View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ISSN 0007-7011

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

JULY • AUGUST 1988




Banking Reform:
An Overview
of the Restructuring Debate
Mitchell Berlin
INVESTMENT
BANKING

Non-

INSURANCE
Commer^
paper

Finance;

IIbaN*

prod^cts

rheDeductit

jindLoc
■ \c■

■ S»«'
X

>

.

*

1

£ °
V

/

/

JULY/AUGUST 1988

The BU SIN ESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. Art­
work is designed and produced by Dianne
Hallowell under the direction of Ronald B.
Williams. The views expressed herein are not
necessarily those of this Reserve Bank or of the
Federal Reserve System.
S u b sc r ip t io n s . Single-copy subscriptions for
individuals are available without charge. Institu­
tional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
B a ck ISSUES. Back issues are available free of
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may order
up to 50 copies by submitting requests on institutional
letterhead; other orders are limited to 1 copy per
request. Microform copies are available for purchase
from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb Road, Ann
Arbor, Michigan, 48106.
R epr o d u c t io n . Permission must be obtained to
reprint portions of articles or whole articles in other
publications. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.

Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes of address, and requests to reprint to the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Department of
Research, Publications Desk, Ten Independence Mall,
Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574, or telephone (215)
574-6428. Please direct editorial communications to
the same address, or telephone (215) 574-3805.




This issue of the BUSINESS REVIEW addresses
two controversial topics: banking reform and
the deductibility of state and local taxes for
federal tax purposes. Both topics have been
hotly debated, with analysts so divided on
certain aspects of both that everyone might not
agree on the descriptions of all the issues pre­
sented here. But to begin to understand the
debates about these topics, it helps to identify
some of the key questions underlying the disa­
greements about the issues.

BANKING REFORM:
AN OVERVIEW
OF THE RESTRUCTURING DEBATE

Mitchell Berlin
Financial markets have undergone many
changes in recent years, and many bankers and
bank regulators say a refashioning of the cur­
rent regulatory structure is now in order. Most
of the proposals for doing so agree that bank
powers should be expanded, that "functional
regulation" is desirable, and that a safety net for
banks should be retained. Important disagree­
ments remain, however, over how far bank
powers should be expanded, how banking
organizations with expanded powers should
be regulated, and what types of corporate struc­
tures are desirable. These disagreements stem
largely from differences of opinion about
whether banks can be adequately insulated
from their nonbanking affiliates.

THINKING ABOUT THE DEDUCTIBILITY
OF STATE AND LOCAL TAXES

Harvey S. Rosen
In writing the Tax Reform Act of 1986, law­
makers were faced with the politically sensitive
issue of whether to retain the deductibility of
state and local taxes. In doing so, they had to
consider two questions. First, should the money
people use to pay state and local taxes be
included, in principle, in the tax base? Second,
how would state and local finances be affected
if deductibility were eliminated? The answer to
the first question depends on how income is
defined in an economic sense, the answer to the
second on how individuals and communities
make decisions on taxes and public spending.

Banking Reform:
An Overview of the Restructuring Debate
Mitchell Berlin*
Proponents of banking reform, whether they
be bankers, nonbank bankers, would-be bankers,
or bank regulators, all agree on one thing: our
current regulatory system is out of sync with the
financial marketplace. Proponents of reform point
out that regulatory restrictions prevent a firm
that might be able to provide a financial service
to customers at lowest cost from competing for
customers' business, and that services that fill

^Mitchell Berlin is a Senior Economist in the Banking
Section of the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia.




the same customer needs and pose very similar
risks—like making short-term loans and under­
writing commercial paper—often cannot be pro­
vided by the same firm. They also have argued
that as customer demand shifts from one product
to another, financial firms frequently face a
dilemma: to seek out ways to evade regulations
or else to lose business.
Policymakers have tinkered with regulations
and patched loopholes in response to marketplace
changes, but this piecemeal approach always
seems to leave regulators one repair behind,
because financial changes have been so rapid.
And each repair is time-consuming, both because
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

of the amount of time required to analyze the
issues being raised in each case and because
many industry groups seek to influence the final
outcome. There is a growing feeling that it is
time for a more fundamental financial restructur­
ing, guided by a longer-term blueprint. Reform
would be made more coherent if public debate
could be focused on a longer-term vision of a
workable and efficient regulatory framework.
There is no shortage of complicated restructur­
ing plans (see A BIBLIOGRAPHIC GUIDE TO
THE RESTRUCTURING PROPOSALS), and
evaluating the merits of the different proposals
may seem like a daunting task. A helpful first
step is to identify and explain the broad areas of
agreement and disagreement among the various
plans. Indeed, most participants in the debate

JULY/AUGUST 1988

agree that bank powers should be expanded and
that a limited safety net for banks should be
retained. There is, however, much disagreement
about what powers banking organizations
should have, what types of holding company
structures — if any — are desirable, and how
holding companies should be regulated. While
the disagreements are far-ranging, they stem
primarily from disagreement about a single
issue: can a bank be insulated from its affiliates?
THREE BROAD AREAS OF AGREEMENT
Bank Powers Should Be Expanded. All the
restructuring proposals agree that some expansion
of bank powers would not only enhance the
competitiveness of banks in financial markets
but would also benefit consumers and businesses.

A Bibliographic Guide to the Restructuring Proposals
To illustrate the various points of view on restructuring the banking system, this article focuses on the
following proposals made by bank regulators:
Comptroller of the Currency-The main elements of the Comptroller's views are contained in the
Statement of Robert L Clarke, Comptroller of the Currency, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and
Urban Affairs, United States Senate, May 21,1987.
FDIC-The views of the FDIC are contained in a staff study, Mandate for Change: Restructuring the Banking
Industry, August 18,1987, and L. William Seidman, Perspectives on Financial Restructuring, Remarks to an
Economic Policy Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson, Wyoming, August 21,
1987.
Federal Reserve System-Although the Fed has not presented a formal long-term plan, the consensus
viewpoint can be gleaned from testimony by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States
Senate, December 1,1987. E. Gerald Corrigan's, Financial Market Structure: A Longer View, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, January 1987, while not an official statement of the Fed, is a good illustration of Fed
thinking on many points.
Bank regulators are not the only participants in the debate. Other restructuring proposals include:
Association of Bank Holding Companies, "Financial Services Holding Company Act of 1988," draft
IV, May 15, 1987.
Association of Reserve City Bankers, Emerging Issues Committee, "Proposals for a Financial Services
Holding Company," May 1987.
Committee on Government Operations, "Modernization of the Financial Services Industry: A Plan
for Capital Mobility Within a Framework of Safe and Sound Banking," House Report 100-324, U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington D.C., 1987.
Other useful summaries of the restructuring debate include:
Thomas F. Huertas, "Redesigning Regulation: The Future of Finance in the United States," Issues in
Bank Regulation, Fall 1987.
Manuel H. Johnson, Statement before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S.
Senate, May 21, 1987.

