View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Knowledge Is Power:
The Importance of Economic Education
Based on a speech given by President Santomero at the Pennsylvania Economic Association Annual Conference,
West Chester University, West Chester, PA, on May 30, 2003

A

BY ANTHONY M. SANTOMERO

s technological advances continue to expand
the range of financial services available to
consumers, money management becomes
increasingly complicated. Helping consumers
navigate this sea of financial products is important.
When households are capable of building wealth, they
are also capable of building more economically stable
neighborhoods and communities. That’s one reason
economic education is vital to the future health of our
nation’s economy. In this article, President Santomero
outlines what the Federal Reserve is doing to promote
economic education and explains why knowledge is
indeed power in our ever more complex world.

Economic education is vital
to the future health of our nation’s
economy. It gives our students the
building blocks for a successful financial future. It empowers consumers by
giving them the knowledge and tools
to improve their economic well being.
It is the best investment we can make
to strengthen our nation’s economy.
Economists recognize that developing basic economic and financial
knowledge is an important goal for a
democratic society that relies heavily on informed citizens and personal
economic decision-making. When
households are capable of building
wealth, they are also capable of building more economically stable neighborhoods and communities.
www.phil.frb.org

As we all know, the business of managing our money in this
environment has become increasingly
complicated. Technological advances
continue to expand the range of
financial services available to consumers. While choice and flexibility
are certainly beneficial to the consumer, they come with increased risks
— especially among consumers who
lack the knowledge and resources to
discern their choices.
American consumers must
not only have access to information,
but they must also be able to both
understand and use it. This is our
challenge. It is difficult enough for
the average American to understand
and choose wisely among the complex
financial products and services now
available. Think what an exceptionally
daunting challenge it is for those with
limited financial experience or education to make such decisions. Therefore,

I would like to share with
you my perspective on the importance
of economic and financial education
and give you some examples of what
we’re doing at the Philadelphia Fed to
further this important cause.
KNOWLEDGE IS POWER
In today’s ever-changing and
increasingly competitive financial
marketplace, knowledge is power. We
are living in an age in which the communications revolution has inundated
consumers with more information than
ever before, even as the financial marketplace has become more complex.
But simply having more information
does not necessarily mean people have
more knowledge.

Anthony M. Santomero, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review Q4 2003 1

educating consumers on the basics
of economics is an issue of critical
importance.
ECONOMIC EDUCATION
AND THE FED
The Federal Reserve has been
involved in economic education initiatives for some time. We consider them
integral to our mission. As you know,
the Fed serves a three-fold function
in our economy: it conducts monetary
policy, supervises and regulates banks
and financial institutions, and maintains an effective payments system.
Our economic education efforts are
important to, and intertwined with, all
three functions.
First, educating the nation’s
populace about economic issues is an
integral part of our role in monetary
policy. Economic education fosters a
better understanding of how policymakers have an impact on the economy. This basic knowledge of economics
helps consumers better understand
Federal Reserve policy actions and
how changes in policy ultimately affect
their own lives.
Second, as a regulator and
supervisor of banks and other depository financial institutions, the Federal
Reserve is responsible for promoting
safety and soundness in the industry.
In addition, Congress has given us the
job of overseeing the industry’s compliance with many consumer protection
laws, including fair access to credit and
service to communities, including provisions of the Community Reinvestment Act. Given Congress’s mandate
to bank regulators to ensure fair and
equitable treatment of consumers, we
believe economic education is a logical
extension of our regulatory duties.
Third, the Federal Reserve’s
duty to maintain an effective payments
system is facilitated by knowledgeable
consumers. Simply stated: If people are
informed about available choices, they

2 Q4 2003 Business Review

will be better able to make appropriate decisions about their payments.
For instance, consumers must make
decisions about when to pay by cash,
check, credit card, or debit card. The
options are increasing, and the choices
have become more complicated.
For all these reasons, economic education is critical to the
Federal Reserve’s long-term objective
of maximum sustainable economic
growth. Educated consumers are
the key to a well-functioning financial market, one that best serves the
nation’s economy. At the Federal

ECONOMIC EDUCATION:
A LONG-TERM SOLUTION
As a long-term solution to the
gap in economic and financial knowledge, economic education programs
should be aimed at school children,
our most important audience. Broadbased economic education initiatives
for school-age children will translate
into a society of financially literate
adults.
Yet, according to a survey
conducted by the American Savings
Education Council, only 21 percent of
students between the ages of 16 and

Economic education fosters a better
understanding of how policymakers have an
impact on the economy.
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, we
consider educating consumers on the
basics of economics to be a vital part
of our business.
Effective economic education
helps people develop the skills to meet
their financial and personal objectives,
including savings, financial stability,
home ownership, higher education, or
retirement. Rather than being merely
reactive in correcting abuses that
occur in financial markets — which
we must — it is better to be proactive
in developing an educated consumer,
knowledgeable enough to avoid being
abused.
The Fed clearly recognizes
the importance of education, but how
best to achieve it is often situational.
I believe the far-reaching nature of
the problem requires an attack on two
fronts: one as a long-term solution
and one as a short-term response to
observed problems in the market for
financial services. Let me outline each
part of this approach.

22 say they have had any exposure to
personal finance training in school.
The current situation stems in part
from the fact that economics and
basic financial concepts are often not
part of a school’s curriculum. Another
problem arises when these courses
are badly taught and, as a result, not
learned. Either way, the result is the
same. Graduates enter the workforce
without an understanding of how our
economy — or their finances — work.
The National Council on
Economic Education reported that
in 2002, 48 states and the District of
Columbia had economics standards in
their schools. However, only 34 states
require those standards to be implemented, and only 27 require testing of
students’ knowledge of economics. It
gets worse. Only 17 states require that
an economics course even be offered in
high school, and just 14 states require
students to take such a course in order
to graduate.
What is the situation closer to

www.phil.frb.org

home? Of the three states in the Third
Federal Reserve District — Pennsylvania, Delaware, and New Jersey — none
requires students to take an economics
course in high school. In fact, none
requires that high schools even offer
an economics course. In Delaware,
schools are required to implement
the economics standards, and student
achievement in economics is tested as
one-quarter of the state’s social studies
test. That test is given at the beginning
of 4th grade, the beginning of 6th grade,
the end of 8th grade, and the end of
11th grade. The 11th grade test plays a
part in determining the type of high
school diploma the student receives. In
New Jersey and Pennsylvania, although
standards are in place, testing of student achievement in economics is not
required.
Starting now, we must all
work to secure economics a place
in school curricula, with substantial
classroom time devoted to economic
instruction.
This is an area where Federal
Reserve financial education programs
can help. To date, the Philadelphia
Fed’s greatest success has been in
Delaware, where a financial literacy
program introduced in one high school
has now spread to seven other schools.
Fortunately, we have built strong
partnerships with the University
of Delaware’s Center for Economic
Education and Entrepreneurship, the
Delaware Bankers Association, and
the Consumer Credit Counseling
Services of Maryland and Delaware.
These partners have been instrumental in making this venture a success.
We expect the course to be offered in
roughly 20 Delaware high schools in
2003-2004. In addition, we are hoping
to replicate our success in Pennsylvania and New Jersey. To that end, we
are building relationships with state
councils on economic education and
with economic education centers at

www.phil.frb.org

colleges and universities. We would
like to find partners to pilot similar
programs in these states.
Equally important are teacher
training programs. Unfortunately, the
overwhelming majority of high school
teachers are ill-equipped to teach
economics and personal finance. Few
majored in these fields when they attended college. This is an area where
we can have an impact by following a

ways to infuse economics into these
assessed disciplines. Our train-theteacher approach is grounded in the
premise that well-trained teachers will
be able to educate large numbers of
students about economics and its role
in our daily lives.
In Pennsylvania, our key partnership with ECONOMICSPennsylvania and its associated centers for economic education makes possible the

Of the three states in the Third Federal
Reserve District — Pennsylvania, Delaware,
and New Jersey — none requires students to
take an economics course in high school.
train-the-teacher model. As a result,
the Philadelphia Fed provides significant training and resources to teachers
so they can get the right message to
students.
We seek ways to excite
educators about economic education
in the K-12 classroom by showing
those educators how economics can
be incorporated into existing language
arts, mathematics, and social studies
curricula.
The greater emphasis that
the No Child Left Behind Act places
on mathematics and reading standards
increases the need to show teachers

implementation of ongoing programs
to train teachers to teach economics in
the K-12 classroom.
We are having some success.
Last year, our Community Affairs Department presented day-long programs
to students in the Pennsylvania Governor’s School for Entrepreneurship
and to teachers as part of the Summer
Institute of the South Jersey Chamber
of Commerce. In addition, the Bank
held an economics seminar for teachers from Philadelphia and its suburbs.
This year, the Philadelphia Fed offered
a course for New Jersey teachers on
personal financial education and co-

Business Review Q4 2003 3

sponsored a summer institute with the
University of Delaware, the Delaware
Financial Literacy Institute, and Citigroup. The program, called “Money
Talks,” attracted 32 teachers. We are
also starting to host sessions to educate
interested people on how to become
economic education trainers.
Across the country, the
Federal Reserve System is playing an
important role in educating students
and teachers about the functions and
characteristics of money. We’re emphasizing the role of the Federal Reserve
in ensuring price stability and sustainable economic growth, the important
function that bank supervision and
regulation play in keeping the economy strong, and the importance of a
strong, viable payments system. Moreover, each Federal Reserve Bank has
its own economic education specialists
who provide tools and resources to
educators and help develop programs
to teach economic education to both
teachers and students.
ECONOMIC EDUCATION
AS A RESPONSE TO PROBLEMS:
A REACTIVE AGENDA
Reaching people before they
make financial mistakes is critical, and
the preventive economic and financial
education programs I just mentioned
serve this purpose well. However, we
also advocate programs for people
already in dire financial straits. These
initiatives typically target consumers
without banking relationships or with
few financial assets. They provide ways
to reach out to consumers, giving them
the tools to build a better financial
future.
I believe curative programs
are our best defense against financial
abuse, fraud, and illegality. To effectively combat these issues, we must
target those market areas that are most
vulnerable, such as the elderly or lowincome and minority communities.

4 Q4 2003 Business Review

There are many such communities in
our Federal Reserve District.
But in the process of addressing predatory lending practices, we
must be careful to effectively differentiate between standard risk-based lending and exploitative practices. This
is an important distinction. In fact, it
is essential for regulators to counter

can create a knowledgeable consumer,
able to understand and use the basics
of money management.
Targeted campaigns built
on motivation and coaching can also
encourage consumers to build wealth
for their future through sustained
savings plans and informed investment
decisions. The Philadelphia Fed is

It is essential for regulators to counter
predatory lending without impeding the
needed flow of capital to all segments
of our society.
predatory lending without impeding
the needed flow of capital to all segments of our society.
But predatory lending activities carry disproportionately high
interest rates and/or onerous terms,
not justified by the borrower’s higher
risk. These terms are imposed by
lenders who are willing to exploit the
borrower’s lack of financial knowledge,
market access, or economic resources.
The best defense against
these harmful practices is education. Consumers who are financially
knowledgeable are more likely to
be financially responsible. Unfortunately, many people learn only through
experience — once burned, twice
informed. While learning and working
through their own financial difficulties, consumers can effect change in
their overall behavior.
Successful programs combine
counseling and education, to empower
consumers in controlling their financial future. Disclosures can be useful
but only if consumers read and understand them; therefore, education is
the core of the solution. Here, the Fed
provides literature and recommended
curricula, for both educators and
consumers. Over the longer term, we

working with partners such as Philadelphia Saves, a campaign designed
to help create wealth through savings,
to change attitudes about money and
saving.
Programs such as these are
part of a wide effort to promote economic and financial education. Currently, efforts are booming in this area.
The FDIC has announced a national
pilot program for financial education.
In addition, the Treasury is establishing an Office of Financial Education,
which will oversee outreach efforts and
develop new policies regarding financial education.
Across the nation, Federal
Reserve Banks are partnering with
a broad constituency of communitybased organizations and associations
to draw attention to the need for
economic and financial education and
the programs designed to support it.
We are also engaged in a national effort to promote education through our
new campaign “There’s a Lot to Learn
about Money.” The strength of the
campaign lies in several key elements.
Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan recorded a public service announcement
that extols the virtues of economic
and financial education.

www.phil.frb.org

This is an aggressive program of media outreach to be sure our
message is heard. We have launched a
national web site,
www.FederalReserveEducation.org,
which features Internet links to instructional materials and tools to
increase understanding of economics and financial education. The site
includes such useful resources as
brochures, newsletters, curricula, references, and research.
On a local level, the Philadelphia Fed continues to develop and promote its own programs to encourage
economic education. We have forged
strong partnerships with organizations
like the Greater Philadelphia Urban
Affairs Coalition; Isles, a New Jerseybased community organization; and
state councils and centers for economic education. These partnerships
help us reach out to communities and
educators. With these partners, we’ve
developed a number of programs aimed
at increasing economic and financial
education, including conferences,
training seminars, and economics
courses for educators.
We have fostered greater
economic education by providing materials and curricula and by supporting
local efforts through our Community
Affairs Department. As I mentioned,
teaching the teacher is of prime
importance. We have increased that
commitment, bringing more resources
to this important part of our agenda.
We help educators identify appropriate
programs and curricula, and we create
evaluation tools to monitor progress.
We also have an aggressive
and ongoing research agenda. We target training to various constituencies,
such as children, adults, low-income
people, and so on, and help economic
education providers assess audience

www.phil.frb.org

demographics and needs. In this way,
we hope to provide substance to the
economic education research agenda
by measuring what participants have
learned and determining how programs meet needs over the long term.
Finally, a new project will put
a unique spin on the Philadelphia Fed’s
education efforts. We have opened a

Improved economic
education will result
in more productive,
fulfilling lives for
individuals and
families — and, in
turn, more vibrant,
economically stable
neighborhoods and
communities.
financial exhibit called “Money in Motion.” It employs the latest presentation
technology and interactive displays to
entertain visitors and simultaneously
teach them the unique role of the Federal Reserve System. It is fitting that
Philadelphia, the home of our nation’s
first bank, should share the story of our
nation’s financial history.
CONCLUSION
Economic education programs developed and promoted by the
Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank
help consumers make better financial
decisions. In classrooms around our
District, we help young people understand the workings of the economy
and the financial system in which they
are just beginning to participate. In

low- and moderate-income communities — often targets of unscrupulous
business practices — we help people
understand risks and evaluate alternatives.
Knowledge is power. Economic education generates knowledge.
It gives people the tools to understand
economic and financial issues and to
interpret events that will affect their
financial futures.
In short, informed, well-educated consumers make better decisions,
increasing their economic security
and well being. These consumers
are better able to contribute to vital,
thriving communities, further fostering economic development. Improved
economic education will result in more
productive, fulfilling lives for individuals and families — and, in turn, more
vibrant, economically stable neighborhoods and communities.
Most important, economic
education is critical to building bridges
between educators, businesses, and
consumers. These bridges will prepare
our society to meet the challenges
of an increasingly knowledge-based
economy. As we work to increase
familiarity with new technological and
financial tools, we give people the resources necessary to secure individual
economic success. Done right, economic education can have large-scale
results — results that are sweeping,
significant, and supportive of a higher
standard of living for all Americans. BR
For more information on
the Philadelphia Fed's economic education
programs, call Andrew Hill, economic
education specialist, at 215-574-4392, or
send e-mail to andrew.hill@phil.frb.org.
Or visit www.phil.frb.org/education.

