value
for Commuter Rail Service
premium associated
with train service can
$ House Value
be used to calculate a
net increase in real
estate values associ­
ated with the com­
muter rail system. A
to tal of 258,437
o w n e r-o c c u p ie d
houses are in census
tracts with train ser­
vice. This implies
that the increase in
suburban value asso­
Entire Region
SEPTA (PA)
PATCO (NJ)
ciated with the train
service is about $1.45
billion.19
Source: Based on data from the U.S. Census (1980) and the Delaware Valley Planning
Service Quality
Commission.
and House Values.
If people are willing
The higher-quality PATCO service has a
to pay a premium to live in an area with train
service, they would likely be willing to pay much larger positive effect on house values
even more for higher-quality train service. Once than the SEPTA service (Figure 4). The pre­
again, Philadelphia provides a natural test for mium of $6,706 in New Jersey is 10.1 percent of
this hypothesis. The two commuter rail sys­ the average house price in Camden County.
tem s servin g the CBD— SEPTA and The $3,437 premium for the Pennsylvania coun­
PATCO—are very different. PATCO service ties, where the average price of a home is higher
is, on average, five times as frequent as than in New Jersey, is 3.8 percent of the average
SEPTA's. Furthermore, PATCO enjoys a greater house price. Because these two systems serve
time advantage, relative to the automobile, the same destination, the difference in premi­
than SEPTA. Thus, PATCO generally provides ums very likely reflects consumers' willingness
to pay for higher-quality transportation.20
higher-quality service.

1^ h e figures, in 1990 dollars, are based on prices in 1980,
inflated by the U.S. Consumer Price Index.
19This assumes that increases in value near stations are
not offset by decreases in areas far from stations. Also, about
one-third of all riders on the system reside within the city
limits; any premiums associated with housing within the
city are not included in the figures.




CONCLUSION
Even in a region with multiple employment

20The difference in premiums could also reflect price
differences between the two services. Additionally, the
PATCO impacts may be magnified by the lack of alternative
employment centers in Camden County.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

centers, access to the CBD remains valuable to
suburban residents. A high-quality, CBD-oriented public transportation system can affect
suburban residents' choice of neighborhood,
the number of cars they buy, and the value of
their houses. The house-value premiums asso­
ciated with the transportation service can be
sustained, however, only if service quality is
m aintained or enhanced , and if the CBD retains
a productive advantage over other employ­
ment centers.
The productivity of the CBD is not indepen­
dent of the transportation system, as an attrac­
tion of the CBD is its accessibility to a wide
labor pool. However, if other factors—such as
local taxes, poor services, or crime— reduce the
CBD's attractiveness, the real estate premiums
associated with the commuter rail system are


12


JULY/AUGUST 1991

likely to diminish. Additionally, increases in
train-service quality are likely to increase housevalue premiums, while eroding service quality
will likely have the opposite effect over time.
In the Philadelphia area, these effects can be
large, as indicated by the estimated $1.45 bil­
lion premium on suburban real estate values
associated with commuter train service. At a
d iscount rate of 10 percent, su burban resid ents
with train service would enjoy positive finan­
cial benefits even if they paid up to $145 million
a year to support the two rail systems that serve
Philadelphia's CBD. This estimate suggests
that, despite the region's increasing decentrali­
zation, over 40 percent of the metropolitan
area's suburban residents have a direct interest
in the quality of public transportation and the
economic health of the CBD.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Lessons on Lending and Borrowing
in Hard Times
p
X roblem loans and highly leveraged trans­
actions have brought home a truth about lend­
ing that is easily forgotten in good times: loans
sometimes fail, with sad consequences for both
borrower and lender. Many existing loans
have soured, causing lenders to tighten credit
terms on new lending. Meanwhile, borrowers
have complained— and policymakers have
openly worried—that lenders are refusing
sound loans.

^Leonard I. Nakamura is a Senior Economist in the
Banking and Financial Markets Section of the Research
Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.