4



FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Banking Reform

While there is no universal agreement about
which products and services banks should be
permitted to sell, the possibilities include financial
services—such as investment banking, under­
writing and selling insurance, and real estate
investment and brokerage—and even nonfinancial products. The reasons for proposing expanded
bank powers are varied, but tend to focus on
efficiencies that might be realized.
Under the current regulatory framework, cus­
tomers for financial services have to use different
types of firms even though the services being
purchased are closely related. Proponents of
expanded powers argue that aside from facing
the simple inconvenience of dealing with more
than one firm, the customer might be able to
purchase several services at lower cost from a
single firm. For example, the credit analysis per­
formed by a bank processing a loan request will
include information that would also be useful in
determining the customer's insurance needs—
what economists call an economy of scope.1
Regulations that restrict the bank from providing
both loans and insurance may increase the costs
of producing both services and, in turn, the price
that customers must pay for them. It should be
noted, however, that the empirical evidence for
significant scope econom ies is actually rather
scanty.
Bank loans and commercial paper illustrate
another potential benefit of an expanded menu
of services for banks that has been proposed by
proponents of reform: expanded powers would
ease the flow of resources between markets as
customer demand changes. Many large and
medium-size firms have switched from bank
loans to the commercial paper market as their
primary source of short-term funds. But when a
firm makes the switch, the bank's accumulated
knowledge about the firm is effectively destroyed

1For a more thorough discussion of economies of scope,
see Loretta J. M ester, "Efficient Production of Financial
Services: Scale and Scope Economies," this Business Review
(January/February 1987) pp.15-25.




Mitchell Berlin

as a valuable resource, because it is difficult to
sell or transfer knowledge to another firm. Thus,
the firm must pay the investment banker to
develop the expertise that was lost. If the commer­
cial bank were permitted to underwrite commer­
cial paper, this added expense to the customer
could be saved and the shift to satisfy the new
customer demand would be facilitated.
While the case for expanded powers is most
convincing for financial services, proponents of
expanded powers also argue that economies of
scope between financial and nonfinancial services
may also exist. All of the major auto firms have
finance subsidiaries, which were initially set up
to coordinate the marketing and financing of
new car purchases. And the successful entry by
these finance subsidiaries into the expanding
markets for other types of consumer loans—
such as mortgages—illustrates the potential
benefits of a free flow of resources between
financial and nonfinancial sectors.
Functional Regulation Is Desirable. If banks
are granted powers to sell insurance or underwrite
securities, policymakers must make sure that
regulatory rules do not favor banks over their
competitors, or vice versa. All restructuring pro­
posals agree, at least in principle, that different
types of firms providing the same service—or
function—should be subject to similar regulatory
rules. This principle is called functional regulation.
Although functional regulation does not necessar­
ily mean that all providers of a particular service
should be governed by the same regulator, it
may be difficult to ensure uniform regulatory
treatment when different regulators are involved.
And while all proposals agree that functional
regulation is desirable, there is no such agreement
about who should regulate which services.
Functional regulation promotes competitive
equity and invites firms to use their ingenuity to
satisfy customer needs rather than to evade
regulations. In the competitive battle for cus­
tomers, the firm with the lowest costs and best
products is supposed to win. But we cannot be
sure that the well-run firm will win if it is saddled
with more burdensome regulatory rules than its
5

BUSINESS REVIEW

poorly run competitor. In fact, the well-run firm
is not likely to take this situation lying down.
Instead, the firm will spend much of its time
figuring out legal ways to evade the regulations
that place it at a competitive disadvantage. From
society's standpoint, all this time and effort are
sheer waste.
A Strictly Limited Safety Net for Banks Is
Needed. Deposit insurance and access to the
discount window are the two main ways in which
the federal authorities provide a safety net for
banks and their customers. The safety net is
designed to guarantee stability in the payments
system and to ensure that banks can play their
special role in providing liquid funds to busi­
nesses and consumers, especially in times of
financial stress. But since the safety net provides
government guarantees to banks and their
customers, it must be supplemented by regula­
tions to make sure that the government is not
writing bankers a blank check to take on risky
activities. These regulations include capital re­
quirements and periodic bank examinations.
Most proposals agree that firms providing
deposits on demand should be protected by a
safety net, yet no one wishes to see government
guarantees and regulations extended willy-nilly
to other types of activities and services; that is,
the safety net should be limited in scope. But this
is easier said than done. If banks' powers are
expanded, how can the government hold the
safety net under the bank when it provides
"banking" services without extending the net to
all the other services provided by the bank? This
question raises a host of vexing issues concern­
ing how bank holding companies should be
organized and regulated. Here, agreement ends
and the proposals part ways.
RESTRUCTURING PROPOSALS DIFFER ON
THREE MAJOR ISSUES
The institutions at issue are bank holding
companies, which are firms that own one or more
banks. Current law defines a bank as either a
firm that offers federally insured deposits or one
that offers demand deposits and makes com­

6


JULY/AUGUST 1988

mercial loans. It is easier to see the differences
among the restructuring proposals using just
the first definition.
What Activities Can Be Carried out within
Bank Holding Companies? Much of the immedi­
ate controversy over banking reform has been
about the desirability of adding particular
financial services to the bank holding company's
menu of permitted activities. And, as a practical
matter, only financial powers—underwriting
and dealing securities, real estate investment
and brokerage, and selling and underwriting
insurance—are under serious consideration by
federal legislators for the near future.2 Each and
every financial power has been hotly contested,
partly because of opposition from entrenched
firms who are unhappy with the prospect of new
competitors, partly because of differences of
opinion about the potential risks to bank safety,
and partly because of different interpretations
about the range of permissible powers under
current banking laws. In particular, the federal
bank regulators do not all agree about which of
these financial services banks should be per­
mitted. (See HOW THE REGULATORS LINE
UP ON BANK POWERS.)
In the long term, however, perhaps the most
important issue is whether bank holding compa­
nies should be permitted to offer just financial
services or whether they should also be permit­
ted to offer nonfinancial services and products,
like automobiles. The example of a bank holding
company selling cars is not unrealistic. General
Motors already sells cars and also makes con­
sumer loans. If it were permitted to offer insured
deposits through its finance subsidiary, it would
be a bank holding company that also produces
cars.
Proposals coming from the Federal Reserve
System take a narrow view of the issue of separat­
ing banking and commerce. Speaking for the

2For a summary of banking legislation before Congress,
see Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Banking Legislation
and Policy, Vol. 7, No. 1 (January/March 1988).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Banking Reform

Mitchell Berlin

How the Regulators Line Up on Bank Powers
REGULATOR

FINANCIAL

Investment
Banking

NON­
FINANCIAL

Real Estate

Insurance

Investment

Brokerage

Underwriting

Sale

Comp­
troller

yes

yes
with
restrictions

yes

yes

yes

no
formal
position

FDIC

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

yes

Federal
Reserve

yes

no
with
exceptions

yes

no
formal
position

no
formal
position

no

Fed, C hairm an A lan G reensp an has argued that

banking should be separated from commerce,
which is just another way of saying that bank
holding companies should not be permitted to
offer nonfinancial services.3 Gerald Corrigan,
President of the New York Fed, has presented
his own detailed restructuring plan that restricts
bank holding companies to offering financial
services. On the other hand, the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) has proposed
that bank holding companies be free to offer a
full range of financial and nonfinancial services.
Under that plan, General Motors could own a
bank subsidiary or Citicorp could own an
automobile factory.
Where Can Nonbank Activities Be Carried
Out Inside the Bank Holding Company? Anyone

3 Actually, "banking" and activities "closely related to
banking" as defined by regulators are not all financial ser­
vices. The distinction between financial and nonfinancial
activities, however, is a close approximation to the distinction
between banking and commerce.




who has examined the organizational chart of a
large company knows that internal organizational
structures can be quite complex. (See AN
IMAGINARY HOLDING COMPANY, p. 8.)
With expanded powers, bank holding companies
might choose a number of different ways to
provide nonbanking services. Take the hypothe­
tical example of a holding company that wishes
to provide both commercial banking services
and underwriting of securities. The holding
company could create two separate subsidiaries, a
commercial bank subsidiary and an investment
bank subsidiary. Each subsidiary would be
separately capitalized and have its own manage­
ment. Or, the holding company could set up a
commercial bank subsidiary which provides in­
vestment banking activities through its own
investment bank subsidiary. That is, the holding
company owns the commercial bank, which in
turn, owns the investment bank. Finally, the
holding company could simply create a single
subsidiary that provides both services, perhaps
in separate departments.
Although there are some analysts who would
7