Business Review Q4 2003 5

Agglomeration Economies:
The Spark That Ignites a City?
BY SATYAJIT CHATTERJEE

I

n industrially developed countries,
employment is heavily concentrated in cities.
A concentration of workers and businesses
in one location — what economists call
agglomeration economies — lowers production costs.
In fact, most economists believe that in the absence of
agglomeration economies, the spatial distribution of
employment would be much more even. In this article,
Satyajit Chatterjee discusses his research, which questions
this belief. He finds that while agglomeration economies
are an important factor, they’re not the most important
one. The combined effects of factors unrelated to
agglomeration economies, such as the availability of
natural resources and local economic policies, appear to
account for the bulk of the spatial concentration of U.S.
employment.

The bulk of an industrially
developed country’s economic activity takes place in cities. Typically,
these cities make up a relatively small
portion of the country’s overall territory. For instance, 83 percent of total

Satyajit Chatterjee
is a senior economic advisor and
economist in
the Philadelphia
Fed’s Research
Department.

6 Q4 2003 Business Review

employment in the U.S. is located in
metropolitan areas, and these areas account for 24 percent of the total land
area of the country.
Why is employment so heavily concentrated in selected areas of
the country? Economists think that
spatial concentration of employment
(or, more generally, economic activity)
develops for two very different reasons.
The first reason — and one that comes
most readily to mind — is that a location attracts people and businesses
because of the presence of some valuable natural resource. Petroleum, coal,
lumber, minerals, and proximity to a

navigable river or to the coast are all
examples of valuable natural resources.
Because such resources are not available everywhere, people and businesses
end up flocking to resource-rich areas.
However, the natural resource
reason does not explain the full extent
of the remarkable spatial concentration
we see in reality. For instance, access
to a deep harbor was no doubt important for the emergence of Philadelphia
as a colonial city, but can it be the
main reason for Philadelphia’s subsequent evolution into one of America’s
pre-eminent metropolitan areas? Studies of urban evolution suggest a second
reason for spatial concentration: A
concentration of workers and businesses in one location lowers production costs because proximity permits
workers and businesses to save on the
costs of transporting goods and people.
Economists refer to this cost advantage
as economies of spatial concentration,
or agglomeration economies, for short.
Agglomeration economies
can be a powerful force for attracting
large numbers of people to a given
location. They can cause a location
with some small advantage in terms
of natural resources to become a place
with a large concentration of diverse
businesses and households. While the
natural resource initially attracts businesses and households to the location,
this original group then becomes the
factor that attracts other businesses
and households to that location. As
the location grows in size, business
costs fall and the location’s attractiveness as a potential spot for other
businesses and households rises, and
more people and businesses move in.
www.phil.frb.org

Although rising congestion eventually chokes off the inflow of people,
agglomeration economies can be the
spark that ignites the development of
a city.
Economists generally believe
that agglomeration economies are the
primary factor that leads to the large
clusters of people and jobs we see in
the real world. In other words, most
economists believe that in the absence
of agglomeration economies, the spatial distribution of employment would
be much more even.
In this article I discuss my research, which tried to determine if this
belief is, in fact, accurate. My research
indicates that while agglomeration
economies are an important contributor to the spatial concentration
of employment, they’re not the most
important factor. Contrary to expectations, factors other than agglomeration
economies appear to account for the
bulk of spatial concentration. It’s not
clear exactly what these other factors
are, but they could be differences in
the availability of natural resources
across metropolitan areas, differences
in economic policies across cities and
states, or some other advantage of
spatial concentration distinct from
agglomeration economies. Whatever
the case, my research suggests that
agglomeration economies are probably
just one of several important factors
affecting spatial concentration of
employment.

people.1 But Lorenz curves can also be
used to show how unevenly employment is distributed across space.
To construct a Lorenz curve
of spatial concentration, I first ranked
metropolitan areas and rural counties
in the continental United States by
their employment density, the densest areas being ranked first. Using
this ranking, I then calculated the
percentage of employment accounted
for by the first, or top, 1 percent of the
total continental land area, then the

The statistician Max O. Lorenz (1880-1962)
developed the Lorenz curve. The curve is
probably the tool most used to analyze income
and other distributions. Remarkably, Lorenz
came up with the idea of the curve in his
undergraduate thesis at the University of Iowa,
circa 1894, at the age of 14! He went on to
have a distinguished career, becoming the
chief statistician of the Interstate Commerce
Commission in Washington, D.C.
1

top 2 percent, and so on. The Lorenz
curve is simply a graph that plots these
calculations (Figure 1). If employment were uniformly distributed over
the continental landmass, this graph
would coincide with the 45-degree line
shown in the figure. That is, the top
1 percent of the continental land area
would account for 1 percent of employment, the top 2 percent of the area
would account for 2 percent of employment, and so on. But if employment is
not uniformly distributed, the graph
will be bowed above the 45-degree line
— as, in fact, it is.
As Figure 1 indicates, the
top 1 percent of total continental land
area accounts for about 15 percent
of employment, the top 2 percent
accounts for about 25 percent, and so
on. Indeed, by the time we include the
top 20 percent of the continental land
area, we can account for more than 80
percent of total employment! Clearly,

FIGURE 1
Spatial Concentration of U.S. Employment, 1999

THE FACT OF SPATIAL
CONCENTRATION
To determine the contribution of agglomeration economies to
spatial concentration, we need a measure of the extent of spatial concentration in U.S. employment. An effective
way to do this is by using a Lorenz
curve, a graphical tool originally
developed to show the extent to which
income is unevenly distributed across

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q4 2003 7

U.S. employment is very unevenly
distributed over space.
The Lorenz curve is an effective visual representation of the
degree of spatial concentration of
employment. It also provides the basis
for the Gini index, a well-known index
of concentration. The Gini index is a
number between zero and one, and it
is a measure of the difference between
the Lorenz curve and the 45-degree
line. It is computed by dividing the
area between the Lorenz curve and the
45-degree line by the total triangular
area above the 45-degree line. When
employment is uniformly distributed,
the Lorenz curve coincides with the
45-degree line, and the Gini index is
zero. The more unevenly employment
is distributed, the more bowed the
Lorenz curve and the larger the area
between the curve and the 45-degree
line. Thus, the Gini index is higher for
a more uneven distribution of employment and lower for a more even one.
In Figure 1, the value of the Gini index
is 0.78, which means the area between
the 45-degree line and the bowed line
represents close to 80 percent of the
total area above the 45-degree line.
This is the measure of spatial concentration I used in my research.
NATURE AND MAGNITUDE OF
AGGLOMERATION ECONOMIES
As mentioned earlier, agglomeration economies arise because proximity permits workers and businesses
to save on the costs of transporting
goods and people. In this section I’ll
highlight one way in which this happens, then discuss what economists
know about the magnitude of agglomeration economies in the U.S.
One reason agglomeration
economies arise is that a large concentration of workers allows a business to
deal more effectively with fluctuations
in the volume of sales. Consider a
business whose future demand can be

8 Q4 2003 Business Review

either high or low, with equal probability. When demand is high, the business
needs four workers; when demand is
low, it needs only two. The business
has to hire workers before it knows
how large demand will be. Suppose the
business chooses to hire three workers.
If demand turns out to be low, workers
work at two-thirds capacity, and all
demand is met. If demand turns out to
be high, all workers work at full capacity, but one-quarter of demand is not
met. So there is a 50 percent chance
that every worker works at less than
full capacity.

capacity is when demand at both firms
is low, which happens with probability
one-quarter.
The movement of workers
between businesses in the same location does happen in reality, although
it takes the guise of contract workers
selling their services to businesses on
a temporary basis. For instance, we
might have a situation where both
businesses hire two permanent employees, and each business has the option
to hire additional contract employees
in the event the level of demand is
high. In this arrangement, there are

Agglomeration economies arise because
proximity permits workers and businesses
to save on the costs of transporting goods
and people.
Now imagine that another
enterprise in the same line of business
moves into the area and this enterprise
faces a similar uncertainty with respect
to demand. However — and this is the
key assumption — the level of the new
firm’s demand is independent of the
level of the first firm’s demand. This
may happen if the firms have different
sets of customers and serve different
markets. This means that the combinations of demand across the two firms
can take one of four possibilities, all
with equal probability: (high, high),
(high, low), (low, high), and (low,
low). Now, when the two businesses
have different levels of demand (which
happens with probability one-half), the
firm with low demand has an incentive
to rent out its one excess worker to the
firm with high demand. This is feasible
because both firms are in the same
location and the cost of moving workers between firms is presumably low. If
the two firms shifted workers between
them in this way, the only time any
worker would work at less than full

four permanent workers and two contract workers. The permanent workers always work at full capacity while
contract workers have a 75 percent
chance of working at full capacity or a
25 percent chance they won’t work at
all. Contract workers take on the risk
of unemployment, but if the two firms
use some of their cost savings to pay
contract workers more than full-time
employees, contract workers might feel
compensated for the risk.
To summarize, physical proximity makes it possible for firms to
share workers and so allows businesses
to take advantage of the fact that the
combined demand of several firms is
more stable than the demand of a single firm. This stability permits a group
of businesses to better utilize workers
than a single business. The improved
utilization of workers lowers business
costs and provides a reason for firms
and workers to cluster together.
Let’s turn now to a description of the strategies economists have
used to estimate the magnitude of agwww.phil.frb.org

glomeration economies that stem from
better utilization of workers. The most
direct way to do this is to measure
changes in the utilization of workers
due to spatial concentration. However, because it’s not easy to directly
measure how hard employees work,
economists have used more indirect
methods. Let’s look at two of these
methods along with the estimates of
agglomeration economies obtained
using each one.
The first method uses information on labor hours and equipment purchased (also called capital)
and goods (output) sold by different
industries in different metropolitan
areas. For any given industry, labor and
capital purchased will have a higher
utilization rate in metro areas with a
large concentration of workers and
firms. Thus, for any given industry and
for any given amounts of labor and
capital, more output will be produced
in a large metro area than in a small
one. The estimate we get from this
method suggests that agglomeration
economies make businesses in metro
areas with more than 2 million people
8 percent more productive than businesses in metro areas with less than 2
million people.2
The second method uses
information on hourly wages businesses pay to workers. Businesses that
use workers more effectively face lower
costs and so make higher profits. Given
that, a business would be motivated to
locate in a large metro area rather than
a small one. But when businesses do
so, they compete with one another and
end up paying more for each worker
they hire. In other words, in a competitive environment, higher worker

productivity will result in higher wages
being paid to workers in large metro
areas. By measuring the wages paid to
similarly skilled workers in metro areas
of varying sizes, we can estimate how
much more productive workers are
due to agglomeration effects. Studies
that follow this approach have found
that as a metro area doubles in size,
the productivity of its workers rises 3
percent.3
AGGLOMERATION ECONOMIES’ CONTRIBUTION TO
SPATIAL CONCENTRATION
Given these estimates of the
magnitude of agglomeration economies, the question is: How important
are these agglomeration effects for the
spatial concentration of employment?
Answering this question involved two
steps.
First, I constructed an
economic model of local employment
that can exactly reproduce the Lorenz
curve in Figure 1, which gives the distribution of workers across metropolitan areas and rural counties in 1999.
Second, I constructed a new Lorenz
curve for a model economy that’s identical to the one in the first step except
that in this model, there are no agglomeration economies. If the Lorenz
curve for this new model economy
turns out to be close to the 45-degree
line, I can reasonably conclude that
agglomeration effects account for the
bowed shape of the Lorenz curve in
Figure 1. More generally, any difference between the Lorenz curve in
Figure 1 and the Lorenz curve predicted by the model with no agglomeration effects can be attributed to the

effects of agglomeration economies.
In particular, the difference between
the Gini indexes for the two Lorenz
curves is a measure of the contribution
of agglomeration effects to the spatial
concentration of U.S. employment.
Description of the Model
Economy. Briefly, the macroeconomic
model in the first step has the following features.4 There is a given set of
locations, corresponding to the 275
metropolitan areas and 2,248 rural
counties in the continental U.S.5 Each
location can produce two types of
goods. One type, which I call traded
goods, can be shipped without cost
to other locations; the second type,
which I call local goods, cannot be
shipped at all. A household living in
a given location derives benefit (or
what economists call utility) from the
consumption of the traded good and
from consumption of the local good
produced in that location. (The household cannot consume the local good
of other locations because local goods
cannot be shipped.)
Locations differ in terms of
natural resources. In my model, the
natural resources available to a location affect the productivity of labor
and capital employed in the production of the traded good in that area. It
may also affect how much enjoyment
a household gets from living there. A
location that has high productivity
due to the presence of some natural

With some modifications, this is the same
model I have used in previous research. The
details of the model are in my article with
Gerald Carlino.
4

The 275 metropolitan areas consist of 258
primary metropolitan areas and 17 consolidated
metro areas. A consolidated metropolitan area
is a group of neighboring primary metro areas
between which there is a significant amount of
commuting.
5

This estimate is the median value of
agglomeration economies across manufacturing
industries reported in Leo Sveikauskas’s article.
3

2

Reported in David Segal’s article.