Leonard I. Nakamura*
New theories about lending and about loan
contracts emphasize the difficulties lenders face
in ensuring repayment of their loans. Accord­
ing to these theories, the collateral for a loan is
not just a back-up source of repayment if the
borrower defaults; collateral is also crucial for
inducing payments from borrowers who can
make them.
Cash-strapped borrowers, when their busi­
nesses sour, will often try to put off lenders and
keep paying their employees, suppliers, and
landlords. In response, lenders will threaten to
seize collateral and declare loans in default to
ensure they get their fair share of a distressed
borrower's cash flows.
13

BUSINESS REVIEW

This threat is a blunt instrument that often
harms the lender as much as the borrower.
After all, the value of the borrower's collateral,
particularly during a recession, may be insuffi­
cient to repay the loan. But there are other
considerations, as well. A foreclosure causes
valuable resources to be lost that would not be
lost otherwise. Management may lose partial
control over the firm becau se of bank ru p tcy
rules, or spend too much time in court, strug­
gling against creditors and other claimants,
and too little time running the business. Cus­
tomer relationships inevitably worsen as cus­
tomers begin looking for alternative suppliers.
And ultimately, if an otherwise viable bor­
rower is liquidated, valuable relationships be­
tween management, employees, and custom­
ers are lost.
If a borrower's business is fundamentally
sound, its longer-term profitability ought to be
the best source to repay the loan. But if the
lender forces the borrower out of business, this
source of funds is lost.
THE DILEMMA OF FORECLOSURE
In the tale of the goose that laid the golden
eggs, the owner foolishly tried to get the goose's
prized eggs more quickly by killing it. Lenders
are not so unwise; still, they might have to
threaten foreclosure as a way to force borrow­
ers to repay. When lenders must carry out their
threats, they kill the golden goose—and this is
the dilemma of foreclosure.
Unfortunately, standard economic theory
had assumed away this dilemma, maintaining
that the interests of borrowers and lenders
could always be aligned through loan agree­
ments. Consequently, economists believed that
inefficiencies associated with loan default were
small and that liquidation decisions were al­
ways sound. After all, wasn't it true that only
firms having no value as going concerns were
liquidated?
More recent theories offer less optimistic
conclusions about lending. They show that
Digitized for
14FRASER


JULY/AUGUST 1991

firms having value as going concerns may well
be liquidated and that inefficiencies associated
with loan default can have important conse­
quences for aggregate economic activity. In
particular, the implication is that some loans
that would ordinarily be made in good times
would not be made in uncertain times. These
newer theories are more realistic about the
potential for conflicts betw een b o rro w er and

lender; accordingly, they are useful guides—to
all parties—for anticipating, and thereby less­
ening, the pain associated with hard economic
times.
Two theories in particular have emphasized
the importance, and difficulty, of maintaining
the borrower's incentive to repay. The idea is
disarmingly simple: if given a choice of how
much to repay, a borrower who wishes to
maximize profits will always choose to repay
the smallest amount. One theory, originated by
Robert Townsend,1 underscores the lender's
ignorance, relative to the borrower, of the
borrower's net worth. The other theory, origi­
nated by Oliver Hart and John Moore,2*empha­
sizes the borrower's control over cash flows
(the revenues that flow to the borrower from
sales of products and services).
TOWNSEND: LOAN CONTRACTS
REDUCE INFORMATION COSTS
Townsend's model stresses the cost to inves­
tors of obtaining financial information about
borrowers. Before granting a loan, outside
financial investors must first obtain detailed
information about the firms seeking finance.
This information extends to the firm's products
and services, the customer base, marketing

R o bert M. Townsend, "Optimal Contracts and Com­
petitive Markets With Costly State Verification," Journal of
Economic Theory 21 (1979) pp. 265-93.
201iver Hart and John Moore, "Default and Renegotia­
tion: A Dynamic Model of Debt," MIT Working Paper
(August 1989).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Lessons on Lending and Borrowing in Hard Times

data, advertising plans, management, alterna­
tive financial resources, plant and equipment,
labor resources and costs—in short, a detailed
financial analysis and forecast. And until the
financing is actually in hand, the firm has a
strong incentive to provide investors with
satisfactory information.
But once the investment is made, the inves­
tors may not be well positioned to keep in­
formed about a firm's net worth. Information
gathering is a costly procedure, requiring, at a
minimum, an audit of current assets and liabili­
ties, an explanation of variances between
planned income and expenses and the results
achieved, and an evaluation of future profit
prospects.
The loan contract, according to Townsend,
minimizes this informational cost by specifying
a fixed dollar amount that the borrower agrees
to pay; as long as repayment is made, no further
financial investigation is required. If the bor­
rower fails to repay, however, the lender inves­
tigates the borrowing firm, learns of its net
worth, and seizes its assets up to the value of the
debt plus the cost of the investigation. A
solvent borrower will have a strong incentive
to repay, as long as the costly investigation
following default makes a solvent borrower
worse off. The loan contract thus minimizes the
cost of post-investment financial investigation
while preserving the incentive to repay.3
The Defaulting Borrower Pays a Penalty.