JULY/AUGUST 1988

BUSINESS REVIEW

An Imaginary Holding Company

BHC Inc. illustrates a holding company structure that might arise if bank holding companies were
permitted to offer underwriting and insurance services and if they were free to choose their own internal
organization. The parent company, BHC, owns stock in its two subsidiaries: a bank subsidiary, Megabank
National, and a nonbanking subsidiary, Two Hands Insurance. Normally, BHC will hold a large share of its
subsidiaries' equity, because there are substantial tax benefits if the parent owns at least 80% of a
subsidiary's stock. Megabank also has its own subsidiary, an investment banking firm, Salmon Brothers.
The bank owns stock in Salmon Brothers, just as BHC owns stock in the bank and the insurance
company. BHC and Two Hands Insurance are both nonbanking affiliates of Megabank. Megabank's own
subsidiary, Salmon Brothers, is also considered a nonbanking affiliate of the bank.3

3 Megabank might also have affiliates outside of the holding company. Under Section 23a of the Federal Reserve
Act, the Federal Reserve System has substantial discretion in defining an affiliate. If business dealings between a bank
and another firm are not “at arm's length," the Fed considers that firm an affiliate of the bank.

Digitized 8 FRASER
for


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Banking Reform

leave the bank holding company free to make
any of these choices, none of the major
restructuring proposals advocates the third
possibility.4 The m ajor proposals are, however,
divided between those which would permit banks
to own nonbanking subsidiaries and those which
would require that nonbanking services be pro­
vided through subsidiaries that are managed
and capitalized separately from bank subsidiaries.
President Corrigan, in his own proposal, and
Chairman Greenspan, speaking for the Fed, have
taken the approach that banking and nonbanking
activities should be housed in separate subsidiaries
of the holding company. The Comptroller of the
Currency has taken the less restrictive stance
that bank holding companies should be free to
choose either organizational form. The FDIC,
while nearer to the Comptroller's position, has
agreed that separate subsidiaries might be
required for some activities that regulators
deem to be especially risky.
What Parts of the Bank Holding Company
Should Be Regulated By Bank Regulators? On
this question, the proposals are divided between
those that advocate consolidated regulation of
the bank holding company and those that would
have bank regulators oversee just the bank sub­
sidiaries of the holding company.
Consolidated regulation can mean different
things to different people. In the official Fed
position, consolidated regulation, at the minimum,
would permit the bank regulator to set capital
requirem ents for the parent company as well as
for its bank subsidiaries.5 The Corrigan proposal

Mitchell Berlin

4Analysts who advocate the third possibility believe that
existing restrictions on interaffiliate transactions are a feasi­
ble alternative to restrictions on organizational choice. See,
for instance, Anthony Saunders, "Bank Holding Companies:
Structure, Performance, and Reform," in William Haraf (ed.)
Restructuring the Financial System, American Enterprise
Institute, Washington, D.C. (forthcoming).

takes a more expansive view of the supervisory
powers of the holding company's regulator. In
his proposal, the holding company's regulator
could also set capital requirements for and exercise
"prudential supervision" over each component
part of the holding company. Thus, a separately
capitalized investment banking subsidiary of
the holding company would be subject to direct
oversight by a bank regulator.
Both the FDIC and the Comptroller take a
narrower view of bank regulators' oversight
role. Specifically, bank regulators would set
standards—like capital requirements and port­
folio restrictions—for the bank, but not for the
holding company or for any of the nonbanking
subsidiaries of the holding company. The bank's
regulators would, however, set and enforce rules
governing relations between the bank and its
nonbanking affiliates: the parent company, the
nonbanking subsidiaries of the holding company,
and the subsidiaries of the bank. For example,
bank regulators would set rules limiting lending
by the bank to an insurance affiliate or to the
parent company.
The Root of the Differences. If we step back
for a minute, we can see that the proposals'
answers to each of the questions are linked.
Proposals requiring strictly separate nonbanking
affiliates also call for consolidated supervision
of the holding company—the Corrigan view
and the Fed view. Proposals granting bank
holding companies more freedom to choose
how to offer nonbanking activities do not call for
consolidated supervision—the Comptroller and
the FDIC view. And those who demand tighter
restrictions on holding company organization
and require consolidated supervision would also
permit bank holding companies to offer fewer
nonbanking services.
But how are the answers to these very different
questions linked? The most important reason
why President Corrigan and the Fed answer one

5The recent Fed interpretation of its traditional position
that the holding company should act as a "source of strength"
to its bank subsidiaries implies an even stronger role for the
consolidated capital of the bank holding company. Under
the source of strength doctrine, regulators can require the

holding company to provide financial support to a weakened
or failing bank subsidiary when the holding company is in a
position to do so.




9

BUSINESS REVIEW

way and the FDIC and the Comptroller another
is that they have different views about the
possibility of insulating the bank from non­
banking affiliates within the holding company.
Both President Corrigan and the Fed believe
that insulation of the bank is quite difficult to
guarantee, while both the FDIC and the Comp­
troller are more optimistic about the feasibility
of insulating the bank.
INSULATION OF THE BANK:
THE KEY TO THE DEBATE
What Does Insulation Mean? In the debate
over regulatory reform, the idea of insulating
the bank has paraded under a number of colorful
phrases such as the creation of "Chinese walls"
or "fire walls" between the bank and its non­
banking affiliates. W hichever term is used, the
basic idea is that the safety net, which neces­
sarily includes government guarantees to the
bank and its depositors, should not be extended
to nonbanking affiliates within the holding
company.
In normal times, when the bank and its af­
filiates are financially healthy, insulation means
that the holding company cannot use the bank
to subsidize nonbanking activities. For instance,
the bank might conceivably pay out "excessive"
dividends to the parent company, which then
reinvests these funds in an insurance subsidiary.
These transfers may weaken the bank financially,
but some of the increased risk is borne by the
FDIC, which generally guarantees the bank's
depositors against loss. This type of policy, in
effect, transfers the benefit of the government
guarantees for bank depositors to the insurance
affiliate.
In times of crisis, when either the parent
company or a nonbanking firm in the holding
company is financially troubled, insulation
means that neither the bank nor bank regulators
will prop up the affiliate. Suppose a real estate
investment affiliate's investments have shaky
foundations and are beginning to fall in value.
The parent company might direct the bank to
make loans to the real estate affiliate, even though

10


JULY/AUGUST 1988

these loans would normally be considered
excessively risky. Should these loans threaten
the health of the bank, bank regulators might
step in to save the bank, effectively passing on
losses from the real estate affiliate to the FDIC.
An insulated bank would neither subsidize its
affiliates nor prop up affiliates in trouble.6
Why Is Insulation the Key? Suppose banks
can be insulated effectively from their non­
banking affiliates. In that case, a whole host of
problems disappear. There is little danger in
permitting bank holding companies to offer a
wide range of nonbanking activities. For example,
regulators need not worry that the highly cyclical
demand for automobiles could lead to periodic
problems for the bank subsidiary of a holding
company that also produces cars. The parent
company can also be given substantial freedom
in choosing its own internal organizational
structure. If loans and other types of financial
transfers between a bank and a real estate
subsidiary of the bank can be easily monitored
and controlled, then it makes little sense to force
the holding company to house banking and real
estate activities in separately managed subsidi­
aries. The holding company can choose the most
efficient organizational form without endanger­
ing the banking system or extending the safety
net to the real estate industry. Finally, bank
regulators will not need to supervise the holding
company or its nonbanking subsidiaries. Regu­
lators can direct their attention to the bank alone