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q4 2003 9

resources will attract firms making the
traded good; an area that’s pleasant to
live in because it has some other natural amenity will attract households.
As a location with some
natural advantage attracts businesses
and households, it gains employment.
The rise in employment generates
agglomeration economies and lowers
business costs. This serves to make the
location more attractive to businesses,
and more businesses move in and
create jobs. However, the people who
move in to take these jobs make the
location increasingly congested, and
this congestion causes the price of the
local good to rise. The rising price of
the local good reduces the purchasing
power of the wages workers receive
in that location and limits the inflow
of workers. The migration of workers
between locations will make the wage
(adjusted for amenities) equal across
all metro areas, and every person
seeking work will be employed in some
location.
In this model, the distribution of employment across locations
reflects the availability of natural
resources in each area, the magnitude
of agglomeration economies, and the
magnitude of congestion costs. The
magnitude of the agglomeration effects
in the model is consistent with the evidence on agglomeration effects noted
in the previous section. Also, the magnitude of congestion costs is consistent
with the evidence on congestion costs
that researchers have found for U.S.
metro areas.
Finally, the model’s parameters use values that determine the
effects of natural resources on employment, so that the employment density
in each metro area and rural county
in the model exactly matches the employment density of that metro area
or rural county in reality. This final
step makes it possible for the model
to exactly reproduce the Lorenz curve
shown in Figure 1.
10 Q4 2003 Business Review

What Does the Model Say
About the Role of Agglomeration
Economies in Spatial Concentration?
Using this model I can investigate the
role of agglomeration economies in the
spatial concentration of U.S. employment. As noted earlier, my strategy for
doing this is to examine what happens
to the spatial distribution of employment in my model when I eliminate
the reduction in production costs due
to agglomeration economies while
keeping all other aspects of the model
unchanged. The solid black line in Figure 2 plots actual employment densities for metro areas in 1999; the dotted
line plots what happens to employment
densities in these metro areas when
agglomeration effects are removed.
As the figure shows, a relatively small
set of high-density locations become
less dense and a large set of relatively
low-density locations become denser.

The first set includes large metro areas,
which benefit the most from agglomeration economies. These metro areas
shed employment because they can no
longer productively employ as many
workers. Workers from these metro
areas end up moving to smaller metro
areas (and also to rural counties not
shown in the figure), and consequently, these areas become denser.
The table lists the top 20
metro areas for which agglomeration
economies seem most important. As
one would expect, big cities like New
York, Los Angeles, Chicago, and
Atlanta are on the list. Los Angeles
appears to be the city that benefits
most from agglomeration economies in
that almost 80 percent of its jobs would
disappear if agglomeration economies
were absent; Phoenix-Mesa is another
area that appears to owe a lot of its
employment to agglomeration econo-

FIGURE 2
Metropolitan Employment Densities With
And Without Agglomeration Economies

www.phil.frb.org

mies. Philadelphia also makes the list
and appears to owe 20 percent of its
jobs to agglomeration economies.
Clearly, agglomeration
economies appear to be very important for the development of specific
cities, especially Los Angeles and
Phoenix-Mesa. But how important is
it generally? Figure 3 helps to answer
this question. It compares the Lorenz
curve when agglomeration effects are
removed from the model constructed
in step 1 with the Lorenz curve from
Figure 1. The new Lorenz curve is less
bowed, indicating that in the absence
of agglomeration economies, employment is more evenly distributed. The
Gini index declines about 16.5 percent,
from 0.78 to 0.65.
The most striking feature of
the new Lorenz curve is that it’s still
pretty far from the 45-degree line.
Even in this world without agglomeration economies (but which is otherwise similar to the U.S. in important
respects), there is considerable spatial
concentration of employment. In
other words, although the contribution
of agglomeration economies is substantial, it’s not as large as we might have
expected. Recall that most economists
consider agglomeration economies the
most important reason for spatial concentration. But my model predicts that
the U.S. would continue to be spatially
concentrated, that is, have very dense
areas, even if agglomeration economies
were completely absent. Apparently,
agglomeration economies are generally
not needed to spark the development
of cities! 6
What, Then, Are the Other
Determinants of Spatial Concentration? If agglomeration economies
are not the key contributor to spatial
concentration, what is? Taken at face
value, my model suggests that it’s the
uneven distribution of natural resources that accounts for the bulk of
spatial concentration. Indeed, some

www.phil.frb.org

researchers have suggested that access
to a navigable river or coast is, in fact,
a key determinant of spatial concentration in the U.S.7 Nevertheless, it’s not
accurate to say that any concentration
left unexplained by agglomeration
economies must result from the effects

It’s possible that economists may have
mismeasured the magnitude of agglomeration
economies and congestion costs, thus affecting
the values built into my model. However, when
I varied the model’s magnitude of agglomeration
economies and congestion costs within plausible
ranges (while ensuring that the model exactly
reproduced the Lorenz curve in Figure 1), the
drop in spatial concentration from elimination
of agglomeration economies rarely exceeded
50 percent. Therefore, even with generous
allowances for mismeasurement, agglomeration
economies do not appear to account for the
bulk of spatial concentration.
6

of natural resources. There are other
factors, besides geography, that might
affect spatial concentration and that
are not captured in my simple model.
One potentially important
factor is city- or state-specific
economic policies. If an area happens
to be located in a state with probusiness laws and regulations, it
will have an advantage in terms of
job creation relative to other areas.8
Another factor could be the cost
savings from transporting goods from
one region to another.9 For instance,

The article by Thomas Holmes presents
evidence that state policies affect the location
of industry.
8

The cost savings from shipping goods within
metro areas are captured in the estimates of
agglomeration economies used in my model.
9

See the article by Jordan Rappaport and Jeffrey
Sachs.
7

TABLE
Metropolitan Areas

Percentage of Employment
Due to Agglomeration Economies

Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County
Phoenix-Mesa
Dallas-Fort Worth
Washington-Baltimore
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria
Denver-Boulder-Greeley
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose
Atlanta
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence-Lowell-Brockton
Minneapolis-St. Paul
St. Louis
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City
New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island
Portland-Salem
San Diego
Cleveland-Akron
Pittsburgh

79
48
32
29
28
27
25
23
23
22
22
22
22
20
20
19
18
13
12
11

Business Review Q4 2003 11

part of Philadelphia’s attraction as a
business location is its proximity to two
other large metro areas: Washington,
D.C. and New York City. Philadelphia’s
proximity to these two places means
that businesses in Philadelphia can
ship goods relatively cheaply to two
other large metro areas, thus giving
them relatively cheap access to a very
large customer base.10 A third factor
could be that some benefits of spatial
concentration go beyond reducing the
costs of producing goods and services.
It’s well known, for instance, that
most inventive activities take place in
cities. Just as spatial concentration can
reduce the costs of producing goods
and services, it may also reduce the
costs of producing new knowledge
through better utilization of knowledge
workers.11
SUMMARY
Economists have generally
pointed to agglomeration economies
as the principal reason a country’s
employment tends to get concentrated
in a relatively small number of geographic areas. Agglomeration economies refer to the reduction in business
costs that results from a concentration
of businesses and workers in the same
geographic area. This reduction in
business costs provides incentives for
workers and firms to cluster together,
despite the costs associated with
increased congestion. Several empirical studies have found evidence of
significant agglomeration economies in
U.S. metro areas.
However, the mere existence
of agglomeration economies does not

settle the question of whether these
effects are the primary cause of the
spatial concentration of employment.
To settle that point, we need to deter-

Just as spatial
concentration can
reduce the costs of
producing goods
and services, it may
also reduce the costs
of producing new
knowledge through
better utilization of
knowledge workers.
mine if agglomeration economies, as
measured, are powerful enough to give
rise to the degree of spatial concentration we see in the real world. This

article highlighted research that seeks
to make this determination. Contrary
to expectations, I found that the bulk
of the spatial concentration of employment results from factors other than
agglomeration economies.
The flip side of my finding is
that some set of other factors accounts
for the bulk of spatial concentration.
Although my research cannot shed
light on the contribution of these other
factors, it’s possible to hazard a guess
(based on the work that other economists have done) as to what these
other factors might be: natural resources, state and local economic policies, proximity to other metro areas,
and spatial concentration’s benefits in
creating new knowledge. Whatever
the case is, my research suggests that
agglomeration economies are one of
several important factors, but not the
principal factor, affecting spatial concentration of employment. BR

FIGURE 3
Lorenz Curves With and Without
Agglomeration Economies

See the article by Gordon Hanson for
evidence in favor of this point.
10

The article by Adam Jaffe, Manuel
Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson and my
article with Gerald Carlino present evidence
that proximity may help in the communication
of new knowledge.
11

12 Q4 2003 Business Review

www.phil.frb.org

REFERENCES

Carlino, Gerald A., Satyajit Chatterjee,
and Robert Hunt. “Knowledge Spillovers
and the New Economy of Cities,” Working Paper 01-14, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, September 2001.
Chatterjee, Satyajit, and Gerald A. Carlino. “Aggregate Metropolitan Employment Growth and the Deconcentration
of Metropolitan Employment,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 48, 2001, pp. 549-83.
Hanson, Gordon H. “Market Potential, Increasing Returns, and Geographic Concentration,” Graduate School of International
Relations and Pacific Studies, University of
California, San Diego, December 2001.

www.phil.frb.org

Holmes, Thomas. “The Effects of State
Policies on the Location of Industry:
Evidence from State Borders,” Journal of
Political Economy, 106, 1998, pp. 667-705.
Jaffe, Adam B., Manuel Trajtenberg,
and Rebecca Henderson. “Geographic
Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as
Evidenced by Patent Citations,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 108, 1993, pp. 577-98.

Segal, David. “Are There Returns to Scale
in City Size?” Review of Economics and
Statistics, 58, 1976, pp. 339-50.
Sveikauskas, Leo. “The Productivity of
Cities,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89,
1975, pp. 393-413

Rappaport, Jordan, and Jeffrey D. Sachs.
“The U.S. as a Coastal Nation,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Working
Paper 01-11, revised October 2002.

Business Review Q4 2003 13

The Impact of Immigration
on American Cities:
An Introduction to the Issues

A

BY ALBERT SAIZ

ccording to the U.S. Census Bureau, about
1 million people immigrated to the U.S. in
2001—a number not too far from the record
1.3 million who arrived in 1907. Like their
fellow newcomers of long ago, latter-day immigrants
generally come here for one reason: to seek a better life.
Debate still rages today – as it did a century ago – over
immigrants’ effect on a host country’s economic and
social structures. Nevertheless, several factors make the
current immigration inflows distinctive. In this article,
Albert Saiz discusses immigration’s impact on a receiving
country’s labor and housing markets, fiscal systems, and
social interactions.

The United States is a
country of immigrants. A majority of
Americans trace their roots to people
who journeyed from far away to seek a
better life. And today’s immigrants to
the United States are doing the same.
Recent immigrants tend to concentrate in a handful of metropolitan
areas, and immigration has become a

Albert Saiz is an
assistant professor
at the Wharton
School of the
University of Pennsylvania. When he
wrote this article,
he was an economist in the
regional section of the Philadelphia Fed’s
Research Department.
14 Q4 2003 Business Review

salient feature of these cities. According to the Census Bureau, about 1 million people immigrated to the U.S. in
2001. That figure was not too far from
the record 1.3 million immigrants who
arrived in 1907 (Figure). However,
immigration at the start of the century
had a relatively greater impact as the
U.S. was much less populated. Relative
immigration rates were at their highest during the first decade of the 20th
century: 11 immigrants per year for
each 1,000 inhabitants, compared with
five per 1,000 in the last decade of the
century. The U.S. was absorbing twice
the proportion of immigrants than it
is today.
Nevertheless, several factors
make the current immigration inflows
distinctive. First, the U.S. government

reduced immigration inflows drastically at the beginning of the Great Depression in 1929. Current immigration
levels are the highest in the memories
of most Americans. Second, the countries of origin of immigrants are more
diverse today than in the 19th and
early 20th centuries. The traditional
countries of origin (Germany, Holland,
Italy, Ireland, UK, and central Europe)
are no longer important sources of
immigration. Third, even if immigration inflows are small relative to the
population levels, they will still have
an important impact on population
growth. If current immigration rates
are sustained, two-thirds of population
growth in the United States could be
accounted for by immigration by 2050.
Are such projections realistic?
That depends on future immigration
policies. Any time immigration has
fueled a country’s population, it has
also sparked heated debates over the
desirability of further immigration. For
example, on September 1, 1910, the
Wall Street Journal ran the following
story on the front page:
“The Labor party in the
colony of Victoria, Australia, which is
practically the dominating influence in
the Government, is protesting against
the immigration of skilled artisans
when they add to the congested population of Melbourne. It is our belief
that these immigrants would in time
tend to distribute themselves to points
where they were more needed, but
the attitude of the Labor party is by no
means unreasonable” [emphasis added].
More than 90 years later, immigration continues to be a furiously
debated topic. Public opinion does not
www.phil.frb.org

always favor letting more people in.
Economists Kenneth Scheve of Yale
University and Matthew Slaughter of
Dartmouth College have demonstrated
that less skilled workers favor limiting immigrant inflows into the U.S.
Thomas Bauer, Magnus Lofstrom,
and Klaus Zimmermann, from Bonn
University, also report that survey
respondents in OECD countries show
substantial support for immigration
limits.1
This article provides background for a reasoned discussion of the
impact of immigration. Economists
and other social scientists have produced substantial research on immi-