3Townsend's model can best be understood by compar­
ing the loan contract with a venture-capital contract, whereby
the investor expects to receive a share of the venture's net
worth. This financing contract repays the investor an amount
depending on the firm's net worth; if the investor is ignorant
of the firm's position, the owner, in an effort to minimize the
repayment, will likely claim that the firm has low net worth.
As a result, this type of contract requires the investor to
always know the firm's net worth— which is costly informa­
tion to obtain— and is likely only when the investor takes a
large stake in the firm and the venture shows potential for
substantial returns. Venture capitalists invest relatively
large stakes in small start-ups and follow them closely.




Leonard I. Nakamura

In practice, a borrower who fails to make timely
repayments faces the threat of loan foreclosure
and seizure of collateral. (See the box on p. 16
for a discussion of collateral.) Although the
borrowing firm can partially protect itself by
seeking bankruptcy protection, its business and
plans become subject to legal restrictions and
scrutiny by the lender. Such constraints, not to
mention the loss of reputation and goodwill
that bankruptcy may entail, can hurt the firm.
The key consequence of default, as required by
Townsend's theory, is that the borrower pays a
penalty:4 a loss of asset value. The penalty can
be imposed on borrowers through various
methods—loan workouts, liquidation, takeover
of the firm by an outside administrator acting
on behalf of creditors, or seizure and selling of
collateral. (The practical steps on the road to
liquidation are briefly defined in the box on p.
17.)
Let's take, as an example, an investment in a
fictitious computer chip manufacturer, Cus­
tom Chip. Custom Chip's value is only par­
tially its factory and inventory of materials and
chips; much of its value is its new ideas for chips.
Only an expert in the computer chip business
can know how much Custom Chip's value
increased—or decreased—in a given period.
One way to find out might be to auction off
Custom Chip's patents, its chip-design depart­
ment, and its manufacturing plant (as would
happen in a liquidation). But doing that would
destroy the firm.
If Custom Chip owes its lender $2 million,
then as long as the firm's true value is greater
than $2 million, the owners will have a strong
incentive to repay the debt rather than risk
having the firm thrust into bankruptcy. The

4For a precise specification of how the losses of collateral
associated with liquidation relate to the optimal debt con­
tract, see Jeffrey M. Lacker, "Collateralized Debt as the
Optimal Contract," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Working Paper 90-3 (March 1990).

15

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1991

bankruptcy.
The high cost of default is most obvious
when the lender seizes collateral. The collateral
is then no longer available to the borrower, who
was actively using it, and it goes to a lender, for
whom it has no direct use. The borrower loses
by not having use of the
collateral, which is often
Are You Sure It's Collateral?
necessary to doing busi­
Collateral may be any asset of the borrower. Physical assets would
ness. In addition, the
be land, plant, equipment, and inventory. Financial assets would
lender incurs costs in
include receivables (customers' promises to pay) and financial securi­
seizing, storing, and sell­
ties (stocks and bonds).
ing the collateral. And as
However, collateral is of value only to the extent that the lender can
the lender has no special
actually claim, seize, and dispose of it in the event of default. For most
expertise with the collat­
borrowers, collateral is property that is a functional part of the
eral, its value may dete­
business, and its value varies with the business's ups and down. Then
riorate further while in
there are other important assets—customer goodwill and other future
the lender's possession.
profit opportunities, for example— that are intangible and cannot be
used as collateral because the lender cannot seize and sell them.
Lender Must Carry
Establishing a clear claim to collateral is not always easy. Lenders
Out the T h reat.
In
must follow procedures, set forth in the Uniform Commercial Code,
Townsend's model, the
to ensure that their claim is valid. In essence, this requires clearly
story ends there. Once
identifying the collateral, making sure that no one else has a prior claim
default occurs, the lender
to it, and making public the lender's claim. This process is called
must carry through the
securing and perfecting collateral. If not crucial to the borrower's
threat of foreclosure and
business, the collateral may actually be held by the lender. However,
seize the collateral. Thus,
very often the collateral is integral to the borrower's business and
Townsend's theory pre­
cannot conveniently be held by the lender.
Numerous anecdotes attest to the problems that can arise with
dicts that costly bankrupt­
collateral. In one instance, the collateral was salad oil, held in vats.
cies will arise from the
When default occurred, the vats turned out to contain water with a thin
existence of debt con­
film of oil on top. In another instance, collateral was mineral rights and
tracts— and that firms
a car. But the borrower, it turned out, had never bought the mineral
having more value as go­
rights, and when the lender came to collect the car, he found that it had
ing
concerns than in liq­
already been sold.
uidation
may be liqui­
A cattle rancher pledged five steers as collateral for a loan, but none
dated solely because they
of the steers was specifically identified as such. Just before the rancher
defaulted, five steers left the herd and, caught in a lightning storm,
cannot pay their debts. If
sought shelter under a tree. The tree was struck by lightning and the
lenders chose instead to
five steers died. The rancher was able to argue successfully that the
renegotiate the terms of
bank's claim was to the five dead steers.
the loan, then borrowers
Collateral often deteriorates in value when the firm's lines of
would lose their incen­
business deteriorate. When oil prices slumped in 1986, drilling rigs fell
tive to repay. Unfortu­
in value. When retail sales slumped in 1990, the value of unsold
nately, by foreclosing on
merchandise declined along with them. If a firm's sales falter because
borrowers
who are po­
its customers are in financial straits, the firm's receivables will turn out
tentially viable, the lend­
to have little value.
ers may lose their best