6Although this account stresses the importance of the
behavior of holding company management and regulators
for ensuring insulation, the beliefs of the public— investors
and customers of the bank and its affiliates— and the willing­
ness of the courts to enforce the doctrine of corporate
separateness are also important. The debate over insulation
is closely related to the debate over so-called conflicts of
interest. Both among regulators and academics, there is
substantial disagreement about the incentives for holding
companies to weaken the financial condition of the bank,
even in the absence of regulatory safeguards to ensure in­
sulation. See Anthony Saunders, "Securities Activities of
Commercial Banks: The Problems of Conflicts of Interest,"
this Business Review (July/August 1985) pp. 17-27, for a
complete discussion of these issues.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Banking Reform

and permit the nonbanking affiliates to make
unfettered business decisions, risky or other­
wise. Insulation guarantees that risky or impru­
dent decisions by a nonbanking affiliate will not
increase the bank's risk or the regulator's ex­
posure. None of this is true, however, if the bank
cannot be insulated or if the regulatory costs of
ensuring insulation are too large.
IS INSULATION POSSIBLE?
If Bank Holding Companies Are Highly Inte­
grated, Insulation Is a Bigger Problem. The
organizational chart of a holding company pro­
vides only a partial picture of the way the busi­
ness is actually run. Consider the example of a
hypothetical holding company, BHC Inc., which
owns just two subsidiaries, a bank and an in­
surance company. This organization might be
run in many different ways. One extreme possi­
bility is that BHC Inc. leaves the two subsidiaries
alone to make all important business decisions,
such as how profits are to be used, which in­
vestments should be made, and which new
markets should be entered. In this case, BHC
Inc.'s managers act like passive investors owning
a two-firm portfolio. They might act this way if
the sole reason for investing in both the bank
and insurance companies were to diversify, that
is, to reduce fluctuations in the returns on their
total investment.
At the other extreme, BHC might centralize
all decisionmaking at the holding company
level. BHC might decide how all profits made by
the bank and the insurance company should be
reallocated between the two companies, which
types of investments should be made by each,
and which new markets should be entered. In
this case, the entire holding company is operated
as a single consolidated organization.
While these extreme cases are unrealistic, they
help to illustrate the connection between the
level of integration of the holding company and
the possibility of insulating the bank. If a bank
holding company is merely a portfolio of com­
pletely independent firms, then the bank is
clearly insulated from both the parent and the



Mitchell Berlin

insurance affiliate. Without direction from BHC,
the bank acts exactly like a bank without any
affiliates. If, however, all decisionmaking is
centralized, then situations may arise where
BHC's management views the profitability and
safety of its bank subsidiary as a secondary con­
cern, less important than the profitability of the
holding company as a whole. Also, bank regu­
lators will find it difficult to separate the affairs of
the bank and its affiliates should the holding
company experience financial difficulties.
The empirical evidence about how bank hold­
ing companies are actually run suggests that
they are not merely portfolios of independently
run firms.7 For instance, banks inside holding
companies normally pay out more dividends
and hold less capital than independent banks.8
Survey evidence shows that parent companies
centralize some decisions but not others. Gary
Whalen finds that parent companies often set
dividend payments by bank subsidiaries and
make other capital management decisions like
how external funds should be raised.9* In

7See Anthony Cornyn, Gerald Hanweck, Stephen
Rhoades, and John Rose, "A n Analysis of the Concept of
Corporate Separateness in BHC Regulation from an
Economic Perspective," Proceedings o f A Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
(May 1986); Timothy Hannan, "Safety, Soundness, and the
Bank Holding Company: A Critical Review of the Literature,"
Working Paper, Board of Governors (1984); and Anthony
Saunders, "Bank Holding Companies: Structure, Perform­
ance, and Reform," for reviews of the empirical literature.
8This does not necessarily mean that banks inside holding
companies are being used to subsidize affiliates or that they
have a greater risk of failure. In part, dividend payments are
used to retire holding company debt used to purchase the
bank. While lower capital, by itself, tends to increase the
bank's risk of failure, the bank's expected profits and the
variability of profits must also be considered. Empirical
studies of the risk of failure for banks in holding companies
have reached varying conclusions.
9Gary Whalen, "O perational Policies of Multibank
Holding Companies," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Economic Review (Winter 1 9 8 1 /8 2 ). For the most part,
empirical studies have concentrated on the relationships
between the parent company and its bank subsidiaries.
Evidence about the degree of coordination of banking and
nonbanking activities by the parent company is scanty and
anecdotal.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

addition, parent companies often have the final
say over major investment decisions by bank
subsidiaries. On the other hand, Whalen finds
that the parent company is likely to leave port­
folio management decisions and pricing deci­
sions to its bank subsidiary.
Since the degree of integration of bank holding
companies appears to be substantial, insulation
of the bank may be a problem. But bank regu­
lators need not be, and are not, helpless ob­
servers, whose only tools for influencing the
behavior of bank holding companies are a wish
and a prayer. And strict limitations on permis­
sible products and services, extensive restric­
tions on organizational structure, and consoli­
dated supervision are not the only regulatory
alternatives.
Existing Regulatory Safeguards Enhance
Insulation . . . Among the safeguards that are
already in place, perhaps the two most important
are the restrictions on interaffiliate transactions
written into Section 23 of the Federal Reserve
Act, and regulatory capital requirements for
banks. The FDIC proposal, in particular, lays
great stress on these regulatory safeguards as a
workable alternative to more extensive regula­
tion of bank holding companies.
Sections 23a and 23b of the Federal Reserve
Act are designed to limit a bank's exposure to its
nonbanking affiliates and to prevent a bank
holding company from using its bank subsidiary
to subsidize nonbanking activities. Section 23a
places quantitative limits on financial trans­
actions between a bank and its affiliates, includ­
ing loans, equity investments, and certain types
of guarantees such as letters of credit.10 To see
how these limits work, consider BHC Inc. again
and imagine, for simplicity, that the only types of
internal financial transactions are loans from the
bank to BHC Inc. and its insurance subsidiary.
Under Section 23a, bank loans to either affiliate

10See "The Banking Affiliates Act of 1982: Amendments
to Section 23a," Federal Reserve Bulletin (November 1982) for
a more detailed description of Section 23a.


12


JULY/AUGUST 1988

could not exceed 10 percent of the bank's capital.
Further, the total loans made by the bank to both
its affiliates together could not exceed 20 per­
cent of the bank's capital. Thus, in the extremely
unlikely event that both the parent company
and the insurance company were unable to repay
any of their loans, the most the bank would
stand to lose is 20 percent of its capital, a painful,
but not necessarily fatal, loss as long as the rest of
the bank's portfolio is healthy. Of course, a 20
percent decline in the bank's capital is no trivial
matter, but recent evidence from a study at the
Board of G overnors of the Federal Reserve
System suggests that, in practice, banks do not
approach the regulatory limits.11 In fact, the
Board study shows that net financial flows from
banks to their affiliates tend to be negative; that
is, funds flow from the affiliates to the bank
rather than the other way around.
Section 23b requires that any transactions
between the bank and the insurance affiliate
must be on terms at least as favorable to the bank
as a similar transaction with an insurance
company outside the holding company. Thus, if
the bank would demand a 10 percent rate of
interest on a one-year loan to a nonaffiliated
insurance company, it could demand no less
from the insurance subsidiary of BHC Inc.
Of course, regulations are only as good as the
information available to regulators. Unless bank
regulators have timely and accurate information
about financial flows between banks and affiliated
companies, they cannot be sure that attempts to
breach restrictions will be caught in time. All of
the restructuring plans agree that more stringent
and detailed reports from banks about transactions
with affiliates are a necessary price to pay for