OECD, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, was formed by
the governments of a group of medium- to
high-income countries to “tackle the economic,
social, and governance challenges of a globalized
economy.”
1

gration’s impact on local economies.
Individual and collective preferences
for policies should be strongly founded
on the available evidence.
Economists generally agree
that a worldwide labor market without

Immigration continues to be a furiously
debated topic. Public opinion does not
always favor letting more people in.
any border restrictions is efficient: that
is, people achieve a maximum level of
production of goods given the existing availability of resources. The issue
with immigration is its impact on the
distribution of real income. Who are
the winners and the losers worldwide?
Can inhabitants of a country that
allows immigration lose because of

FIGURE
Immigrants in the U.S. by Decade

www.phil.frb.org

it? Regardless of the average impact
on a country, what is the distribution
within a country of gains and costs
arising from immigration?
This article will deal with
these questions from the point of view

of countries receiving immigrants.
Although other important questions,
such as the impact on countries sending immigrants and the progress and
welfare of immigrants themselves,
should also be part of the discussion
on immigration policies, they will not
be covered here. We will examine
immigration’s impact on host countries’ labor and housing markets, their
fiscal systems, and social interactions.
IMMIGRATION’S IMPACT
ON LABOR MARKETS
Immigration’s impact on labor
markets can be gauged by wages or
employment. Does immigration affect
wages? How? Does it influence the
employment prospects of natives or
change the unemployment rate?
Wages. By far, most of the
economic literature on immigration
has concentrated on its impact on
labor markets, specifically wages. Do
immigrants compete with natives in
the labor market and drive real wages
down?
To answer this question
we need to think first about what
distinguishes international labor flows
(emigration and immigration) from
international trade. Actually, the
United States can use foreign labor
by importing products produced by
workers in the rest of the world. In
theory, international trade of goods
Business Review Q4 2003 15

and services could equalize the
wages and other payments made to
the different factors of production
worldwide. After all, why would a firm
in the U.S. pay more for an input,
such as labor, when it faces price
competition from producers in other
countries?
In practice, under current
economic and political conditions,
this so-called factor-price equalization
does not happen. Why? First, there
are a number of trade barriers, such
as import quotas and tariffs. Second,
there are products, such as personal
services and local public goods,
that cannot be traded and thus do
not face international competition.
Third, education levels, technological
developments, and institutions have
proved difficult to transplant. Many
countries do not possess the skills
or technology to compete in some
product markets.
Thus, the impact of immigration will not be quite the same as that
of importing goods produced by foreign
labor. For this reason, and given the
relatively small size of exports and imports in the United States, labor economists have concentrated on models
of the economy without international
trade. These economic models, which
are simplified representations of the
economy (as a map is a simplified
representation of a geographic area),
help us understand the effects of
changes in fundamental variables, such
as population, on outcomes of interest,
such as wages. According to Harvard
economist George Borjas, these models
indicate there are positive overall gains
to natives from immigration but point
to a distributive impact: There may be
winners and losers within the native
population.
The simplest model considers a single type of labor and a fixed
amount of capital.2 This model predicts overall gains from immigration.
16 Q4 2003 Business Review

The increase in labor supply exerts
downward pressure on wages, but the
gains to firms from greater availability
of labor more than offset native workers’ wage losses. The distribution of the
benefits from immigration hinges on
the initial distribution of firms’ shares
of ownership. For instance, if everyone is a worker but also an investor,

The relative skills
of immigrants in the
U.S. have been
decreasing since
the 1960s.
everyone experiences net gains from
the availability of more people who
produce at a lower cost.
But, in reality, the amount
of capital in the economy is not fixed.
When we allow capital to adjust freely
(maybe because of the availability of
foreign capital), results are different.
Suppose that if we doubled the total
amount of resources devoted to production, we would double the amount
we produce.3 In this setup, immigration does not generate any change in
wages and does not generate economic
gains or losses to natives. This happens
because as the amount of available
labor increases via immigration, investors find it desirable to increase the
amount of capital as well, so that the

Capital refers to investments in durable
productive assets, such as computers, factories,
and so on.
2

3
In economists’ jargon, this technology exhibits
constant returns to scale. Such productive
technology seems to represent fairly well
the production process at the national level.
However, at the local level, for example, in
metropolitan areas, this need not be the
case. See Satyajit Chatterjee’s article on
agglomeration economies.

amount of capital per worker is kept
at the initial level before immigration.
This level was the one that minimized
the costs of production, and immigration doesn’t change that.
For example, imagine that
the population of a country doubles
because of immigration. Capital per
worker will adjust to the initial level
(the level that is optimal for investors).
The new economy, after immigration, will just be a duplicate of the old
economy! Total gross domestic product
(GDP) will double, but per capita GDP
will stay the same. Wages will remain
unchanged and so will the dividends
paid to each owner of capital.
An even more realistic model
takes into account the existence of
several types of labor. Take, for
example, the case in which there are
two types of labor: highly skilled and
unskilled. The availability of formal
education and knowledge, which help
determine the level of skills that a
country’s workers have, is approximately fixed in the medium run.
In this situation, and if new
capital can be put into place, immigration will benefit natives only if the
distribution of skills in the immigrant
population (for example, the proportion of people who are low skilled)
is different from that of the native
population. If the skill composition of
immigrants and natives is identical,
we are back to a “replicated economy”
scenario: Doubling the country’s
population just doubles the economy
without any changes in income per
capita. But if the composition of skilled
and unskilled workers is different in
the immigrant and the native populations, relative wages will change.
For example, if immigrants tended
to be more highly skilled, this would
increase the relative supply of highly
skilled individuals, reducing wages for
the highly skilled and increasing wages
for low-skilled workers.

www.phil.frb.org

In reality, economists have
worried about the potential impact
of immigration on low-skilled natives.
George Borjas, one of the most active
economists studying immigration in
the past decade, has pointed to the fact
that the relative skills of immigrants
in the U.S. have been decreasing since
the 1960s. To be sure, the United
States attracts a good deal of highly
skilled professionals, such as doctors,
computer programmers, engineers,
scientists, and Ph.D. economists. In
1990, 26.2 percent of male immigrants
25 years or older were college graduates
(the same proportion as natives). Nevertheless, the share of immigrants with
less than a high school diploma was
37.1 percent, much higher than the
same proportion for natives (14.1 percent). Is the influx of such a relatively
low-skilled population affecting wages
for low-skilled workers? Considerable
research has been devoted to answering this question.
Most studies have compared
the change in wages in cities that
receive major immigration inflows to
the change in wages in other areas.
These are generally known as area
studies. Surprisingly, the results only
yield evidence of a weak negative
association between immigration and
wages in the sectors and metropolitan
areas where immigrants tend to find
employment.
Area studies have been
criticized because they do not take
into account firms’ and immigrants’
responses to changing economic
conditions. If, for instance, immigrants are systematically attracted to
areas that are experiencing economic
booms, we should not expect to see a
clear-cut negative association between
immigration and wages. Without immigration, wages may have been higher
in these areas, but there is no way to
disentangle the impact of immigration
from the positive effect of a booming

www.phil.frb.org

economy. Similarly, firms that tend to
use immigrant labor will move to areas
where immigrants tend to concentrate,
increasing the demand for labor in
those areas.
David Card, a labor economist at Berkeley, studied the impact
of the Mariel boatlift on wages and
employment in Miami, Florida. Between May and September 1980, about
125,000 Cuban immigrants arrived in
southern Florida. The sudden inflow
of people arriving in boats (balsas in
Spanish and, hence, the name balseros
for contemporary Cuban immigrants
who follow the same route) resulted

Miami compared with those in similar
metropolitan areas.
Still, some economists
think that looking at specific highimmigration metropolitan areas
is not enough to learn about the
general impact of immigrants on
wages. George Borjas, teaming with
Larry Katz and Richard Freeman
from Harvard, argues that the
mobility of natives may counteract
the local effects of immigration on
wages. If immigration puts downward
pressure on wages in the areas where
immigrants concentrate, natives may
decide to leave or may be less willing

Some economists think that looking at specific
high-immigration metropolitan areas is not
enough to learn about the general impact of
immigrants on wages.
from the Cuban government’s decision to allow free emigration from the
island’s port of Mariel. Card estimates
that about 50 percent of the Mariel
immigrants settled in Miami in 1980.
Initially, this represented a sudden
7 percent increase in the city’s labor
force. By 1983, many more resettled
refugees had found their way south
to Miami. Mariel immigrants were
relatively unskilled, both in terms
of formal education and fluency in
English. The advantages of studying
that massive immigration episode, in
light of the criticisms of area studies,
are that its timing was independent of
the evolution of Miami’s economy and
that firms could not have predicted it
in advance.
But Card’s study suggests
that even a major shock of low-skilled
immigrants such as that represented by
the Mariel boatlift did not change the
relative wages of low-skilled workers in

to move into these areas. In this sense
local economies are interconnected:
The impact of immigration on wages
will be spread over the entire nation
as natives move in response to
immigration inflows into specific areas.
Borjas, Katz, and Freeman
estimated the national impact of
immigration on wages. They used a
simplified model of the economy and
estimates of the general responsiveness
of wages to changes in the supply of
low-skilled workers in order to approximate the impact of immigration. They
report a modest impact. Wages for
high-school dropouts would have been
about 3 percent higher relative to wages
for other workers in 1990 without any
immigration in the 1980s. Notice that
this implies that relative wages for other workers (those with at least a high
school diploma) would have been lower
without the immigration of the 1980s.
However, as George Borjas pointed

Business Review Q4 2003 17

out, the estimates from the Harvard
trio can be subject to criticism.4 Their
calculations are rather uncertain, since
they rely on their model’s adequacy
and the accuracy of its parameters.
We are left with the
impression that the empirical
evidence is inconclusive as to the
actual magnitude of the impact of
immigration on wages. However, it is
fair to argue that immigration may
have had a modest negative impact
on the wage growth of low-skilled
individuals in the United States and
a corresponding positive impact on
wages for the rest.
Employment. Economists
have also investigated the association
between immigration and employment.
Does immigration reduce the proportion of natives who are working or actively looking for jobs, usually referred
to as labor force participation? Does
immigration generate unemployment?
Immigration affects labor
force participation only if wage effects
are sizable. In other words, if immigration substantially reduced the wages of
a particular group, some individuals
in that group may decide to withdraw
from the labor force. Similarly, if
immigration substantially increased
the wages of a particular group, some
individuals in that group may decide to
enter the labor force. In practice, since
wage effects are very small, we expect
the impact on labor participation to be
minor.
Using an area study approach,
David Card has looked at such an
impact. Confirming what the evidence
from the research on wages suggests,
he finds that immigration has a very
small impact on the employment of
natives in the same skill category.
Robert Fairlie of the Univer-

See George Borjas’ 2002 Harvard University
mimeo.
4

18 Q4 2003 Business Review

sity of California at Santa Cruz and
Bruce Meyer of Northwestern University have found that immigration
can have a negative effect on native
self-employment. Immigrants are more

ing people to jobs within the country.
If institutional and social
factors associated with high unemployment rates are present, as is the
case in many European countries, one

The effect of immigration on unemployment
depends on the nature of the labor market.
likely than natives to own and operate
small businesses such as convenience
stores and restaurants. However, these
authors also found that immigration
does not affect self-employment by
African-Americans. Since immigration barely affects total employment
and wages, the results imply that some
natives prefer to take on other, more
available jobs rather than compete
with immigrants’ small businesses.
The effect of immigration on
unemployment depends on the nature
of the labor market. Institutional and
social factors sometimes make quick
transitions from unemployment to jobs
difficult. For example, the geographical
distribution of jobs may not correspond
to the geographical distribution of
population (so jobs may not necessarily
be where people are). Or some people
might be unwilling to move from
their hometown and would rather stay
unemployed.
In a market with few such
institutional and social factors, immigration should not affect unemployment. Economists agree that this is
the case in the United States. A large
majority of people looking for a job at
current wages are usually able to find
a job after some searching. Moreover,
according to Borjas, immigration may
“grease the wheels” of the labor market. Immigrants are much more mobile
than natives and respond more quickly
to changes in the economic situation.
This may speed the process of match-

might suspect that immigrants to those
countries are competing with natives
for jobs. There is no empirical evidence
that this is actually the case.5 The
explanation is akin to the argument
advanced when we discussed what
would happen if we doubled a country’s population. Immigration increases
the scale of the economy, but it needn’t
change the unemployment rate.
IMMIGRATION'S IMPACT ON
THE HOUSING MARKET
As we discussed earlier, using labor from other countries is not
exclusively a matter of immigration.
Trading goods between countries
also means using foreign labor. What
sets immigration apart from trade is
its residential aspect: immigration
involves foreign workers living in the
U.S. Therefore, one might expect to
find that immigration has a major effect on the local housing market.
Does immigration affect
housing prices? Immigration certainly
increases the demand for housing. Its
impact on prices depends on what
economists call the elasticity of housing supply—that is, the sensitivity of
the supply of housing to changes in
price. In some markets, only small

