View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ISSN 0007-7011
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

JULY • AUGUST 1987




Is There Consistency
in Monetary Policy?
Edward G. Boehne
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

JULY/AUGUST 1987

The BUSIN ESS REVIEW is published by the
Department of Research six times a year. It is
edited by Judith Farnbach. Artwork is designed
and produced by Dianne Hallowell under the
direction of Ronald B. Williams. The views ex­
pressed herein are not necessarily those of this
Reserve Bank or of the Federal Reserve System.
S u b s c r ip t io n s . Single-copy subscriptions for
individuals are available without charge. Institu­
tional subscribers may order up to 5 copies.
B a c k is s u e s . Back issues are available free of
charge, but quantities are limited: educators may order
up to 50 copies by submitting requests on institutional
letterhead; other orders are limited to 1 copy per
request. Microform copies are available for purchase
from University Microfilms, 300 N. Zeeb Road, Ann
Arbor, Michigan, 48106.
R e p r o d u c t io n . Permission must be obtained to
reprint portions o f articles or whole articles in other
publications. Permission to photocopy is unrestricted.

Please send subscription orders, back orders,
changes o f address, and requests to reprint to the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Department of
Research, Publications Desk, Ten Independence Mall,
Philadelphia, PA 19106-1574, or telephone (215)
574-6428. Please direct editorial communications to
the same address, or telephone (215) 574-3805.




IS THERE CONSISTENCY
IN MONETARY PO LICY?.......................3
Edward G. Boehne
In a speech presented to the Pennsylvania
Economic Association, President Boehne
applies economic theory to analyze the
conduct of recent monetary policy and the
challenges of policymaking in the future.
BANK LOANS AND MARKETABLE
SECURITIES: HOW DO FINANCIAL
CONTRACTS CONTROL
BORROWING F IR M S ? ...........................9
Mitchell Berlin
Will firms increasingly turn to marketable
securities instead of bank loans as a source
of funds for business? Recent economic
theory sheds some light on this question
by analyzing the essential differences
between bank loans and marketed securi­
ties. In particular, the research explores
the types of financial contracts among firm
insiders, firm outsiders, and banks as
delegated monitors.

NEW GUIDELINES FOR BANK
CAPITAL: AN ATTEMPT
TO REFLECT RISK..................................19
Janice M. Moulton
Bank regulators have proposed new capital
guidelines that are designed to account for
both the different risks of balance sheet
assets and the riskiness of a number of offbalance sheet assets that have become a
more prominent feature of banking. This
paper looks at how the guidelines would
be applied, how they would affect capital
requirements for area banks, and some
controversial issues that remain to be
resolved.

Is There Consistency
in Monetary Policy?*
Edward G. Boehne, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
One sometimes gets the impression from the
press and elsewhere that both the goals and the
conduct of monetary policy vary erratically, and
that there is no consistency from year to year in
monetary policy. Now the Federal Reserve is
said to care about exchange rates. Earlier it was
said to have focused on interest rates. Before
that it was said to have focused on economic
growth, or inflation, or unemployment, or the
money supply.

*An address to the annual conference of the Pennsylvania
Economic Association, Bloomsburg University, Bloomsburg,
Pennsylvania, May 2 9 ,1 9 8 7 .




As economists, we can apply some straight­
forward economic theory to see that monetary
policy decisions over the past several years do fit
into a consistent analytic framework. And we
can ask about the implications of that analytic
framework for the conduct of monetary policy
during 1987 and future years. Before applying
the theory we need to agree on the goals of
monetary policy, however.
THE TWO MAJOR GOALS
OF MONETARY POLICY
In my view there are two major goals of
monetary policy. The first goal is achieving
continued, sustainable growth to return the
3

BUSINESS REVIEW

economy to full employment and then to keep
the economy at, or near, full employment. The
second goal is reducing the inflation rate—at
least from one business cycle to the next, if not
from year to year—until price stability is
achieved. It is easy for economists and policy­
makers to agree on these goals; it is harder to
agree on specific policies to achieve them, or to
agree on exactly what we mean by “full employ­
m ent" or "price stability." Nonetheless, we need
to keep these goals in mind as we discuss the
theory of monetary policy.
THE THEORY OF MONETARY POLICY
Despite all of the arguing about the details of
monetary policy, economic theory tells us that
basically there are just two ways to conduct
monetary policy. The first way is for policy­
makers to use the money supply as an instrument
or as an intermediate target. To do so, policy­
makers would set the level and growth rate of
the money supply at values they believe consis­
tent with the desired level of output and desired
rate of inflation, and let interest rates be deter­
mined solely by market factors. The alternative
is for policymakers to use an interest rate as their
instrument or intermediate target. Policymakers
would do so by setting a nominal interest rate at
a level that they believe will produce a real rate
that is consistent with the desired level of output
and desired rate of inflation, and let the money
supply be determined by market forces.1
Although it is an oversimplification, we can
usefully think of policymakers as if they target a
sequence of short-run goals that converge to
long-run goals, and then set the value of their

! l should note that policymakers could also use the
exchange rate as an instrument or intermediate target. To do
so, they would have to let the money supply and interest
rates adjust to whatever values are necessary to keep the
exchange rate equal to its target value. In practice this would
mean giving up the possibility of an independent monetary
policy, and letting our monetary policy be determined by
foreign central banks. That may be a good idea for some
small economies, but it is not a good idea for the United
States.

4



JULY/AUGUST 1987

chosen instrument each period so as to hit the
sequence of short-run objectives. Regardless of
which instrument is chosen, the appropriate
value of the instrument (the value that will hit
the desired short-run goal) will change if there
are changes in other factors, or if there are changes
in behavioral relationships.
Theory tells us that the two ways to conduct
monetary policy will work equally well if there
are no unanticipated shocks to either goods
markets or financial markets, and if behavioral
relationships are stable. If there are unanticipated
shocks, however, theory tells us that the two
ways to conduct monetary policy will not pro­
duce the same results.
Theory also offers some guidance about how
to choose the instrument or intermediate target.
When goods markets are subject to demand
shocks, but financial markets are not, then the
monetary authority can minimize fluctuations
in output and prices around their target values
by using the money supply as its instrument or
intermediate target.2 But when financial markets
are subject to shocks and goods markets are not,
then the monetary authority should use an
interest rate as its instrument or intermediate
target.3 (I should note that the theory indicates
that policymakers should use a real interest rate
as their instrument in this situation, but in prac­
tice policymakers are limited to setting a nominal
interest rate at a level that they hope will produce
the desired real rate.) If we are in the unfortunate
position of having shocks to both financial and
goods markets, theory suggests that the mone­
tary authority should focus on the primary source

2In economists' terminology, when the IS curve is subject
to shocks but the LM curve is not, then using the money
supply rather than an interest rate as the instrument of
monetary policy will result in smaller fluctuations in output
and the price level around their target values.
3In technical terms, when the LM curve is subject to
shocks but the IS curve is not, then using an interest rate as
the instrument of monetary policy can stabilize output and
the price level at their target values, while using the money
supply as the monetary instrument will produce fluctuations
in output and the price level.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is There Consistency in Monetary Policy?

of shocks, unless the shocks to financial and
goods markets routinely happen to cancel. These
results were elegantly derived by William Poole,
who was then an economist in the Federal
Reserve System. I will refer to these results as
Poole's Rule.
While there are some important issues in
monetary policy that are not addressed by this
theoretical framework, it can nonetheless give
us a good deal of insight into the recent conduct
of monetary policy, and into the conduct of
monetary policy during 1987 and future years.
We will see that there is an underlying consis­
tency in monetary policy in recent years.
POOLE'S RULE AND
RECENT MONETARY POLICY
Many people have characterized monetary
policy as being "accom m odative" during the
past several years, by which they mean that
interest rates have fallen. I think that it is correct
to characterize monetary policy during 1985
and 1986 as "accommodative," if we use that
word in the economist's technical sense of
accommodating shifts in the demand for
money.
The last few years were a period in which the
demand for money grew much more rapidly
than was predictable on the basis of its historical
relationship to income, interest rates, and other
variables. The unusual behavior of money
demand has lasted so long that one must admit
that there was a shift in the demand for money,
rather than just a temporary deviation from a
stable demand for money function. That conclu­
sion is inescapable for M l, which grew roughly
twice as fast during 1985 and 1986 as we would
have expected on the basis of its pre-1980
behavior. The conclusion also seems true for M2
and M3, although their deviations from expected
growth are not so drastic. As best we can tell
within the Federal Reserve, the shift in money
demand reflects a change in people's preferences
about how much of various assets to hold in
their portfolios. The shift in portfolio preferences
has resulted, in turn, from deregulation of finan­



Edward G. Boehne

cial intermediaries and the resulting proliferation
of new financial instruments, such as superNOW accounts.
Poole's Rule tells us that the monetary authority
should choose an interest rate as its instrument
if the major source of uncertainty about the
economy arises in financial markets, in this case
because of unpredictable behavior of money
demand. That is essentially what the Federal
Reserve did. Henry Wallich, then a Governor of
the Federal Reserve System, described the details
of that monetary policy in a speech to the
Midwest Economic Association; his speech was
reprinted in a 1984 article in the Kansas City
Federal Reserve Bank's Economic Review. While
the Federal Reserve does not directly control
interest rates, except for the discount rate, the
Federal Reserve did adjust the supply of bank
reserves and the discount rate to keep the federal
funds rate roughly at a level that was consistent
with achieving the major goals of monetary
policy. And the Federal Reserve allowed the
federal funds rate to adjust in response to evi­
dence that the economy was beginning to deviate
from a path that converged to long-run full
employment and price stability.
Of course the FOMC did adopt targets for
growth of the money supply in 1985 and 1986.4
But the members of the FOMC recognized that
the targets were based on the assumption that
the demand for money would have the same
relationship to economic variables as in the past.
When that assumption proved false, money
growth was allowed to deviate from the targets,
in accordance with Poole's Rule. It is in this
sense that monetary policy was "accommodative"
during recent years; the Federal Reserve accom­
modated a shift in the demand for money.

4 The Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC, is
responsible for making monetary policy decisions in the
United States. The FOMC is composed of the Governors of
the Federal Reserve System and, on a rotating basis, five of
the Presidents of the twelve regional Federal Reserve
Banks.

