View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A Farewell from President Santomero

O

by Anthony M. Santomero

n March 31, 2006, President Anthony M.
Santomero will step down as president of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. In this
quarter’s message—his last—he reflects on the
economic challenges and changes of the past six years and
summarizes some of the Bank’s accomplishments.

This will be my final contribution to “The Third Dimension” as
president of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia. My tenure as a Fed
president has spanned an especially interesting period. I came to the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia in the
summer of 2000, on the tail end of one
of the greatest bull markets in financial history and in the 10th and final
year of the longest economic expansion in U.S. history. We then saw an
unprecedented series of disturbances:
a terrorist attack on American soil,
two wars, numerous financial scandals,
even major natural disasters. Meanwhile, longer term trends, such as the
blossoming of the Internet age and the
globalization of markets, continued to
transform the economic and financial
landscape. All of these things challenged the Fed—as monetary policymaker, as banking regulator, and as
payment system provider.
During this time, the Federal Reserve was under the chairmanship of
Alan Greenspan, a man who has been
called the greatest central banker who
ever lived. It has been my privilege to

www.philadelphiafed.org

work toward meeting these challenges
both as a member of the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) and as
president of this Bank.
Along the way, I have shared my
perspectives on many of these issues
with you here in the Business Review.
I hope you have found them interesting. Indeed, I hope you have found
— and will continue to find — all of
the articles we bring to you through
the Business Review worthwhile. They
represent our best effort to share with
you the work of our dedicated staff of
economists in the realms of economic
policy, banking and payments, and financial and regional economics. More
broadly, the Business Review is one way
in which our Bank achieves what I see
as its fundamental goal: to serve as a
center of central bank knowledge and
capability.
I want to take this opportunity to
summarize some other important ways
in which the Bank has been building,
sharing, and applying knowledge to
contribute to the Fed's effectiveness as
the nation's central bank.
In the area of economic research

and policy, we have built a more
vibrant research enterprise. Our
economists are producing high-quality
research on issues important to central
banking and sharing that work with
others via participation in professional
conferences across the country and
around the world. In addition, we have
also increased the number of conferences and workshops that we have
organized here at the Bank.
Indeed, our palpable presence at
the nexus of research and policy is
perhaps best embodied in our Philadelphia Fed Policy Forum.* This remarkably successful annual event brings
together leading academics, policymakers, and market economists for debate and discussion of relevant macroeconomic and monetary policy issues.

For a summary of the 2004 Policy Fourm, see
the Third Quarter 2005 issue of the Business
Review.
*

Anthony M. Santomero, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Q1 2006 Business Review 

We are honored that one commentator
has called it the “Jackson Hole of the
East,” referring to the highly regarded
annual conference of economists held
in Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
All of these activities help deepen
the Fed’s understanding of monetary
policy and its impact on the national
economy. On a personal level, the
work of our Research Department
has served me well—challenging my
thinking as an economist and helping me sharpen my contributions to
the discussions at the FOMC. Let me
add that participating in the FOMC
discussions in Washington has truly
impressed upon me the gravity of the
Fed’s role in our nation’s economy.
The Bank has been active in other
areas of central banking as well. The
Philadelphia Fed has long been a System leader in the payments arena. We
operate one of its premier check processing centers, and recently we have
been named as a System consolidation
site, absorbing the check volume from
New York’s East Rutherford Operations Center. At the same time, we are
advancing the System’s knowledge of
the evolving payments system with the
establishment of our Payment Cards
Center. And we are playing a key role
in modernizing government payments
through the services we provide to the
U.S. Treasury.
In the area of bank supervision,
we established a unit in our Supervision, Regulation and Credit Department to analyze retail credit risk.
Now the System has charged us with
developing the strategy for imple-

 Q1 2006 Business Review

menting this part of the new Basel
II capital requirements. Our Bank is
also now responsible for implementing the System’s new discount window
lending policy and overseeing requisite
upgrades to our technology.
At the same time, our Bank has
made strong contributions to economic education and financial literacy.
We are System leaders in economic
education and have developed finan-

delphia community and to become
an integral part of economic policy
discussion in our District and the nation. Our Bank has had the opportunity to contribute to such discussions
throughout our region and to establish
its expertise in monetary policy on the
national stage.
In my view, the Philadelphia Fed
has established itself as an outstanding component of the Federal Reserve

As part of the nation’s central bank, we are an
organization with an important niche in public
service and a stellar reputation for quality and
credibility.
cial literacy curricula used locally and
nationally. Our programs to promote
financial literacy, improve access to
credit, end predatory lending, and
foster urban development continue to
make a real difference in our communities.
To increase public understanding of the Fed and its role, our Bank
opened its doors to visitors on Independence Mall with the “Money
in Motion” exhibit. This interactive
financial exhibit has brought over
67,000 national and international
visitors to our Bank since it opened.
We also sponsored and hosted roughly
572 events in our new state-of-the-art
conference center in its first year of
operation.
Over the six years of my tenure,
our Bank has strived to become an
even more important part of our Phila-