See, for instance, Rudolf Winter-Ebmer and
Josef Zweimuller’s article, which reports a lack
of evidence that immigration has a negative
impact on youth unemployment in Austria.
5

www.phil.frb.org

price hikes are necessary to increase
supply enough to accommodate increasing demand. In these cases, supply
is very elastic. In other markets, where
supply isn’t as elastic, small changes in
demand translate into higher prices. In
these markets, it takes a much greater
increase in prices for supply to respond
to the increased demand.
Studies in housing economics
demonstrate that, at the national level,
the supply of housing is fairly elastic.
Increases in population that are spread

out over the country needn’t translate
into higher housing prices. The supply
of housing increases sufficiently with
small changes in price. But while housing supply may be relatively elastic at
the national level, it may be much more
inelastic in specific locations. Plus,
immigrants tend to concentrate in
densely populated metropolitan areas
where housing supply is typically fairly
inelastic (see Table and map). This implies that housing rents and prices may
be expected to grow faster in response

to population growth in these areas.
My research has focused on
the impact of immigration on local
housing rents and prices. I started
by looking at the Mariel boatlift. It
is an interesting episode because of
its magnitude and exact timing. It
is also important because, as David
Card convincingly demonstrated, it
is an example of the small impact of
even massive immigration on wages.
My research shows that one year after
the Mariel boatlift, rents in Miami

TABLE
MAJOR IMMIGRANT METROPOLITAN AREAS (1983-1997)
The table shows the main 20 destinations of legal immigrants in the 15 years from 1983 to 1997. Impact is defined as the
total number of immigrants as a proportion of the initial (1983) population. Philadelphia is the only metropolitan area
in the Third District that makes it to the top of the list. However, immigration in Philadelphia is not very important in
terms of its population impact over this period (3.23 percent) compared to other close major metropolitan areas such as
New York, the Northern New Jersey cities, and Washington.
Rank

MSA

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20

www.phil.frb.org

Population in 1983

Immigrants 83-97

Impact*

New York
Los Angeles-Long Beach
Chicago
Miami
Washington, D.C.
San Francisco
Anaheim-Santa Ana
Houston
San Jose
Boston
Oakland
San Diego
Newark
Philadelphia
Bergen-Passaic
Nassau-Suffolk
Dallas
Seattle-Bellevue-Everett
Detroit
Jersey City

8,491,429
8,182,905
7,301,085
1,776,909
3,809,206
1,570,619
2,171,929
3,205,171
1,419,521
5,383,370
1,908,848
2,126,091
1,953,893
4,818,838
1,301,487
2,621,547
2,432,840
1,778,460
4,224,650
568,869

1,653,393
1,111,542
476,754
455,085
359,918
268,688
253,008
230,027
215,957
203,951
196,428
184,192
172,904
155,583
150,603
139,701
134,703
124,525
112,249
111,619

19.47%
13.58%
6.53%
25.61%
9.45%
17.11%
11.65%
7.18%
15.21%
3.79%
10.29%
8.66%
8.85%
3.23%
11.57%
5.33%
5.54%
7.00%
2.66%
19.62%

20 Biggest Immigrant Cities

67,047,667

6,710,830

10.01%
Business Review Q4 2003 19

MAP
IMMIGRATION IN THE THIRD DISTRICT
The map shows the number of immigrants as a percentage of population by postal zip code. The data correspond to the
15-year period starting in 1983. It is easy to see that immigrants tend to cluster in metropolitan areas (delimited in the
map). Many areas of the Third District are not exposed to immigration. The main areas of attraction are northern New
Jersey and Philadelphia.

increased 7 percent to 11 percent. I
have obtained similar results for other
immigrant destinations in the United
States. An immigration inflow that
amounts to 1 percent of the city’s
population is associated with increases
in housing values and rents of about 1
percent.
20 Q4 2003 Business Review

Immigration’s effects on housing markets are much more substantive than its effects on labor markets.
Remember that one explanation for
why immigration may not have an
impact on labor markets is that some
natives avoid areas where immigrants
concentrate, such as New York or Los

Angeles. Although there is no definitive consensus on how the internal
flows of native workers respond to
immigration, a National Research
Council report on immigration has
argued that “competing native workers migrate out of the areas to which
immigrants move.” Given the fact
www.phil.frb.org

that immigration doesn’t affect wages,
higher housing rents can help explain
why certain areas might become less
attractive to natives.
In the short run, the results
have implications for the distribution
of real income through the housing
market. Homeowners stand to gain
from immigration while renters
experience slightly higher prices.
But there are reasons to think that
these effects may disappear in the
long run. Remember the idea of an
economy as an interconnected system
of cities. When a city becomes more
expensive, some people will find it
less attractive to live there. In time,
immigrants become natives in terms of
tastes and motivations. Thus, in time,
some natives and immigrants can be
expected to leave immigrant areas for
less expensive areas. Housing demand
will decrease in immigrant cities and
increase in the rest of the country.
Since supply is highly elastic at the
national level, the long-run impact of
immigration on national housing prices
may be relatively small.
Some people have argued
that immigration can help revitalize
rundown neighborhoods, especially
in declining cities. Joe Gyourko and
I have demonstrated a clear link
between housing prices, building costs,
and housing reinvestment (investment
in housing renovation, additions, and
maintenance). A house with a market
value below what it would cost to
build a unit with similar characteristics is not a good investment: the cost
of replacing parts of the house that
deteriorate over time is greater than
the market value of what is replaced.
We would expect landlords (and home
owners) not to invest much in these
units. Immigration pushes up demand
and prices in rundown areas. If house
values go from being below to being
above replacement costs, we should
expect major revitalization. In other

www.phil.frb.org

cases (in which there are price hikes
but units are above or below construction costs both before and after
immigration), changes in renovation
expenditures will be relatively small.
Immigration needs to be associated
with higher prices in a neighborhood

a singularly good deal for Americans,
since about 35 percent of immigrants
emigrate back to their countries of
origin after some time in the U.S. and
never claim the benefits.6
But are immigrants net
contributors to the total tax system,

Social scientists have studied whether, on
average, natives are subsidizing or being
subsidized by immigrants through the federal,
state, and local tax systems.

in order to bring revitalization. But
higher prices are a necessary, not sufficient, condition for revitalization.
NONMARKET IMPACT OF
IMMIGRATION
Immigration has many other
economic and social impacts that don’t
involve markets. We will consider two
of these issues: taxes and crime.
Taxes. Immigrants come
to the United States in search of a
better life, but they can avoid neither
death nor taxes here. Indeed, legal
immigrants pay federal, state, and
local taxes. Immigrant families also
enjoy some of the benefits of public
services and receive transfer payments.
Social scientists have studied whether,
on average, natives are subsidizing
or being subsidized by immigrants
through the federal, state, and local
tax systems.
Ronald Lee and Timothy
Miller, two demographers at the
University of California at Berkeley,
concluded that immigrants are net
contributors to the federal tax system. New immigrants have relatively
high labor participation rates and pay
federal income and social security
taxes. The taxation of immigrants
through the social security system is

including state and local taxes as well
as federal taxes? The National Research Council found a small negative
contribution (that is, native taxpayers
subsidizing immigrants) in the case of
New Jersey and a substantial deficit
in California, once local and state
taxes are taken into account. Since
New Jersey and California are among
the states with a higher proportion
of immigration, immigrant families
in these states are among the major
beneficiaries of the school system and
other local public spending programs.
The results point to the fact that the
net contribution of immigrants is very
sensitive to local and state policies.
Indeed, in the same study,
the National Research Council found
the fiscal benefits of immigrants
for the average U.S. taxpayer to be
positive, taking all federal, state, and
local taxes and outlays into account.
How can we reconcile this fact with
the findings from New Jersey and
California? Again, immigration has a
mild distributive impact. In states with
a major number of immigrants and
generous spending policies, immigrants
For more on social security and immigration,
see the article by Alan Gustman and Thomas
Steinmeier.
6

Business Review Q4 2003 21

receive more than they contribute in
taxes. In other states, taxpayers enjoy
their share of the positive contribution
of immigrants to the federal budget
without requiring major additional
expenditures. These two scenarios
average out as a positive surplus for the
typical native U.S. taxpayer.
An issue that has captured
the attention of many researchers is
participation in welfare programs.
Economists Michael Fix, Jeffrey Passel, and Wendy Zimmermann, at the
Urban Institute in Washington, D.C.,
summarized the main facts of the early
1990s. Immigrants used welfare slightly
more than natives (6.6 percent versus
4.9 percent). However, welfare use was
disproportionately concentrated among
refugees and elderly immigrants. Nonrefugee, working-age immigrants had
welfare participation rates similar to
those of natives. In any case, changes
in federal assistance programs in the
late 1990s made it more difficult for
immigrants to access such programs.
Crime. Economists have only
recently started to examine the impact
of immigration on social interactions.
Clearly, these interactions are important in assessing immigration’s general
impact.
Economists Kristin Butcher
and Anne Morrison Piehl have studied
one of the most controversial topics
in this area: the relationship between
immigration and crime. Their results
are quite unexpected. They found
that the incarceration rate of male

22 Q4 2003 Business Review

immigrants was about two-thirds that
of natives. The fact that immigrants
tend to be incarcerated less often than
natives (and presumably to commit less
crimes) is even more surprising when
one considers they have, on average,
less education and earn lower wages.7
Butcher and Piehl also found that the
longer the time a foreign-born individual had spent in the United States,
the closer his probability of incarceration is to that of natives. These authors
argued that “this suggests that immigrants may assimilate to the (higher)
criminal propensities of natives.”
CONCLUSION
Immigration has been at the
center of many policy debates over
the past two centuries. Unfortunately,
the discussion has not always revolved
around the existing evidence. I have
argued that immigration provides
overall economic gains to a country.
Indeed, the U.S. experience as an
immigrants’ country is one of phenomenal economic growth.
However, there are winners
and losers in the short run. The trend
toward a relatively more unskilled immigrant population has been associated with mildly slower growth in the
wages of low-skilled individuals. This
effect is hard to measure, but it seems
These results may be explained by the threat of
deportation, but more research in the U.S. and
other countries will help us learn more about
this topic.
7

to be small. I have also argued that
immigration seems to have no sizable
impact on employment or unemployment in the United States.
Immigration has a positive
impact on housing prices and rents
in cities that attract the foreign-born.
This benefits existing homeowners and
landlords but makes these cities less
attractive to renters and prospective
native in-migrants. In the long run,
these effects are bound to dissipate as
immigrants and their offspring become
Americans and leave the traditional
port-of-entry cities.
The average U.S. taxpayer
benefits from immigrants’ contributions to the tax system, taking all federal, state, and local taxes and outlays
into account. But the impact is mild,
and the average distribution of income
through the tax system is not uniform.
Immigrants’ federal tax contributions
result in benefits to natives in most
states with low immigration levels. But
states with high immigration levels
have higher expenditures associated
with the increased burden on public
services.
The distributive consequences of recent immigration inflows cannot be ignored, although which mix of
distributive or immigration policies is
better for dealing with them is a matter
of opinion.
Finally, I have discussed that,
in the United States, there is evidence
that immigrants have lower propensities to commit crimes than natives. BR

www.phil.frb.org

REFERENCES
Bauer, Thomas K., Magnus Lofstrom,
and Klaus F. Zimmermann. “Immigration
Policy, Assimilation of Immigrants and
Natives’ Sentiments Towards Immigrants:
Evidence from 12 OECD Countries,” IZA
Discussion Paper No.187, August 2000.
Borjas, George. “The Economics of
Immigration,” Journal of Economic
Literature, 32, December 1994,
pp.1667-1717.
Borjas, George J. “The Economics of
Immigration,” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 9, 2, Spring 1995, pp. 3-22.
Borjas, George J. “Does Immigration
Grease the Wheels of the Labor Market?”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1,
(2001): 69-119.
Borjas, George J. “The Labor Demand
Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining
the Impact of Immigration on the Labor
Market,” mimeo, Harvard University,
November 2002.
http://icg.harvard.edu/~ec2390d/Papers/
February_5_2003_George_Borjas_Immigration_And_Labor_Market.pdf

Borjas, George J., Richard B. Freeman,
and Lawrence F.Katz. “Searching for
the Effect of Immigration on the Labor
Market,” American Economic Review, 86, 2,
May 1996.

Card, David. “Immigrant Inflows, Native
Outflows, and the Local Market Impacts
of Higher Immigration,” Journal of Labor
Economics, 19, 1, 2001, pp. 22-64.
Chatterjee, Satyajit. “How Important Are
Agglomeration Economies for the Spatial
Concentration of Employment?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review, Third Quarter, 2003.
Fairlie, Robert W., and Bruce D. Meyer.
“The Effect of Immigration on Native
Self-Employment,” Journal of Labor
Economics, 2002.
Fairlie, Robert W., and Bruce D. Meyer.
“Does Immigration Hurt AfricanAmerican Self-Employment?” in Daniel S.
Hamermesh and Frank D. Bean, eds, Help
or Hindrance? The Economic Implications
of Immigration for African-Americans. New
York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1998.
Fix, Michael, Jeffrey Passel, and Wendy
Zimmermann. “The Use of SSI and Other
Welfare Programs by Immigrants,”
testimony before the House of
Representatives’ Ways and Means
Committee, May 23, 1996.
Gustman, Alan L., and Thomas L.
Steinmeier. “Social Security Benefits of
Immigrants and U.S. Born,” in George
Borjas, ed., Issues in the Economics of
Immigration. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press, 2000.

Gyourko, Joseph, and Albert Saiz. “Urban
Decline and Housing Reinvestment:
The Role of Construction Costs and the
Supply Side,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Working Paper 03-9 (May
2003).
Lee, Ronald, and Timothy Miller. “Immigration, Social Security, and Broader
Fiscal Impacts” American Economic Review:
Papers and Proceedings, 90, 2, 2000.
National Research Council. The New
Americans: Economic, Demographic, and
Fiscal Effects of Immigration. National
Academy Press. Washington, D.C., 1997.
Saiz, Albert. “Immigration and Housing
Rents in American Cities,” mimeo,
Harvard University. January 2002.
Saiz, Albert. “Room in the Kitchen for
the Melting Pot: Immigration and Rental
Prices,” Review of Economics and Statistics,
August-November 2003.
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Matthew
Slaughter. “Labor Market Competition and
Individual Preferences Over Immigration
Policy,” Review of Economics and Statistics,
83, 1, February 2001, pp.133-45.
Winter-Ebmer, Rudolf, and Josef
Zweimuller. “Do Immigrants Displace
Young Native Workers: The Austrian
Experience,” Journal of Population
Economics, 12, 2, 1999.