5

BUSINESS REVIEW

We know that there were surprises in goods
markets as well as in financial markets over the
past couple of years, although goods markets
generally turned out closer to what economic
forecasters had predicted. Two shocks to goods
markets stand out. The U.S. trade deficit was sub­
stantially larger than had been predicted, in both
1985 and 1986, as prices of imported goods
responded with a longer than expected lag to
changes in the exchange rate. And tax reform
generated much weaker investment spending
in 1986 than had been predicted, because the
forecasters had not anticipated that tax reform
would actually be enacted. These shocks to
goods markets generated slower than expected
growth in output, and seemed likely to end
progress toward full employment, at least tempo­
rarily. In response to these shocks to goods
markets, the Federal Reserve lowered the dis­
count rate, and thus the federal funds rate, to
levels that seemed consistent with continued
progress toward the long-run goals of monetary
policy.
It is also the case that we had a good-sized
"supply shock" during this period—the big drop
in the price of oil during 1986. The Poole's Rule
framework does not tell us how to respond to a
supply shock; such a shock affects both the
markets for goods and for financial instruments.
We can easily convince ourselves that a one­
time change in the price of oil does not change
the need to use an interest rate as the instrument
of monetary policy, so long as there remains sub­
stantial uncertainty about the demand for money. The
oil price shock may well change the appropriate
level of the instrument, however, if the shock
pushes the economy away from the path that
converges toward policymakers' long-term goals.
On balance the oil price drop slowed the U.S.
economy in 1986, as the negative effects on
energy-producing regions outweighed the
positive effects on energy consumers. Thus the
oil price shock helped to generate a reduction in
interest rates during 1986.
Looking back over the past few years, we can
conclude that Poole's Rule serves us reasonably

6


JULY/AUGUST 1987

well as an aid to understanding monetary policy.
Monetary policy basically used an interest rate
instrument during a period of unpredictable
behavior of the demand for money. The outcome
was that the economy continued to expand, the
unemployment rate gradually fell, and the rate
of inflation declined somewhat further—even
abstracting from the temporary effects of lower
oil prices. We could have achieved even better
results had we been able to coordinate monetary
and fiscal policies more effectively, but that is
something that the Federal Reserve System
cannot do by itself.
THE CHALLENGE FOR MONETARY POUCY
IN 1987 AND FUTURE YEARS
We know that measured inflation in 1987 will
be higher than in 1986, because oil prices
reversed their precipitous decline, and because
the depreciation of the dollar on foreign exchange
markets is generating large increases in import
prices this year. Much of the measured deceler­
ation in inflation during 1986 was a temporary
phenomenon due to falling oil prices. And much
of the jump in the Consumer Price Index and
Producer Price Indexes early in 1987 reflects the
turnaround in oil prices and higher prices of
imports, rather than an acceleration of price
increases for U.S.-made goods. Because oil prices
are no longer rising appreciably, the jump in
measured inflation during the first few months
of 1987 is also likely to be temporary.
The challenge facing monetary policy now is
to ensure that temporarily higher inflation in 1987
is not allowed to become permanently higher
inflation during the following years. Fortunately,
higher oil prices and higher import prices are
not generating big wage increases, or widespread
price increases for domestically produced goods,
so far. Thus it should be possible to prevent a
sustained increase in inflation without causing a
sharp slowing in the economy.
What does the theoretical framework provided
by Poole's Rule tell us about how to run monetary
policy in 1987 and later years? Poole's Rule first
leads us to ask about the sources of uncertainty
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Is There Consistency in Monetary Policy?

in the economic outlook. In contrast to the past
few years, now it seems that the major source of
uncertainty about the economic outlook comes
from uncertainty about demands for goods and
services. While most forecasters now expect real
GNP growth of 2.5 to 3.5 percent during 1987,
and roughly the same growth in 1988, there is
much disagreement and uncertainty about the
sources of that growth. There is uncertainty
about fiscal policy because it is difficult to say
with any precision just what the Congress and
the Administration will do about the GrammRudman-Hollings deficit reduction targets. That
uncertainty is particularly acute for 1988. There
is uncertainty about the effects of tax reform on
consumption and investment spending; no one
yet understands the full implications of the new
tax law. And there is uncertainty about the future
value of the dollar and how much the trade
balance will improve.
Poole's Rule advises that a situation in which
the major uncertainty is about goods markets
(and thus about the location of the IS curve) is
one in which the monetary authority should use
the m oney supply rather than an interest rate as
the instrument of monetary policy. Which
measure of the money supply should the Federal
Reserve use as its monetary policy instrument?
On the basis of economic relationships up to
1980, one would argue that the Fed should use
M l because M l growth was closely linked to
economic growth and, with a lag, to inflation.
But on the basis of M l's behavior during the past
five years, and during 1985 and 1986 in particular,
one would be hard-pressed to justify using M l
as the monetary instrument. In contrast to its
historical trend of 3 percent growth, M l velocity
fell at an average rate of nearly 9 percent during
1985 and 1986. And it is still falling during the
early part of 1987. Even taking into account the
declining opportunity cost of holding checkable
deposits during 1985 and 1986, M l velocity fell
about four times as much as predicted. Until we
get evidence that the demand for M l has stabil­
ized, policymakers will be reluctant to put much
weight on M l (because, in economists' jargon,



Edward G. Boehne

controlling M l is unlikely to result in a stable LM
curve). But the Federal Reserve will continue to
monitor M l to see if its behavior does stabilize.
Because of the uncertainty about M l's behav­
ior, policymakers are forced to rely on M2 and
M3, instead. Prior to 1980, M2 and M3 growth
had a looser relationship to output growth and
inflation than did M l. But during the 1980s the
relationship has been much more stable for M2
and M3 than for M l. Still, the relationship
between M2 or M3 and future real GNP and
inflation is much too loose simply to set a value
of the M2 or M3 instrument that is believed
consistent with the long-run goals of monetary
policy, and then wait for the desired outcomes.
Instead, it will be necessary to continue moni­
toring other economic variables for evidence on
whether the economy is behaving as expected.
Some people criticize this as "looking at every­
thing," but it is a sensible thing to do in the
current economic environment. By continuing
to monitor a variety of economic variables, the
Federal Reserve will be able to recognize a situ­
ation in which it becom es necessary to adjust the
settings of the M2 and M3 instruments in order
to prevent a sustained increase in the inflation
rate.
By implementing a monetary policy that is
consistent with low and declining inflation over
the long run, the Federal Reserve will try to
ensure that the temporary rise in inflation that
we are seeing during 1987 does not generate
expectations of permanently higher inflation.
Following such a policy will help to ensure that
temporarily higher inflation in 1987 is not built
into large wage increases, or into large price
increases for domestically produced goods. If
we succeed in that task, it should be possible for
the U.S. to continue making progress toward
both of our long-term goals—price stability and
full employment. O f course, to convince people
that the Federal Reserve actually will follow a
long-run anti-inflationary policy, it may well be
necessary to adopt somewhat tighter monetary
policy in response to short-run inflationary
pressures. As Chairman Volcker indicated in
7

BUSINESS REVIEW

Congressional testimony at the end of April, the
FOMC already has taken a step in that direction.
Let me close this discussion of Poole's Rule
and how it helps us to understand current
monetary policy by cautioning you that the
Federal Reserve does not have direct control
over M2 and M3. So M2 and M3 are unlikely to
grow as smoothly as one might like. Because the
Fed can affect M2 and M3 only indirectly, it
would be a mistake to interpret month-to-month
variations in M2 or M3 growth as indications of
changes in monetary policy. But Poole's Rule
does indicate that in contrast to 1985 and 1986,
this year is a good year for policymakers to pay
more attention to the average growth rate of the
money supply—along with other data that would
reveal the presence of shocks to goods or finan­
cial markets—and to focus less on the level of
interest rates as an intermediate target.

8



JULY/AUGUST 1987

THE UNDERLYING CONSISTENCY
IN MONETARY POLICY
Let me conclude by recalling the two major
goals of monetary policy. First, a continued,
sustainable return to full employment. Second,
continued progress toward lower inflation and
eventual price stability. For 1987 in particular,
the challenge is to ensure that temporarily higher
inflation caused by higher oil prices and rising
import prices is not allowed to become perma­
nently higher inflation.
Economic theory tells us that the proper way to
implement monetary policy in order to achieve
these goals may change from time to time, as it
has during the 1980s, depending upon the source
of shocks to the economy. So while some critics
may give the impression that the goals and
conduct of monetary policy vary erratically, as
economists we should understand that there is
in fact an underlying consistency.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Bank Loans and Marketable Securities:
How Do Financial Contracts
Control Borrowing Firms?
Mitchell Berlin
INTRODUCTION
Even a close observer of today's financial
markets may be bewildered by the ever-changing
array of new financial contracts and the shifting
fortunes of traditional intermediaries. But behind
all this change, the same basic problem is being
solved over and over again by savers, borrowers,

•Mitchell Berlin is an Economist in the Banking Section of
the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia.




*

and the financial specialists who serve them.
Market participants are seeking the most effi­
cient way to transfer the savings of households
to firms who need funds. This happens when­
ever a saver decides whether to deposit her
funds in a bank or to call her broker to purchase
securities for her portfolio. The same is true
when a firm chooses whether to take out a bank
loan or to sell securities to the public.
These particular choices—the saver's choice
between deposits and securities and the firm's
choice between bank loans and securities—have
9

BUSINESS REVIEW

been a hot topic in the business press in recent
months. The reason is that some firms that used
to rely primarily on commercial loans have begun
to sell securities directly to the public. The growth
of the markets for commercial paper, mediumterm notes, and low-grade bonds has raised
questions about the preeminent role of commer­
cial banks as intermediaries between savers and
businesses.1 This has excited the interest of crys­
tal ball gazers seeking to decipher long-term
trends and economic theorists seeking to explain
the roles of bank lending and the direct sale of
securities in financial markets.
Banking theorists have been hard at work on
this problem in recent years. The kinds of ques­
tions that these economists ask are: What func­
tions do intermediaries perform that individual
security holders can't perform themselves? Why
do some firms seek bank loans while others sell
bonds to the public? Why do many firms secure
finance through a mixture of bank loans and
marketed securities? How do these different
types of financial contracts control the behavior
of firms?
One basic theme of recent research is that the
answers to these questions begin with a simple
observation: it is too costly for investors who are
not intimately involved in the day-to-day run­
ning of the firm, firm outsiders, to stay informed
about developments inside the firm. In turn,
they are unable to influence the firm to prevent
mismanagement. Banks arise to fill this gap;
they play the part of delegated monitors to keep a
check on the behavior of firm insiders, the manag­
ers who run the firm on a day-to-day basis.

T o r popular accounts of the changing role of banks in
financial markets see, for example, "The World is Their
Oyster," The Economist (March 16, 1985) p. 20, and "The
Consumer is Sovereign," The Economist (March 22, 1986)
p. 20. For a description and analysis of the low-grade bond
market, see J.G. Loeys, "Low-Grade Bonds: A Growing
Source of Corporate Funding," this Business Review
(November-December 1986) pp. 3-12, and the references
therein.