threat of foreclosure enforces the loan repay­
ment and means that the lender need not pay
computer consultants to analyze Custom Chip's
value. However, if Custom Chip cannot or will
not repay the $2 million, the lender may have to
declare a default and thrust Custom Chip into




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Lessons on Lending and Borrowing in Hard Times

Leonard I. Nakamura

source of repayment: the borrower's value as cash flows and can always divert them from
investors by, say, using cash to pay workers
an ongoing business.
A partial parallel for the lender's dilemma and suppliers instead.
The only commitment entrepreneurs can
can be found in the famous Bible story about
King Solomon. The wise king was able to make is collateral—and lenders can seize col­
discern which of two women claiming to be a lateral if fixed payments are not made. This
baby's mother was telling the truth
when he threatened to cut the
The Road to Liquidation:
child in two. Similarly, the lender
must threaten to destroy the firm
Some Terminology
in order to learn the owners' true
assessment of its worth. In both
Bankruptcy - A debtor is afforded relief from its debt under
cases, the threat must be made in
the provisions of the Bankruptcy Code either through a
liquidation (Chapter 7 of the Code) or rehabilitation (Chapter
order to learn information. King
11 for commercial enterprises and Chapter 13 for individu­
Solomon, at least, had the advan­
als). In a liquidation proceeding, the assets are collected and
tage of knowing that his threat
distributed by a trustee. In a bankruptcy, lenders cannot
was only a th reat.
But in
seize assets or attempt to collect payments; secured lenders
Townsend's model, the lender
are entitled, eventually, to payments equal in value to their
may discover that the firm cannot
collateral, but unsecured lenders often receive little. Reha­
repay and that the threat will have
bilitation and emergence from bankruptcy proceedings typi­
to be carried out. And so, a tem­
cally involve the consent of creditors and equity holders.
porary cash shortage can result in
Collateral - Any property of the borrower that secures the
business failure when the lender
debt to a lender. In the event of default, a lender may seize
cannot verify that the borrower's
the borrower's collateral; in bankruptcy proceedings, a se­
problems are indeed temporary.
cured lender has first claim to proceeds from collateral.

HART AND MOORE:
COLLATERAL MAKES
RENEGOTIATION POSSIBLE
A more recent model, by Hart
and Moore, explores loan renego­
tiation as an alternative to liqui­
dating the firm. But unlike
Townsend's model, this one as­
sumes that investors have no dif­
ficulty maintaining good infor­
mation about borrowers—only
trouble controlling them contrac­
tually.
Hart and Moore assume that
investors and entrepreneurs be­
gin with the same information
and that they always learn new
in form ation sim u ltan eou sly.
However, entrepreneurs control



Default - A borrower's violation of the loan's terms. Failure
to make timely payments or to fulfill other terms, such as
providing timely and accurate financial data, constitutes a
default. The lender's response— foreclosure of the loan—
typically includes the right to demand full loan repayment
and the right to seize any collateral specified in the loan
contract.
Loan workout - A business plan by which a borrower tries to
resolve a problem loan. The business plan is typically an
agreement arrived at by the lender and the borrower in an
effort to avoid bankruptcy proceedings. Renegotiation of
loan payments is often a part of a loan workout.
Liquidation - The collection and disposal of a borrower's
assets.
Renegotiation - Resetting the terms of a loan contract, typi­
cally involving a delay of payments and often a reduction in
interest or principal.