Butcher, Kristin F., and Anne Morrison
Piehl. “Recent Immigrants: Unexpected
Implications for Crime and Incarceration,”
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 51, 4,
1998, pp. 654-79.

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q4 2003 23

Taking the Measure of Manufacturing
BY TIMOTHY SCHILLER & MICHAEL TREBING

D

espite manufacturing’s decline as a
share of the U.S. economy, it is still a
significant sector, and an increasing number
of surveys monitor its movements. Why this
continuing strong interest in manufacturing? Because it
is more cyclically sensitive than the total economy, the
manufacturing sector can serve as an indicator of cyclical
fluctuations as they develop. In this article, Tim Schiller
and Mike Trebing outline several of the most important
surveys and indexes that track manufacturing, describe
their similarities and differences, and discuss their
usefulness in providing timely and accurate data on the
sector.

Why the continued strong
interest in manufacturing? Manufacturing remains an important industry, and because it is more cyclically
sensitive than the total economy, the
manufacturing sector can serve as an
indicator of cyclical fluctuations as
they develop.1
Several measures have been
developed to monitor conditions in
the manufacturing sector. One of
the broadest and oldest series is the
Federal Reserve System’s national
Industrial Production Index, which
has sub-indexes for manufacturing,
mining, and utilities. Because of the
cyclical sensitivity of these sectors,
this monthly index is included as a
component of the index of coincident
indicators of the overall economy.
Other monthly measures of

The cyclical sensitivity of manufacturing is
evident in an analysis of the average decline
during recessions. The average decline in
gross domestic product (GDP) during the
nine recessions in the past 50 years was 1.7
percent; the average decline in manufacturing
as measured by the Industrial Production Index
was 7 percent. GDP itself can be separated into
the production of goods excluding structures
and all other production. The average decline in
the goods component, of which approximately
75 percent is manufacturing, was 4.7 percent
during recessions; the average decline in the
production of services and structures was 0.1
percent.
1

The decline in the manufacturing sector as a share of the U.S.
economy in the last half of the 20th
century has been one of the most notable changes in the nation’s economic
structure. In nominal terms (that is,
in current dollars), manufacturing’s
share of the total output of the U.S.
economy is only about half of what it
was in 1950. Manufacturing employ-

Tim Schiller is a
senior economic
analyst in the
Research Department of the
Philadelphia Fed.

24 Q4 2003 Business Review

ment has also declined as a share
of total employment. These trends
have been even stronger in the Third
Federal Reserve District — Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Delaware — than
in the nation. Despite these trends,
manufacturing is still a significant part
of the U.S. economy, and it remains
a key indicator of changes in national
and regional economic conditions.
Thus, even while manufacturing’s
share of total output has declined, it
continues to be closely monitored and
analyzed. Data collection devoted to
monitoring manufacturing has not
declined; in fact, it has increased, and
the manufacturing sector receives as
much attention now, both nationally
and regionally, as it ever has.

Michael Trebing is
a senior economic
analyst in the Research Department
of the Philadelphia
Fed.

www.phil.frb.org

manufacturing come from the Census
Bureau, which compiles statistics on
manufacturers’ orders, shipments, and
inventories. Among private organizations, the Institute for Supply Management publishes a monthly survey of
changes in manufacturing activity that
receives wide attention. There are also
regional surveys and indexes of manufacturing, such as the Philadelphia
Fed’s Business Outlook Survey.
LONG-RUN TRENDS
IN MANUFACTURING
Before we look at some of the
short-run measures of manufacturing,
a brief review of the long-run trends in
the sector will provide some context.
From 1950 to 2000 (the last full year
before the 2001 recession), manufacturing’s share of current-dollar GDP
fell from 29 percent to 15 percent.
Nevertheless, by this measure, manufacturing is still the third largest of the
industry classifications into which the
economy is usually divided for analytical purposes (Table 1).2 From 1950 to
2000, the number of manufacturing
jobs in the nation increased by around
3 million, a 21 percent gain. Meanwhile, total nonagricultural employment increased by approximately 87

million jobs, nearly a 200 percent gain.
As a result, manufacturing’s share of
nonagricultural employment declined
by more than half, from 34 percent to
14 percent.3 Still, manufacturing is the
fourth largest industry division by employment (Table 2).4 (There have also
been shifts in the regional distribution
of manufacturing within the U.S. For
a discussion of how they have affected
the Third District’s region, see Manufacturing in the Region.)
The decline in manufacturing’s share of national nonagricultural
employment and nominal GDP can be
attributed to several developments. In
part, this decline in share represents
stronger-than-average growth in pro-

ductivity in this sector of the economy.
This growth in productivity made it
possible for real output in manufacturing (the value of output adjusted for
inflation) to expand while the number
of workers required to produce the
expanded output decreased.5 Another
factor in manufacturing’s declining
share of employment and output is
the fact that a greater portion of the
U.S. economy is now devoted to the
consumption of services.6 And even if
goods had retained their share of U.S.
consumption, the share of domestically
produced goods would have declined
because imports now make up a greater portion of goods consumed in the
U.S. than they did in the past.7
Also contributing to the

These are the industry divisions of the
Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
system. Beginning in 2004, GDP by industry
will be organized using the North American
Industry Classification System (NAICS).

5

2

From 1950 to 2000 manufacturing output per
hour increased 3.8 times while output per hour
in the total nonfarm business sector increased
2.7 times.
In 1950 manufactured goods made up 63
percent of personal consumption expenditures.
By 2000, manufactured goods accounted
for just 41 percent of personal consumption
expenditures.
6

Agricultural employment is not measured in
the same way as employment in other sectors,
so it is not included in the employment
comparisons used here.
3

Employment data for 2000 (the most recent
year in the table) are available in NAICS, but
we use SIC for historical comparisons and to
be consistent with the GDP data, which will
use SIC until 2004.
4

In 1950, U.S. exports of manufactured goods
exceeded imports. By 2000, the balance of
trade in manufactured goods was reversed, and
U.S. imports of manufactured goods exceeded
exports.
7

TABLE 1

TABLE 2

GDP Shares, Current$, Percent

National Nonagricultural
Employment Shares (Percent)

1950
Services
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Manufacturing
Government
Retail trade
Transportation and public utilities
Wholesale trade
Construction
Agriculture, forestry, and fishing
Mining

www.phil.frb.org

8.2
10.5
28.6
10.8
10.8
9.1
6.7
4.5
7.0
3.2

2000
21.5
20.1
15.5
12.4
9.0
8.2
7.1
4.7
1.4
1.4

Services
Retail trade
Government
Manufacturing
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Transportation and public utilities
Wholesale trade
Construction
Mining

1950

2000

11.9
14.9
13.3
33.7
4.2
8.9
5.9
5.2
2.0

30.7
17.7
15.7
14.0
5.8
5.3
5.3
5.1
0.4

Business Review Q4 2003 25

Manufacturing in the Region

T

he broad trends that affected the national
manufacturing sector during the last half
of the 20th century also had an impact
on manufacturing in the tri-state region
(Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Delaware).
Manufacturing has declined as a share
of both output and employment in the region. Besides the
national trends, the region has also been affected by the shift
of manufacturing away from northern and eastern areas of the
nation and toward the southern and western areas (see the
article by Ted Crone).
The shift in manufacturing within the nation has
resulted in increases in the share of manufacturing output in
the five southern and western economic regions as defined by

the Bureau of Economic Analysis and declines in the three
northern and eastern regions — New England, Mideast, Great
Lakes (see Figure).a The three states in the Third Federal
Reserve District, which are in the Mideast region, shared in this
decline.b In fact, the Mideast had the greatest relative decline
in its share of manufacturing output among all the regions.
Within the Mideast region, the relative decline in manufacturing was greater in New York than in any of the other states.

The eight BEA regions are New England, Mideast, Great Lakes,
Plains, Southeast, Southwest, Rocky Mountain, and Far West.
a

b

The Mideast region also includes New York and Maryland.

FIGURE
Shares of Manufacturing Output*

*Output is measured by total GSP for the 50 states and the District of Columbia. Regions are those defined by the Bureau of
*Economic Analysis.

26 Q4 2003 Business Review

www.phil.frb.org

Consequently, the share of the Mideast region’s manufacturing
output accounted for by Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Delaware
(as well as Maryland) rose slightly from 1977 (the first year for
which gross state product data are available) to 2000. Even
though each of the three states fared better than the Mideast
region as a whole, they each lost shares of national manufacturing output (see Table ).
As the region’s manufacturing sector has declined with
respect to national manufacturing, it has also diminished as
a part of the region’s overall economy. In Pennsylvania, New
Jersey, and Delaware, manufacturing output as a share of total
state output declined from 1977 to 2000, and the relative
decline in the three states was greater than in the nation.
Manufacturing’s share of the total GSP of all 50 states fell from
23 percent in 1977 to 16 percent in 2000.c Manufacturing’s
share of GSP in Delaware decreased from 35 to 15 percent;
in New Jersey it decreased from 27 to 14 percent; and in
Pennsylvania it decreased from 29 to 19 percent. Pennsylvania’s
economy was more manufacturing oriented than the
national economy in 1977, and it remained somewhat more
manufacturing oriented in 2000. Over the same period, New
Jersey moved from a greater concentration in manufacturing
than the nation to a lesser concentration. Delaware,
which started with a significantly greater concentration in
manufacturing, moved to a virtually equal concentration.
Employment from 1977 to 2000 shows a pattern similar to
that in the data for output. Nationally, manufacturing employment declined 6 percent. The decline was much greater in all
three Third District states. Manufacturing employment fell 31
percent in Pennsylvania, 40 percent in New Jersey, and 14 percent in Delaware. As a share of employment, manufacturing declined from 24 percent to 14 percent nationally. The decline in
manufacturing’s share of employment in each of the three states
was greater: from 30 percent to 16 percent in Pennsylvania, from
27 percent to 12 percent in New Jersey, and from 28 percent
to 14 percent in Delaware. In 2000, manufacturing retained a
greater share of employment in Pennsylvania than it did in the
nation, but the difference narrowed. Manufacturing employment fell from a greater to a lesser share in New Jersey than in
the nation. In Delaware, manufacturing’s share decreased from
above the national share to an equal share.

There is a slight difference in the methods by which national output
(GDP) and state output (GSP) are calculated, and this accounts for the
difference between manufacturing’s share of national output and its
share of the total of states’ GSP.

The trend of dispersion in manufacturing around the
country away from the traditionally heavy manufacturing
centers was also reflected to some extent within the region.
From 1977 to 2000, manufacturing employment declined in all
the metropolitan statistical areas in the three states except Lancaster. Moreover, the manufacturing jobs that remain in the region have become more dispersed. Manufacturing jobs in some
of the more populous counties in the larger metro areas are
now a smaller percentage of total manufacturing employment
in the three states. This is true for Allegheny and Philadelphia
counties in Pennsylvania; Essex and Union counties in New
Jersey; and New Castle County in Delaware. Conversely, some
of the counties in the less populous metro areas had higher
percentages of the manufacturing jobs in the tri-state area, for
example, Lancaster, York, and Centre counties in Pennsylvania;
Cumberland, Middlesex, Somerset, and Hunterdon counties
in New Jersey; and Kent County in Delaware. This dispersion
of manufacturing jobs from large metro areas to smaller ones
was part of a general shift in the shares of all types of jobs from
more densely populated to less densely populated areas (see the
article by Gerald Carlino).
Dispersion also took place within the large metro areas,
as suburban counties gained shares of manufacturing employment and central city counties lost shares. Examples include
gains in share for Bucks, Burlington, and Camden counties in
the Philadelphia metro area and Morris County in the Newark,
NJ, metro area.

TABLE
State Shares of National
Manufacturing Output*

Delaware
New Jersey
Pennsylvania

%
1977

%
2000

0.46
3.83
6.31

0.35
3.20
4.82

c

www.phil.frb.org

*Measured as a percent of the manufacturing portion of total GSP
for the nation

Business Review Q4 2003 27

decline of measured employment in
the manufacturing sector has been the
increased outsourcing of manufacturing firms’ ancillary nonproduction
functions. Workers in areas such as
accounting, marketing, and shipping
would have been counted in manufacturing employment if they were
employees of manufacturing firms. If
they are employed by accounting firms,
advertising agencies, and transportation companies — as many now are
— they are counted in service-producing employment. Similarly, a large increase in the use of temporary workers
in the manufacturing sector increased
the number of workers counted in the
services industry (where temporary
employment is counted) and decreased
the number counted in manufacturing.8 Manufacturing firms now make
greater use of service firms that provide ancillary functions, and they more
frequently turn to agencies that supply
temporary workers rather than using
their own employees for these activities. In addition, some of the decline in
measured manufacturing employment
has come about because workers had
been classified by the industry of the
firm for which they worked; now they
are classified by the type of work done
at their place of employment.9
MEASURING MONTHLY
CHANGES IN
MANUFACTURING OUTPUT
Changes in Levels. As noted
earlier, the manufacturing sector continues to be more cyclical than the
overall economy (especially the service
sectors). The cyclical variability of

The increase was especially sharp in the 1980s
and 1990s; see the article by Bill Goodman and
Reid Steadman.
8

The new NAICS classifies workers by the
type of work performed at their location. For
example, a manufacturing firm’s research facility is now classified under services instead of
manufacturing.

manufacturing has prompted efforts
to develop measures of manufacturing
that would give frequent and timely
indicators of change in activity in the
sector.
The Federal Reserve’s Industrial Production Index (IP) has evolved
from statistical efforts that began in
1919 with the goal of providing monthly measures of the physical volume of
production and trade (it does not give
dollar value) in major industries and in

The cyclical variability of manufacturing
has prompted efforts to develop measures
of manufacturing that would give frequent
and timely indicators of change in activity
in the sector.
total.10 Because it is an index number,
this measure can be used to compare
the level of activity in one period
with the level in another and to show
changes over time.
The Census Bureau publishes
other indicators of the level of manufacturing activity. These measure the
dollar value of manufacturers’ shipments, orders, and inventories. The
data series are monthly from 1958 and
include measures for many subsectors of manufacturing as well as total
manufacturing. Like the Industrial
Production Index, these series can be
used to compare the level of activity
in one period with that in another
period and to show changes over time.
For the Census measures and the
Industrial Production Index, interest
in the monthly reports focuses on the
change from the previous month as an
indication of the direction of change in
manufacturing activity.
There are few monthly data

data on manufacturing establishments and employment are included
in County Business Patterns, another
annual series available with a lag from
the Census Bureau.12
Breadth of Changes. In
addition to measuring the level of
production, there’s another way to
track changes in activity: national and
regional surveys that directly measure
the breadth of change in the manufacturing sector. These surveys often
attract interest because of their timeliness.
One of the most widely followed measures of manufacturing
activity is the index based on the
monthly survey of manufacturing firms
by the Institute for Supply Management (ISM), which was formerly the
National Association of Purchasing
Managers. The ISM’s index is still of-

For a description of the Industrial Production
Index methodology, see the publication from
the Board of Governors.

