View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Insuring Some Progress in the
Bank Capital Hassle
The Earnings Picture for Women:
Slack Job Markets Behind the
Downward Trend
Federal Regulation of
Stock Market Credit:
A Need for Reconsideration

business review
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA




IN THIS ISSU E . . .
Insuring Some Progress in the
Bank Capital Hassle
. . . Profit-motivated bankers keep trying to
operate with less and less capital while diligent
regulators strive to protect the economy's sound­
ness by resisting this decline. However, society's
interests might be better protected if this battle
over capital adequacy could be replaced by
charging banks a deposit insurance fee which
varies with the risks that their capital stinginess
imposes on society.
The Earnings Picture for Wom en:
Slack Job Markets Behind the Downward Trend
. . . Slack job markets for women workers spell
declines in their wages relative to those of men.
Federal Regulation of Stock Market Credit:
A Need for Reconsideration
. . . Stand-by margin requirements may be the
way to lessen the growing burden of security
credit regulation without discarding controls on
stock market lending.

On our cover: Andalusia, one of America's most famous Greek revival mansions, is located on the banks of
the Delaware River, just northeast of Philadelphia off US 13. The older part of the present structure was built
in 1795 and the stately portico was added in 1834. It was the home of Nicholas Biddle, president of the
Second Bank of the United States (1822-36), and has remained in the Biddle family since. Although pri­
vately owned and presently occupied, Andalusia is open for tours by appointment during the summer.
(Photograph for Historic American Buildings Survey by Jack E. Boucher and courtesy of the National Trust
for Historic Preservation, Washington, D.C.)

B U SIN ESS R E V IE W is produced in the Department of Research. Editorial assistance is provided by Robert
Ritchie, Associate Editor. Ronald B. W illiam s is Art Director and Manager, Graphic Services. The authors will be
glad to receive comments on their articles.

Digitized for Requests for additional copies should be addressed to Public Information, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
FRASER
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19105. Phone: (215) 574-61 15.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Insuring Some
Progress in the
Bank Capital
Hassle
By Ronald D. Watson

W hat do bank managers want less of, bank
regulators want more of, and ordinary depositors
seldom care a wit about? The size of a bank's
capital account (see Box 1). The generalization is
too broad, but it captures the flavor of a problem
that has long been a bone of contention between
bankers and regulators.

bank's front window. W h o cares how much cap­
ital the Ninth National Bank has as long as its
deposits are insured?
Clearly, the bankers and supervisors care a
lot— both have something at stake. But the gen­
eral public should also care, because it has
something equally important at stake. Capital is a
scarce resource, and society's best interests dic­
tate that it be used efficiently. If banks are forced
to use more capital than the market requires,
their operating costs and, therefore, prices may
be higher than necessary. However, bank fail­
ures resulting from inadequate capital can im­
pose costs on the bank's depositors, investors,
and the whole society. In the long run everyone's
interests are best served (and capital may be used
most productively) when each bank holds the
amount of capital which just balances the social
costs of its failure with the losses which result
from carrying more capital than the market re­
quires.

Aggressive bankers have repeatedly tried to
extend the frontiers of "prudent management
policy" by operating their banks with less and
less capital— often in defiance of regulatory
guidelines (see Box 2). Supervisory authorities
— on guard against bank failures— continue to
resist this decline of capital.
W h ile corporations with large uninsured de­
posits may be concerned about bank capital,
most small depositors are oblivious to the whole
issue. To them the safety of their money depends,
not on the size of that bank's capital account, but
on the FDIC membership sticker displayed in the




3

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

BO X 1

WHAT CONSTITUTES BANK CAPITAL?
It's axiomatic in corporate finance that a company must have some capital to remain in
business over any extended period. In this respect, banks are no different from other corpora­
tions. A bank must have a minimal amount of capital as a legal prerequisite to receiving its
charter. Furthermore, capital protects the bank's solvency by absorbing losses which occur in
the normal course of business. The key capital questions are “ how much?" and “ what kind?"
The basic building block in a bank's capital account is common stock— money invested by
the bank's shareholders in the hope of making a profit. All banks employ some of this
permanent source of funding. In fact, they need minimal amounts of common stock before
regulators will grant them a charter to begin operation as a commercial bank.
A second source of equity funds is preferred stock, although this is becoming less and less
common for banks. In addition, any bank that has been profitable has probably augmented its
capital account with some retained earnings. The high cost of issuing new common stock often
makes retention of earnings the least expensive and most practical way fora bank to increase its
capital account.
Less obvious sources of capital are the reserves normally set aside for losses on securities
investments and on bad loans. These two reserve accounts may not appear explicitly as capital
on the'bank's balance sheet, but they can be treated as capital. In the absence of special reserve
accounts, a bank's capital accounts would serve the same function of absorbing operating
losses.
The final source of capital to a bank is intermediate- and long-term debt (usually subordi­
nated to the claims of other creditors and sometimes convertible into common stock). Adoption
of this form of financing is a relatively recent phenomenon and is generally available only to
larger banks (although some small banks have been successful in selling debt to the general
public or to their major correspondents). However, debt has characteristics that make it riskier
than equity, so there are important public policy questions concerning the appropriateness of
treating debt capital as a substitute for equity capital.

to reduce their capital as long as they were w ill­
ing to pay the cost of insuring this higher risk. In
effect, it may be possible to substitute deposit
insurance for some of a bank's capital without
harming the interests of society.

Setting the “ proper" amount of capital for
commercial banks entai Is weighing the costs and
benefits to all parties involved. Regulators and
bankers each offer a solution to the “ adequacy"
problem. Unfortunately, there is little common
ground, because each sees his own objectives as
being of primary importance. However, since a
basic reason for enforcing capital adequacy
standards is to protect the nation's deposit insur­
ance reserves, compromise may be possible. If
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) were to levy deposit insurance premiums
according to the risk associated with each institu­
tion, bank managers could be given the freedom




THE SEED OF THE CONTROVERSY
Regulators and bank managers may differ
widely on the issue of capital adequacy, but both
embrace the same basic objectives for the com­
mercial banking system. Both want banks to be
safe, to serve the interests of the general public
and the economy, and to be profitable. They
differ on capital adequacy questions— and may
4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

BO X 2

A MINIHISTORY OF BANK CAPITAL
For well over a century this country's bankers have been steadily reducing the proportion of
capital they use in operating commercial banks. In the early 1800s banks relied heavily on
long-term capital for the money used in lending and investing activities. A bank raising
more than half of its funds from capital sources was not at all unusual.
However, permanent capital is usually a more expensive source of money than deposits or
other short-term borrowed funds. It stood to reason that a bank could increase its profits if
deposits could be increased relative to capital funds— subject, of course, to preserving the
safety and stability of the bank's operations.
Over the years, then, competition and desire for greater profits have led bankers to whittle
away at their capital accounts— not by reducing the size of the capital account, but by failing to
augment it at the same rate that the bank's assets were expanding. As a result, very few banks in
operation today count on capital to provide more than 10 percent of their funds. For some the
proportion is even below 5 percent.
W h ile today's banks may be much better managed than those of 40 to 50 years ago, the basic
reason that banks have been able to reduce their reliance on capital as a source of working
funds is the increasing stability of the commercial banking industry. Creation of the
national banking system and the Federal Reserve System made banking a more sound industry.
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation was also instrumental in stabilizing the industry.
This insurance increased the public's confidence in banks and made deposits a less volatile
source of funds to the banks. If bankers can count on their deposits to provide a large and stable
proportion of their operating funds, they can reduce their reliance on the more expensive
alternative source— capital. Continuing expansion and the stability of the economy since the
Depression have enabled bankers to reduce their capital accounts to very low levels relative to
their asset holdings.
Expansion into new bank-related activities through the holding company organization has
injected another element of uncertainty into the banking business. The Federal Reserve Board
has recently been applying pressure to the most aggressive banks and their holding companies
to increase their capitalization. No one is positive that capital positions have been reduced to
their absolute minimum working levels, but Federal Reserve authorities are unwilling to take
additional risks in this area.

the one hand, bank regulators want banks to
compete, because competition will stimulate the
industry to be as efficient as possible. On the
other hand, bank failures can have a very high
cost for society, and regulators must try to pre­
vent the costs of bank failures from exceeding
any benefits that might be gained from competi­
tion.
On an operating level, the bank supervisor
doesn't always prefer more capital to less. He

always differ— because each attaches different
priorities to accomplishing these objectives.