17

BUSINESS REVIEW

collateral, however, is worth more when left in
the hands of the entrepreneur. And if collateral
falls in value, as often happens in recessions,
the lenders' ability to collect payment decreases.
This theory rests on the idea that the variety
of possible events that can affect a business is
simply too large and complex to be captured in
a contract. Moreover, as contract provisions
become more complicated, both writing and
interpreting the contract become increasingly
expensive. Lenders thus keep financial con­
tracts in a form as simple as possible in order to
enforce them at low cost. This allows them
control over specific types of collateral, but not
over details about cash flows.
By Hart and Moore's reasoning, the owner
of Custom Chip will repay the loan as long as
the manufacturing plant and inventory of com­
puter chips (as distinct from anticipated future
profits) remain valuable. However, if the plant
and inventory fall in value, the owner can
divert cash and ideas to start up a new firm,
defaulting on the original loan, even if current
cash flows would suffice to repay it.
Threat of Loss Enforces Repayment. An­
other example of the role collateral plays in
enforcing payment can be found in the mort­
gage market. Consider Robin House, who is
buying a $200,000 house with a 10 percent
down payment of $20,000; her debt is therefore
$180,000. Initially, the value of the collateral—
the house— exceeds the value of the debt by
$20,000. The threatened loss of home easily
enforces Robin's mortgage payments. But sup­
pose the housing market deteriorates and the
home falls in value to $150,000. If Robin values
her credit reputation (including assets the mort­
gage lender might be able to seize) at only
$20,000, she has an economic incentive to de­
fault on the mortgage: her debt exceeds the
value of the collateral plus bankruptcy cost.
She may refuse to make mortgage payments
even though she can afford them.
Borrowers who lose their incentive to repay
when their collateral falls in value frequently
Digitized for18
FRASER


JULY/AUGUST 1991

do default. It is also true that when borrowers
are unable to repay, their collateral is often low
in value—and both situations occur for the
same reason: a weak economic environment.
Consider inventory as collateral. When a firm
fails, its inventory will consist of those goods it
could not sell at close to the original price.
Loans that are overcollateralized when made
may be severely undercollateralized when fore­
closed on. Yet, this does not mean that the
collateral serves no purpose; indeed, it helps
ensure repayment during periods in which the
borrower can repay.
While lenders would prefer collateral with
an unshakable value, it is extremely hard to
find. Indeed, it is not always easy to put the
proper value on collateral in the first place.
Collateral may not be as difficult to evaluate as
the value of an ongoing concern, but it still may
not be straightforward. (See the box at right for
difficulties in determining how much the home
underlying a mortgage is worth.)
Collateral Is Key to Renegotiation. In Hart
and Moore's model, lenders can renegotiate a
loan instead of seizing collateral. In a renego­
tiation, lenders may allow payments to be
stretched out or even reduced so as to avoid the
losses from seizing collateral. But since only
collateral can enforce repayment, the lender
will be willing to do this only if the borrower
can offer immediate cash and future collateral
that are at least as good as what the lender can
gain through immediate seizure. If future col­
lateral is inadequate, the lender will foreclose
and a viable firm may be lost. Thus, renegotia­
tion only partially solves the dilemma.
Suppose Custom Chip is unable to repay a
loan during a period in which profit margins
decline because of a recession in the computer
industry. The lender has two options. One, it
could seize the plant and its inventory of chips.
Or two, it could renegotiate— permit Custom
Chip to stay in business, accept an incomplete
payment of the loan, accept the owner's beach
condo, say, for additional collateral, and agree
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Leonard I. Nakamura

Lessons on Lending and Borrowing in Hard Times

Who Assumes the Risk in Offers
to Pay Closing Costs?
Real estate ads sometimes include the come-on "Seller will pay
closing costs." This practice creates the innocent appearance of a
generous home seller helping the prospective buyer who otherwise
would have trouble making the down payment on the house. But is
this practice innocent from the perspective of the mortgage lender?
No, because the seller is really being generous with the lender's
money.
An offer to pay closing costs actually inflates the house's selling
price. To see this, consider a house priced by its owner at $100,000 but
whose true market value has fallen to $92,000. In method 1, the
standard method, the owner straightforwardly lowers the price by
$8,000, to $92,000. In method 2, the owner offers to pay the borrower
$8,000 up front by paying the buyer's closing costs.