Digitized for10
FRASER


JULY/AUGUST 1987

BANKS AND OTHER FINANCIAL
INTERMEDIARIES
Depository Intermediaries Reduce Transac­
tions Costs. Depository intermediaries like
savings and loans, mutual funds, and banks link
ultimate borrowers, especially firms, and ulti­
mate savers, the households of the economy.
While borrowers and savers might seek each
other out and strike deals without going through
intermediaries, traditional banking theory says
that this will be a groping and inefficient pro­
cess.
To see the difficulties, consider what a typical
saver would have to do to invest her money in
some firm without using an intermediary. First,
she would have to locate a firm that needs money
and determine whether this firm is creditworthy.
Then, she and the firm would have to bargain
over how much money she will invest, for how
long, and at what rate of return. She would
probably prefer to buy securities with small
denominations that pay off quickly so that her
money isn't all tied up. The firm, on the other
hand, would most likely rather sell just a few
large securities, and it may need money for a
project that will not pay off until sometime far in
the future. Suppose the firm and the saver over­
come all of these problems and actually strike a
deal. Then she still has to keep a close watch on
the firm until she is paid back.
This account, of course, is very unrealistic. But
it does illustrate the notion of transactions costs,
that is, the time, trouble, and expense of trans­
acting business.2* More likely than not, these
costs are so large that the deal will never be
made. The firm will simply make a best guess
about the types of securities that can be sold.
And the saver will either buy securities that
don't meet her needs or refuse to buy securities
at all. Thus, transactions costs are a barrier

2See George Benston and Clifford W. Smith, 'T h e Trans­
actions Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial Inter­
mediation," Journal of Finance (May 1976) pp. 215-232, for a
discussion of banks as institutions that minimize transactions
costs.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Bank Loans and Marketable Securities

between savers and firms.
One way to bridge this barrier is with an
intermediary, such as a bank. Our saver can put
her money in the bank, which then invests the
funds in a portfolio of borrowers' IOUs. In effect,
intermediaries perform a number of functions
that match borrowers and savers. They buy large
securities, while offering savers small accounts—
a function called "size transformation." They
hold securities that are hard to sell, while offering
savers immediate access to their savings—known
as "liquidity transformation." By holding a large
portfolio of the securities of many firms, they
allow even small savers to diversify. Finally,
they monitor the firms in their portfolio.
Monitoring includes not only keeping track of
each firm's financial condition, but also super­
vising firms and enforcing loan contracts.
But Not All Intermediaries Act Like Banks.
Like banks, other intermediaries such as mutual
funds and money market mutual funds over­
come many transactions costs. They assemble
diversified portfolios of securities and sell differ­
ent size shares that are readily transformed into
cash. But, unlike banks, mutual funds perform
only part of the monitoring function. While they
collect and interpret information about the firms
in their portfolio, they do not supervise firm
managers or negotiate and enforce loan contracts.
Thus, a single transactions cost, the cost of moni­
toring firms, is key to understanding the differ­
ence between bank lending and other types of
intermediation.3
In fact, recent economic theories of financial
intermediation consider the cost of monitoring
to be the key to understanding the difference
between bank loans and all marketable securities,
whether held by intermediaries like mutual
funds or by individuals. Recent economic theory
views bank loans and marketable securities as

3Many of the statements made about banks in this article
are also true of insurance companies, which monitor private
placements— nonmarketable bonds usually held by a small
number of investors. Insurance companies have longer term
assets and liabilities than do banks.




Mitchell Berlin

alternative methods of controlling the behavior
of borrowing firms, each with its own advantages
and disadvantages (see A SELECTED BIBLI­
OGRAPHY, p. 18). By making a full account of
these advantages and disadvantages, the theory
of financial intermediation attempts to explain
the role of both banks and securities in financial
markets.4
THE TROUBLES WITH SECURITIES MARKETS
Insiders, Outsiders, and "Agency Problems."
"Agency problem s" don't just arise in securities
markets, they crop up any time people expect
somebody else to do something for them. When
someone hires a lawyer to represent him in
court or pays a mechanic to fix his carburetor,
the lawyer and the mechanic are both agents.
They are supposed to act on someone else's
behalf. Problems may arise, though, because the
agents have their own interests to think about.
The lawyer may do a shoddy job because he
wants to concentrate on a more important case.
And the mechanic's bill may include a charge for
repairs to a fuel pump that was working perfectly
when the car was brought in. In other words,
agents may well pursue their own interests
whenever they can get away with it, even at the
expense of their delegated responsibilities.5*
In securities markets, firms are agents of the
bondholders who lend them money. Bond­

4This article emphasizes the asset services provided by
banks. A second strand of the recent literature views banks
as providers of liquidity insurance— that is, the ability to
obtain funds quickly—to risk-averse savers. See Charles J.
Jacklin, "Banks and Risk Sharing: Instabilities and Coordi­
nation," Working Paper No. 185, Center for Research in
Security Prices, University of Chicago Ju n e 1986), for a
review of this literature. In addition, deposits are insured up
to $100,000 by federal deposit insurance agencies, another
attractive feature for risk-averse savers.
5Michael Jensen and William Meckling, "Theory of the
Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Capital
Structure," Journal of Financial Economics, (1976) pp. 305-360,
is the seminal article on agency costs in a finance setting. See
Oliver Hart and Bengt Holmstrom, "The Theory of Contracts,"
in Truman Bewley (ed.) Advances in Economic Theory,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press (forthcoming), for
a review of the principal-agent literature.

11

BUSINESS REVIEW

holders expect the firm to make prudent deci­
sions so that the loan can be repaid. Likewise,
firm managers are agents of the stockholders
who own the firm. Stockholders expect the
managers to run the firm as profitably as possible.
If bondholders and stockholders have up-todate and detailed information about what's going
on inside the firm, they should have a fairly easy
time controlling the behavior of their agents. But
more often than not, firm outsiders know much
less about how the firm is managed and how its
projects are going than do managers inside the
firm.6
Insiders have more information than bond­
holders about the firm's current revenues and
about the future of long-term investments.
Therefore, they can better assess whether the
bondholders will be repaid in full or not. Manag­
ers are also in a much better position than stock­
holders and bondholders to know if the firm is
being run efficiently, that is, if costs are being
kept down to a minimum and if people in the
organization are exerting all their effort. In addi­
tion, many complex and uncontrollable factors
affect firm performance besides management
decisions. When a firm performs badly, outsiders
often can't tell what is at fault: bad management
or bad luck.
Without firsthand information, lenders and
stockholders cannot be sure that their agents
will faithfully discharge their responsibilities.
The firm's managers have strong reasons to
report results that serve their own purposes
instead. They may understate the revenues of
the firm to reduce payments to stockholders.
They may exaggerate the probable returns to
troubled projects to avoid having these projects
liquidated or to avoid the blame for mistakes.
And since efficiency requires considerable effort,
self-interested managers may choose to take it

6This paper emphasizes the agency problem between
outsiders and insiders, but there is an extensive literature on
the conflicts of interest between stockholders and bond­
holders. See Smith and W arner (cited in A Selected Bibli­
ography) for an account of this conflict of interest.


12


JULY/AUGUST 1987

easy rather than work their hardest, or to indulge
themselves with perks. Expensive vacations
masquerading as business trips and three-martini
"business" lunches that last all afternoon are
well-known examples.
O f course, investors do have several second­
hand sources of information, such as rating
agencies, trade newspapers, and investment
analysts. But each investor will ask himself if the
gains are worth the time and money required to
collect information. For investors who do not
have substantial amounts of money invested in
any one firm, the answer will be "n o." Even if an
investor does take the trouble to become
informed, he must decide whether or not to use
his knowledge to take an active role in super­
vising the firm. Unless the investor has a very
large stake in a firm, he is likely to make a hasty
decision to buy or sell the firm's securities, rather
than take on the full-time job of attempting to
control the behavior of firm insiders. The same
is true of intermediaries like mutual funds, which
assemble a diversified portfolio by investing
relatively small amounts in particular firms. In
general, the holders of marketable securities
have little incentive to monitor firms to keep a
check on agency problems.
In fact, even though each investor may be
acting rationally when he chooses not to monitor,
too little monitoring will often result. This is
possible because monitoring is an example of
what economists call a public good.7* When an
investor supervises the firm, all other investors
benefit whether they monitor or not. But each
investor will ignore the benefits he provides for
others when he decides whether monitoring is
worth the time and trouble. Thus, every investor
may decide that his personal gains from moni­
toring are too small, even when the total gains to
all investors are quite large. Everyone would be
better off if someone chose to monitor, yet no
one may be willing to do so. In this sense, too

7See Stiglitz (cited in A Selected Bibliography) for a more
complete discussion.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Bank Loans and Marketable Securities

little monitoring occurs in securities markets.
Contracts Inside and Outside the Firm Are
Alternatives to Monitoring. Since securities
markets are plagued by agency problems and
inadequate incentives to monitor firms, why is
anyone willing to purchase any firm's securities?
Part of the answer is that the use of managerial
compensation schem es and the incentive fea­
tures of bond contracts can reduce (but not
eliminate) agency problems.
Stockholders, through their board of directors,
design reward schem es that tie top managers'
compensation to the performance of the firm. A
typical example is an incentive payment linked
to measures of success like divisional sales or
profits. Also, managers are given options to
purchase stock, so that they have a direct stake in
increasing the value of the firm.8 But the interests
of managers and stockholders can't be aligned
perfectly, because managers receive only a share
of the firm's revenues, while they exert most of
the effort needed to produce these revenues. As
lon g as they receive on ly a portion of the pro­
ceeds, managers will still expend too little
effort.
Many common features of bond contracts are
designed to reduce firm insiders' ability to
misrepresent the firm's current and prospective
performance. Unlike shares of stock, bonds
require the firm to pay a fixed return to investors,
usually broken up into a number of coupon
payments. These payments are usually made to
a trustee, who services the contract on behalf of
bondholders. And if a firm misses a payment,
bondholders can place the firm in default. In
addition, bonds contain covenants that require
the firm to satisfy a number of conditions or face
default. Some covenants require the firm to meet
minimum values for certain financial ratios—

8Anthony Saunders, "Securities Activities of Commercial
Banks: The Problems of Conflicts of Interest," this Business
Review (July-August 1985) pp. 17-26, describes the incentive
effects of managerial compensation schemes and the disci­
pline imposed upon management by the marketplace.




Mitchell Berlin

such as the ratio of working capital to total assets
or the equity-debt ratio—to prove that its finan­
cial condition is healthy. If the firm cannot meet
these ratios, it is often an early signal that the
firm may not be able to make payments to
bondholders.9
The threat of default ensures that firm manage­
ment will make every effort to repay bond­
holders whenever possible, which reduces
bondholders' need to monitor the firm's reve­
nues. And covenant restrictions give bondholders
the legal right to intervene to protect their
investment when the firm appears to be in
trouble. More often than not, firms will take
steps quickly to remedy any breach of covenant
restrictions. In more extreme cases, however,
the firm may undergo reorganization. And in
the worst cases, the firm's assets may be liqui­
dated and distributed to its bondholders.
But Bond Contracts Tend to Be Inflexible. While
bond contracts protect investors against losses
when a firm is in trouble, the price of that protec­
tion is inflexibility. A firm with a healthy future
may not be able to make payments because of
temporary factors beyond the control of manage­
ment; for example, a recession may cause a
decline in demand for the firm's products that
will soon abate. Or a firm might breach a cove­
nant because of an unforeseeable change in
business conditions. For instance, a firm might
fall below its working capital floor because of an
unexpected increase in production costs. Yet,
the firm may well be capable of reducing its
costs given sufficient time.
In these cases, both managers and investors
would benefit if managers could request some
breathing space to recover and respond. But
when no investor is willing to monitor the firm,
the firm's managers cannot easily convince
investors that a reprieve is not being used merely
to delay the day of reckoning. Thus, opportu­
nities for a timely renegotiation of the contract

9See Smith and W arner (cited in A Selected Bibliog­
raphy).