The Regulator's Priorities. There are many
reasons for regulating banks, but the most impor­
tant one is protecting the public's best interests.
In broad terms, this means trying to assure that
the banking community uses its resources effi­
ciently and that the social costs associated with
banking are borne as equitably as possible. On




5

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

are risky and would require capital and extensive
management attention. Even a management that
is strongly profit-oriented may judge the added
risks to be too great for existing capital to support
and would then have an incentive to get more
capital. However, adding more capital is de­
signed to achieve that combination of risks and
profits that management feels is ideal for the
bank rather than simply to avoid risks.

knows that excessive amounts of capital can
prevent a bank from earning the return necessary
to stay in business and attract new capital for
growth. However, while his charge is to protect
the public interest, this broad objective tends to
be translated into the more easily measured (and
less appropriate) goal of trying to prevent banks
from failing. A banking industry with very few
failures inspires public confidence.
It also gives the appearance that the regulator
has done his job well. His performance is not
measured by his ability to hold the combined
costs of regulation and bank failures to a
minimum. Instead, he is judged by the number
and size of the banks that fold.1 Regulators suffer
a high personal cost when a bank's capital turns
out to be inadequate, but none when it's too
high.2

What Is an Unusual Loss? A crucial differ­
ence in the way regulators and bankers treat
capital is the magnitude of the losses each ex­
pects it to absorb. Both presume that the capital
account should be sufficient to cover any and all
of the common losses that banks face. Operating
expenses may be unexpectedly high, bonds may
have to be liquidated to meet deposit withdraw­
als or to adjust the maturity structure of the port­
folio, and some loans will certainly sour. That's
the nature of the business. However, with few
exceptions these losses should be small enough
that they can be covered out of current earnings.
A profitable operation is clearly the bank's first
line of defense against occasional losses.3
It's the question of covering unusual losses
that brings out differences of opinion. Aggressive
bankers believe that they should be responsible
for handling any losses resulting from an
economic recession or from a mild natural disas­
ter but should not be prepared for another de­
pression or the losses resulting from a collapse
of financial markets. They argue that the Federal
Government is officially committed to programs
of economic stabilization. W hat's more, the
economy has been able to stay on a "reasona­
bly" steady course since the 1940s. In light of
this experience, it may be wasteful to plan the
industry's liquidity and capital requirements
around another depression.
Regulators don't really want capital adequate
for another depression,4 but they clearly want

The Banker's Priorities. The bank manager
finds himself in the opposite position. His goal is
sizable profits for the bank's stockholders. His
salary and promotions depend on making
profits— not simply on avoiding bankruptcy.
Naturally, success in the long run requires that
the banker protect the interests of depositors and
shareholders by maintaining the bank's sol­
vency. He must also safeguard its solvency to
protect his own reputation, future job prospects,
stock options, and pension. However, solvency
is a constraint on the manager's decisions rather
than a primary objective.
A rational banker will want additional capital
if his current capital base is insufficient. A bank
wanting to add new services, open additional
offices, or move into new markets may need
more capital before tackling these activities. All
’ In the minds of some critics, the occurrence of a bank
failure is presumed to be sufficient reason for closer regula­
tory control. Seldom is concern shown for balancing the
costs of more supervision with the probable benefits it
would yield.

3ln 1971, the worst year for loan losses that the industry has
faced since W o rld W a r II, the industry's ratio of net loan loss
to after-tax earnings was just under 21 percent.

2lt isn't clear that supervisory authorities have been suc­
cessful in their attempts to make banks em ploy more capital
than the banks feel they need. (See Sam Peltzman, “ Capital
Investment in Comm ercial Banks and Its Relationship to
Portfolio Regulation/' Journal of Political Economy, 78
[1970]: 1-26.)




“ Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Annual Report—
1957 (Washington: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
1958), p. 49.

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

should be taken strictly at face value without the
benefit of judgmental modification. But the fact
that ratios are the foundation of the evaluation
indicates that many regulators find them useful
and more defensible than any alternative mea­
sure.
Underlying this reliance on ratios is the belief
that, forall theirfaults, they're the most workable
analytical tool available. There is a body of his­
torical information available about bank capital
ratios. The analysis that has been done of histori­
cal experience used ratio analysis. In short, ex­
aminers feel comfortable in their beliefs about
what capital levels have been adequate histori­
cally. Regulators argue that they have been flexi­
ble in applying ratios, and that their perceptions
of capital needs have changed in recent years.
However, the regulator wants to minimize bank
failures by sticking to "proven" methods of capi­
tal evaluation even though they may not be ap­
propriate for fully evaluating "adequacy."

banks to be prepared for emergencies worse than
anything experienced since the 1940s. The for­
mulas used by bank supervisors (see Box 3) to
define capital adequacy are based, in some
sense, on a pessimistic psychology. In effect,
they assume that the bank is sold to pay the
depositor's claims with all expected losses from
asset liquidation made up from capital. If liquida­
tion were the standard way to handle an insol­
vency problem, this would be reasonable, but
many banks— e sp ecially larger ones— that
encounter problems are merged into other insti­
tutions.5 In that case, the conservative valuation
placed on bank buildings and certain loan
categories may undervalue the assets and there­
by overstate real capital needs— or so say the
bankers.

THE "P R O P ER " APPROACH TO
CAPITAL EVALUATION
Differences over the actual amount of capital a
bank should have are the chief disagreements
that arise between aggressive bankers and strict
regulators, but they are not the only ones. Bank­
ers and supervisors also have rather opposite
philosophies of how capital needs should be
calculated.

The Manager's Market Method. W h ile some
regulators are wedded to ratio analysis, aggres­
sive banks are equally committed to using the
capital market's evaluation of their institution as
the true measure of its soundness. Bankers hold
that the investors who supply the bank with debt
and equity capital are equipped to evaluate the
risks inherent in their investment. Stockholders
obviously wantto avoid defaults and insolvency,
but their interest in profits provides a balancing
motive for economizing on capital. Bankers also
claim that a stockholder is more likely to eval­
uate the bank as an ongoing organization
and examine its ability to meet obligations
through profits and liabilities management7 as
well as through asset liquidation. Factors such as
management quality, liquidity, and growth
prospects also enter into an investor's determina­
tion of a bank's capital adequacy in much the

The Regulator's Ratios. In general, supervi­
sory authorities have shown a strong preference
for ratio analysis in measuring a bank's capital
position.6 Such affection is understandable. The
objective numerical precision that ratio analysis
offers is reassuring in an area fraught with uncer­
tainties. Ratios also enable the analyst to com­
pare a bank with others in the industry or with its
own past record.
No regulator would suggest that ratio analysis

5Roughly half of the banks that have failed since 1945 were
merged into other institutions. H ow ever, many banking
problems are solved by the regulators prior to an official
failure, by merging the weak bank or by finding new capital
for the bank.

lia b ilitie s management is a relatively new technique for
bank liquidity managers. It involves meeting a need for cash
by acquiring a new liability rather than by selling an asset. For
instance, a large deposit withdrawal might be covered by
selling new certificate of deposit liabilities rather than by
liquidating an existing investment.

T h e Comptroller of the Currency's examiners claim that
they rely only incidentally on formulas and ratio analysis to
evaluate bank capital adequacy.




7

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

BO X 3

MEASURING CAPITAL ADEQUACY
Imagine trying to draw a precise blueprint with a stubby piece of charcoal. The tool just isn't
up to the task. Much the same can be said about trying to "measure" the adequacy of a bank's
capital account. Regulators have only the foggiest conceptual notion of what constitutes
adequate capital. Finding numerical measures for capital adequacy just compounds the
problem.
The commonest adequacy measures depend on analysis of financial ratios— primarily
comparisons of accounts on the bank's balance sheet. The grossest of these tools are the ratios
of capital to assets and capital to deposits. The capital-to-assets ratio implies that a bank's risks
stem from its asset holdings. The greater the size of the capital account relative to total assets,
the lower the chance that losses suffered on asset values will impair the bank's solvency or
result in losses to depositors. Much the same information is gleaned from the capital-todeposits ratio. The principal objective of this measure is to define the proportion of longversus short-term funds being used by the bank. The more long-term funds employed, the
lower the risk of losses to depositors.
Of necessity, a somewhat more sophisticated measure— a ratio comparing a bank's capital
to its risky assets— was developed following World W ar II. During the war banks bought a large
share of the newly created Government war debt without increasing their capital accounts
proportionately. This change in the asset structure of banks caused many of them to "fa il" the
basic capital adequacy tests. The problem focused attention on the economic fact that the
composition of a bank's assets could have as much to do with its risk as the size of its assets.
Accordingly, the capital adequacy ratios were revised to fit the new industry structure. The new
measure of capital adequacy was capital-to-risk assets, where risk assets were defined as total
assets minus cash, bank balances, and U. S. Government securities.
Still other refinements were in order— one of the most elaborate being an adjusted risk asset
method developed in the Federal Reserve System in the early 1950s. Bank assets were
categorized according to their probable risk and assigned a hypothetical capital reserve
depending on the amount of the asset held. The sum of these hypothetical reserves (with an
additional adjustment for liquidity) set a standard for "adequate" capital in the bank being
analyzed.*
Each succeeding refinement of the capital adequacy measures has added more surface
realism to the analysis process. Flowever, the implied precision of these refinements may lull
users into assuming these tools have a higher level of accuracy than is really the case. Aware of
the inherent fallibility of ratio measures and of the need for using seasoned judgment in
evaluating capital adequacy, regulators try to temper their numerical analysis by considering
other factors. In addition to an examination of a bank's capital position from its balance sheets,
most supervisory authorities consider factors such as profitability, management quality, effi­
ciency, fixed costs, and competitive environment. Ratios have an important place in this
informal analysis, but bank regulators usually try not to be dependent on them for an "answ er"
to the question: "Is capital adequate?"
*This formula was revised in 1972.