House price
Down payment
Mortgage loan
Closing costs
Buyer puts up
Seller gets

Method 1
$92,000
$9,200
$82,800
$8,000
$17,200
$92,000

Method 2
$100,000
$10,000
$90,000
$8,000
$10,000
$92,000

The only difference in the bottom line is that the lender has loaned
$7,200 more to the borrower; in both cases, the seller winds up with
exactly the same amount of money. But suppose the house falls in
value by 10 percent, to $82,800. In the first case, the lender is fully
protected, and the borrower has no incentive to default on the
mortgage. But in the second case, the lender is likely to take a
substantial loss if the borrower defaults on the mortgage— and now
the borrower may have an incentive to default because the collateral
that the borrower loses is less than the debt the borrower would
otherwise have to pay.

to a partial write-down of the remaining debt.
However, if Custom Chip cannot come up with
some combination of current cash and future
collateral that is more valuable than existing
collateral, the lender will go with the first op­
tion and seize the collateral. So, in this case,
although Custom Chip might have a good
chance of substantial future earnings, it is un­
able to realize them because it cannot promise
the lender an adequate share of future earnings.
Renegotiations preserve the firm's value.



eral, with which

And loans that make re­
negotiation more possible
by preserving repayment
incentives are attractive
to borrowers as well as
lenders. In renegotiation,
loans in which borrowers
have uncom m itted re­
sources to offer the lender
are preferable to loans in
which borrowers have no
negotiating room. In the
Custom Chip example,
the fact that the owner's
beach condo can be put
up as collateral helps keep
the firm alive. If the owner
lacked this resource, re­
negotiation would be less
attractive to the lender.
In 1989, M ichael
fensen5argued that highly
leveraged transactions
would not result in bank­
ruptcies because lenders
would always be better
off renegotiating. In ret­
rospect, fensen's argu­
ment appears incorrect.
One reason may be that,
in many highly leveraged
transactions, the borrow­
ers had very little cash
margin, or extra collat­
to renegotiate.

LENDING DURING A RECESSION
Lenders' most difficult decisions are made
during recessions. For the prospective bor­
rower, access to additional financing may be

5Michael Jensen, "Is Leverage an Invitation to Bank­
ruptcy? On the Contrary— It Keeps Shaky Firms Out of
Court," Wall Street Journal, February 1,1989.

19

BUSINESS REVIEW

crucial to survival. But for the lender, recession
financing is treacherous. In recessions, the
probability of bad economic outcomes is higher
than at other times, and inefficient, costly bank­
ruptcies and liquidation are more likely.
Unless lenders have established procedures
for commanding cash flows from troubled bor­
rowers, they will be unable to lend profitably
during recessions, when cash flows become
more questionable. Collateral is crucial—both
as an ultimate source of repayment and as a
threat to command repayment. But in reces­
sions, collateral— unfortunately—becomes less
reliable.
Loan Contracts Are Less Efficient in Reces­
sions. According to both of the models just
discussed, firms with going-concern value may
be shut down if loan repayments cannot be
made. This is more likely to occur during
recessions, when demand falls and cash flows
dry up. As a consequence, loan contracts are
more likely to lead to inefficiency during bad
times than in good times, since bankruptcies
and liquidations are more likely. Thus, the
practice of making fewer loans in a weak
economy is consistent with these theories.
Several other points about lending during a
recession fall out of these models:
1. More collateral will be required to further
ensure repayment, although this makes borrowing
more difficult. During a recession, the increased
risk that collateral will fall in value means that
lenders will need larger amounts of it to main­
tain the borrower's incentive to repay. Inevita­
bly, more potential borrowers will find that
they lack the collateral necessary for the loan
they're seeking.
2. More documentation will be presented, and
past lender-borrower relationships will be more
important. Lenders should attempt to know
more about borrowers during recessions be­
cause default is more likely— and more
expensive— when lenders are relatively igno­
rant. This makes it doubly hard on borrowers
whose normal lenders themselves become cash



JULY/AUGUST 1991

constrained; for borrowers to exchange a lender
who knows them well for one who does not will
be expensive, if not impossible. Detailed and
accurate record-keeping may make the differ­
ence in whether new financing is obtained.
3.
Noncredit terms on loans will tighten. Tight­
ening noncredit terms for borrowers may make
it harder for them to qualify for loans, but at
least lenders will be able to continue making
profitable loans in hard times. For example, in
a weak real estate market, lenders should re­
quire higher down payments on mortgages
and be particularly wary of techniques home
sellers may use to foist greater risk on the
lender.
In addition, lenders may demand more cov­
enants to their loans. Loan covenants are legal
conditions added to the loan contract that per­
mit the lenders to declare loans in default.
Some covenants constrain managerial discre­
tion; others specify standards of continued
creditworthiness. Covenants increase the
lender's ability to seize collateral while it re­
tains much of its value.
RENEGOTIATION IN RECESSION
Hart and Moore's model also has implica­
tions for what borrowers and lenders can ex­
pect from loan renegotiations during a reces­
sion. The lender's purpose in renegotiating a
loan is to achieve new combinations of cash and
collateral that leave the lender better off than
under the previous agreement.6 For example, a
lender will write down an unsecured loan,