13

BUSINESS REVIEW

will often be lost. Instead, with the threat of
default in mind, managers will attempt to fulfill
the terms of the contract, even when this means
cutting back on projects that are fundamentally
profitable.
In the worst possible scenario, managers may
be unable to comply with the terms of the con­
tract, and a viable firm with severe, but temporary,
problems may go bankrupt. Not only can this
result in lost future earnings, but the firm's
managers and investors are forced to spend
precious time and money in expensive bank­
ruptcy and reorganization proceedings. Although
investors may need the threat of bankruptcy to
motivate the management to run the firm effi­
ciently, spending the time and money to act on
this threat benefits neither the firm nor its inves­
tors. Everyone (except the lawyers) would do
better to reduce the likelihood of unnecessary
bankruptcies.10*
The inflexibility of bond contracts is not such
a problem for large firms with long histories in
established markets. It is relatively easy to design
covenants that will not prove overly burdensome
when sales revenues are stable and when the
firm's usual balance sheet ratios are well-known.
On the other hand, firms in new markets or
markets undergoing significant changes are
likely to have unstable income and expenses.
Such firms will view inflexible bond contracts as
a straitjacket and will seek a more flexible alter­
native.11
BANKS ACT AS DELEGATED MONITORS
Bank Loans Are a More Flexible Substitute
for Securities. Firms can borrow funds from
households yet avoid many of the problems of
direct borrowing by taking out a bank loan. By

10See Brian C. Gendreau and Scott S. Prince, "The Private
Costs of Bank Failure: Some Historical Evidence," this
Business Review (March-April 1986) pp. 3-16.
n See Berlin and Loeys (cited in A Selected Bibliography).
In addition, some firms may be too small to bear the under­
writing fees and other costs of marketing their own securities
directly. These firms really have no alternative to bank
loans.


14


JULY/AUGUST 1987

borrowing from a bank, the firm replaces many
small lenders with a single lender. Since the
bank makes large investments in firms, it will be
more willing to monitor and renegotiate con­
tracts than would a group of individual inves­
tors.
When a firm cannot make interest payments
on time or when its balance sheet indicates
trouble, a banker's first response is to take a
closer look at the firm's condition. If he finds that
the firm's longer term prospects are good, the
banker may offer to reschedule interest pay­
ments or waive temporarily some covenant. To
make sure that good money is not being thrown
after bad, however, the banker must stand ready
to respond quickly to further declines in the
firm's health. It is the bank's willingness to
monitor that allows it to be flexible without taking
on excessive risks.
By monitoring, the banker is also better able
to determine whether the firm's managers are
acting efficiently. While it is clearly impossible
(and undesirable) for the banker to become
involved routinely in detailed management
decisions, the bank's watchful eye can reduce
the occurrence of serious managerial abuses. In
this sense, one can think of the bank as setting a
minimum standard of managerial effort.
But Bank Loans Don't Replace All Securities.
Although bank loans offer some real advantages
over marketable securities, there are good rea­
sons why we see a mix of bank loans and securi­
ties in financial markets. The first is that a little
monitoring may go a long way, because moni­
toring is a public good. While it is true that a
bank must have a substantial stake in a firm—or
else it will act much like other small security
holders—it doesn't follow that the bank needs
to hold all of the firm's debt. As long as the bank
is closely monitoring the firm, the firm's other
investors also benefit, even if they remain
passive.
Since bank supervision ensures that managers
exert at least some minimum amount of effort,
the firm's other investors know that the average
level of effort is higher than it would be without
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Bank Loans and Marketable Securities

monitoring. Indeed, bank supervision also bene­
fits the firm, because investors will be willing to
pay a higher price for the firm's securities if they
know that managers are being watched. When a
firm takes out a bank loan, in effect, it hires the
bank to certify that the firm is behaving efficiently
(see EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE THAT BANKS
ARE DELEGATED M O N ITO RS).12
The firm's other investors also benefit from
the bank's ability to renegotiate contract terms.
In troubled times, a firm will often meet with a
committee of its largest lenders to adjust its
contracts. This committee invariably includes
the firm's bankers, who represent both their
own depositors and, indirectly, the firm's other
bondholders. While the bank and other bond­
holders don't always have identical interests,
everyone gains when a basically healthy firm
avoids premature liquidation.!31
*
3
2

12See Gorton and Haubrich, and Stiglitz (cited in A
Selected Bibliography).
13Michelle White, "Econom ics of Bankruptcy: Liquidation
and Reorganization," Working Paper No. 239, Salomon
Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New
York University (1981), provides a good discussion of the
differing interests of banks and bondholders.

Mitchell Berlin

The second reason why bank loans do not
replace securities is that a bank, after all, is a firm
much like any other firm. When savers lend to
firms indirectly through a bank, they have not
found a magic wand that makes agency problems
disappear. The bank itself is an agent of its
depositors, delegated to monitor on their behalf.
Bank insiders know more than depositors about
the bank's current revenues, about problem
areas in the loan portfolio, and about the effi­
ciency of bank management. Bank insiders have
the same reasons as any other firm insiders to
misrepresent results and to take advantage of
perks. Since most depositors are unlikely to
monitor their bank, they must have some device
to control the behavior of bank insiders.
In fact, interest-earning deposits are a particu­
larly simple type of debt contract that requires
the bank to pay a return to its depositors. As in
other debt contracts, the threat of bankruptcy
gives the banker a powerful motive both to
monitor the firms in its portfolio and to make
required payments to depositors. Yet, this
arrangement shares the vices of other debt
contracts: inflexibility and the potential for a
costly, premature liquidation of the bank's assets.
When a bank fails, depositors may lose their

Empirical Evidence That Banks Are Delegated Monitors
Recent empirical tests in Christopher James, "Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans,"
Journal o f Financial Economics (forthcoming) are largely consistent with the view that banks act as
delegated monitors. James finds that when a firm announces a public debt offering, the firm's stock price
falls. This is not surprising, because bondholders must be paid before stockholders can receive any
payments. Yet, when a firm announces that it has signed a loan commitment with a bank, the firm's stock
price rises. This is true despite the fact that banks, like bondholders, have priority over shareholders.
This price rise may indicate that stockholders believe that the bank will supervise firm managers.3
While this suggests that the market believes that banks play a special role, it does not prove that the
market believes that banks are delegated monitors. For instance, an alternative hypothesis consistent
with the evidence is that loan commitments raise the value of the firm by providing insurance against
credit rationing or future increases in borrowing costs. Also, James finds that announcements of private
placements lead to a decline in the borrowing firm's stock price. This is troublesome for the view that
banks are delegated monitors, because the institutions that hold private placements— primarily insur­
ance companies—have many similarities to banks.

aEugene Fama, "W hat's Different About Banks?" Journal of Monetary Economics 15 (1985) pp. 29-36, uses a different
approach and also finds evidence consistent with the theory of the bank as a delegated monitor.




15

BUSINESS REVIEW

funds and borrowing firms may be forced to
engage in a costly search for alternative lend­
ers. These costs must be weighed against the
gains from having a delegated monitor.
If there were no bank regulation, this would
be the whole story. But regulators monitor banks
quite closely and enforce a weighty system of
legal rules and restrictions. By monitoring bank
behavior, regulators can reduce agency prob­
lems and reduce the likelihood of bank failures.
In addition, regulators are often quite flexible in
applying regulations to banks in difficulty. In
this sense, bank regulators may be thought of as
the bankers' bankers.14
On the other hand, bank regulations have a
strong element of inflexibility, because they
must apply to thousands of banks and cannot be
tailored routinely to the needs or capabilities of
any one bank. A bank will neither seek nor be
granted an exception unless the bank is in serious
trouble. While at least some of these regulations
may be necessary for the stability of the banking
system, their inflexibility must be reckoned
alongside the other costs of intermediated
finance.
Bank Diversification Reduces Agency Costs.
While the agency costs of indirect lending help
to explain why bank loans don't always replace
direct securities, they also seem to pose a paradox.
If depositors place their funds with banks to
avoid the agency costs of direct lending, but
simply end up with another agent who is difficult
to monitor, how can bank loans ever be an
improvement over direct lending?
Unlike the very best paradoxes, this one
disappears upon further reflection. The problems
of debt finance arise when a borrower with
basically healthy prospects cannot make current
payments. If the borrower has many separate

14The deposit insurance system also reduces the costs of
bank failures, because the failing bank's assets usually are
purchased by another bank, or the bank is simply merged
with another. Thus, most depositors lose nothing, and the
costs to borrowing firms are substantially reduced.

16



JULY/AUGUST 1987

projects in different markets, however, it is very
unlikely that all projects will go bad at once,
unless the borrower is particularly inefficient or
inept. Similarly, if a bank faithfully monitors a
large portfolio of loans that includes different
firms in many different markets, the probability
of many firms facing troubles at once is quite
small. And this probability falls as the bank's
portfolio grows larger and more diversified.15
Even with diversification, the threat of bank­
ruptcy forces the bank to monitor. If a bank is
lackadaisical about the soundness of its loan
portfolio, then many loans are likely to go bad
and the bank will be unable to pay its depositors.
But as long as the bank does monitor, the
revenues from a large loan portfolio will tend to
be stable. By monitoring, the bank reduces the
likelihood of bankruptcy for its borrowing firms,
and by holding a diversified portfolio, it lowers
its own probability of bankruptcy. Thus, indirect
lending through a delegated monitor that is well
diversified actually reduces the wasted time and
effort of premature bankruptcy proceedings.
SUMMARY AND OUTLOOK
Recent economic theory has provided new
insights into the particular role banks play in
credit markets and the essential differences
between bank loans and marketed securities.
When a firm requires outside finance, lenders
either must monitor the firm's affairs or provide
incentives for firm insiders to run the firm effi­
ciently. Marketed securities do provide such
incentives, but security holders will seldom be
willing to bear the costs of monitoring the firm.
By depositing their funds in a bank, savers hire
an agent to make loans and monitor the invest­
ments on their behalf.
The goal of the theory of financial intermedia­
tion is to provide insights into the role of inter­
mediaries and other contractual alternatives in
credit markets. But these theoretical inquiries

15See Diamond, and Boyd and Prescott (cited in A Selected
Bibliography).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Bank Loans and Marketable Securities

may also interest crystal ball gazers who want to
know whether marketable securities will
increasingly replace bank loans as a source of
funds for business.
Many observers have claimed that techno­
logical improvements have lowered the costs to
individual security holders of obtaining and
processing information about firms. In particular,
the largest firms are watched closely by many
market specialists, and individual investors may
have found that the cost of purchasing and
interpreting this information in a timely fashion
is decreasing. In fact, the larger firms have
reduced their reliance on bank loans, and money
center banks that have traditionally specialized
in providing services to larger firms have shifted
away from commercial lending.16 Should infor­
16See "Top 10 Business Loans Decline Again "American

Banker (June 2 4 ,1 9 8 6 ) pp.1-38.