8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA
the number of bank failures that were averted
because regulators required additions to the cap­
ital of weak banks. However, statistical analysis
has shown that capital ratios for banks that have
failed are seldom materially different from those
of banks that didn't fail. A crucial reason for this
is that many banks failed because of fraud or bad
management practices that aren't captured in the
ratio comparisons. Two banks with apparently
identical balance sheets can have very different
insolvency risks, and, therefore, needs for capi­
tal.
Bank regulators include these incidental fac­
tors in deciding how vigorously to enforce the
capital standards. Nonetheless, if judgmental
factors become overwhelming considerations in
the evaluation of capital, an elaborate ratio
analysis scheme is rather pointless. Furthermore,
regulators note that the market's stock analysts
and securities rating agencies also use ratios in
making their assessments of risk.
The social costs of bank failure represent the
key reason why an unmodified “ market dis­
cipline" rule is inadequate.9 A bank's failure
has an obvious cost to its investors, but their
loss is limited to their investment. However,
society may also pay a cost. Apart from the many
inconveniences suffered by a local community
when a bank that serves it fails, banks are a vital
cog in the nation's economy— as savings and
safekeeping institutions, lenders, and payments
system intermediaries. If a large bank should
fail— or more important, a number of large
banks— the event could disrupt the public's con­
fidence in the soundness of the industry. In the
extreme, a 1930s-style “ run" on the banks could
develop with accompanying liquidity crises,
contractions of reserves, and severe strains on
the resources of the FDIC
This scenario is highly unlikely. The Govern­
ment's economic stabilization policies, deposit

same way that they influence a regulator's.
The attractiveness of a bank's stock (its profit
potential and risk) determines the price that the
institution must pay for new capital. Sharehold­
ers are more vulnerable to loss than any of the
bank's creditors or depositors. If either the cur­
rent or potential stockholders feel that the bank's
capital position is weak (and the bank, therefore,
is too risky), the stock's price will fall. A falling
stock price is a powerful signal to management
to change its policies, because that price affects
the cost of new equity capital and the value of the
current shareholder's investment. Managers that
are not responsive to the best interests of the
shareholders may not be around long enough to
pick up their retirement checks. Investors in a
bank's debt capital can convey the same signal
to management. As the bank's riskiness in­
creases, the bond market will increase the in­
terest rate that must be paid for new debt capital.
Rising debt costs will lower residual profits for
the common stockholders, and management
will get the message in a hurry.8
Bankers don't argue that the market is always
perfect in its evaluation of risks, but they do
champion it over the regulator's analysis. Inves­
tors require that a bank's capital be adequate to
meet its commitments with very high probabil­
ity. But that probability need not be 100 per­
cent. Unlike the regulator, stockholders are will­
ing to risk insolvency because in doing so the
bank can conserve on capital and realize a
higher return.

Each Has Shortcomings. Even with the alter­
native approaches so clearly drawn, choosing
sides is difficult. W h ile ratios are mathematically
precise, easy to use, and apparently of some
validity as a historically proven guide, they are
theoretically inadequate.
Primary objections to ratio analysis stem from
its unreliability as a method for detecting poten­
tial bank failures. The criticism is a bit unfair
because there are no statistics available to show

9 any economists argue that there would be gains in the
M
private sector's efficiency if more banks were allowed to fail,
and these gains might outweigh the social costs of those
failures. The difficulty, of course, is defining the limit where
added efficiency becomes secondary to the uncertainty that
increased failures create for all banks.

8
Market discipline may be somewhat dulled if the regula­
tory agencies publicly guarantee the solvency and liquidity
of banks that encounter difficulty.




9

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

whole society. Perhaps a solution to this conflict
might be found in a compromise by both parties
of their operating objectives.
Would society be better off with the private
sector benefits of improved capital allocation
and the social costs created by more bank
failures or with fewer failures and some degree
of overcapitalization? Many bankers opt for the
first combination— regulators for the second.
What is needed is a more objective basis for
choosing the amount of risk a bank should
take— a scheme which allows a banker to select
any amount of capital he wishes as long as he
pays the cost of protecting society against the
risks his choice creates.1
1
Accordingly, regulators and legislators might
consider several modifications of the FDIC's in­
surance system. First, banks could be charged a
fee for their deposit insurance which varies with
the risk of the bank. Banks currently pay a flat
rate which is the same no matter how safe the
bank is. Second, all demand deposits at banks
could be fully insured by the FDIC rather than
leaving deposits of more than $20,000 vulnera­
ble to loss when a bank fails.

insurance programs, and the Federal Reserve's
discount window are all designed to prevent it
from happening. Refinement of bank manage­
ment techniques also reduces the risk. But it is
still a possibility if the industry takes on too
much risk relative to its capital position. Multiple
failures are a cost which regulators are currently
unwilling to pay— the cause of capital efficiency
notwithstanding. Finding a merger partner for
a troubled $10 million bank is one thing— for
a $10 billion bank quite another.1 Virtually
0
any institution large enough to absorb such a
big problem bank as a merger partner would be
an illegal suitor for antitrust reasons.
If all the costs to society of multiple failures
could be included in the market's valuation of
bank capital, supervisory authorities might be
willing to let the market work. Sketchy informa­
tion about the riskiness of bank investments and
thin markets for bank stocks would not be prob­
lems of sufficient seriousness to force abandon­
ment of the market as “ chief disciplinarian." But
since the full cost of banks taking risks is not
entirely shouldered by the investor, regulators
feel they have an obligation to impose a greater
constraint on bank operations than the market
will. Too large a segment of society can be
harmed by the mistakes of a relatively small
number of over-aggressive banks for those banks
to be free of any social responsibility for their
policies.

Using the Market. A central feature of this
compromise approach to capital adequacy
would be to make better use of markets to deter­
mine society's real preferences. Presently, only a
portion of a bank's funds are sensitive to its risk.
Stockholders and long-term creditors are very
likely to demand a return which compensates
them for their risks. However, only the largest
and most sophisticated of the bank's depositors
do, because the FDIC protects most deposit
funds from loss. The cost of most of a bank's
deposits does not respond to changes in its risk.
If the FDIC were to vary its insurance premium
according to the risk of the bank rather than just
the total amount of its deposits, the bank would
have to pay an additional insurance fee for trying
to reduce its long-term capital. An insurance rate

A BETTER SO LUTIO N?
Though the conflict between aggressive banks
and regulators (with each trying to keep his own
costs to a minimum) is understandable, official
policies on bank failure should be selected with
an eye to bringing the greatest net benefit to the
’“Investors seeking to reduce or limit total risk can diversify
their stock and bond holdings among a number of industries,
thus avoiding some of the risk that their bank investments are
undercapitalized. Regulators don't have the same option.
The FD IC is diversified in the sense that it insures a wide
spectrum of banks, but it cannot diversify against the risk that
the entire industry is undercapitalized. This is w h y bank
deposits cannot be protected by a private insurance com ­
pany.




’’Several proposals are found in the literature. Suggestions
from the work of Tussing, Jacobs, M ayer, Kreps and W acht,
and Robinson and Pettway (see Bibliography) are combined
in this plan.

10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

that increased as the relative amount of long­
term capital decreased would place an implicit
risk premium on deposits of a low-capital bank.
Since, everything else being equal, the risk of the
low-capital bank failing is higher than that of a
better-capitalized bank, it is only appropriate
that the price for insuring its deposits be higher.
The cost of FDIC insurance might also be ad­
justed to reflect the asset composition, liquidity,
profitability, and management of the bank as
well as its mix of liabilities. This would further
refine the price paid by the bank for engaging in
riskier activities. The objective would not be one
of preventing banks from increasing their risks
but of making sure that they pay the appropriate
cost to society of assuming these risks.
The obvious objection is that the artificiality of
the capital adequacy evaluation might not be
improved. It might even be argued that setting an
explicit insurance fee according to the result of
the evaluation compounds the problem. How­
ever, the importance of developing a rational fee
structure that is actuarially sound would give
bankers and regulators an incentive to work to­
gether to build a solid system for distinguishing
various grades of risk. Once this rate structure
was established it would have the advantage of
giving greater decision-making flexibility to the
banker. It would make the costs of each decision
more explicit. If he thinks the benefits of adopt­
ing a riskier capital structure will outweigh the
cost of insuring society against the risk, he is free
to make that choice (see Box 4).
The revised capital evaluation system would
stress ranking the risk of each bank against a
wide spectrum of possibilities. There would not
be any "adequate versus inadequate" line— a
subject of continual debate— but, instead, a
choice between increasing the bank's risks (and
insurance costs) or decreasing them. With a vari­
ety of risk classes and a similar spectrum of rates,
bankers could make more rational cost/profit
decisions. The cost of each of the bank's sources
of funds would respond to management's policy
decisions, thus bringing the discipline of the
market into each decision without imposing cap­
ital constraints which are rigid and artificial on
the banks and without forcing society to bear




additional uncompensated risk. More bank fail­
ures might occur under this plan, but higher
insurance fees from the riskier banks should
cover the costs of these failures. Furthermore, if
the regulator's insurance-premium rating for
each bank were made public, this additional
information would aid the securities markets in
setting costs for the bank's long-term funds.
The insurance-premium method for regulating
risk would be superior to the bank supervisor's
determination of "adequate" capital, because it
focuses the regulator's objective more clearly on
the broad goal of controlling the total cost im­
posed on society by the banking system rather
than the present narrower objective of prevent­
ing bank failures. Setting capital adequacy stan­
dards is now tantamount to preventing any bank
from exceeding a risk limitation. Variable insur­
ance premiums put the regulator in the more
appropriate position of a risk manager whose
goal is to control the total risk and cost that
society faces rather than to limit the management
discretion of each bank.
The second element of this plan to rationalize
the bank capital problem is 100-percent insur­
ance on demand deposits. W hile this is a retreat
from the market discipline advocated for a riskbased insurance fee, it is intended to serve soci­
ety by making the entire banking system less
vulnerable to financial panic. Depositor protec­
tion is an obvious but still secondary function of
this plan. The prime objective is to reduce the
likelihood and the social costs of a major crisis
caused by multiple bank failures.
This proposal has always been rejected on the
grounds that sophisticated depositors would not
leave their funds in banks which had inadequate
capital. A banker's interest in attracting such
money would force him to maintain adequate
capital. Yet, while these uninsured deposits do
encourage management to respond to market
pressures, these funds may be very unstable dur­
ing a period of financial uncertainty. The failure
of one major bank could generate immediate de­
posit outflows at institutions throughout the in­
dustry which are otherwise quite sound. Full
demand deposit insurance would obviate the
need for short-term depositors to set in motion

11

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

BO X 4

SETTING THE RATE
Setting a proper insurance premium is a crucial element of the proposal. Without trying to
minimize the difficulty of the task, it should be possible to do this with sufficient precision. The
regulatory authorities have access to an enormous store of banking data extending over several
decades. Since the 1940s, America's banks have managed to cope with several recessions and
a couple of severe credit crunches. Careful analysis with the statistical tools currently available
should enable regulators to set insurance rates that would accurately reflect the change in risk
that the insurance fund must absorb if a bank changes its capital policies. Past experience may
be a poor indicator of future developments, but it does define the current capabilities of the
Government's stabilization policies and the effect that volatile interest rates and several credit
crunches have had on the liquidity and solvency of the banking system. Virtually any method
developed would be more rational than charging a very conservative, I iquid bank the same rate
for insurance as that charged a rather risky institution.