11See John Rose and Samuel Talley, "Financial Trans­
actions Within Bank Holding Companies," Staff Study # 123,
Board of Governors (May 1983). Their results are only
suggestive, because they do not include all types of financial
flows. Also Section 23a limits do not net out offsetting
financial transactions between the bank and its affiliates. It is
possible for the bank to make loans to affiliates equal to 20%
of its capital yet still have a net inflow of funds.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Banking Reform

permitting bank holding companies to offer more
nonbanking services.
Minimum capital requirements for banks also
insulate the bank from its affiliates' financial
losses, because capital serves as a cushion against
potential losses. In fact, capital standards serve a
double duty in this regard, because the quantitative
limitations in Section 23a are all expressed as
fractions of the bank's capital. A bank without
much capital faces severe limits on the dollar
value of loans or guarantees to its affiliates. If the
bank is pressing against its limits, yet wishes to
expand financial transactions with affiliated firms,
it must increase its capital, perhaps by selling
new equity.
If bank capital cushions the bank and the FDIC
against losses, won't additional capital require­
ments for the parent company or nonbanking
subsidiaries of the holding company work even
better? It is true that the FDIC's potential losses
are smaller if the consolidated organization has
a larger capital cushion. However, it doesn't
necessarily follow that any additional capital
should be held by the parent company or other
nonbank subsidiaries, as long as bank regulators
enforce capital requirements for each bank strin­
gently. Requiring holding company capital to
serve as a backup for bank capital only makes
sense if regulators believe that banks in holding
companies are riskier than independent banks.
But if there is reason to believe that banks inside
holding companies should hold more capital
than independent banks, then an alternative is
for regulators to impose a supplemental re­
quirement on the banks directly, rather than on
the parent company or nonbanking subsidi­
aries. This alternative approach would not only
be more direct but would also be more consistent
with the principle of functional regulation.
. . . But Insulation Is Possible Only if Regu­
lators Will Keep the Bank Separate. Inevitably,
situations will arise where the parent company
or a nonbanking affiliate is in serious financial
trouble, while the bank is financially healthy.
Much of the debate about the feasibility of in­
sulation has focused on the behavior of the



Mitchell Berlin

holding company's management in these situa­
tions. Equally important—maybe more so—is
the behavior of bank regulators. If regulators
feel compelled to extend guarantees to troubled
affiliates out of fear that the public will lose
confidence in the bank when an affiliate fails,
then insulation is not feasible.12
The regulator might reason that since a
troubled nonbanking subsidiary and the bank
are part of the same organization, the public will
interpret troubles in the nonbanking company
as evidence of weak management of the holding
company and, in turn, of the bank. If regulators,
who by nature take a wary and conservative
view of the dangers of financial instability, do
reason this way, then public pronouncements
that the safety net will not be extended to non­
bank activities are not credible. And if regulators
cannot credibly commit to separate the bank
from its troubled affiliates, then the holding
company management won't take as seriously
regulatory restrictions designed to keep the bank
separate.
The credibility of regulators' commitment not
to extend guarantees to nonbanking affiliates
also will depend on how the financial and regu­
latory system is restructured. A bank regulator
who supervises the holding company on a con­
solidated basis may have considerable power to
intervene to save a struggling nonbanking affili­
ate. The consolidated supervisor of the holding
company might be sorely tempted to devise
complicated recovery plans involving transfers
between the firms in the holding company to
save the organization from failure. On the other
hand, a regulator whose supervisory role is
limited to setting standards for the bank alone
will have fewer options to extend guarantees to
nonbank affiliates.
One likely effect of expanded powers for bank

12See Anthony C om yn , et. al., "A n Analysis of the
Concept of Corporate Separateness...," pp.185-191, and
Anthony Saunders, "Bank Holding Companies: Structure,
Conduct and Reform," pp. 32-37, for contrasting readings of
the empirical evidence about public attitudes.

13

BUSINESS REVIEW

holding companies is the emergence of larger
organizations, which will also affect the options
facing regulators. This development cuts two
ways. In general, regulators are much more con­
cerned about the potential failure of a large banking
organization than a small one, because the dis­
ruptive effects to the financial system of the
failure of a large organization are more widespread.
Commitments to keep the bank separate when a
very large bank holding company is on the edge
of collapse may be very difficult to honor. But
the emergence of larger banking organizations
may also mean that there will be m ore firms that
could purchase a bank from a financially troubled
holding company. The greater the number of
firms that can afford to purchase the bank, the
more credible regulators' commitment to keep
the bank separate from the holding company's
problems.
CONCLUSION
Diverse as the recent proposals for restruc­
turing the financial system are, they agree on
some basic principles: bank holding company
powers should be expanded, functional regula­
tion is desirable, and a strictly limited safety net
for banks should be maintained. How far powers
should be expanded, how bank holding com­
panies should be organized, and how much of
the bank holding company should be supervised
by bank regulators are the major sources of
disagreement. These disagreements flow in large
part from different beliefs about the possibility
of insulating the banks from their affiliates.


14


JULY/AUGUST 1988

Whether banks can be insulated is a compli­
cated, and unresolved, issue. The effectiveness
of Section 23a and 23b restrictions have yet to be
tested in an environment where bank holding
companies engage in a wide range of financial,
and perhaps nonfinancial, services. Whether
regulators can keep the bank separate and avoid
extending the safety net to nonbanking affiliates
in large bank holding companies is another open
question. Bank regulators' behavior since the
rescue of Continental Illinois Bank, however,
does provide some evidence on this issue. In
recent years, regulators have gained substantial
experience in dealing with large troubled bank­
ing organizations, especially in Texas and
Oklahoma. For the most part, regulators have
avoided bailing out parent companies when the
troubled banks were reorganized or sold.13
Ultimately, debates over economic issues in­
form but don't dominate the course of legislative
reform. Self-interested industry groups will all
have their say, and legislators and regulators are
unlikely to ignore their pleas. As the banking
bills now winding their way through the House
and Senate show, restructuring will occur in fits
and starts and will not be as coherent as the
formal plans that have been presented. Public
debate over the economic issues, however, can
only improve the coherence of regulatory reform
as it unfolds.
13See FDIC, "Mandate for Change..." for a summary of
regulators' experience with bank failures since Continental
Illinois' rescue.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Thinking About The Deductibility
of State and Local Taxes
Harvey S. Rosen *
INTRODUCTION
Through most of its history, federal tax law
has allowed itemizers to deduct state and local
property, income, and general sales taxes. Data
provided by the Executive Office of the Presi­
dent estimated that this provision decreased
federal tax revenues by about $30.8 billion in
1985. Over the last several years, Congress, the
President, and the people have debated the
merits of partially or totally eliminating state
and local tax deductibility. The U.S. Treasury
*Harvey S. Rosen, Professor of Economics at Princeton
University, is currently a Visiting Scholar in the Philadelphia
Fed's Research Department.




recommended complete abolition of deducti­
bility in 1984, as did President Reagan in 1985.
However, those who favored deductibility
argued that its elimination would have a dis­
astrous impact on state and local public finance.
In this view, if people could not deduct state and
local taxes on their federal tax returns, then they
would vote to reduce these taxes. State and local
public officials appear to believe this scenario.
When the United States Conference of Mayors
convened in 1985, the New York Times reported
that the meeting "... ended with an unusual
display of bipartisan unanimity: only one 'no'
vote was audible on a resolution urging Con­
gress to amend the [President's] tax plan to keep
15