12

9

28 Q4 2003 Business Review

below the national scale on the level
of output in the manufacturing sector.
The Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
computes a monthly Texas Industrial
Production Index, similar to the national index, but most sub-national
data are annual.11 The most detailed
data are at the state level, and they are
available with a lag from the Census
Bureau’s Annual Survey of Manufactures, which includes a measure of
value added in manufacturing. Some

10

For a description of the Texas Industrial
Production Index, see the article by Franklin
Berger and William Long.
11

The lag between the reference year and publication year for these Census Bureau statistical
series is up to two years.

www.phil.frb.org

ficially called the Purchasing Managers
Index, or PMI. In its current form,
the PMI is a weighted average of five
indexes that track monthly changes in
new orders, production, employment,
supplier delivery times, and inventories
at ISM’s member firms. Firms surveyed
report whether each of these measures
of activity has increased, decreased,
or been unchanged since the previous
month.
Surveys of the direction of
change have several advantages compared with other economic statistics.
They are usually less intrusive and
easier for firms to respond to, since
they do not require specific numbers
but only an indication of an increase,
decrease, or no change. This contributes to a better response rate among
firms surveyed and quicker compilation of results compared with more
detailed survey questions. Diffusion
indexes are derived from the difference between the percentage of survey
respondents indicating an increase in
some measure of activity and the percentage of survey respondents indicating a decrease in that measure. Over
time, diffusion indexes reflect how
changes in economic conditions actually develop, as the spread between the
percentage of firms reporting increases
and decreases widens.
According to Geoffrey
Moore, former director of the Center for International Business Cycle
Research, “One of the fundamental
features of our economic system is that
economic movements spread from one
firm to another, from one industry to
another, from one region to another,
and from one economic process to
another. Moreover, these spreading
movements cumulate over time. This
being so, it is desirable to have measures showing how this spreading and
cumulation goes on. A diffusion index
is just such a measure.”
By measuring the diffusion, or

www.phil.frb.org

spreading, of survey responses (toward
one extreme or another of the index’s
range), diffusion indexes reflect the
way changes in the pace of economic
activity are propagated across firms.
For example, in an economic expansion, the first effects are usually felt by
just a few firms. When they experience a pickup in business, they step
up production to meet the stronger
demand. They buy more raw materials
and machinery, hire more labor, and so
forth. This process repeats itself at the
firms that supply materials to the first
few firms, and the higher employment
leads to higher incomes and spending,
which gives a boost to other firms and

Philadelphia, Kansas City, New York,
and Richmond conduct manufacturing
surveys.13 Diffusion indexes are
compiled from these surveys, as
they are from the ISM’s survey. (See
Constructing Diffusion Indexes for a
description of the different ways in
which the diffusion indexes discussed
here are calculated.)
EVALUATING THE
INDICATORS OF MONTHLY
CHANGE FROM NATIONAL
AND REGIONAL SURVEYS
While the Federal Reserve
Board’s index of industrial production
tells us a great deal about trends

By measuring the diffusion, or spreading, of
survey responses, diffusion indexes reflect the
way changes in the pace of economic activity
are propagated across firms.
industries. As the process continues,
the expansion spreads through the
economy. As the expansion spreads,
statistical measures of the level of
output begin to increase, confirming
in detail the process first reflected by
the increase in diffusion indexes that
signaled the beginning and spreading
of the expansion.
In addition to national
measures of changes in manufacturing
activity, there are regional surveys.
Local associations of the ISM produce
their own reports that include
diffusion indexes. Currently, 13 local
associations produce reports, although
not all of them are monthly. The local
associations that conduct surveys are
Arizona, Austin, Buffalo, California,
Chicago, Cleveland, Dallas, Georgia,
Houston, New York, Northwest Ohio,
Pittsburgh, and Western Washington.
Within the Federal Reserve System,
the Federal Reserve Banks of

in the manufacturing sector and
about the magnitude of the monthly
changes in production, market
participants rely on surveys to get an
even earlier indication of changes
in the sector. Both the PMI and the
index constructed by Chicago’s local
association of the ISM, which is called
the Business Barometer Index, have
a long history, and they are available
near the beginning of each month.14

Monthly releases are available on the
Federal Reserve Banks’ web sites: Richmond,
www.rich.frb.org/research/surveys/; Kansas
City, www.kc.frb.org/mfgsurv/mfgmain.htm;
New York, www.newyorkfed.org/rmaghome/
regional/mfg_survey/index.html; Philadelphia,
www.phil.frb.org/econ/bos/. More details on the
surveys conducted by Philadelphia, Richmond,
and Kansas City are available in the article
by Michael Trebing, the article by Christine
Chmura, and the one by Tim Smith.
13

Historical data are available for the PMI from
1931 and for the Chicago Purchasing Managers
index from 1948.
14

Business Review Q4 2003 29

Both are used extensively to forecast
changes in the IP index, which is
published later in the month. Several
Federal Reserve Bank manufacturing
surveys are also available before the
IP index, and the Philadelphia Fed’s
Business Outlook Survey (BOS) is the
oldest of these.
Table 3 presents the correlations between four measures of monthly change in manufacturing activity:
monthly changes in the manufacturing
component of the industrial production index (IP-M), the Philadelphia
Fed’s general activity index, the PMI,
and the Chicago Purchasing Managers Business Barometer Index. The
correlations cover the 36-year period
corresponding to the history of the
Philadelphia Fed’s Business Outlook
Survey. Similar diffusion measures
constructed at the Kansas City, New
York, and Richmond Federal Reserve
Banks have a much shorter history and
thus are not included in the table.15
The two purchasing manager surveys (the PMI and Chicago Business
Barometer Index) are highly correlated
with each other, and both are correlated with monthly changes in the
IP-M. In addition, the correlation
of the Philadelphia Fed’s Business
Outlook Survey index with the IP-M is
comparable to the correlation between
the IP-M and the PMI.

The regional measures for the Richmond Fed
shipments index and the Kansas City production index have the lowest correlation with the
monthly change in the IP-M (0.42 for Richmond and 0.43 for Kansas City). The broadest
measure in the Richmond Fed’s survey is manufacturing shipments, and seasonally adjusted
data are available from November 1993. Kansas
City’s index is not available seasonally adjusted
because of its short history (available only since
July 2001), which may explain its lower correlation to the national manufacturing measures.
The New York Fed’s new Empire State Index is
highly correlated with the IP-M (0.66), but its
limited history (since July 2001) may limit its
usefulness as a forecasting tool.
15

30 Q4 2003 Business Review

Constructing Diffusion Indexes

T

he principle of the diffusion index is the same for all of the
diffusion indexes discussed in this article, but their arithmetic
computation varies. Consequently, the base or “no change”
level and the minimum and maximum values that the indexes
can take are different. The Philadelphia Fed’s Business Outlook Survey consists of a number of questions about business processes such as
new orders, shipments, employment, and workweek among manufacturing firms
in the Third Federal Reserve District. Diffusion indexes are calculated for each
question in the survey. To gauge how widespread changes in an indicator are
among firms, we calculate the percentages of firms reporting increases, decreases, and no change, and we subtract the percentage decrease from the percentage increase. The resulting diffusion index can vary from +100, when all firms
report an increase, to –100, when all firms report a decrease. The midpoint
is 0, when the percentage of firms reporting increases equals the percentage
reporting decreases. Firms in the survey have never been unanimous, so the
diffusion index has taken on a value between –100 and +100. The indexes
computed by other Federal Reserve Banks are similar. The closer the index is
to either of these two extremes, the more diffuse, or widespread, is the change
(either decrease or increase) in the indicator reported.
The Institute of Supply Management’s Purchasing Managers Index
(PMI) is computed differently. Instead of subtracting the percentage decrease
from the percentage increase, the PMI adds one-half of the percentage of firms
reporting no change to the percentage reporting an increase to form the index.
As a result, the PMI can vary from 0 to 100, with 50 being the midpoint.
Another difference among the surveys is that the overall index in the
Philadelphia Fed’s Business Outlook Survey is derived from a separate question
that measures manufacturers’ assessments of overall business conditions; in
the other surveys, the overall index is a composite of the indexes calculated
for specific questions.
FORECASTING INDUSTRIAL
PRODUCTION WITH
MANUFACTURING SURVEYS
The diffusion indexes from
the major surveys are positively correlated with changes in IP-M, but how
much new information do they provide
about manufacturing? The availability of diffusion indexes ahead of the
release of the industrial production
indexes provides a test of their usefulness in forecasting the current month’s
change in the manufacturing component of the IP. The ISM releases its
data on the first business day of each
month covering the previous month.

In addition to the composite index
for manufacturing (PMI), the ISM
produces 10 sub-indexes, including one
for production. Since the IP indexes
are not released until mid-month, the
information contained in the ISM
indexes provides forecasters with a way
to predict the IP-M.
The statistical relationship
between the PMI and the IP-M is
well established, which explains the
attention it receives from financial
analysts.16 Table 4 presents statistical
See the articles by Mark Rogers; Ethan Harris; and Evan Koenig.
16

www.phil.frb.org

TABLE 3
Correlation Coefficients for Key Measures of Monthly Change
in Manufacturing
Monthly Change
in Manufacturing
Component of
Industrial Production
Index (IP-M)*
Monthly Change in Manufacturing
Component of Industrial Production
Index (IP-M)*

Philadelphia Fed
Business Outlook
Survey, General
Activity Index

1.0

Philadelphia Fed Business Outlook
Survey, General Activity Index

ISM Composite
Index (PMI)

Chicago Purchasing
Managers Business
Barometer Index

0.57

0.54

0.48

1.0

0.74

0.67

1.0

0.92

ISM Composite Index (PMI)
Chicago Purchasing Managers
Business Barometer Index

1.0

NOTES: Sample period is from May 1968 to June 2003, the period for which data are available for the Business Outlook Survey.
* Monthly change is calculated as the log difference in the index multiplied by 100, which is approximately
equal to percent change.

TABLE 4
Forecasting Monthly Change in the U.S. Manufacturing
Production Index (IP-M)
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.

Explanatory Variables:
Current Month’s Purchasing Managers Composite Index (PMI)
Current Month’s Purchasing Managers Production Index
12 lagged values of percent change in IP-M
12 lagged values of percent change in IP-M plus current month’s PMI
(composite index)
12 lagged values of percent change in IP-M plus current month’s ISM
production index
Percent change in manufacturing hours (current and lagged 3 months)
Percent change in manufacturing hours, lagged IP-M,
plus current month’s PMI (composite index)
Percent change in manufacturing hours, lagged IP-M,
plus current month’s ISM Production Index

R2
0.29
0.36
0.21

Coefficient on Diffusion Index*
0.064 (13.2)
0.065 (15.2)

0.32

0.065 (8.2)

0.36
0.60

0.068 (9.8)
—

0.61

0.023 (3.7)

0.63

0.035 (6.0)

NOTES: Regressions are based on the estimation period of 1969 to 2003. Monthly change is calculated as the log difference
multiplied by 100, which is approximately equal to percent change.
* Absolute values of t-statistics are shown in parenthesis. The t-statistic tests the hypothesis that the diffusion index
coefficient is significantly different from zero. In all of the regressions the diffusion index is significant at less than
the 0.01 level, meaning there is less than a 1 percent probability that the diffusion index coefficient is equal to zero.
www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q4 2003 31

results of various regression models to
estimate how well the indexes from
the ISM survey predict the monthly
change in the production index for
manufacturing. Since the ISM produces both a composite diffusion index
and a production index, results using
each are shown in the table.17 The
regressions are estimated using data
from 1969 through June 2003. That
time period was chosen to correspond
to availability of data for the Business
Outlook Survey so that a comparison of forecast performance could be
made. In each of the models shown,
the dependent variable (the variable
to be forecast) is the monthly percent
change in the Industrial Production
Index for manufacturing (IP-M). The
explanatory variables include indexes from the ISM survey and other
information available to the market at
various times prior to the release of the
Industrial Production Index.
The results demonstrate that,
by themselves, the diffusion indexes
from the ISM survey “explain” 29 to
36 percent of the month-to-month
variation in the monthly changes in
the IP-M (see rows 1 and 2 of Table
4).18 The results also indicate that the
PMI and the production index from
the survey add information, even when
the history of the IP-M itself is in the
regressions. (Rows 3, 4, and 5 include

The PMI is a composite index based on the
seasonally adjusted diffusion indexes of five
separate indicators with the following weights:
new orders, 30 percent; production, 25 percent;
employment, 20 percent; supplier deliveries, 15
percent; and inventories, 10 percent.
17

The t-statistics indicate that the PMI diffusion index is statistically significant in the
forecast of the IP-M, which is released about
two weeks after the PMI. In all of the regressions, the coefficient on the diffusion index
is significantly different from zero at less than
the 0.01 level, meaning there is a less than 1
percent probability that the diffusion index
coefficient is equal to zero.
18

32 Q4 2003 Business Review

12 lagged values of the change in the
IP-M as explanatory variables.)
Near the beginning of the
month (following the release of the
PMI and the production index from
the ISM survey, but ahead of the
release of the IP-M), data on manufacturing employment and work hours
also become available to the market.
Table 4 also shows that available
employment and average workweek

on the third Thursday of the reference month for the IP-M, it is available almost a month earlier than the
release of the IP-M and two to three
weeks earlier than the PMI. Table 5
summarizes the statistical relationship between the Philadelphia Fed’s
general activity diffusion index and the
monthly percent change in the IP-M
for the months estimated over 1969 to
2003.