The Rate Setters. Specifically, a politically independent panel of experts might be charged
with the task of determining the appropriate rate structure for insuring society against the risks
of alternative levels of bank capitalization. Bankers, regulators, statisticians, banking scholars,
and actuaries should all be represented on such a panel. Judgment and reason should be
combined with rigorous statistical and economic analysis to set these rates.* Further, the panel
might’be reconvened at five-year intervals (or sooner, should the regulator feel it necessary) to
revise the rate structure in light of new developments in the economy and the banking industry
and new research findings.
The Rates. It is unlikely that any "perfect" method could be found for setting the insurance
fee schedule. However, with serious effort it should be possible to construct an internally
consistent, rational set of rates that would beat least as sound as the present capital adequacy
rules and, perhaps, much better because of the new flexibility given the banker. ** At the outset
*The risk insurance fees should not be used as a tool for selective credit control.
**G iven the same analytical resources and the correct objectives, regulators would be able to set capital adequacy
standards just as rationally. How ever, improved goal specification and increased flexibility for all participants make
this a better approach to the problem.

such chain reactions, thereby reducing the
chance of this happening. The banking system's
legal privilege of not paying time-deposit with­
drawal requests as though they were demand
deposits should provide the industry with suffi­
cient flexibility to withstand any short-term fi­
nancial crisis, if it is sound in all other respects.
Furthermore, the benefits of market discipline
would still not be lost entirely. Not only would




the cost discipline of an insurance fee based on
risk be substituted for analysis by uninsured de­
positors, but the bank would continue to have to
satisfy the market's standards on any funds raised
through nondeposit sources. Since these funds
sources are of great importance (especially to the
major banks), the market would still have a
strong influence on the kinds of risks bankers
take.
12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

it might be desirable to set the insurance fees rather conservatively, assigning relatively high
social costs to management policies which are radically different from current standards. As
regulators and bankers learned to live with the new plan, any artificial conservatism could be
gradually done away with, thus increasing flexibility and discretion under this system to the
greatest extent possible.

The Insurance Fund. This does not mean that the FDIC's reserve fund must necessarily grow
larger than it is now. No one knows exactly how large the fund must be to do its job, but its
present size seems sufficient to satisfy the regulatory community.*** (In fact, for many years the
FDIC has been rebating a portion of each year's official insurance premium to its member
banks.) There is no reason for the fund to increase further (vis-a-vis insured bank deposits)
unless the risk associated with protecting those deposits increases. Under the proposal offered
here, banks that are less risky than average would pay a lower premium for insurance, and
those that are more risky than average would pay more— an amount equivalent to the cost of
protecting society against the higher risk of that bank's operations.
Uncle Sam's Role. The Federal Government should be ready to backstop the industry's
insurance programs againstthe possibility of a depression, because it isn't practical for banks to
pay the full cost of insurance or hold sufficient capital. The Government is committed to a
program of stabilizing the economy— a commitment that bankers and regulators both agree
precludes the need for capitalizing banks to withstand another depression. In the event of an
economic disaster it would be in the nation's best interests to preserve the industry. Since the
benefits of supporting the whole industry would fall not only to depositors but to everyone, the
job of preserving the system rightly falls to the Government. W hen the public is the primary
beneficiary, it should bear some of the costs.
In some sense, this kind of commitment has already been formally acknowledged. The
Treasury stands ready to provide the FDIC with several billion dollars should that agency's
insurance reserves ever be exhausted.
***The FD IC 's insurance reserve fund presently has assets of over $5 billion and has an additional $3 billion of
borrowing authority from the Treasury. Between 1933 and 1972 the corporation had suffered only $74.4 million of net
losses as a result of bank failures. (W h ile losses are only a small portion of the reserve, it must be remembered that no
major bank has failed since 1940, and the FD IC has been very successful in disposing of failed banks at very small
losses. Furthermore, the potential losses faced by the corporation from the failure of the United States National Bank in
San Diego are well above $100 million.) Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Annual Report— 1972 (Washington:
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 1973), p. 28.

Protect the Depositors, But Not the Bankers.

strategy of finding new ownership and manage­
ment has sometimes been explored.

In conjunction with the variable insurance pre­
mium and higher deposit insurance, the FDIC
and the other regulators should continue their
policy of trying to minimize the cost and incon­
venience suffered by depositors when a bank
fails. A very common solution to date has been
the speedy merger of a distressed bank with a
stronger institution. Where state law or antitrust
considerations preclude such a merger, the




This basic approach is laudable. One of the
regulator's chief goals should be to prevent an
isolated failure from jeopardizing the public's
trust in all banks. Preservation of a distressed
bank's ability to continue to serve its customers
while it is being reorganized is vital to keeping
that trust.
13

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

However, this protection should not be ex­
tended to either senior management, stockhold­
ers, or uninsured investors in the bank's debt.
These persons either made the decisions that led
to the losses that created the bank failure or
invested in the bank with knowledge that there
was some risk. Investors may not have been ful ly
aware of the bank's policies, but taking those
risks is part of the implicit contract they made
when they invested. Before the market can im­
pose any discipline on bank management's deci­
sions to take additional risks, investors must be
aware that they can and will lose their money if
the risks prove too great. Regulators should be
careful not to let their enthusiasm for saving a
bank inadvertently cause them to shield former
managers or investors from the adverse conse­
quences of making bad decisions.

their money at risk. Furthermore, in the event of
liquidation, capital adequacy requirements are
only protection for some depositors since the
bulk of the funds deposited by unsophisticated
investors are insured by the FDIC.
Instead, a major function ofthe minimum cap­
ital rules is to limit the risk exposure of the FDIC
and, thereby, the probable cost to the Govern­
ment of “ bailing out" the industry during a
period of extreme financial stress. Since the
regulator's objective should be to control costs
incurred by the public sector rather than to main­
tain minimum capital standards as an end in
themselves, there may be a way to dispense with
these rules. If the regulators can charge a deposit
insurance fee that varies with the riskiness of a
bank's structure yet covers the expected addi­
tional social costs of management opting for that
extra risk, society's interests can be protected
within a freer banking environment. Further­
more, if deposit insurance protection could be
extended to all demand deposits, the risk to soci­
ety of a financial crisis might be reduced appre­
ciably. Naturally, bankers and regulators would
continue to argue over how risky each bank is.
But the important change is the substitution of a
pricing mechanism for the “ adequacy versus in­
adequate" capital rules. This will provide greater
flexibility for bankers willing to pay the full cost
of stretching their capital.

ADEQUACY AND EQUITY
One of the theoretical roles of bank capital is
to protect the interests of shareholders while the
bank is in operation and both creditors and unin­
sured depositors upon liquidation. However, the
minimum capital requirements that bank ex­
aminers try to enforce aren't needed as protec­
tion for these investors. A bank's stockholders
and creditors should rely on their own financial
savvy and the free market for capital to assure
themselves of a competitive return for investing




14

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

APPENDIX
Capital's Role in Absorbing Losses

There's a common misconception that a bank's capital accounts constitute a pool of funds that are
available for either investing in buildings and equipment or covering the bank's losses. Not even the
“ retained earnings" segment of the bank's capital account is available in the form of a cash reserve. The
capital account found on a bank's Statement of Condition doesn't describe asset holdings at all. Instead, it
defines the amount of long-term funds the bank has raised and who supplied those funds. It is listed as a
liability of the bank.
For example, the Ninth National Bank (shown below) starts with a total of $100 million invested in
cash, bonds, loans, and its buildings. This money came from two basic sources— depositors and stock­
holders, although the stockholders' contribution is usually divided into several different accounts
(common stock, surplus, reserves for loan and bond losses, and retained earnings).