Mitchell Berlin

mation costs continue to fall, the theory predicts
that more firms will rely primarily on marketed
securities.
At the same time, the theory provides a
counterweight to predictions that banks' com­
mercial lending will soon become a thing of the
past. Since diversification reduces the agency
costs of intermediated lending, greater oppor­
tunities to diversify loan portfolios should
increase the efficiency of bank lending. Thus,
the theory suggests that relaxed interstate
banking restrictions should enhance banks'
ability to compete in credit markets. Also, firms
in unsettled markets and firms entering new
markets should continue to rely primarily on
bank loans, because bond contracts are too
inflexible. Finally, since bank monitoring bene­
fits all security holders, even firms that sell
securities will continue to borrow through a
mixture of bank loans and direct securities.

17

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1987

A Selected Bibliography
Mitchell Berlin and Jan G. Loeys, "The Choice Between Bonds and Bank Loans," Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, Working Paper No.86-18 (December 1986), shows why particular types of firms will
borrow from banks and others will borrow from savers directly.
John H. Boyd and Edward C. Prescott, "Financial Intermediary Coalitions," Journal o f Economic Theory
(April 1986) pp. 211-232, presents an elegant but mathematically difficult analysis of contractual
alternatives to agency problems in credit markets.
Timothy Campbell and William Kracaw, "Information Production, Market Signalling, and the Theory of
Financial Intermediation," Journal o f Finance (September 1980) pp. 863-882, is an early, easy to read
treatment of intermediaries as agents that produce information about firms. The paper shows that
institutions other than depository intermediaries can serve the same function.
Douglas W. Diamond, "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring," Review o f Economic Studies
(August 1984) pp. 393-414, is the seminal article in the literature on banks as delegated monitors. It
emphasizes diversification as a means of overcoming the agency costs of delegated monitoring.
Gary B. Gorton and Joseph G. Haubrich, "Bank Deregulation, Credit Markets, and the Control of
Capital," Working Paper, Rodney White Center for Financial Research, University of Pennsylvania
(February 1986), presents a model of bank loans and marketed securities as complementary solutions to
the agency problem and contains an insightful discussion of the effects of technological and regulatory
changes on the relative shares of bank loans and marketed securities.
Clifford W. Smith and Jerome B. Warner, "O n Financial Contracting: An Analysis of Bond Covenants,"
Journal o f Financial Economics (1979) pp. 117-161, is an exhaustive and fascinating analysis of the
incentive effects of bond covenants.
Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Credit Markets and the Control of Capital," Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (May
1985) pp. 133-152, provides a readable introduction to the literature on market failures in credit
markets and explains how banks may play a special role in remedying these failures.


18


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital:
An Attempt to Reflect Risk
Janice
For many years, bank capital has been a
steadying influence on the banking industry,
buffering the risks that banks face. Now it is
receiving new emphasis. U.S. federal bank regu­
latory agencies—the Federal Reserve, the Comp­
troller of the Currency, and the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation—and the Bank of

*Janice M. Moulton, Research Officer and Economist,
heads the Banking and Financial Markets Section of the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Phila­
delphia. Special thanks go to Avraham Peled for expert
research assistance.




M. M oulton *

England have proposed new guidelines aimed
at establishing appropriate capital standards,
which require that a minimum level of capital be
held against assets.1 Unlike the current standards,

lrThe Board's guidelines released for comment on February
1 2 ,1 9 8 7 are based upon the proposed U.S./U.K. agreement
on primary capital and capital adequacy assessment. One
policy objective is to develop a convergence in the supervision
and treatment of capital of international banking organiza­
tions, a topic not covered explicitly in this article. The February
1987 proposed guidelines revise the Board's January 1986
proposal for a supplemental adjusted capital measure.

19

BUSINESS REVIEW

these new guidelines relate a bank's capital to
the risk profile of its assets. Although some
aspects of the new guidelines remain to be
worked out, the Federal Reserve Board would
use them in tandem with existing capital guide­
lines in the supervisory process.
Regulators proposed the risk-based guidelines
in view of major changes occurring in the
banking industry that have dramatically altered
the risk-taking environment. For example, banks
now are able to pay market rates on most depos­
its. Also, they can continue to expand into certain
new activities, and some of these new activities,
such as securities underwriting or real estate
development, are believed by regulators to
involve considerably more risk than, say, buying
U. S. Treasury bills. In addition, banks have been
expanding into what are called off-balance sheet
activities. These involve potential, or contingent,
claims on a bank rather than actual, current
claims, and hence are not on the bank's balance
sheet. These activities typically produce fee
income for the bank, and include such items as
financial guarantees and trade-related credit.
Overall, banks now face a much broader spectrum
of potential risks—with chances for large gains
or large losses—when choosing which assets to
invest in and which services to offer.
The new guidelines divide banks' assets into
five broad categories that correspond to levels
of riskiness. Included in those categories are
some off-balance sheet items, such as commer­
cial and consumer credit lines, and guarantees,
which the current capital measure ignores.
Accordingly, a bank that has more assets in the
high-risk categories or more off-balance sheet
items will need a greater amount of capital than
a comparable size institution with more liquid
assets and a lower risk profile. In general, most
banks, except perhaps the very largest, will not
need to raise additional capital to meet the new
guidelines unless higher minimum capital ratios
are imposed as part of the new guidelines. To
illustrate the local effects, adjusted capital ratios
were estimated for banks in Pennsylvania, New
Jersey, and Delaware; these banks generally have
20



JULY/AUGUST 1987

strong capital backing, and, indeed, their adjusted
capital ratios are higher under the new guide­
lines. In the future, however, these guidelines
will affect the distribution of capital among banks
as well as incentives to invest in certain kinds of
assets.
THE PURPOSES OF BANK CAPITAL
AND HOW MUCH IS ENOUGH
The change in regulatory stance to a riskadjusted capital measure that supplements the
current capital guidelines points out the different
functions that bank capital serves. Banks and
their regulators may have quite different view­
points about this matter, and correspondingly,
about the appropriate amount of capital.
From the Bank's Viewpoint... Capital for a
bank is primarily an investment in the institution,
which carries a concomitant responsibility to
return a yield to the investor. Bank capital can
take the form of equity, such as common stock
and perpetual preferred stock, or it can take the
form of mandatory convertible debt issues that
convert to stock at some future date. Reserves
for loan losses and other contingencies also
count as part of regulatory capital.2* In effect,
monies invested in the capital stock of a bank are
available funds. Naturally, banks want to put
that capital to use where it yields the most value
per dollar invested in providing financial ser­
vices to their commercial and retail customers,
subject to risk constraints. However, each bank
may emphasize different uses. For example, in a
bank where top management believes its most
important resource is its people, the emphasis

2For more discussion of the different items included in
bank regulatory capital, see R. Alton Gilbert, Courtenay
Stone, and Michael E. Trebing, "The New Bank Capital
Adequacy Standards," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review (May 1985) pp. 12-20. The proposed definition of
capital under the U.S./U.K. agreem ent in the new guidelines
consists of base primary capital (such as comm on stock),
which counts fully as primary capital, and limited primary
capital (such as perpetual preferred stock and some manda­
tory convertible securities), which can count up to a specified
percentage of base primary capital. See the Board's proposed
guidelines, pp. 12-22 and 57-73.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

will be on teaching employees new skills or
reorienting their thinking to a riskier environ­
ment. Others will want to upgrade their tech­
nology in order to support their expansion into
new activities and to modernize their operations.
And banks that plan to acquire and merge with
other banks need a sufficient capital base to
allow such purchases and still m eet regulatory
capital standards.
In today's competitive marketplace, banks also
prepare for the likelihood that they will accept
some risks that result in unforeseen, negative
effects on earnings. Banks use capital to buffer
their unanticipated earnings losses. Without
knowing exactly which losses will arise, bankers
can plan for some overall dollar amount of losses
on loans or investments, or losses through fraud,
interest rate changes, and other factors. Banks,
however, tend to weigh the costs—in terms of
forgone earnings—of maintaining loan loss
reserves and other buffers against earnings
losses more heavily than the regulators do.3
...A nd

From

Janice M. Moulton

goals of safety and soundness. For many years,
regulators have emphasized the importance of
holding a certain amount of capital against assets
as a buffer against adverse circumstances, to
buttress both individual banks and the system.
Because of these broader concerns, regulators
may demand more capital than banks would
otherwise raise. At the same time, regulators
stress that capital helps protect the solvency of
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) fund. The FDIC goes a long way toward
instilling confidence in the system by insuring
individual accounts of depositors of commercial
banks and savings banks up to $100,000 in the
event of a bank failure.4 Thus, if a particular bank
goes under, small depositors are protected. The
insurance fund, however, is a backup measure,
to be used only when a bank's own resources are
exhausted. To the extent that banks have suffi­
cient capital to withstand earnings setbacks,
those banks will not have to rely on the aid of the
FDIC to bail out their depositors.

the Regulator's Viewpoint.

Regulators are concerned not only about the
safety and soundness of individual banks, but
also about the banking system as a whole. They
recognize that when a single bank fails, it may
have adverse repercussions beyond that bank,
particularly if it reduces public confidence in the
ability of other banks to function normally.
Regulators are responsible for ensuring public
confidence in the banking system and in the
payments mechanism, confidence that is essen­
tial to a safe and sound banking system. There­
fore, regulators want to ensure that banks are
managed prudently, with adequate internal
controls, and that incentives encourage sound
management practices for individual banks.
Sufficient capital is critical to achieving these

3In fact, one study finds that direct bankruptcy costs are
negligible relative to the value of large banks. For a discussion
of bank failure costs (and the associated leverage decision)
in the 1930s and earlier, see Brian C. Gendreau, "The Private
Costs of Bank Failures," this Business Review (March/April
1986) pp. 3-14.




CAPITAL TRENDS
Regulators and Capital Since the ABC System.
Regulatory views on capital have continually
emphasized its importance to the supervisory
structure. Moreover, the idea of risk-related
capital requirements is not a new one; in the
1950s the Federal Reserve implemented a
variant of this concept called the Analysis of
Bank Capital (ABC) system.5*In some respects,
4Regulators also have proposed risk-related insurance
premiums instead of the flat premium currently in effect.
Conceptually, these insurance premiums would relate the
overall risk (credit risk, interest rate risk, and so on) of an
institution to the yearly premium paid; more risky institu­
tions would pay more for their depositors' insurance. See
"Deposit Insurance: Analysis of Reform Proposals," Staff
Study of the U.S. General Accounting Office, Volume 1,
September 30, 1986, and Mark J. Flannery and Aris A.
Protopapadakis, "Risk-Sensitive Deposit Insurance Premia:
Some Practical Issues," this Business Review (September/
October 1984) pp. 3-10.
5For a critical review of the supplemental capital proposal
and how it relates to the earlier ABC system, see Paul Horvitz,
"Warming Over the ABC Idea," American Banker (February
26, 1986) pp. 4-5.