6This article assumes that a firm's lenders are acting in
concert. A natural tension between lenders often emerges in
loan renegotiations, and the presence of many independent
lenders may complicate renegotiation outside the frame­
work of bankruptcy court. A lender acting independently
should be cautious about infringing on the rights of other
lenders; indeed, obtaining a preference over other lenders
can be reversed if bankruptcy actually occurs. Worse yet, if
the borrower is viewed as being in a lender's control, that
lender may become liable to other lenders for the borrower's
debts.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Lessons on Lending and Borrowing in Hard Times

forgiving part of the debt to obtain collateral
and immediate cash under a new agreement.
Conversely, borrowers should realize that in
times of a weak economy, failure to repay a loan
is lik e lie r to have serious co n seq u en ­
ces— collateral may be seized, for example. In
assessing their possibilities for a successful
renegotiation, borrowers should review those
assets that may be used for cash and collateral.
Lenders are best off pushing for low-risk
operation of the firm. A debt-burdened bor­
rower has a strong incentive to divert funds at
the lender's expense.7 To counter this, the
lend er w ill— in what is called a "loan
workout"—actively negotiate the borrower's
business plan to maximize the probability of
receiving cash flows. In the loan workout, the
lender should push to err on the side of safety
and carefully monitor the borrower's expenses
and receipts to see whether the borrower is
adhering to plan. (A bank that handles a
borrower's transactions is often well positioned
to conduct a loan workout because it can best
observe the borrower's behavior.) Cutting costs
to conserve cash should almost always be part
of a workout plan. A borrower who must give
up something during renegotiation is less likely
to default frivolously.
Both parties to the renegotiation should rec­
ognize the fundamental importance of good
information. A strong relationship between
lender and borrower and full, open communi­
cation are crucial to sound loan renegotiations.
In a renegotiation, lenders often demand more
information than in the initial loan process.
Borrowers should recognize that, lacking good
information, lenders ought not to make conces­
sions in a renegotiation.

7See Leonard I. Nakamura, "Loan Workouts and Com­
mercial Bank Information: Why Banks Are Special," Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 89-11 (Febru­
ary 1989).




Leonard I. Nakamura

A final but crucial point following from the
logic of Hart and Moore's model is one more
pertinent to planning for the next recession
than surviving the current one. When embark­
ing on a relationship with a lender, borrowers
too often care only about the short term, believ­
ing that all will be fine if only the lender grants
the loan request. But borrowers ought to be
forward-thinking, too, and ask themselves
whether the lender will be helpful in hard times
or force them to turn elsewhere when loan
funds tighten generally. Just as lenders must
look for sound borrowers, so should borrowers
seek out sound lenders.
CONCLUSION
Recent theories on lending and the loan
contract build on the idea that borrowers may
lack adequate incentives to repay lenders. One
conclusion they share is that loan defaults can
have important economic consequences and
lead to the failure of otherwise viable busi­
nesses. Another conclusion is that noncredit
terms of loans can be expected to tighten in
recessions.
In a downturn, credit terms to new borrow­
ers normally tighten. The models attribute this
tightening to the inherent conflicts that inten­
sify between lender and borrower during re­
cessions. Consequently, lending becomes less
efficient and is more likely to lead to foreclo­
sures and real economic losses. By tightening
up lending practices, lenders may be able to
increase their confidence in repayment and
perhaps avoid being excessively conservative
in hard times. And by anticipating potential
credit problems, borrowers may be better able
to minimize them.
Tighter credit terms are unpleasant for the
borrower and may reduce the borrower's ac­
tivity from the original plan. But they may be
crucial for borrowing to continue in a tough
economic environment.

21

Philadelphia/RESEARCH
Working Papers
Institutions and libraries may request copies of the following working papers, written by our staff
economists and visiting scholars. Please send the number of the paper desired, along with your address, to
WORKING PAPERS, Department of Research, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 10 Independence Mall,
Philadelphia, PA 19106. For overseas airmail requests only, a $2.00 per copy prepayment is required; please
make checks or money orders payable (in U.S. funds) to the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
1990
No. 90-1

Gerald Carlino and Richard Voith, "Accounting for Differences in Aggregate State Productivity."

No. 90-2

Brian Cody and Leonard Mills, "The Role of Commodity Prices in Formulating Monetary
Policy."