NINTH NATIONAL BANK
Statement of Condition ($000,000s)
ASSETS
Cash
Bonds
Loans
Building
TOTAL

LIABILITIES
15
20
60
5

Deposits
Capital
Common Stock
Surplus, Reserves,
and Retained Earnings
TOTAL

100

90
5
5
100

Deposits are a short-term liability of the bank because requests by depositors to withdraw money must
be met quickly. The capital account, however, represents a permanent source of funds to the business. If a
stockholder wishes to liquidate his ownership position in the bank, he can only do so by selling his shares
to someone else. Their transaction doesn't reduce the amount of capital available to the bank. Further­
more, depositors have a claim on the bank for a fixed number of dollars. This claim for payment takes
priority over other parties who supplied funds to the bank. Shareholders have only a residual claim to
earnings or assets after obi igations to the depositors have been satisfied. They share the bank's profits if it is
successful, but they must also absorb their share of the losses when it is not. A bank is solvent only as long
as the value of its assets exceeds the fixed, legal claims for payment held by depositors and it's able to meet
those demands for payment.
The Ninth National Bank must be prepared to face losses from several quarters, and it's the capital
account that is used to absorb these losses. Tracing the impact on the bank of three kinds of losses
(operating, emergency asset liquidation, and major loan defaults) may clarify the role capital plays.




15

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

An Operating Loss of $1 Million. If operating expenses exceed operating revenues by $1 million the
bank may have a net outflow of that much cash. Since the bank's assets and liabilities must always be
equal, and since the depositors' claims against the bank are fixed, the residual value of the stockholders'
claims must be reduced by the amount of the loss. This is done by deducting the loss from the retained
earnings account.
ASSETS___________________________________________________ LIABILITIES
Cash
Bonds
Loans
Buildings

14
20
60
5

TOTAL

Deposits
Capital
Common Stock
Surplus, Reserves,
and Retained Earnings
TOTAL

99

90
5
4
99

Thus, the loss is charged against capital, but the bank remains solvent since there has been no impairment
of the depositors' claims against the bank.

Deposit Runoff of $20 Million. If a bank's major corporate customer closes its local plant and lays off a
number of workers the bank might lose a substantial share of its depositors in a relatively short time.
Demands for deposit withdrawals must be met in cash, but the Ninth National has only $15 million in
cash and a good part of the cash is needed for a day-to-day transactions and reserves. At best perhaps $5
million of the losses could be absorbed from reduced cash holdings. Profits from operations plus maturing
bonds and loans might provide some extra cash. However, most of the other $15 million must come from
liquidating parts of the bond and loan accounts. If the bank is very lucky it may be able to raise the $15
million by selling bonds and loans without serious loss— but that would be unusual. Often when
banks must liquidate bonds and loan holdings under a severe time pressure, losses result. For example, if
the losses amounted to $1 million from selling $10 million of bonds and another $1 million from
liquidating $7 million of loans, a partial write-off of the capital account would be necessary. Charging the
bond and loan losses first against the valuation reserves and then if necessary against retained earnings
and surplus, the balance sheet becomes:
ASSETS

LIABILITIES

Cash
Bonds
Loans
Building

10
10
53
5

TOTAL

78




Deposits
Capital
Common Stock
Surplus, Reserves,
and Retained Earnings
TOTAL

16

70
5
3
78

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

Loan Defaults of $7 Million. If the bank were to experience very heavy loan losses (perhaps associated
with a natural disaster in the bank's locale), the book value of its loans must be reduced. This loss would
first be charged against the bank's reserve for loan losses. W hen that account has been exhausted the
remaining losses are charged against retained earnings and then surplus. In the case of a $7 million of
losses, $2 million would remain after all of the surplus, reserves and retained earnings accounts had
been written down to zero. The remaining loss is then charged against the common stock account.
ASSETS___________________________________________________ LIABILITIES
Cash
Bonds
Loans
Building

15
20
53
5

TOTAL

93

Deposits
Capital
Common Stock
Surplus, Reserves
and Retained Earnings
TOTAL

90
3
0
93

However, any significant impairment of the common stock account of the bank will cause supervisory
authorities to consider liquidation or reorganization of the bank. In this example, the bank's capital has
been sufficient to insulate depositors from losses, but had the bank's losses exceeded $10 million, the
depositors' funds would have been jeopardized to the extent that they were not protected by the FDIC.
Capital, then, serves the dual purpose of protecting both depositors and society in general against major
losses w hile providing the bank's stockholders with a cushion that insulates their investment from the
shock of lesser losses.




17

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY-AUGUST 1974

SELECTED BIBLIOGRAPHY

Cohen, Kalman J. “ Improving the Capital Adequacy Formula." journal of Bank Research
1(1970): 13-16.
Cotter, Richard V. “ Capital Ratios and Capital Adequacy." National Banking Review 3(1966):
333-46.
Dince, Robert R. and Fortson, James C. “ The Use of Discriminant Analysis to Predict the
Capital Adequacy of Commercial Banks." Journal of Bank Research 3(1972): 54-62.
Institute for Financial Education. “ The Capital Adequacy Problem in Commercial Banks,
1974-1978." Banking Research Report, February 1974'(unpublished report).
Kreps, Clifton FI. and Wacht, Richard F. “ A More Constructive Role for Deposit Insurance,"
Journal of Finance 26(1971): 605-14.
Lindlow, Wesley. “ Bank Capital and Risk Assets." National Banking Review 1(1963): 29-46.
Mann, Maurice. “ Competitive Viability— A New Dimension for Capital Adequacy Require­
ments." Speech to National Correspondent Banking Conference. American Bankers
Association, Washington, D.C., 6 November 1973.
Mayer, Thomas. “ A Graduated Deposit Insurance Plan." Review of Economics and Statistics
47(1965): 114-116.
Mayne, Lucille S. “ Supervisory Influence on Bank Capital." Journal of Finance 27(1972):
637-51.
Meyer, Paul A. and Pifer, Howard W . “ Prediction of Bank Failures." Journal of Finance
27(1970): 853-868.
Peltzman, Sam. “ Capital Investment in Commercial Banking and Its Relationship to Portfolio
Regulation." Journal of Political Economy 78 (1970): 1-26.
Reed, Edward W . “ Appraising the Capital Needs of Commercial Banks." Bankers Magazine
147(1964): 73-83.
Robinson, Roland I. and Pettway, Richard H. Policies for Optimum Bank Capital. A study
prepared for the Trustees of the Banking Research Fund— Association of Reserve City
Bankers, 1967.
Shay, Jerome W . “ Capital Adequacy: The Regulators' Perspective." Magazine of Bank Ad­
ministration, October 1974, pp. 22-25.
Sheehan, John E. “ Bank Capital Adequacy - Time to Pause and Reflect." Speech to National
Correspondent Banking Conference, American Bankers Association, 6 November 1973.
Staats, W illiam F. “ Capital Adequacy of Commercial Banks." Ph. D. dissertation, University of
Texas, 1965.
Tussing, A. Dale. “ Bank Failure: A Meaningful Competitive Force." Proceedings of a Confer­
ence on Bank Structure and Competition Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, 13 May 1968.
Tussing, A. Dale. “ The Case for Bank Failure." Journal of Law and Economics 10(1967):
129-147.
Vojta, George J. Bank Capital Adequacy. New York: Citicorp, 1973.
Vojta, George J. “ Capital Adequacy: A Look at the Issues." Magazine of Bank Administration,
September 1973, pp. 22-25.




y

18

The Earnings Picture For Women: Slack Job Markets

Belli

the
Downward
Trend
By Vincent A. Gennaro
CHART 1
WOMEN’S PARTICIPATION IN THE LABOR MARKET HAS INCREASED
CONSIDERABLY DURING THE PAST 25 YEARS . . .
Percent

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

* Refers to all women in the labor force as a percent of the total noninstitutional population of all women 16 years and over. Percentages are annual
averages.
Source:




U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

19

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY-AUGUST 1974

CHART 2

AND THE PROPORTION OF WOMEN IN THE TOTAL LABOR FORCE
HAS RISEN DRAMATICALLY

1950

1955

1960

1965

* Includes both employed and unemployed.
Source:




U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

20

1970

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

CHART 3
BUT THE WOMEN HAVE GENERALLY FOUND IT INCREASINGLY
MORE DIFFICULT THAN MEN TO FIND WORK, . . .

* (Unemployment Rate of Women/Unemployment Rate of Men) x 100. 16
old and over.
** Trend line calculated by method of semi-averages.
Source: U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.




21

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

CHART 4*
WHICH HAS CONTRIBUTED TO THE DOWNWARD TREND IN THE
MEDIAN EARNINGS OF WOMEN RELATIVE TO MEN
Index
.65

Median Earnings of Women/Median Earnings of Men

.55

1960
* M ed ian E a rn in g s of W o m e n / M e d ia n E a rn in g s of M en. Full-tim e w o rk e rs
in c lu d e th o se w h o w e re em p lo yed 50 w e e k s or m ore in a year.
** Trend line c a lc u la te d by m ethod of sem i-averages.
S o u rc e :
U. S. D ep artm ent of C o m m erce, C u rren t P o p u la tio n Su rve y , S e r ie s

P-60.