21

BUSINESS REVIEW

the ABC system was a precursor of things to
follow. Using a very precise formula, the ABC
approach required a certain percentage of capital
to be held against different asset categories. For
example, the formula required that banks hold
0.4 percent capital against U.S. Treasury bills
and 10 percent capital against business loans.
Off-balance sheet items entered indirectly through
a capital requirement against trust department
activities equal to a certain percent of trust
earnings.6 Another forerunner of things to come
was that small banks were thought to have fewer
opportunities to diversify their portfolios, and
therefore, they were subject to what was effec­
tively a higher capital requirement than large
banks. (There was a fixed capital amount, which
translated into a higher percent of assets for
small banks.) As the ABC system evolved over
the years, it became more complex, more precise,
and more difficult to administer. It was finally
dropped in the m id-1970s because adequate
capital levels could not be agreed upon.
For the next few years, regulators persuaded
or cajoled banks into increasing capital when
needed and, in extreme cases, required a bank to
formulate a plan to raise capital. It wasn't until
1981 that federal bank regulators announced
minimum primary capital-to-asset ratios. Pri­
mary capital consists mainly of equity, undivided
profits, capital reserves, and reserves for loan
losses—all of which are on banks' balance sheets.7
But, at first, the regulators differed somewhat in
setting the minimum requirements. The FDIC
adopted a minimum primary capital-to-asset

JULY/AUGUST 1987

ratio of 5 percent. The Fed and the Comptroller
set the ratio at 6 percent for banks under $1
billion in assets and at 5 percent for banks over
$1 billion in assets, called regional banks. At that
time, the capital-to-asset ratios of the 17 largest
U.S. banks—often known as multinationals—
were considered on an individual basis, depend­
ing upon the overall characteristics of each
banking organization. In 1983, armed with new
authority from the International Lending and
Supervision Act, regulators adopted a (generally
higher) minimum capital requirement for the
largest banking organizations of 5 percent, the
same as the regionals.8 Two years later, in 1985,
all three federal regulators agreed on uniform
capital ratios—5.5 percent for primary capital
and 6 percent for total capital—for all banks,
regardless of size.9
How Have Capital-to-Asset Ratios Changed?
After hitting a low point in the late 1970s
following the demise of the ABC System, capitalto-asset ratios have risen for commercial banks
in the U.S. during the 1980s, as regulators raised
minimum capital requirements (see PRIMARY
CAPITAL-TO-ASSETS RATIOS ARE RISING).
In December 1980, commercial banks, on aver­
age, had primary capital equal to 6.3 percent of
their assets, while by December 1986, their
capital had risen a percentage point to 7.2 per­
cent of assets. These average figures obscure
differences among size classes, however. Small
banks (those with less than $200 million in assets)
long have maintained strong capital-to-asset
ratios, and currently average 8.8 percent across
the nation. In contrast, larger banks, encouraged
by regulators, have raised substantial amounts
of new capital in the last few years. Since 1980,

6Though trust activities are not the sort of off-balance
sheet exposure that the new guidelines are aimed at, trust
department assets are not on the bank's balance sheet. (Trust
income is reported on the income statement.) A capital
requirement against gross trust earnings reflected the risk
that lower trust earnings might adversely affect the bank's
earnings.

8Bank holding companies must meet the same minimum
capital ratios as banks, although the components included in
capital differ slightly.

7Minimum ratios were also set for a bank's total capital
(primary capital plus subordinated notes and debentures
and some other items); these minimums usually were a half
percentage point higher than the primary capital-to-asset
ratios.

9The regulators also established numerical zones for total
capital for banks with more than $1 billion in assets. These
zones set out objective standards on how the total capital
ratio works with the minimum primary capital ratio,
depending upon asset quality and other financial concerns.

22



FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

Janice M. Moulton

Primary Capital-to-Asset Ratios Are Rising

Percent

74
SOURCE: Statistics on Banking (Washington, DC: FDIC, various years). These data are from year-end call reports for all
insured commercial banks' domestic and foreign offices.

banks with assets between $1 billion and $10
billion have raised their capital ratios nearly
one-half of a percentage point, to 6.6 percent.
And the largest banks (greater than $10 billion
in assets) have increased their capital ratios from
4.4 to 6.6 percent over the same period. Taken
altogether, these numbers appear to support the
claim of a stronger capital base for the banking
system than a few years ago.
These numbers tell only part of the story,
however, because the existing capital ratio is not
sensitive to the risk exposure of the bank's assets
nor does it capture off-balance sheet assets. Two
banks can have the same capital ratio and the
same asset size, but very different overall risks
to their earnings streams if each invests and
manages in a unique way. These sorts of differ­
ences are what the new guidelines hope to
address.



THE FEDERAL RESERVE'S
NEW CAPITAL GUIDELINES
The Purpose. The basic purpose of the new
guidelines is to relate a bank's capital to its risk
profile so that higher risk activities require
relatively more bank capital. Accordingly, the
guidelines allow capital standards to reflect
developments in the banking industry that alter
asset risk. Two important developments affecting
bank risk have been the growth of off-balance
sheet assets, such as standby letters of credit and
consumer commitments, which are not included
in the standard capital-to-asset ratio because
they aren't counted as assets, and the reduction
in liquid assets.
Banks have taken on additional risks via offbalance sheet activities, risks that now represent
a substantial credit exposure. For example,
standby letters of credit, where the bank “stands
23

BUSINESS REVIEW

by" ready to make payment in case the firm
defaults on its transaction, pose a contingency
risk because the bank may need to make good
on its promise to provide payment. (These
increased from 5.8 percent of the assets of U.S.
banks at the end of 1981 to 11.4 percent in mid­
year 1985.) Similarly, loan commitments expose
the bank to risk because the bank promises to
make a loan in the future at the customer's
demand. Regulators recognized that implicitly
banks—particularly large banks—had an incen­
tive to circumvent existing capital requirements
by adding these and other off-balance sheet
items to earn fee income.
Banks also have reduced their holdings of
liquid assets relative to total assets in the last few
years. Indeed, for U.S. multinationals, the pro­
portion of liquid assets to total assets fell from
15.6 to 12.8 percent from 1981 to 1985. Liquid
assets—such as other institutions' certificates of
deposit, federal funds sold, and short-term
securities which are easily converted into cash—
enable a bank to m eet unexpected withdrawals,
earnings losses, and so on. But generally, banks
that are more aggressive in their funds manage­
ment have substituted higher yielding, higher
risk assets for lower yielding, lower risk assets.
Since many higher risk assets are also less liquid,
regulators grew concerned that the current
incentives encourage holding a higher risk port­
folio at the expense of holding liquid assets.
In responding to these developments, regula­
tors contend that the risk-based guidelines will
reduce the (distorted) incentives to shift into
off-balance sheet assets by requiring capital
backing for them. And they hope to stop the
downward trend in the proportion of low-risk
assets banks hold by requiring less capital to
back them.
How Do the New Guidelines Classify Assets
According to Risk? The guidelines chart a bank's
risk profile by establishing a relationship between
assets and five general categories of risk, to be
weighted at 0, 10, 25, 50, or 100 percent. Each
asset is assigned a category depending on its
credit risk, which is based mainly on the type of

24


JULY/AUGUST 1987

borrower. The risk categories cover both assets
that are in the standard ratio as well as offbalance sheet assets. Off-balance sheet assets
convert to a balance sheet equivalent before
being placed in a risk category. Interest rate and
foreign exchange contracts incorporate more
complex conversion factors. (See RISK CATE­
GORIES, A SSETS, AND CONVERSION
FACTORS: A SUMMARY, p. 26.)
Asset categories place cash and balances with
Federal Reserve Banks in the lowest risk class,
with a weight of 0 percent, meaning that cash
and Federal Reserve deposits require no capital
backing. Put another way, banks that wish to
expand these assets can do so without adding
regulatory capital. The next category receives a
10 percent weight. It includes claims that are
backed by the full faith and credit of the U.S.
government and that are highly liquid. Some
examples are short-term U.S. Treasury securities
and short-term claims on U.S. government
agencies, such as the Government National
Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae) and the
Federal Housing Administration. The 25 percent
category captures long-term U.S. Treasury secu­
rities and long-term claims on U.S government
agencies. Though there is no risk of default, the
higher weight reflects the interest rate risk
inherent in the longer maturity—the risk that
the price of the security will rise or fall as interest
rates fluctuate. Short-term interbank claims,
whether domestic or foreign, also fall within this
category; for example, fed funds sold to a
domestic bank and certificates of deposit of a
foreign bank are treated alike.
Assets that generally have more credit risk
than those in the above categories but less credit
risk than the typical commercial bank loan fall in
the 50 percent category. This category includes
claims on U.S. government-sponsored agencies,
such as mortgage-backed securities issued by
the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation
(Freddie Mac) and the Federal National Mort­
gage Association (Fannie Mae). These claims
are considered somewhat more risky because
they are not explicitly guaranteed by the full
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

faith and credit of the U.S. government. General
obligation debt of state and local governments
also falls in this category. Assets in the highest
risk category receive a 100 percent weight,
meaning they count fully as assets when calcu­
lating the risk-adjusted capital ratio. Many of the
usual bank assets fall within this group, including
commercial and industrial loans, residential real
estate loans, and consumer loans. So do corpo­
rate securities, commercial paper, and loans to
foreign governments.
Off-balance sheet assets are included in the
guidelines on a "credit equivalent" basis; that is,
the face amount of the item is multiplied by a
conversion factor to make it into an on-balance
sheet equivalent credit, which then is assigned a
risk category. The proposed guidelines apply a
100 percent conversion factor to financial guar­
antees that are effectively a direct extension of
credit to the customer. Such direct credit substi­
tutes would include standby letters of credit that
back repayment of commercial paper or other
commercial loans. Trade-related guarantees like
commercial letters of credit convert at 50 percent;
they present a contingency risk to the bank if the
party defaults on its obligations or does not
perform up to standard. Another group of offbalance sheet items that represent commitments
to extend credit have various conversion factors
depending upon the maturity, such as overdraft
facilities, revolving credit, and home equity lines;
the unused portion of these credit lines counts
as an asset, too.
In the February 1987 proposed guidelines,
the regulators expressed a desire to include the
credit risks of interest rate swaps and forward foreign
exchange contracts in the risk-based capital mea­
sure, and in March, the Federal Reserve proposed
a way to do that.10 The proposal is aimed at only
the largest banking organizations and is consis­

1 °For an understandable discussion of interest rate swaps
and how they work, see Jan G. Loeys, "Interest Rate Swaps:
A New Tool for Managing Risk," this Business Review (M ay/
June 1985) pp. 17-25.