BUSINESS REVIEW

deductibility of state and local taxes
The landmark Tax Reform Act of 1986 em­
bodied a compromise on this issue. It disallowed
deduction of state sales taxes, but continued
those for income and property taxes. More
changes in the tax code are likely in the next few
years, and state and local tax deductibility will
probably remain a controversial issue.* In
2
analyzing this controversy, two main questions
arise. First, is it sensible for the tax base of the
federal income tax to exclude individuals' pay­
ments of state and local taxes? Second, what
would happen to state and local revenues and
expenditures if deductibility were eliminated?
The correct answers to both questions are con­
troversial for two reasons. First, economic theory
does not provide firm guidelines as to how
"incom e" should be defined for purposes of
taxation. Second, certain data that are required
to understand how state and local governments
react to changes in the federal tax structure are
not available.
DO STATE AND LOCAL TAXES
BELONG IN THE TAX BASE?
Defining Income. In order to determ ine
whether an individual's state and local tax pay­
ments should be excluded from his taxable income,
we need some kind of criterion for deciding
what ought to be included. That is, we require a
careful definition of "incom e." Interestingly, the
statutes provide no such definition. The consti­
tutional amendment that introduced the tax

!"W h at Happens if Washington Changes the Rules?" New

York Times (June 23, 1985) p. E5.
2There are also claims that removing deductibility would
lead to an unfair increase in the tax burden on middleincome taxpayers. The distributional implications of de­
ductibility, both across states and across income classes, are
discussed in Daniel R. Feenberg and Harvey S. Rosen, "The
Deductibility of State and Local Taxes: Impact Effects by
State and Income Class," Growth and Change (April 1986) pp.
11-31, and Daphne Kenyon, "Implicit Aid to State and Local
Governments through Federal Tax Deductibility," mimeo,
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Office of Tax Analysis
(1986).

Digitized16 FRASER
for


JULY/AUGUST 1988

merely says "The Congress shall have power to
lay and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever
source derived." While the tax law does provide
examples of items that should be classified as
incom e—wages and salaries, rents, dividends,
and so forth—the words "from whatever source
derived" do not really provide a standard that
can be used to decide whether or not the ex­
clusion of certain items from taxation is appro­
priate.
Public finance economists have traditionally
used their own standard, the so-called HaigSimons (H-S) definition: income is the money
value of the net increase to an individual's power
to consume during a period.3 This is equal to the
amount actually consumed during the period
plus net additions to wealth. Net additions to
wealth—saving—must be included in income
because they represent an increase in potential
consumption. The justification for the H-S
definition is that an individual's potential con­
sumption is a good measure of his ability to pay
taxes, and tax liabilities should be based on ability
to pay.
Using this criterion requires including all
sources of potential increases in consumption,
regardless of whether the actual consumption
takes place, and regardless of the form in which
the consumption occurs. At the same time, it
requires that any decreases in an individual's
potential to consume should be subtracted in
determining income. For example, if certain
expenses have to be incurred to earn income,
these should be subtracted. If the gross revenues
from an individual's business are $50,000 but
business expenses were $40,000, then the indi­
vidual's potential consumption has only in­
creased by $10,000.
Another important implication of this criterion
is that nondiscretionary expenses should be de­
ductible from income. If you have no choice
over some expense and it is not contributing to

3Named after Robert M. Haig and Henry C. Simons,
economists who wrote in the first half of the 20th century.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Deductibility of Taxes

your ability to consume, then it should not be
included as part of your income for tax purposes.
A classic example is extraordinary uninsured
medical expenses. Consider the case where two
people earn $60,000 each, and one has had to
pay $20,000 in hospital bills for treatment of a
heart attack, while the other has not. Despite the
fact that their earnings are equal, their abilities to
pay are not. According to the H-S criterion, it
would make sense to allow the heart attack victim
to deduct his $20,000 in medical expenses, so
that he is treated as if his ability to pay were
$40,000. In fact, U.S. tax law does follow this
model; it allows individuals to deduct unreim­
bursed medical expenses that exceed 7.5 percent
of their total incomes.
What does the H-S criterion tell us about the
deductibility of state and local taxes? The key
question is whether payments of state and local
taxes are “like" medical expenses. If they rep­
resent nondiscretionary decreases in people's
ability to pay, then they should not be counted
as part of income. If, on the other hand, state and
local taxes are discretionary, then according to
the H-S criterion, there is no reason to permit an
individual to deduct them.
Are State and Local Taxes Discretionary?
Suppose that people have no control over their
state and local taxes, and they reap few benefits
from these taxes. Then, according to the H-S
definition, state and local taxes are nondiscre­
tionary and ought to be deductible. This view is
quite a popular one. For example, during the
public debate over deductibility, people from
high tax states like New York argued that it
would be "unfair" to disallow deductibility, be­
cause they would be hurt compared to citizens
of low tax states (like New Hampshire). Implicit
in this view is that New Yorkers do not derive
much benefit from their taxes. Otherwise, why
should the taxes be regarded as a burden that
reduces their ability to pay?
A very different view of state and local taxes
was espoused by economist Charles Tiebout
(rhymes with "m e too") in an article published
in 1956. To understand Tiebout's hypothesis, it



Harvey S. Rosen

helps to begin by thinking about the options
available to people who disapprove of some
action being taken by the U.S. federal govern­
ment (like giving aid to the Contras or funding
Planned Parenthood). Only in extreme cases do
we expect people to leave the country because
of federal government policy. Because of the
large monetary and psychic costs of emigrating,
a more realistic option is to stay home and try to
change the policy. On the other hand, most
citizens are not as strongly attached to their local
communities. If you dislike the policies being
followed in Ardmore, Pennsylvania, the easiest
thing to do may be to move a few miles away to
Haverford.
Tiebout argued that people take advantage of
their mobility to "vote with their feet" and locate
in the community that offers the bundle of public
services and taxes they like best. Much as a
person satisfies his desire for private goods by
purchasing them on the market, he satisfies his
desire for publicly provided goods like education
by the appropriate selection of a community in
which to live. The taxes he pays are simply fees
for these goods. Ultimately, according to Tiebout,
people distribute themselves across communi­
ties on the basis of their demands for publicly
provided goods. Each individual receives his or
her desired level of these goods and cannot be
made better off by moving (or else the individual
would).
If Tiebout's view of the world is correct, there
is no more reason to allow an individual to
deduct his state and local taxes than there is to
deduct his expenditures on cottage cheese. Both
represent payments for something the indi­
vidual wants.4

4Another assumption of the Tiebout model is that spend­
ing in one community affects the welfare only of its own
members. If there are beneficial spillover effects, then de­
ductibility might be viewed as a way to encourage such
desirable activities. However, a more efficient way to do this
is for the federal government to provide matching grants for
the relevant activities.