22

Federal Regulation
Of Stock Market
Credit: A Need for
Reconsideration
By James M. O'Brien
Financing the purchase of an asset by borrow­
ing is as American as apple pie. Most of the time
the size of the loan is worked out by the bor­
rower and lender. However, an exception oc­
curs when the purchase is stock.
Since 1934, Uncle Sam has restricted stock
market lending by imposing Federal margin
requirements which fix the maximum amount of
the loan relative to the value of the collateral.1
Suppose, for example, the margin requirement
were 65 percent and a potential stock pur­
chaser puts up $1,000 worth of stock as col­
lateral. The most he could borrow would be
$350 or, alternatively, the minimum "m argin"

would be $650. The Federal Reserve Board,
custodian of this regulation, varies Federal
margin requirements according to conditions in
the stock market. Currently requirements are 50
percent which, except during the late 1930s
and early 1940s, is the lowest they've ever
been. Prior to regulation, lenders had generally
only required between 10 and 30 percent
margin.
Margin requirements are mainly intended to
eliminate a destabilizing impact on stock prices
that supposedly results when "too much" credit
is used to buy stock. However, it seems unclear
whether regulating security credit has actually
made a significant contribution to the stability of
the stock market. Moreover, even without legal
taboos, stock market loans would likely be
playing a smaller role on W all Street today than
prior to 1934. Despite these considerations, the
scope and complexity of margin regulation have

'H ow ever, for reasons of feasibility, Federal margin re­
quirements apply only if the collateral is stock or a security
which can be converted to stock. Usually, but not always,
the stock being purchased serves as the collateral for the
loan.




23

BUSINESS REVIEW

JU L Y - A U G U S T 1974

market credit ultimately came from banks that
treated the credit extension as a liquid asset— a
short-term loan which could be "called " for
repayment when the bank needed reserves. The
importance of "c a ll" loans supposedly threat­
ened the stability of the banking system. In the
event of a serious decline in stock prices, the
value of these loans, and hence banks' solvency,
might be jeopardized. Whatever the merits of
this argument may have been, since the early
1930s other sources of bank liquidity have
developed independently of stock market credit
regulation. Today banks hold large amounts of
U.S. Government securities which can readily
be converted into cash. There also exists a
highly developed mechanism for interbank
lending— the Federal funds market. These and
still other sources of bank liquidity have obviated
the use of call loans as an important secondary
reserve for banks.

been expanding substantially. And sizable
"gaps" in regulation still remain. As security
credit control reaches its 40th birthday, a reevaluation of its need and structure may be in
order. One possible alternative to the current
regulatory apparatus would be to maintain only
standby control over stock market credit. Restric­
tions on lending to buy stock would be applied
only if a special need appeared to arise.

THE UNCERTAIN GAINS OF STOCK MARKET
CREDIT CONTROL
Regulating stock market credit originated with
the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. Prior to
the 1930s, the use of credit had become a
popular way to buy stock, particularly where
the investor figured to profit on expected nearterm price increases. Following the stock market
crash of 1929 and the early 1930s, support for
security credit regulation became quite strong.
Many observers believed that low margin re­
quirements had accentuated both the stock
market boom of the '20s and the bust of the
'30s. From 1926 to 1929 stockbrokers' loans to
customers jumped from $3 billion to $8 billion
but by 1932 stock market credit had dropped to
only a half billion dollars! This importance of
security credit and its volatility gave rise to
several arguments for regulation.2

Reducing Credit for Productive Trade? A
second contention was that margin credit (stock
market credit) which financed "speculation"
reduced the volum e of loans available for
"p ro d u c tiv e " trade. H ow ever, many have
pointed out that this argument is erroneous.
Margin credit merely facilitates the exchange
of securities from one party to another. It does
not represent a claim on real resources and,
hence, does not reduce the overall ability of
consumers and businessmen to buy food,
homes, or machines. Proceeds from the stock
loan must end upasasource of finance for either
businesses or consumers.

Undesirable Effects on the Banking System?
One argument rested on the fact that most stock

b ackground references enumerating the arguments for
margin regulation are Jules I. Bogen and Herman E. Kroos,
Security Credit: Its Economic Role and Regulation (Engle­
wood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1960); Robert E. Harris,
"Federal Margin Requirements: A Selective Instrument of
Monetary P o licy ," University of Pennsylvania, unpublished
dissertation, 1958; Carl Parry, “ A Short History of Regula­
tion T and U ," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, unpublished (1949); Frederic Solomon and Janet
Hart, "Recen t Developments in the Regulation of Securities
Credit," journal of Public Law 20 (1971): 165-69; John
Stoffels, “ The Use of M argin Credit in the Trading of
Securities/' M ichigan State University, unpublished disserta­
tion (1969); U.S. Congress, Senate, Committee on Banking
and Currency, Factors Affecting the Stock Market, 84th
Cong., Istsess., 30 April 1955, chap. 3.




Destabilizing Effects on Stock Prices? But the
main argument for curbing the use of security
credit is that unregulated lending increases the
volatility of stock prices. The evidence is the
strong tendency of security credit to rise and fall
with stock prices. It is argued that prices would
rise less if credit to finance stock purchases
were restricted. And with a smaller amount of
credit outstanding, less stock would be sold to
repay loans when prices start declining. Con­
sequently, stock prices presumably would not
24

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

TABLE 1
SOME MEASURES OF THE BEHAVIOR OF
STOCK MARKET CREDIT
AND PRICES SINCE THE EARLY 1900s
A
B
Stock Market
A Measure of
Credit
Coincidence Between
Volatility12
Stock Prices and
Stock Market Credit3
Jan
Sep
Jan
Jan
Jan
Jan

1900-Aug
1918-Nov
1926-Dec
1939-Dec
1950-Dec
1960-Jun

1918
1922
1933
1949
1960
1970

*

*

44.0
l 89.5
28.6
6.0
8.9

.84
.87
.59
.50
.47

C
D
Average Federal Stock
Margin
Price
Requirement Volatility1

55%
66
71

11.4
15.7
89.1
15.7
8.5
8.8

*Stock-market credit data not available (also data were not available for December 1922-December 1925).
’The volatility measure is the variance. Both stock prices (Standard and Poor's 500 Index) and the stock market
credit statistics are expressed as monthly rates of change. Thus 11.4 is the variance of the monthly rate of change in
stock prices between January 1900 and August 1918.
lim it e d availability of stock market credit data made it necessary to use somewhat different measures of stock
market credit. Stock market credit for September 1918-Novem ber 1922 and January 1926-Decem ber 1933
comprise bank loans to brokers. January 1939-December 1949 credit data are broker loans to customers. The
remaining data include broker loans to customers plus bank loans to nonbroker customers. All data since 1939 refer
to regulated security credit. Differences in definitions of security credit are unlikely to be sufficiently important to
account for much of the observed differences in volatility among the respective periods. Source: Banking and
Monetary Statistics (Securities Markets), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Bulletins.
3
The measure of coincidence is the correlation coefficient for rates of change in the two variables. A correlation of
1.0 means a perfect coincidence and a correlation of 0 means no coincidence.

less dramatic changes in the volatility of stock
prices (see Tables 1A and 1D). The tendency of
security loans to fluctuate with stock prices has
also been less pronounced (see Table IB ).
These facts help to corroborate the view that
Federal margin requirements have helped to
stabilize stock market credit.4 Still, it may be that

fall so far.3
Since the enactment of margin regulation,
stock market credit does appear to have been
less volatile— particularly when compared to the

3
This argument raises the question of whether the price
fluctuations supposedly fostered by margin trading might
represent, in some sense, proper reevaluations of firms'
expected earnings and, hence, be justified on grounds of
econom ic efficiency. The issue of what constitutes "exces­
sive " fluctuations in stock prices is not addressed here and
the goal of reducing stock price fluctuations that might be
caused by margin trading is accepted without question.
H ow ever, the issue is not resolved among economists.
See Irwin Friend, "T h e Econom ic Consequence of the Stock
M arket," American Economic Review 62 (1972): 212-19.




“All credit data since 1939 reported in Table 1 is regulated
security credit. How ever, the margin credit measures of
volatility and coin cid en ce with stock prices w ere also
computed for January 1971-May 1973, using a definition
of margin credit which also included reported data on un­
regulated security credit as well. The results were very
similar to those obtained using only regulated credit over
the same period.

25

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW




INSTITUTIONAL GROWTH HAS DIMINISHED THE ROLE OF THE
INDIVIDUAL TRADER AND MARGIN CREDIT
Percent

1900-29

1939-51

1952-59

1960-68

Percent

Public Trading on the New York Stock Exchange**
F I Individual

; 2 Institutional

'Source: Institutional Investor Study Report of the Securities and Exchange Com­
mission 1 (March 10, 1971): 78, 119. Institutional stock holdings are presented on an
annual basis and only for selected years between 1900 and 1952. These percentages
are averages of the years for which data are available.

''Source: 1971 Public Transaction Study, Research Department of the New York
Stock Exchange, Inc., April 1972, pp. 13, 15. Before 1959, estimates were based on
analysis of transactions on only one or two days of each year and no analysis was
made in 1962 and 1964. In 1969 transactions analysis is based on single day reports in
each half of the year. In 1971 the transactions analysis is only for the first and second
quarters. Because of inavailability of data, 1969-71 does not include trading data for
1970.

26

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

A G R O W IN G REGULATORY BURDEN

other factors have had some hand in altering the
behavior of margin credit (without correspond­
ing effects on stock price behavior). Of particular
note is the substantial growth of institutional
investors such as life insurance companies, pen­
sion funds, mutual funds, and trusts. These in­
vestors now account for a large share of stock
market trading (see Chart). Because institutional
investors are prohibited from using security
credit, their growth has significantly lessened the
importance of margin trading in the stock
market. This could help account for the de­
creased coincidence between fluctuations in
stock market credit and stock prices.
But even if margin control has curbed fluctu­
ations in stock market credit, this need not
mean it has helped make stock prices more
stable. To a large degree, stock prices fluctuate
because of fluctuations in what market traders
think prices will be in the future. For example, if
traders revise their forecasts of stock prices up­
ward, they w ill want to hold more stock,
expecting to profit on the difference between
current prices and predicted future prices. Stock
prices can be expected to bid up until they match
the more optimistic expectations of the "m arket."
The increased demand for stock will be financed
by a heavier use of credit, the sale of other
assets, or simply by holding stock that otherwise
would have been sold. Hence, a strong co­
incidence between changes in stock market
credit and stock prices need not mean the former
causes the latter. Both may simply reflect a
changed consensus concerning future stock
prices which, in turn, can result from any
number of factors.
It is entirely possible that this is usually the
situation. If so, restricting the use of security
credit may be having relatively little effect on
stock price fluctuations. The end result of margin
regulation may be simply a greater reliance
on unregulated sources of finance to buy stock
with little effect on stock price stability. (The
uncertainty of the gains from stock market
credit control is also reflected in other studies
as indicated in the Appendix.)