Janice M. Moulton

tent with the credit equivalent approach used in
the treatment of other off-balance sheet assets.
The credit equivalent amount is the sum of both
a measure of potential exposure and current
exposure. Potential exposure represents the
risks that may arise later in the contract because
of fluctuations in interest rates or exchange rates;
it is calculated by multiplying the conversion
factor times the notational value of the contract.
Current exposure is simply the marked-to-market
value—that is, the amount the banking organi­
zation would have to pay in today's market to
replace the net payment stream in the contract.
See EXAMPLE OF CAPITAUTO-ASSET CALCU­
LATIONS (p. 32) for an illustration of the calcu­
lations involved in the risk-adjusted measure.
How Will the Guidelines Be Used? The Federal
Reserve is careful to stress the supplemental nature
of the new capital guidelines. That is, these
guidelines add to the current capital guidelines
rather than replace them .1 1 But federal bank
11
regulators disagree on this matter—the Federal
Reserve and the FDIC agree that the risk-based
ratio would be used in tandem with existing
capital ratios, while the Comptroller wants the
risk-based capital ratio to replace the existing
minimums for all national banks. To the extent
that the adjusted ratio requires less capital, the
Comptroller's proposal would allow banks to
reduce their regulatory capital, an outcome the
Fed is strongly opposed to. Aside from this issue,
however, the regulators are in basic agreement,
and this difference may be resolved before the
final guidelines are released.
In accordance with the supplemental concept,
the Fed views the risk-adjusted capital measure
as an additional component in the supervisory

11 The framework for setting the minimum level for the
risk-adjusted capital measure assumes the current minimum
capital standards will remain the same for primary and total
capital. However, the Federal Reserve probably will establish
new numerical zones for banks with over $1 billion in assets
to replace the zones currently used for total capital, and
these new zones may be higher. These zones would set out
objective standards on how the risk-adjusted ratio would
work in tandem with the minimum primary capital ratio.

25

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1987

Risk Categories, Assets, and
Conversion Factors: A Summary
Asset Risk Categories
0 Percent Weight
• C a s h — d o m e stic a n d fo re ig n

• Claims on Federal Reserve Banks

10 Percent Weight
• Short-term claims (1-year or less) on U.S. government and its agencies

25 Percent Weight
•
•
•
•

Cash items in process of collection
Short-term claims on U.S. depository institutions, foreign banks, and foreign central banks
Long-term claims on U.S. government and its agencies
Claims collateralized by cash or U.S. government or agency debt (including repurchase
agreements)
• Claims guaranteed by the U.S. government or its agencies
• Local currency claims on foreign central governments to the extent that bank has local currency
liabilities
• Federal Reserve Bank stock

50 Percent Weight
•
•
•
•

Claims on U.S. government-sponsored agencies
Claims collateralized by U.S. government-sponsored agency debt (including repurchase agreements)
General obligation claims on states, counties, and municipalities
Claims on multinational development institutions

100 Percent Weight
• All other assets not specified above, including:
- Long-term claims on domestic and foreign banks
- Claims on private entities and individuals
- All other claims on foreign governments and private obligors

Selected Off-Balance Sheet Assets and Conversion Factors
Off-Balance Sheet Assets

Conversion Factors

• Direct credit substitutes
- Financial guarantees
- Standby letters of credit

100 percent

• Sales and repurchase agreements
and asset sales with recourse

100 percent

Digitized 26 FRASER
for


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Janice M. Moulton

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

Conversion Factors

Off-Balance Sheet Assets

50 percent

• Trade-related contingencies
- Commercial letters of credit
- Bid and performance bonds
- Performance standby letters of credit
• Other commitments
- Commercial and consumer credit lines
(including home equity lines)
- Overdraft facilities
- Revolving underwriting facilities
- Underwriting commitments
j

Maturity®
50 percent
25 percent
10 percent

Over 5 years
1-5 years
1 year or less

Interest Rate and Foreign Exchange Contracts and Conversion Factors
Interest Rate Contracts

Exchange Rate Contracts

Exclusions

• Single currency interest rate
swaps
• forward rate agreements
• interest rate options
purchased

• Cross currency interest rate
swaps
• forward foreign exchange
contracts
• foreign currency options
purchased

• Spot foreign exchange con­
tracts
• futures and options contracts
traded on organized ex­
changes and marked-tomarket daily.

Conversion Factors for Calculating Potential Exposureb

Remaining Maturity
Less than 3 days
3 days to 1 month
1 month to 3 months
3 months to 1 year
1 year or more

Interest Rate
Contracts
0 percent
0 percent
0 percent
0 percent
0.5 - 1.0 percent
per complete year

Exchange Rate
Contracts
0 percent
1 2 percent
2 4 percent
4 8 percent
5 - 10 percent
plus 1 - 2 percent
per complete year

a Maturity is the original maturity date or the earliest possible time that the bank may unconditionally cancel the
commitment, whichever comes first.
bThe methodology used in determining the conversion factors is explained in a technical working paper by the
Staff of the Board of Governors, titled "Potential Credit Exposure on Interest Rate and Exchange Rate Related
Instruments." Estimates were made of the probability distributions of potential replacement costs for various
contracts over their remaining life, assuming matched pairs of contracts. The confidence limits for these distributions
correspond to the ranges for the conversion factors.




27

BUSINESS REVIEW

structure, to be taken together with other
quantitative and qualitative information. It would
add significantly to the off-site information
regulators gain through financial statement
analysis and surveillance techniques, which are
important in tracking a bank's ongoing financial
condition. The adjusted measure would also be
used in conjunction with the on-site information
gained during the examination of a bank and its
records. For example, examiners look at collat­
eral and guarantees associated with loans, both
important factors affecting credit risk. Examiners
also consider the concentration of assets in
various industries when assessing the risk of the
portfolio.
HOW WILL THE GUIDELINES AFFECT
CAPITAL RATIOS IN THE TRI-STATE AREA?
Banks in Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and
Delaware generally have strong capital positions.
The same factors that lead to the healthy financial
condition of these banks, the superior asset
quality, and the low incidence of problem banks
have enabled them to build up their capital at a
moderate pace.12 Over the last few years, banks
in the tri-state area have raised their average
capital-to-asset ratio, but not by as much as the
typical U.S. bank. Currently, the average capital
ratio for banks in the tri-state area is 7.02 percent,
just under the 7.20 percent national average,
and considerably above the 5.5 percent minimum
regulatory standard.
Table 1 compares the capital ratios under the
old and new guidelines for banks of different
size classes in Pennsylvania, New Jersey, Dela­
ware, and the region as a whole. The standard
capital-to-asset ratios in the top portion of the
table clearly show area banks are starting from a
strong position as they move to the adjusted

12For a discussion of the financial condition of these banks,
see Thomas K. Desch and Richard W. Lang, "The Health of
Banking in the Third District," this Business Review (September/O ctober 1985) pp. 3-11.

Digitized28 FRASER
for


JULY/AUGUST 1987

capital measure. The bottom portion gives esti­
mates of how banks in this region would be
affected by the proposed guidelines, using the
asset risk categories and off-balance sheet assets
(other than foreign exchange and interest rate
swaps), and associated weights. Because these
estimates required numerous assumptions
about the data for individual bank assets, they
are best viewed as illustrative of the effects, and
are not to be interpreted as precise measure­
ments.13 Nevertheless, the estimated riskadjusted ratios for area banks are well above the
existing minimum capital requirements, and, in
fact, are consistently higher than the current
capital ratios. Banks in each size classification
have higher ratios, from a gain of 1 percentage
point for large banks to a gain of nearly 3 per­
centage points for small banks. What's more,
even the few banks in the region that currently
have standard capital ratios under 5.5 percent
will find their estimated ratios to be substantially
higher.
The risk-adjusted ratios were also estimated
with interest rate and foreign exchange contracts
included with other off-balance sheet items. For
banks under $5 billion, the estimates change
barely at all, while banks over $5 billion experi­
ence a 0.3 percent drop in their capital ratios.
These results suggest that even large regional
banks in the tri-state area have minimal exposure
to off-balance sheet risk from these types of
contracts, and would experience little effect if
the guidelines should be extended in this
fashion.

13Many assumptions were necessary to estimate the
adjusted capital-to-asset ratios using call report data because
the data are not entered in the same way as the items in the
risk categories. For example, asset categories in the proposed
guidelines distinguish between claims collateralized by U.S.
government or agency debt (25 percent) and claims collater­
alized by U.S. government-sponsored agency debt (50 percent).
Line items on the call report, however, do not tell what
percent of claims, such as repurchase agreements, are collater­
alized, much less what form the collateral takes. A complete
listing of these types of assumptions is available on request
from the author.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

janice M. Moulton

TABLE 1

Comparing Current and Proposed
Capital Measures
Total Assets
(in millions)

Primary Capital-to-Asset Ratios
Delaware3

New Jersey

Pennsylvania

Tri-State

C u rre n t

Below $200
$200-$400
$400-$l,000
$l,000-$5,000
Above $5,000
Average

8.80
7.10
6.52
6.90

Below $200
$200-$400
$400-$l,000
$l,000-$5,000
Above $5,000
Average

11.59
8.27
6.73
8.25

—

6.99

7.39
6.35
6.75
6.66
6.10
6.64

9.48
8.21
7.80
7.03
6.57
7.20

8.89
7.53
7.41
6.82
6.52
7.02

12.52
10.24
9.99
8.76
7.47
8.50

11.74
9.41
9.32
8.34
7.50
8.40

P ro p o s e d 1
3

8.25

9.73
8.03
8.31
8.07
7.72
8.20

SOURCE: Data are from December 31, 1986 call reports.
aDelaware banks include only the home-state banks, not Financial Center Development Act banks or consumer
credit banks.
^Proposed estimates exclude foreign exchange and interest rate contracts.

These findings are not surprising, despite the
fact that the debate surrounding this risk-based
proposal has focused on the increased risks that
banks are taking. One explanation for the strong
showing of area banks is that three of the five
proposed asset risk categories are weighted at
substantially less than 100 percent, and cashtype assets not at all, in summing up the assets.
For area banks, this change apparently more
than compensates for the addition of some offbalance sheet assets (at the various weights) in
the calculation.
Another reason why area banks come out
stronger under the proposed guidelines is their
moderate size. Typically, the largest banks are
most likely to engage actively in off-balance



sheet activities, including guarantees that are
related to loan commitments, standby letters of
credit, and so forth. Small banks, in contrast,
tend to hold larger proportions of liquid assets,
which would fall into the lower risk categories.
In the tri-state area, only about 45 banks are
larger than $1 billion in assets, while nearly
three-fourths are under $200 million in assets.
Table 2 (p. 30) illustrates the proportion of offbalance sheet assets to primary capital for area
banks. The calculations show that, overall, about
26 percent of the 426 banks have off-balance
sheet assets greater than their primary capital,
and the largest banks, those above $5 billion,
have the highest average ratio at 5.9. When
interest rate and foreign currency contracts are
29

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1987

TABLE 2

Off-Balance Sheet Activity for Banks in Tri-State Area
Average Ratio of Off-Balance Sheet Items to Primary Capital
Bank Size

With Foreign Exchange
and Interest Rate Swaps

(Total Assets
in millions)

Number
of Banks

% of Banks

OBS/C Ratio

% of Banks

OBS/C Ratio

Below $200
$200-$400
$400-$l,000
$l,000-$5,000
Above $5,000

297
45
37
38
9

10.8%
37.8
64.9
76.3
100.0

1.79
1.93
2.14
2.70
5.85

10.8%
40.0
67.6
78.9
100.0

1.79
1.95
2.58
3.01
8.29

TOTAL

426

26.0%

_

26.8%

_

Proposed Guidelines

NOTES: To focus on those banks with the most off-balance sheet activity, only banks with ratios of offbalance sheet items to primary capital (OBS/C) greater than 1.0 are included in the last four columns.
Off-balance sheet items, including foreign exchange and interest rate contracts, are included at their
full value, not the credit equivalent, in the calculations.