17

BUSINESS REVIEW

Tiebout's provocative hypothesis has stimu­
lated a huge amount of research. Som e of this
research has criticized his model for being based
on unrealistic assumptions. For one thing, people
are not perfectly mobile; they are attached to
communities by jobs, personal ties, and other
commitments. Even if people could move around
costlessly, there are probably not enough com­
munities so that each family can find one with a
bundle of services that suits it perfectly. More­
over, contrary to what the Tiebout model implies,
we observe many communities within which
there are massive income differences and hence,
presumably different desired levels of public
goods provision. Just consider any major city.
However, we should not dismiss the Tiebout
mechanism too hastily. There is a lot of mobility
in the American economy. A persistent pattern
is that in any given year, about 17 percent of
Americans have residences different from those
they had the year before, according to the U.S.
Bureau of the Census. Moreover, within most
metropolitan areas, there is a wide range of
choice with respect to type of community. In the
Philadelphia metropolitan area alone there are
some 300 municipalities from which to choose.
Certainly, casual observation suggests that across
suburbs there is considerable residential segre­
gation by income, and that exclusionary zoning
is practiced widely. In addition, it is not hard to
find popular accounts of classic Tiebout-type
behavior. Recently in California, for example, a
number of communities voted to increase their
taxes in order to pay for more police protection.
Where does this leave us? The Tiebout model
is quite relevant for people who live in suburban
settings, but for citizens of big cities it does not
seem to apply. And it is surely stretching the
theory to argue that it is relevant to an indi­
vidual's choice of a state (as opposed to a com­
munity). It would be nice to know what pro­
portion of state and local taxes can properly be
regarded as Tiebout-type user fees, but such
data are not available. Therefore, we are left
concluding that the question of whether state
and local taxes should be included in the tax
18



JULY/AUGUST 1988

base does not have a clear answer.
Legislators, of course, have to go ahead and
make decisions even when these issues are
unresolved, as the recent Tax Reform Act attests.
The reform eliminated deductibility for state
sales taxes but retained it for local property taxes.
If the H-S criterion guided this choice, then
legislators must have believed that sales taxes
are more like discretionary user fees than are
property taxes. However, since it is easier to
move from one nearby community to another
than from one state to another, it is likely that
just the opposite is the case.
Regardless of how one comes down on this
question of what should or should not be de­
ductible, it is still important to know how state
and local public finance would react if deducti­
bility were eliminated. Indeed, even if one be­
lieved, based on the Haig-Simons point of view,
that the deduction should be removed, doing so
might not be socially desirable if it leads to
drastically reduced revenues for state and local
governments. Economists have approached the
issue of measuring the effects of removing
deductibility in a number of ways, and they have
come up with differing answers. We can begin to
sort through these results by analyzing the im­
pact of removing deductibility when all state
and local taxes are levied on households, and
then turn to the complications that arise when
businesses are taxable as well.
HOW DEDUCTIBILITY AFFECTS
INDIVIDUALS' AND COMMUNITIES'
DECISIONS
In a world in which the Tiebout model held
exactly, everyone in a community would want
the same amount of public spending. This, how­
ever, is not a good description of reality. Within
a community, generally there is some disagree­
ment about the best level of public expenditure.
Therefore, some kind of public choice process is
required to take the citizens' preferences and
translate them into a decision for the community.
In the current context, this suggests that thinking
about the impact of removing deductibility on
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Deductibility of Taxes

public spending requires two steps. The first is
to find out how removal affects each individual's
demand for public expenditure; the second is to
determine how these changes translate into a
collective decision.
The Individual's Decision. What factors de­
termine how much public expenditure an indi­
vidual citizen demands? For concreteness, think
about the commodity "public education." Like
any other commodity, the quantity that a person
demands depends on his income, the price per
unit of education, his demographic status (chil­
dren or not), and so forth. As the price per unit of
education and the individual's income change,
so does the amount of his desired level of public
expenditure on education. In particular, other
things being the same, when the price goes up,
the quantity desired by the individual decreases
by some amount. This observation is crucial
because there is a direct link between the indi­
vidual's price for publicly provided goods and
the deductibility of the taxes used to finance
them. To see why, consider Smith, whose marginal
federal income tax rate is 28 percent, and who
itemizes deductions on her income tax return.
Then each dollar of taxes that Smith pays for
state and local expenditure costs her only 72
cents. Why? Because state and local taxes are
deductible, each dollar of these taxes lowers her
taxable income by one dollar. Given a 28 percent
tax rate, one dollar less of taxable income saves
Smith 28 cents in taxes. Hence, the effective
price of one dollar of public expenditure is one
dollar minus 28 cents, or 72 cents. More gener­
ally, for an itemizer, the "effective price" of a
dollar of state or local public expenditure is one
minus her marginal tax rate.
Suppose now that deductibility were elimi­
nated. How would this affect Smith's demand
for local public goods? Without the deduction,
each dollar of public expenditure costs Smith
exactly one dollar. In effect, then, removing
deductibility raises her effective price for a dollar
of public expenditure from 72 cents to one dollar,
an increase of about 39 percent. Now, assume
for illustrative purposes that whenever the price



Harvey S. Rosen

of publicly provided goods increases by 10 per­
cent, the quantity demanded by Smith falls by 3
percent. (In the jargon of economists, this means
that the price elasticity of demand for publicly
provided goods is -0.3.)5 Therefore, Smith's
demand for public goods falls by 11.7 percent
(0.3 x 39).
To summarize, for an individual who itemizes,
the elimination of deductibility raises the effec­
tive price (also referred to as the "tax price") of
publicly provided goods by an amount that
depends on her marginal tax rate. This translates
into a decreased demand for the publicly pro­
vided good. The precise amount of the decrease
depends upon the responsiveness of quantity
demanded to a change in price.
Note that for someone who does not itemize,
the story is quite different. The elimination of
deductibility does not change the effective price
of public spending—it is one dollar with or
without deductibility.
The Community's Decision. Imagine that
deductibility has been eliminated. The itemizers
in the community will want less public spending
than they did previously, although the amounts
will differ from person to person. The demands
of non-itemizers will not be affected. What will
the community do? The answer depends on
how public decisions are made. Although there
is no definitive model of how the public decision­
making process works, it is still useful to consider
one popular view of this process, the "median
voter model."
Imagine a community in which decisions on
public expenditure are based on majority voting.
Each voter has a most preferred level of public
expenditure, which is based in part on his effec­
tive price of publicly provided goods. The
"median voter" is the voter whose preferences
are in the middle of the set of all voters' prefer­

5For an explanation of the concept of elasticity, see Richard
Voith, "Com m uter Rail Ridership: The Long and The Short
Haul," this Business Review (November-December 1987) pp.
13-23.

19

BUSINESS REVIEW

ences. By definition, as many voters want more
expenditure than the median voter as do less.
Under a broad set of conditions, the outcome of
majority voting reflects the preferences of the
median voter. This is called the “median voter
theorem ." (See THE M AJORITY VOTES WITH
THE MEDIAN VOTER.) If the median voter
theorem applies, then to determine how the
community decision changes when deductibility
is removed, all we have to do is find how the
median voter's choice changes.
To illustrate, suppose that a community is
comprised entirely of itemizers, two-thirds of
whom have a marginal tax rate of 28 percent and
identical preferences for public goods, while
one-third have a marginal tax rate of 33 percent
and are similarly identical. In this community,
the median voter is one of the taxpayers in the 28
percent bracket. If deductions were removed,
the median voter's cost of each dollar of local
taxes would go up 28 cents. And if, as in our
earlier example, a 10 percent increase in the
effective price reduces the quantity of the public
good demanded by 3 percent, then the median
voter's desired amount of public goods falls by
11.7 percent. If the community's decisions are
guided by the median voter rule, community
expenditures fall by just that amount.
The analysis increases in complexity when we
make the more realistic assumption that not all
voters itemize. Indeed, according to the Internal
Revenue Service in 1985, only about 39 percent
of all tax returns were itemized. As noted above,
the elimination of deductibility does not change
the effective price for public spending facing a
non-itemizer—it is one dollar with or without
deductibility. Thus, if community decisions are
governed by the median voter model and the
median voter is a non-itemizer, then the elimi­
nation of deductibility will have no impact on
public spending at all.
How likely is the median voter to be an itemizer? The likelihood of voting increases with
income, but as income increases, so does the
propensity to itemize. Hence, we expect item­
izers to vote in disproportionately large numbers,