If margin regulation was costless, the un­
certainty of the benefits would be of little
concern. But controlling security credit is
not costless. Taxpayers must pay for the ad­
ministration and enforcement of the rules. The
regulated must keep records and report periodi­
cally to Uncle Sam on some of their lending
and borrowing activities. Resources are spent in
developing ways around the controls. And, for
enforcement purposes, some rules extend be­
yond just loans to purchase stock. These costs
will be difficult to tally, but at least they can be
expected to grow with the scope and complexity
of the regulatory repertoire.
Margin regulation has, in fact, experienced
substantial growth, particularly in recent years.
Extensions in coverage of lenders and in the
types of securities purchased have been numer­
ous. Rules governing margin lending have been
tightened. And, all of this has significantly
compounded the complexitiy of controlling
stock market credit. The causes of this regulatory
growth have been changes in the structure of
the stock market and the development of credit
avenues designed to avoid margin require­
ments (see Box for a more detailed description
of the growth in security credit regulation).
Moreover, a significant amount of avoidance
remains, creating the possibility of even more
regulation in the future.

SIGNIFICANT GAPS REMAIN
Some stock market loans are purposely ex­
cluded from margin requirements. For example,
there are loans whose tendency to destabilize
the stock market is believed to be small— credit
to buy some stock traded over the counter and
the special exemption and privilege categories
(see Table 2). Also important are those security
loans w hich w ould be esp e cially hard to
regulate. The most notable of these are loans to
purchase stock which do not have equity as the
collateral— unrestricted collateral loans. Banks
make almost all of the unrestricted collateral

27

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

INCREASING THE SCOPE AND COMPLEXITY
OF STOCK MARKET CREDIT CONTROL
Extending the Scope of Regulation. In 1934 margin requirements applied only to stock
market credit extended by brokers. In 1936, not unexpectedly, it was found necessary to
extend margin regulation to stock loans made by bankers. Security credit loans of other
domestic lenders, after a long and significant growth, were brought under margin control in
1968. Concern also grew during the 1960s over the unregulated use of foreign sources
of security credit. By extending legal responsibilities for the application of margin rules to the
borrower of security loans in 1971, an attempt has been made to curb this avenue of
stock market credit too.
In terms of lending purposes, margin requirements initially applied only to credit to buy
stock registered on a national securities exchange. In 1953, credit to buy mutual fund
shares was explicitly brought under regulation. W hile the equity issued by most mutual funds
was not registered on a national exchange much of the securities they held were. A 1968
amendment extended more generally the Federal Reserve Board's power to regulate credit to
purchase unregistered securities (according to criteria set down in the amendment). This was
the result of the development of the over-the-counter market and consequent growth in the
importance of unregistered stock. Convertible bonds, securities which could be converted to
stock at the owner's option, were also subjected to margin regulation in 1968.1These securities
and the use of low-margined bank credit to finance their purchases had become increasingly
popular in the 1960s. Still another amendment in 1969 declared that credit used to help
finance a package or plan offering a combined purchase of equity and any other asset, good
or service was subject to margin requirements regardless of the stated purpose of the loan. The
immediate cause of this amendment was the increased use of credit to finance insurancepremium funding plans— plans which provided for the combined purchase of stock and life
insurance.
There have been still other rule changes many of which have been relatively minor.
However, at least some have added further restrictions to stock market credit transactions. For
example, some of the special privileges (where margin rules are eased) have had to be
curbed because of abuse. Also the requirements concerning the statement of purpose of a
stock-collateraled loan have been expanded on three separate occasions because of concern
with evasive extensions of security credit.2
Increasing the Complexity. Amplifying margin regulations has also generally made applica­
tion by the regulated and enforcement by the regulator an increasingly complex task. The ap-

'From the broker's view , this regulatory change was an easing, since prior to this convertible bonds could not be used
as collateral for broker extended security credit.
2
The most detailed review of these and other developments in security credit regulation in recent years is Frederic
Solomon and Janet Hart, “ Recent Developments in the Regulation of Securities Credit,” Journal of Public Law 20
(1971): 165-69. A review of the amendments concerned with the purpose statement can be found in Jules I. Bogen
and Herman E. Kroos, Security Credit: Its Economic Role and Regulation (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall,
1960), pp. 136-38, and a statement of the Federal Reserve Board's concern with abuse of the purpose statement in
the Federal Reserve Bulletin, M arch 1960, p. 265.




28

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

propriate margin rules for extending credit collateraled by securities depend on a growing
number of circumstances surrounding the loan. In making stock market loans, bankers face
different reporting and lending requirements than do brokers. Other lenders are subjected
to margin rules which differ from either those followed by bankers or brokers. The type of
security being purchased is also important in determining the appropriate margin require­
ment. Convertible bonds have a lower required margin than stock and some issues of
unregistered stock are not subject to margin requirements while others are (currently
about 460 issues of unregistered equity are on the Federal Reserve's "O-T-C margin list").
Then there is the question of whether a stock market loan properly qualifies for any one of a
number of special privileges and exemptions. There are also a large and growing number of
definitional issues which must be interpreted by the regulator and understood by lenders and
borrowers.

TABLE 2
REGULATED AND UNREGULATED FORMS OF
STOCK MARKET CREDIT (MILLIONS OF DOLLARS)1
Banks

Total Regulated2

Brokers

858
52
18

Subject to Margin Requirements
Margin Stock
Convertible Bonds
Subscription Issues

7,236
245
31
7,512

928

Not Subject to Margin Requirements
Nonmargin O-T-C Stock Purchases
Unsecured or Unrestricted
Collateral Loans
Exempted Accounts at Brokers3
Total Unregulated

1,666
1,378
*

373

3,044

373

'Federal Reserve Bulletin. Average end-of-month figures for January 1972-May 1973. Unsecured or unrestricted
collateral loan data is not available after M ay 1973.
2
This omits the relatively small amount of credit extended by other lenders which is also regulated.
T a k en from Federal Reserve staff report on security credit outstanding June 30, 1970. See Federal Reserve Bul­

letin, Decem ber 1970, p. 911, Table 1.
T y p e of loan not made by respective lender.




29

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY-AUGUST 1974

of "business" or "p e rso n a l" loans used to
facilitate stock purchases is significant, it does
seem to imply a significant potential for avoid­
ance— a potential which must add to concern
for the ability of current margin rules to limit
stock market credit effectively.7

loans since brokers are generally not allowed
to make such loans. The amount of this credit
is greater than regulated loans extended by
banks and is even significant relative to the total
volume of regulated stock market credit (see
Table 2).
Finally, there are those security loans (collateraled by stock) that circumvent Federal
margin requirements because they are declared
by the borrower to be for a purpose other than
purchasing stock (or simply not reported by
the lender). Few facts on the amount of this
lending are available. However, the volume of
bank loans secured by stock but declared to be
for other purposes can give some indication of
the potential for this form of evasion. Based on a
1962 survey of commercial banks, the Securities
Exchange Commission reported that only 13 per­
cent of all stock-collateraled loans extended by
banks were reported to be for the purpose of
purchasing stock and, hence, subject to margin
requirements. Forty-nine percent were declared
to be "single payment personal" loans and 33
percent "b u s in e s s" loans (4 percent were
"other").5
To what extent a borrower can obtain a
"business" or "personal" loan to help buy stock
will depend on how similar these loan cate­
gories are to regulated stock market credit.
When several types of credit are similar, the
borrower can more easily move from one source
to another. Moreover, the regulator will find it
difficult to police the illegal use of highly sub­
stitutable sources. Information collected by the
SEC's study indicated that, besides having the
same collateral, the "business" and "personal"
loans were similar to the regulated "purpose"
loans in other respects as w ell— location of
lender, size of loan, and maturity of loan.6
W hile this need not mean that the actual amount

AN OPTION FOR REDUCING THE
REGULATORY BURDEN
Given the uncertainty of the benefits of
security credit control, the marked expansion in
regulation and the potential importance of
remaining regulatory gaps, some alternatives to
the current regulatory structure may be worth
considering. One alternative would be to rescind
the Government's responsibility for controlling
stock market lending. However, the spector of
1929 still haunts many as does the possibility
that the unprecedented build-up in stock
market credit accentuated the Great Crash. A
more moderate option might be to eliminate the
permanent imposition of Federal margin require­
ments. Normally, lenders and borrowers would
decide themselves the appropriate margin level.
Yet to prevent a replay of the 1920s credit
frenzy, the Federal Reserve Board would main­
tain authority to reimpose some form of margin
control should a similar situation arise again.8
In order to monitor security credit activity,
the Federal Reserve could continue to collect
information on the volume of bank and broker
stock lending— although in far less detail than is
now being done. Except for infrequent surveys,
information on stock market credit extended by

7ln fact the Board of Governors has indicated its concern
about this potential for avoidance by its attempts to tighten
the legal requirements concerning the statement of purpose
of a stock collateraled loan and by its limited attempt to
control credit used to “ carry" stock— that is, credit used to
finance another purchase w hile cash which was originally
intended to finance the purchase is instead diverted to the
purchase of stock, see Solomon and Hart, op. cit. p. 199.