Although the PMI and accompanying indexes
add information to a forecast for the IP-M, the
availability of the Philadelphia Fed’s Business
Outlook Survey indexes makes it possible to
create a forecast even sooner.
statistics also forecast monthly IP-M.
By creating a total manufacturing
work-hour statistic (average hours multiplied by manufacturing employment),
we can “explain” about 60 percent of
the month-to-month variation in the
IP-M (row 6). But even when we use
this additional information on hours
worked, the PMI and the production
index from the same survey remain
significant in explaining the variation
in IP-M (rows 7 and 8). Table 4 shows
that the diffusion indexes by themselves are useful for predicting changes
in manufacturing production. It also
shows that when the diffusion indexes
are combined with other available
information, they can increase the accuracy of a forecast of changes in the
IP-M.
Although the PMI and
accompanying indexes add information to a forecast for the IP-M, the
availability of the Philadelphia Fed’s
Business Outlook Survey indexes
makes it possible to create a forecast
even sooner. Since the BOS is released

Table 5 (row 1) shows that
the simple model using the general
activity index from the Business Outlook Survey explains approximately
the same percentage of variation in
the change in the IP-M as the national Purchasing Managers Index.19
Table 5, row 2 also includes a model
using a constructed BOS “weighted
index” based on the same weights the
PMI uses for its five sub-indexes. (We
substituted the BOS shipments index
for the production index, since the
BOS does not include a production
index.) The R2 for that model (0.26)
was lower than that for the general
activity index (0.33), so weighting the
individual questions from the BOS

The relative size of the coefficients (0.024 for
the BOS and 0.064 for the PMI) is to be expected because of differences in methods used
for constructing indexes. The BOS diffusion
ranges from -100 to +100 while the PMI ranges
from 0 to +100; so the equivalent indexes are
linear transformations of each other.
19

www.phil.frb.org

TABLE 5
Forecasting Monthly Change in the U.S. Manufacturing
Production Index (IP-M) Using the Business Outlook Survey (BOS)
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.

Explanatory Variables:
Current month’s Business Outlook Survey general activity index
Current month’s Business Outlook Survey weighted index**
12 lagged values of percent change in IP-M
12 lagged values of percent change in IP-M
plus current month’s BOS general activity index
12 lagged values of change in IP-M plus current month’s
BOS weighted index
Percent change in manufacturing hours (current and lagged 3 months)
Percent change in manufacturing hours, lagged IP-M, plus
current month’s BOS general activity index
Percent change in manufacturing hours, lagged IP-M,
plus current month’s BOS weighted index

NOTES:

R2
0.33
0.26
0.21

Coefficient on Diffusion Index*
0.024 (14.2)
0.038 (12.2)
—

0.34

0.021 (8.9)

0.30
0.60

0.032 (7.2)
—

0.63

0.012 (6.3)

0.62

0.016 (4.9)

Regressions are based on the estimation period of 1969 to 2003.
The t-statistic tests the hypothesis that the diffusion index coefficient is significantly different from zero. In all of the
regressions, the diffusion index is significant at less than the 0.01 level, meaning there is less than a 1 percent probability
that the diffusion index coefficient is equal to zero.
Monthly change is calculated as the log difference multiplied by 100, which is approximately equal to percent change.
** Absolute values of t-statistics are in parenthesis.
** Since the PMI is a weighted index of five sub-indexes, the BOS weighted index was constructed using the same
weights as the PMI, but we substituted the BOS shipments index for the production index, since the BOS does not
include a production index.

does not improve its ability to predict.
When the recent history of the IP-M
and information on employment and
hours are used in the regression model,
the general activity diffusion index retains its significance and matches the
PMI in its ability to forecast changes in
the manufacturing component of the
Industrial Production Index (rows 4, 5,
7, and 8).
The Appendix evaluates the
usefulness of the remaining Business
Outlook Survey diffusion indexes in
forecasting other measures of manufacturing activity, such as the change
in new orders, shipments, and employment.
Although the models’ ability
to track changes in the IP-M within
the sample period in which the models

www.phil.frb.org

are estimated is important, the real
test of the models’ performance is
their ability to forecast change in
production outside that sample period.
An evaluation of the out-of-sample
performance of the PMI and the diffusion index from the Philadelphia Fed
over the past several years can best be
seen in the figure. The model forecasts
are based on the historical relationships between IP-M and the diffusion
indexes through December 2000 (Figure). That is, the monthly prediction
after that time is based on the models
estimated from the available diffusion
indexes up to that time. The chart
displays the actual monthly change in
the IP-M and its predicted value based
on the simple models using the PMI
and the diffusion index from the Phila-

delphia survey as the sole explanatory
variables. While neither of the models
precisely captures the highly volatile
month-to-month changes in the IP-M,
the forecasts from the models track
the broader accelerations and decelerations in the IP-M over several months.
A closer examination of the forecast
errors shows that, on average, the BOS
model outperforms the PMI model
for the period January 2001 to June
2003 (Table 6). This period covers the
recent downturn in the manufacturing sector as well as the early stages of
recovery. The standard measures of
forecast performance — the root mean
squared error and mean absolute error
— are slightly smaller for the model
using the BOS than for the model using the PMI.
Business Review Q4 2003 33

SUMMARY
Although manufacturing has
experienced rapid technological and
managerial advances and continues
to do so, it remains an important
sector of the economy that is subject
to significant cyclical movements.
Therefore, business analysts and
economic policymakers follow the
sector closely. They rely on frequently
published measures of activity, such as
monthly reports and surveys, to track
changes in this sector.
Qualitative surveys, such as
the one conducted by the Institute
for Supply Management, are intended
to give an early read on changing
conditions. The Institute’s Purchasing
Managers Index provides timely
information on the manufacturing
sector nationally. Regional surveys
of manufacturing can provide even
earlier indications about changes in
the national manufacturing sector,
in addition to the information they
provide about conditions in their
own regions’ manufacturing sectors.
The Philadelphia Fed’s Business
Outlook Survey is the oldest of the
regional surveys produced by the
Federal Reserve Banks. Moreover,
the Philadelphia index comes out
much earlier than the PMI, and it
is as accurate as national surveys in
predicting the monthly change in the
U.S. Industrial Production Index for
manufacturing. BR

34 Q4 2003 Business Review

TABLE 6
Forecast Prediction Performance for the Monthly
Changes in the IP-M (BOS vs. PMI Model)
Model
Business Outlook Survey Diffusion Index
PMI

RMSE
0.318
0.378

MAE
0.215
0.268

NOTES: Estimation period was January 1969 to December 2000. Out-of-sample forecast
errors are based on January 2001 to June 2003.
RMSE is root mean squared error and MAE is mean absolute error.
Regressions are for monthly percent change in Industrial Production Index for
manufacturing and the explanatory variables are the subject diffusion
indexes. Monthly change is calculated as the log difference multiplied by 100,
which is approximately equal to percent change.

FIGURE
Model Forecasts and Actual Change in IP-M
(Out-of-Sample Forecast for 2001:01 to 2003:06)

www.phil.frb.org

REFERENCES
Berger, Franklin D., and William T. Long
III. “The Texas Industrial Production
Index,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Economic Review, November 1989,
pp. 21-36.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System. Industrial Production, 1986.
Carlino, Gerald A. “From Centralization to
Deconcentration: People and Jobs Spread
Out,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review, November/December
2000, pp. 15-27.
Chmura, Christine. “New Survey Monitors
District Manufacturing Activity,” Cross
Sections, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Winter 1987/88.
Crone, Theodore M. “Where Have All
the Factory Jobs Gone—and Why?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review, May/June 1997, pp. 1-16.

www.phil.frb.org

Getz, Patricia, and Mark G. Ulmer.
“Diffusion Indexes: A Barometer of the
Economy,” Monthly Labor Review, April
1990, 12-21.
Goodman, Bill, and Reid Steadman. “Services: Business Demand Rivals Consumer
Demand in Driving Job Growth,” Monthly
Labor Review, April 2002, pp. 3-16.
Harris, Ethan S. “Tracking the Economy
with the Purchasing Managers Index,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly
Review, October 1995.
Institute for Supply Management. Manufacturing Report on Business Information Kit
Koenig, Evan F. “Using the Purchasing
Managers Index to Assess the Economy’s
Strength and the Likely Direction of
Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas Policy Review, 1, 6, 2002.

Moore, Geoffrey H. “Diffusion Indexes,
Rates of Change, and Forecasting,” in Business Cycle Indicators, Volume I. Princeton:
National Bureau of Economic Research,
1961, pp. 282-93.
Rogers, R. Mark, “Forecasting Industrial
Production: Purchasing Managers’ Versus
Production-Worker Hours Data,” Economic
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
January/February 1992.
Smith, Tim R. “Tenth District Survey of
Manufacturers,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City Economic Review, Fourth
Quarter 1995.
Trebing, Michael E. “What’s Happening in
Manufacturing: ‘Survey Says…’” Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review, September/October 1998.

Business Review Q4 2003 35

APPENDIX
Comparing the BOS Results with National and Regional
Manufacturing Data
Although the main goal of the
Philadelphia Fed’s Business Outlook
Survey is to obtain meaningful and
timely information about the pace of
growth of the Third Federal Reserve
District’s manufacturing sector, the
evidence suggests that it can be useful
in gauging national manufacturing
activity as well. To determine the
usefulness of the diffusion indexes
from the survey’s questions on specific
measures of manufacturing activity, we

again use the common technique of regression analysis.
The table shows the results of 12
regression models in which the current
month’s diffusion indexes alone are used
to predict the change in the corresponding regional or national data. The BOS
indexes are most successful at forecasting
total industrial production, manufacturing
production, regional and national manufacturing employment, manufacturing
inventories, delivery times, and producer

prices. The individual BOS indexes
have very weak explanatory power (a
low R 2 statistic) for national shipments,
new orders, manufacturing workweek,
and unfilled orders. The only series
for which the BOS has no statistically
significant relationship to the underlying national data (a low t-statistic on
coefficient) are the manufacturing
workweek and unfilled orders.

TABLE
Simple Regression Results—Explaining U.S. and Regional Economic
Measures Using Counterpart Business Outlook Survey Diffusion Indexes

Constant

Diffusion Index
Coefficients
(t-statistic)

R2

Time Period

Industrial Production

0.015
(0.44)

0.020
(13.32)

0.30

1969:01
2003:06

Manufacturing Production

0.005
(0.13)

0.028
(14.18)

0.33

1969:01
2003:06

Manufacturing Shipments

-0.067
(-0.46)

0.292
(3.24)

0.07

1992:02
2003:06

Manufacturing New Orders

-0.082
(-0.43)

0.034
(2.77)

0.05

1992:02
2003:06

Delivery Times/Vendor Deliveries

56.16
(109.00)

0.722
(14.52)

0.34

1969:01
2003:06

Dependent Variable:
National Data

36 Q4 2003 Business Review

www.phil.frb.org

TABLE (continued)
Simple Regression Results—Explaining U.S. and Regional Economic
Measures Using Counterpart Business Outlook Survey Diffusion Indexes
Constant

Diffusion Index
Coefficients
(t-statistic)

R2

Time Period

Manufacturing Employment

-0.03
(-1.59)

0.023
(14.75)

0.35

1969:01
2003:06

Manufacturing Workweek

0.003
(0.92)

0.003
(0.92)

0.00

1969:01
2003:06

Manufacturing Unfilled Orders

-0.00
(-0.02)

-0.001
(-0.22)

0.00

1992:02
2003:06

Manufacturing Inventories

0.288
(6.14)

0.025
(5.63)

0.19

1992:02
2003.06

Producer Prices (Finished Goods)

0.148
(5.18)

0.016
(11.01)

0.23

1969:01
2003:06

Producer Prices (Intermediate Goods)

-0.244
(-5.70)

0.020
(16.89)

0.41

1969:01
2003:06

District Manufacturing Employment
(Tri-State)

-0.152
(-7.03)

0.018
(8.44)

0.31

1990:01
2003:04

District Manufacturing Employment
(District Totals)

-0.151
(-5.19)

0.018
(6.74)

0.22

1990:01
2003:04

Dependent Variable:
National Data

Regional Data

Source: Federal Reserve Board, Census Bureau, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Institute of Supply Management. District manufacturing
data for state employment include Delaware, New Jersey, and Pennsylvania. District employment is the total of manufacturing
employment for the metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) within the Third Federal Reserve District. All of the dependent variables
(except vendor deliveries) are calculated as the log difference multiplied by 100, which is approximately equal to percent change. The
delivery times variable is the ISM’s diffusion index for current month supplier deliveries.

www.phil.frb.org

Business Review Q4 2003 37