20


JULY/AUGUST 1988

a conjecture that is borne out by voter surveys.6
On this basis, a number of investigators have
argued that it is safe to assume that the median
voter is an itemizer, and local expenditure would
fall if deductibility were eliminated.
BY HOW MUCH WILL LOCAL
EXPENDITURES FALL?
For illustrative purposes we assumed that a 10
percent increase in the effective price of publicly
provided goods led to a 3 percent decrease in
the quantity demanded. In order to get at the
actual size of the effect of nondeductibility on
local expenditures, investigators have to examine
community expenditures, and how they vary
with the tax prices their citizens face. In some
cases, such calculations have been done assum­
ing that only households are taxpayers; in others,
that businesses also pay taxes.
If Only Households Are Taxpayers. Given the
median voter rule, a natural statistical strategy is
to gather data on the per capita expenditures in a
number of jurisdictions, and see how these ex­
penditures vary with the tax prices faced by the
citizens in the jurisdictions. (Of course, it is
necessary to take into account other factors that
might influence the amount of public spending,
such as the size of the jurisdiction, its median
income, and so forth.) A number of papers have
followed this strategy. In one influential study,
Martin Feldstein and Gilbert Metcalf found that
a 10 percent increase in the tax price leads to
about a 5 percent decrease in state and local
spending.7 For a city like Pittsburgh, for example,
whose general government expenditure was
$278 million in 1984, public expenditure would
fall by $13.9 million (0.05 x $278 million), if

6See Helen F. Ladd, "Federal Aid to State and Local
Governm ents," in Federal Budget Policy in the 1980's, ed. by
Gregory V. Mills and John L. Palmer (Washington, D.C.:
Urban Institute Press, 1984) pp. 165-202.
7See Martin S. Feldstein and Gilbert Metcalf, "The Effect
of Federal Tax Deductibility on State and Local Taxes and
Spending," Journal o f Political Economy (August 1987) pp.
710-736.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Deductibility of Taxes

Harvey S. Rosen

THE MAJORITY VOTES WITH THE MEDIAN VOTER
The median voter theorem has a nice graphical representation. In the figure, the horizontal axis
indicates the possible public expenditure levels in a hypothetical community with 461 members. The
vertical axis shows the number of people in the community who most prefer each expenditure level. For
example, 30 people most prefer $100 worth of expenditure, 50 people $200 worth of expenditure, and so
on. According to the diagram, half the voters (230 people) want $400 or less of expenditure, and half
want $400 or more. By definition, then, the median voter wants $400 of expenditure.
Now suppose that there is a vote between a $400 level of expenditure and any other level, say $600.
Each voter supports the expenditure level that is closest to his or her most preferred level. The $600
proposal will, therefore win the votes of all people who want $600 or more, as well as some of the votes
between $600 and $400. Because $400 is preferred by the median voter, one half of the voters lie to the
left of $400. Therefore, the $400 proposal will receive all of these votes and some of those to the right of
$400, guaranteeing this proposal a majority. Given the model's assumptions, no proposal can beat the
expenditure level favored by the median voter.




21

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1988

eliminating deductibility increased the tax price
by 10 percent.
A problem with Feldstein and Metcalf's analy­
sis is that, from a statistical point of view, their
estimates of the impact of the effective price of
public spending on fiscal behavior are not very
"significant." That is, a very wide range of re­
sponses is consistent with the data. Moreover,
other empirical studies have obtained different
estimates. For example, Douglas Holtz-Eakin
and Harvey Rosen found that a 10 percent
increase in the effective price would lead to an
18 percent decrease in public expenditure, a
rather larger magnitude.8 And in this scenario,
Pittsburgh's expenditures would fall by about
$50 million (.18 x $278 million).
Why do the studies differ? There are two
major reasons. First, different samples are used.
Feldstein and Metcalf consider both states and
municipalities; Holtz-Eakin and Rosen look only
at municipalities. Second, there are no publicly
available data on the actual tax prices in various
jurisdictions. Investigators have to try to guess
at the relevant tax prices by looking at data on,
say, average income in the jurisdiction. Unfor­
tunately, different reasonable procedures for
estimating tax prices can lead to quite different
substantive results. In short, data limitations have
made it impossible to reach a consensus on how
much local spending would change if deducti­
bility were eliminated.
If Businesses Also Are Taxpayers. The dis­
cussion so far has implicitly assumed that the
only sources of state and local revenues are
deductible taxes paid by individuals. In fact,
governments have access to other sources, such
as business taxes. Perhaps the removal of de­
ductibility on individuals' tax returns would
merely induce state and local governments to
shift more of the tax burden from individuals to
firms.

In the same study mentioned above, Feldstein
and Metcalf examined the statistical relation
between each state's use of business taxes and
taxes on individuals that are nondeductible, and
the average effective price of public spending in
that state. They found that states with higher
effective prices do indeed rely more heavily on
business and nondeductible taxes. According to
their estimates, if deductibility on individual tax
returns were eliminated, the increased taxes on
businesses and nondeductible sources would
tend to counterbalance the decreased taxes from
individuals. In other words, ignoring the possi­
bilities for substitution among different revenue
sources would lead to serious overestimates of
the effect of removing deductibility on state and
local spending.
Just as in the case of expenditures, however,
there is no consensus on the extent of revenue
substitution. Walter Hettich and Stanley Winer
used different data and statistical techniques
from Feldstein and Metcalf, and estimated that
barely any revenue substitution would occur.9
In any case, not all communities will be able to
substitute business taxes for individuals' taxes
to the same degree. Communities with very
little commercial property cannot be expected
to rely too heavily on business taxation, espe­
cially in light of the fact that businesses also can
"vote with their feet" if their tax burdens become
too onerous.
The possibility that at least some communities
can substitute among various tax instruments
has important implications for federal tax
revenues. From the federal point of view, pre­
sumably a major motivation for eliminating
deductibility is to increase revenues. However,
if removing deductibility would induce states
and localities to change their revenue structures
along the lines suggested by Feldstein and
Metcalf, then the federal government might not

8See Douglas Holtz-Eakin and Harvey S. Rosen," Tax
Deductibility and Municipal Budget Structure," NBER Working
Paper No. 2224 (April 1987).

9See Walter Hettich and Stanley Winer, "A Positive Model of
Tax Structure," Journal o f Public Economics (1984) pp. 6787.

Digitized 22 FRASER
for


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Deductibility of Taxes

gain much revenue from this policy change. The
key factor is that businesses would still be al­
lowed to subtract state and local taxes in the
computation of their federal taxable income. If
businesses have to pay higher taxes to state and
local governments, then their net income drops,
and their federal tax liability goes down. Thus,
while federal personal income tax collections
increase, collections from businesses decline.
The net effect is hard to predict; Feldstein and
Metcalf argue that under certain circumstances,
the federal government could even lose money
if deductibility were eliminated.
CONCLUSION
The policy debate over the deductibility of




Harvey S. Rosen

state and local taxes raises two related questions.
First, in principle should state and local taxes be
included in the base of an income tax system?
Second, if deductibility were eliminated, what
would be the impact on state and local public
finance? The answers to both questions are
inextricably linked to the issue of how public
sector taxes and expenditures are determined.
Unfortunately, there is no consensus on the
nature of the decisionmaking process of state
and local governments. Nevertheless, the re­
search does suggest that we can reject two
extreme views: that removing deductibility
would have no effect at all, and that it would
decimate the state and local public sector.

23

FEDERAL
RESERVE BANKOF
PHILADELPHIA
BUSINESS REVIEW Ten Independence Mall, Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574