5
The SEC's 1963 Special Study of Securities Markets (Part
4, Chapter 10) is currently the most exhaustive public report
on stock market credit. H ow ever, in an early 1955 survey
of 271 banks, the Senate Banking Committee reported that
64.5 percent of security collateraled credit was declared
“ nonpurpose" and, hence, not regulated.

8
The stock market credit bubble of the 1920s was far from
being something the Federal Reserve was unaware of or un­
concerned about. Rather the situation was one where they
lacked the statutory authority to influence margin lending
directly. See Stoffels, op. cit., pp. 5-8.

6
Special Study . . . , Chapter 10, pp. 51-60.




30

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

other lenders may not be necessary. These
lenders extend only about 5 percent of regulated
security credit.9 Federal margin requirements
would be imposed only during a period when
stock market credit, or its rate of expansion,
reached some "critical" level. The behavior of
stock market lending in the late 1920s and pos­
sibly preceding earlier market crises might be
used in helping to establish the critical condi­
tions.
If this stand-by authority were used only
infrequently, the problem of effective regulation
could be eased in several ways. First, the
regulatory burden would be reduced. Most of
the time individual stock market traders would
have greater flexibility in their trading activities
than currently. The reduced need for informa­
tion on security credit lending also would
mean lower regulatory costs for lenders, bor­
rowers, and Government. Second, if a need for
temporary Federal margin requirements arose,
the problem of effective control could be simpli­
fied. Under such a system, there would likely
be fewer channels or methods for extending
security credit than now. Many of those forms
of stock market lending which developed be­
cause of Federal control over the ordinary chan­
nels would be eliminated through competition.
The relatively short and infrequent times that
margin requirements might be applied would
make redeveloping at least some of these inef­
ficient channels unprofitable. Another potential
advantage is that it may be unnecessary to
maintain all the special privileges and exemp­
tions which have added measurably to the scope
and complexity of current margin regulation.
Imposing credit controls on a temporary basis
is not new. In the past, part-time controls have

been applied to consumer and housing credit.
The New York Stock Exchange imposes special
(100 percent) margin requirements on a tem­
porary basis to loans extended by brokers for
purchasing particular issues of stock as a per­
ceived need arises. The Federal Reserve Board
itself periodically alters the level of margin
requirements under changing stock market con­
ditions. These various experiences might be use­
fully applied to a more complete study of a stand­
by form of control on stock market credit.

A NEED FOR RECONSIDERATION
Federal regulation of stock market credit has
been in force for 40 years. For many, the impor­
tance of regulation has been a foregone conclu­
sion. However, hard facts to substantiate this
bel ief are not easy to come by. It appears to be an
open question whether margin regulation has
helped to reduce "excessive" swings in stock
prices. In any event, the growth of institutional
investing has probably diminished the impor­
tance of margin trading on stock prices relative
to that before regulation. The uncertain and
possibly diminishing gains from margin control
notwithstanding, regulation has grown substan­
tially. Still, avoidance of margin requirements
appears to be at least significant. Closing remain­
ing avenues of avoidance could mean even more
regulation for the future. These considera­
tions suggest that some basic changes in the
current structure of security credit regulation
might be warranted. Putting margin control on a
stand-by basis is one alternative that could
reduce the regulatory burden without foregoing
complete control over stock market credit.

9See Federal Reserve Bulletin, December 1970, p. 916.




31

JULY-AUGUST 1974

BUSINESS REVIEW

Appendix
OTHER STUDIES OF THE EFFECTS OF MARGIN REQUIREMENTS
There have been only a handful of studies which have looked at several different questions concerning
the effects of margin requirements. These studies still appear to leave a significant amount of uncertainty
about what effects margin regulation has on stock market credit and prices.

EFFECTS OF M ARGIN REQUIREMENTS ON STOCK MARKET CREDIT
Two different studies related various measures of regulated security credit to the level of margin
requirements (using multivariate regression analysis) finding only a weak negative relationship.1 The
conclusion was that margin requirements have relatively little effect on regulated stock market credit.
However, this conclusion can be challenged on several counts. One is that no argument or evidence was
presented to indicate that the level of stock market credit did not concurrently influence the level of
margin requirements imposed by the Federal Reserve Board. The tests performed in these studies would
understate the true effects of margin requirements on credit if the level of margin requirements was made
relatively high when the (market equilibrium) level of stock market credit was also relatively high. Second,
there is ample evidence that stock market traders have, and do, use alternative unregulated channels to
avoid the high level of Federal margin requirements (see text). This would seem to provide some
indication that Federal margin regulation does keep the volume of regulated credit below what the total
volume for stock market credit would be in the absence of regulation. However, the most important and
still unaddressed question is the effect that margin regulation has on the total volume of stock market
credit including that from both regulated and unregulated channels.

EFFECTS OF M ARGIN REQUIREMENTS ON STOCK MARKET PRICES
Results from several studies suggest that Federal margin requirements, or changes in margin require­
ments, have little effect on the average level or rate of change in stock prices.2 A most interesting
experiment was performed in the Largay and W est study which examined the average daily behavior of
stock prices (expressed as a rate of change) for 30 days following each change in margin requirements.3
From independent evidence and a priori reasoning based on recent research in stock price behavior, they
formulated the hypothetical behavior of stock prices that would be expected in the absence of margin
changes or if such changes had no effects on stock prices. The actual behavior of stock prices following
margin changes was very close to this hypothetical expectation. However, for a small number of days
immediately following an increase in margin levels, there appeared to be a "trivial'' depressing effect on
stock prices. This was attributed to the regulator's announced increase in margin requirements as having
some impact on stock trader's expectations of future stock prices.
The results of these studies are not without interest but it can be contended that the main objective of

’Jacob Cohen, "Federal Reserve Margin Requirements and the Stock M arket /' Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 3 (1966): 30-54; Thomas G. Moore, "Sto ck Market Margin Requirements,'' Journal of Political Economy 74
(1966): 158-67.
’James A. Largay and Richard R. West, "M argin Changes and Stock Price Beh avior," Journal of Political Economy 2
(1973): 328-39; Cohen, op. cit.
’ Largay and West, op. cit.




32

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA

margin regulation is not to control or influence the average level, but the volatility, of stock prices. The fact
that margin regulation might have no significant effect on the expected value of stock prices, or stock price
changes, does not mean it has no significant effect on their volatility. In fact, a recent study did find that a
measure of the variability of stock prices (the standard deviation of the rate of change in prices) tended to
be relatively low when margin requirements were relatively high.4 But even this result is somewhat
ambiguous. The period of this study (1926-60) was one where the variability of stock prices exhibited
a significant downward trend and margin requirements a significant upward trend (see Table 1 in text).
It is possible that the downward trend in stock price variability reflects other changes in the character of
the stock market rather than the rising trend in margin levels (or changes in the volatility of corporate
dividends which were also used to explain changes in the volatility of stock prices).
The most appropriate conclusion from the present collection of evidence on margin requirements
would appear to be that more research is needed. W hat is also needed is a more rigorous conceptual
formulation of the behavior of stock market traders who use credit and the implied effects on stock prices.
W ithout a conceptual framework it becomes difficult to interpret the “ facts" unambiguously or even to
formulate the right kind of testing procedures.

4George W . Douglas, “ Risk in Equity Markets: An Empirical Appraisal of Market Efficiency," Yale Economic Essays 1
(Spring 1969): 3-45.

NOW AVAILABLE:
INDEX TO FEDERAL RESERVE BANK REVIEWS
Articles which have appeared in the reviews of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks have been
indexed by subject by Doris F. Zimmermann, Librarian of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadel­
phia. The index covers the years 1950 through 1972 and is available upon request from the
Department of Public Services, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
19105.




33

BUSINESS REVIEW

JULY-AUGUST 1974

NOW AVAILABLE
BROCHURE AND FILM STRIP ON
TRUTH IN LENDING
Truth in Lending became the law of the land in 1969. Since then the law,
requiring uniform and meaningful disclosure of the cost of consumer credit,
has been hailed as a major breakthrough in consumer protection. But
despite considerable publicity, the general public is not very familiar with
the law.
A brochure, "W h a t Truth in Lending Means to You," cogently spells out
the essentials of the law. Copies in both English and Spanish are available
upon request from the Department of Bank and Public Relations, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19105.
Available in English is a film strip on Regulation Z, Truth in Lending, for
showing to consumer groups. This 20-minute presentation, developed by
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, is designed for use
with a Dukane project or that uses 35mm film and plays a 33 RPM record
synchronized with the film. Copies of the film strip can be purchased from
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, D. C.
20551, for $10. It is available to groups in the Third Federal Reserve District
without charge except for return postage.
Persons in the Third District may direct requests for loan of the film to
Truth in Lending, Federal Reserve Bankof Philadelphia, Philadelphia, Penn­
sylvania 19105. Such requests should provide for several alternate presenta­
tion dates.




34

w
m 'IKAL KC8EH E D
V
ANK

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PEIVIVSYLVAIVIA 19105

business review
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA
PHILADELPHIA, PA. 19105