added, the percent of banks involved remains
about the same, but the level of off-balance sheet
exposure relative to primary capital rises some­
what further for the largest banks.
WHAT LIES AHEAD? SOME OPEN ISSUES
The risk-adjusted capital guidelines are a
regulatory response to the increased variety and
higher level of risks that banks face in today's
financial system. These guidelines were devel­
oped in close cooperation with the Bank of
England in an effort to agree on a uniform
standard. More particularly, they are intended
to eliminate some distortions that have arisen in
recent years in the incentives to hold liquid
assets and to expand into off-balance sheet
activities. Through the guidelines, the risk
exposure of a bank is related to five major cate­
gories of asset risk, ranging from highly liquid
and marketable assets to typical commercial
loans. Because of the weights chosen for the
different risk categories, few banks nationally,
and probably none in the tri-state area, will need
to raise new capital to m eet the guidelines. The
Digitized 30 FRASER
for


incentives to hold capital against various assets
will become more explicit, however, resulting in
some redistribution of capital both within and
among banks.
These proposed guidelines have stirred debate
on at least three issues that regulators and
bankers must grapple with as the guidelines are
implemented. The first issue concerns the
potential for credit allocation. By their nature,
the risk-based guidelines attempt to restructure
capital incentives for holding different assets.
Since more capital must be held against assets in
the higher risk categories, bankers have an
incentive to reduce those assets and increase
assets in lower risk categories. And the use of
credit conversion factors for off-balance sheet
assets, while tailoring the guidelines to individual
items, increases the chances of credit allocation.
Moreover, there is considerable disagreement
on whether particular assets, such as loan
commitments, are assigned to the right cate­
gories. As a result, some critics oppose the
guidelines on the grounds that regulators should
not become involved in credit allocation. Regu­
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

lators respond that they want to clarify the
relationship between credit risk and capital so
that bankers can take these general risk cate­
gories into account when choosing their activities
and assets. Since the guidelines formally recog­
nize that more capital is needed to back higher
risk assets, regulators appear willing to accept
some redirection of resources. This acceptance
stems from a belief that, in total, the risk-adjusted
guidelines are not introducing new distortions,
but are simply eliminating old ones.
The second issue focuses on the ways in which
the adjusted capital ratio is a partial measure of
the riskiness of a bank's assets, and some per­
ceived disadvantages to that approach. The
guidelines' five broad risk categories would
surely be more finely divided for a truly riskbased measure. Further, the guidelines look at
only one asset at a time and ignore diversification
effects. They do not attempt to incorporate the
interaction among the different asset returns or
the presence of a common factor among assets,
which would be part of the assessment of the
riskiness of the whole portfolio. A well-diversi­
fied portfolio of assets does not concentrate too
heavily on assets in one industry or area, so that
adverse economic conditions in one sector do
not overwhelm the entire portfolio. In addition,
the risk-adjusted measure emphasizes the credit
risk of the asset and not the risks that banks face
due to interest rate changes, exchange rate
movements, and so on (although the March
proposal was a step in that direction). Regulators
are well aware of the limitations inherent in the
risk-adjusted capital ratio. They also want to find
the balance between the need for quantitative
analysis and the need for subjective judgment




Janice M. Moulton

that is critical to the examination process. Thus,
a comprehensive evaluation of the different risks
that banks face need not be part of the riskadjusted ratio since this analysis is covered within
the supervisory and examination framework.
A third unresolved issue centers on how these
guidelines will evolve over time. Will the riskadjusted guidelines receive greater emphasis
over time relative to the standard capital ratios?
How will they be integrated with the examination
process? Will the regulatory agencies attempt to
expand the risk measure to make it more
comprehensive? The regulatory agencies already
have taken steps to fine-tune the proposed
guidelines by adding conversion factors and by
expanding the coverage of off-balance sheet
assets. What other adjustments lie ahead? Fi­
nally, will regulators set the minimum capital
standards for the risk-adjusted measure above
5.5 percent, the current minimum for primary
capital, and perhaps raise them later?14 If so, the
guidelines will have more of a bite in the
future.15
These issues and the questions they raise point
to the complexity of the task ahead. The riskadjusted approach to regulatory capital entails
major changes that will take a while to work out.
Whatever precise form it takes, the risk-adjusted
capital measure will be a significant regulatory
tool in assessing the capital position of a banking
organization.

14The Federal Reserve has not set an overall capital rate.
15The guidelines also would have more of a bite if loanloss reserves were phased out of primary capital. The Board
raised this possibility and asked for comment.

31

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY/AUGUST 1987

Example of Capital-to-Asset Calculations
Under the proposed guidelines, where all assets are multiplied by risk weights, calculating the ratio of
capital to assets involves several steps. Assets on the balance sheet are simplest: they are just multiplied
by their risk weights. Off-balance sheet items are more complex because "credit equivalents" must be
determined before multiplying by the risk weights. For off-balance sheet items other than interest rate
and foreign exchange contracts, the credit equivalent equals the dollar value of the asset times a
conversion factor. For interest rate and foreign exchange contracts, calculating the credit equivalent
involves one more step: after multiplying the dollar value of the asset times the conversion factor to get
the potential exposure, the current exposure (the marked-to-market value) is added.*
3
2
1
To see these calculations played out, imagine a bank with $100 million in on-balance sheet assets
distributed among each of the asset risk categories, a selected mix of $100 million of off-balance sheet
assets, and primary capital equal to $7 million.1
3

Balance sheet assets

$100 million

Off-balance sheet assets
Standby letters of credit
Consumer credit lines (3-yr.)
3-mo. forward foreign exchange contract
3-yr. fixed/floating interest rate swap

Primary capital

20
40
10
30

million
million
million
million

7 million

Step 1. Calculate risk-weighted balance sheet assets.
Asset Category
0%
10%
25%
50%
100%

Balance Sheet Assets
5
15
25
15
40

Weighted Assets
0
1.50
6.25
7.50
40.00
55.25

aA positive marked-to-market value means that the bank suffers a loss when the counterparty defaults on the
contract and the bank has to replace it. A negative marked-to-market value for a contract indicates a default would
result in a (theoretical) profit for the bank. However, a negative marked-to-market number may offset the amount of
potential exposure (from future rate changes) only until the credit equivalent amount falls to zero.
^For the purposes of illustration, the following assumptions are made:
(1) all off-balance sheet items are claims on individuals or private entities, so their risk categories are 100
percent;
(2) the current exposure numbers in Step 3 are purely illustrative and represent the marked-to-market value of
the contract as of the reporting date;
(3) the conversion factors in Step 3 are at the lower end of the range.

32



FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

New Guidelines for Bank Capital

Janice M. Moulton

Step 2. Calculate credit equivalents for off-balance sheet items other than interest rate and
foreign exchange contracts.
Off-balance
Sheet Asset

Nominal
Amount

X

Conversion
Factor

=

Credit
Equiv.

X

Asset
Category

=

Weighted
Assets

Standby
Letter of
Credit

20

1.00

20

100%

20.00

Consumer
Credit Line
(3-yr. maturity)

40

0.25

10

100%

10.00

30.00

S tep 3 . C alcu late cred it eq u ivalen ts for in terest ra te and fo reig n e xch an g e co n tracts.

Off-balance
Sheet Asset

Nominal
Conversion
Potential
Current
Credit Asset Weighted
Amount X
Factor
= Exposure + Exposure = Equiv. X Cat. = Assets

3-mo. forward
foreign exchange
contract

10

0.04

0.4

3-yr.
fixed/floating
interest rate
swap

30

0.015

0.45

0.1

0.5

100%

0.50

-0.2

0.25

100%

0.25

0.75

Step 4. Calculate ratio of capital to assets.
Current guidelines:
Proposed guidelines:




$7 million/$100 million
$55.25
$30.00
$ 0.75
$7 million/$86.00

million
million
million
million

=

7%

=

8.14 %

33

The Philadelphia Fed's Research Department occasionally publishes working papers based on the current
research of staff economists. These papers, dealing with virtually all areas within economics and finance, are
intended for the professional researcher. The 19 papers added to the Working Papers Series in 1986 are listed
below.
A list of all available papers may be ordered from WORKING PAPERS, Department of Research, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 10 Independence Mall, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106. Copies of papers may
required.

No. 86-1/R

Edwin S. Mills, "Has the United States Overinvested in Housing?" (Revision of 86-1).

No. 86-2

Theoharry Grammatikos, Anthony Saunders, and Itzhak Swary, "Returns and Risks of U.S.
Bank Foreign Currency Activities."

No. 86-3

Paul Calem, "MMDAs, Super-NOWs, and the Differentiation of Bank Deposit Products."

No. 86-4

Richard McHugh and Julia Lane, "The Age of Capital, The Age of Utilized Capital, and Tests of
the Embodiment Hypothesis."

No. 86-5

Richard McHugh and Julia Lane, "The Decline of Labor Productivity in the 1970's: The Role of
Embodied Technological Change."

No. 86-6

Michael Smirlock, "Inflation Announcements and Financial Market Reaction: Evidence from
the Long-Term Bond Market." Reissued in the Review o f Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

No. 86-7

Brian R. Horrigan, "Monetary Indicators, Commodity Prices, and Inflation."

No. 86-8

John Gruenstein "The Pattern of Employment and Residential Land Use and Densities in a
Stochastic Model of Urban Location."

No. 86-9

Gary Gorton, "Banking Panics and Business Cycles."

No. 86-10

Gary Gorton, "Banking Panics and Business Cycles: Data Sources, Data Construction, and
Further Results."

No. 86-11

Aris A. Protopapadakis and Jeremy J. Siegel, "Is Money Growth and Inflation Related to
Government Deficits? Evidence From Ten Industrialized Economies."

No. 86-12

Stephen A. Meyer, "Gold Prices and Government Gold Auctions: A Test of Resource
Valuation."

No. 86-13/R

Gerald A. Carlino and Edwin S. Mills, "The Role of Agglomeration Potential in Population and
Employment Growth." (Revision of 86-13).

No. 86-14

Michael Smirlock and Howard Kaufold, "Bank Foreign Lending, Mandatory Disclosure Rules
and the Reaction of Bank Stock Prices to the Mexican Debt Crisis."

No. 86-15

Brian R. Horrigan, "The Long-Run Behavior of the Public Debt in the United States."

No. 86-16

Alessandro Penati and Aris Protopapadakis, "The Effect of Implicit Deposit Insurance on
Banks' Portfolio Choices with an Application to International 'Overexposure'."

No. 86-17

Gerald Carlino and Richard Lang, "Interregional Flows of Funds as a Measure of Economic
Integration in the United States."

No. 86-18

Mitchell Berlin and Jan Loeys, "The Choice Between Bonds and Bank Loans."

Jan Loeys and Herb Taylor, "Optimal Base Drift: Some VAR Estimates."
DigitizedNo. FRASER
for 86-19