No. 90-3

Loretta J. Mester, "Traditional and Nontraditional Banking: An Information-Theoretic Ap­
proach."

No. 90-4

Sherrill Shaffer, "Investing in Conflict."

No. 90-5/R

Sherrill Shaffer, "Immunizing Options Against Changes in Volatility."

No. 90-6

Gerald Carlino, Brian Cody, and Richard Voith, "Regional Impacts of Exchange Rate Move­
ments."

No. 90-7

Richard Voith, "Consumer Choice With State-Dependent Uncertainty About Product Quality:
Late Trains and Commuter Rail Ridership."

No. 90-8

Dean Croushore, "Ricardian Equivalence Under Income Uncertainty."

No. 90-9

Shagil Ahmed and Dean Croushore, "The Welfare Effects of Distortionary Taxation and
Government Spending: Some New Results."

No. 90-10

Joseph Gyourko and Richard Voith, "Local Market and National Components in House Price
Appreciation."

No. 90-11

Theodore M. Crone and Leonard O. Mills, "Forecasting Trends in the Housing Stock Using AgeSpecific Demographic Projections."

No. 90-12

William W. Lang and Leonard I. Nakamura, "Optimal Bank Closure for Deposit Insurers."

No. 90-13

Loretta J. Mester, "Perpetual Signaling With Imperfectly Correlated Costs." (Supersedes 89-22.)

No. 90-14

Sherrill Shaffer, "Aggregate Deposit Insurance Funding and Taxpayer Bailouts."

No. 90-15

Dean Croushore, "Taxation as Insurance Against Income Uncertainty."

No. 90-16/R Loretta J. Mester and Anthony Saunders, "When Does the Prime Rate Change?"
No. 90-17

James McAndrews and Richard Voith, "Regional Authorities, Public Services, and the Location
of Economic Activity."

No.
Digitized
for90-18
FRASERSherrill Shaffer, "A Test of Competition in Canadian Banking."


No. 90-19

Brian J. Cody, "Seignorage and the European Community: Is European Economic and Monetary
Union in Danger?"

No. 90-20

John F. Boschen and Leonard O. Mills, "The Role of Monetary and Real Shocks in NearPermanent Movements in GNP."

No. 90-21/R Mitchell Berlin and Loretta J. Mester, "Debt Covenants and Renegotiation."
No. 90-22

Richard Voith, "Transportation, Sorting, and House Values in the Philadelphia Metropolitan
Area."

No. 90-23

Gerald A. Carlino and Leonard O. Mills, "Persistence and Convergence in Relative Regional
Incomes."

No. 90-24

Sherrill Shaffer, "Stable Cartels With a Cournot Fringe."

No. 90-25

Ahmed Mohamed, "The Impact of Domestic Market Structure on Exchange Rate Pass-through."

No. 90-26

Loretta J. Mester and Anthony Saunders, "Who Changes the Prime Rate?"

No. 90-27

Sherrill Shaffer, "The Lerner Index, Welfare, and the Structure-Conduct-Performance Linkage."

No. 90-28

Sherrill Shaffer, "Regulation and Endogenous Contestability."

No. 90-29

Brian J. Cody, "Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies in Anticipation of a European Central
Bank."

No. 90-30

Leonard I. Nakamura, "Reforming Deposit Insurance When Banks Conduct Loan Workouts and
Runs Are Possible."
1991

No. 91- 1

Dean Croushore, "A Measure of Federal Reserve Credibility."

No. 91-2

James J. McAndrews and Leonard I. Nakamura, "Worker Debt With Bankruptcy"

No. 91-3

William Lang and Leonard I. Nakamura, "Housing Appraisals and Redlining."

No. 91-4

Paul S. Calem and John A. Rizzo, "Financing Constraints and Investment: New Evidence from
the U.S. Hospital Industry."

No. 91-5

Paul S. Calem, "Reputation Acquisition, Collateral, and Moral Hazard in Debt Markets."

No. 91-6

Loretta J. Mester, "Expense Preference and the Fed Revisited."

No. 91-7

Choon-Geol Moon and Janet G. Stotsky, "The Effect of Rent Control on Housing Quality Change:
A Longitudinal Analysis."

No. 91-8

Dean Croushore, "The Short-Run Costs of Disinflation."

Digitized
for 91-9
FRASER Leonard I. Nakamura, "Delegated Monitoring With Diseconomies of Scale."
No.


3

FEDERAL
RESERVE BA NK O F
PHILADELPHIA
BUSINESS REVIEW Ten Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574

Address Correction Requested