System. As part of the nation’s central
bank, we are an organization with an
important niche in public service and a
stellar reputation for quality and credibility. I am confident that the Bank
will continue to move forward under
its new leadership and will remain
steadfastly committed to the strength
and growth of the Third District’s
economy.
In closing, I would like to express my gratitude for having had the
pleasure of national service in a truly
outstanding institution and for the
opportunity to work under Chairman
Greenspan. With Greenspan’s departure, President Bush has made an excellent choice in Ben Bernanke as our
new Chairman. I am confident that
the reins of the Federal Reserve are in
good hands. I wish him, my colleagues,
and our readers the very best. BR

www.philadelphiafed.org

Debt Maturity:
What Do Economists Say? What Do CFOs Say?
by Mitchell Berlin

L

ike households, firms that borrow money
to finance operations must make decisions
about the optimal maturity of their debt.
Should a firm take a short-term loan now
and refinance later? Or is the firm better off locking in
a long-term interest rate now? In this article, Mitchell
Berlin discusses recent theories of how firms choose their
debt maturity. Some of these theories are very useful for
explaining how chief financial officers (CFOs) choose
the maturity of their firms’ debt. However, CFOs seem
to believe that they can predict future interest rates and
time their borrowings accordingly, and this behavior
fundamentally conflicts with most economic theories.

Any homeowner who has shopped
around for a mortgage would recognize
many of the concerns facing the chief
financial officer (CFO) puzzling over
her firm’s optimal debt maturity. A
CFO may ask, “Should my firm sell a
long-term bond and lock in the current
30-year rate, or should my firm sell a
five-year note and refinance in five
years?” One of the CFO’s concerns
is that the five-year loan may subject

Mitchell Berlin
is an assistant
vice president
and economist in
the Philadelphia
Fed’s Research
Department. He
is also head of the
department’s banking and financial
markets section.
www.philadelphiafed.org

her firm to the risk of refinancing at
an inopportune time, for example,
when the bond market is skittish and
risk premiums are high, or following a
string of negative earnings reports.
There is now substantial evidence
that many CFOs also ask themselves,
“Do I think that long-term rates are
going to fall soon? If so, maybe we
should take out a short-term loan
now and refinance at a lower rate five
months from now.” While this reasoning may seem sound to some readers,
economic models of the relationship
between short-term rates and longterm rates say that the CFO is wasting
his or her time hoping to lower the
firm’s borrowing costs in this way, as
I’ll discuss later.
Some leading theories of firms’
choice of debt maturity are based on

the idea that firms are better informed
about their own creditworthiness than
are lenders, another consideration that
may be familiar to household borrowers. For example, a CFO of a firm
with a promising, but untested, new
product may reason that by borrowing short-term and reentering debt
markets next year, the firm can lower
borrowing costs because lenders are
likely to raise their projections of firm
profitability once initial sales figures
come in. Another leading theory says
that short-term debt tends to mitigate
the conflicting interests of a firm’s
stockholders and its bondholders about
the firm’s choice of investments.
Empirical studies of firms’ debt
maturity choices suggest that finance
theorists have made significant
progress in explaining these matters;
at the same time, these empirical studies have uncovered a few interesting
puzzles. Sophisticated borrowers’ belief
that they can lower their funding costs
by timing the maturity of their borrowings based on their forecasts of interest
rate movements is one of these puzzles.
PRIVATE INFORMATION MAY
AFFECT DEBT MATURITY
Short-Term Loans Make Funding Costs More Sensitive to New
Public Information About Firms.
In an influential model by Douglas
Diamond, a firm’s insiders (its managers and large stockholders) have
information about the firm’s likelihood
of default that is superior to that of
outsiders, in this case, its creditors.
That is, insiders have what economists
call private information. This is not
to say that creditors are completely
uninformed about the firm. They may
Business Review Q1 2006 3

have a number of observable indicators
of the firm’s credit risk, for example,
a credit rating from Moody’s. However, the firm’s managers will often
have better information than creditors
about the firm’s prospects because of
managers’ involvement in the running of the firm. This means that
two firms that both have B+ ratings
from Moody’s may actually have quite
different probabilities of defaulting on
their debts. This is a problem not only
for creditors but also for the firm that
is truly more creditworthy than other,
similarly rated firms. Unless the lower
risk firm can find some way to signal
its private information to its lenders, it
will end up borrowing at the same high
rate as all the other B+ firms because
creditors will be unable to tell them
apart.
Diamond argues that one possible
way for the low-risk firm to lower its
borrowing costs is to shorten its debt
maturity. Matters known only to management today will gradually become
more public in the course of time; for
example, a firm that has a low risk
of default is more likely to generate a
good quarterly earnings report in the
future than a higher risk firm. When
lenders see a new earnings report,
they update their beliefs about a firm’s
credit risk, and the firm will be able to
borrow at a lower rate than previously.
So a manager with private information that his firm is more creditworthy
reasons: “With short-term loans we
can make our borrowing costs more
sensitive to public information as it
becomes available to lenders. Since
our earnings report is likely to contain
good news about our future prospects,
our cost of funds is likely to fall.” 1
But Refinancing Short-Term
Debt Creates Liquidity Risk. If the
future were perfectly predictable, this
would be the end of the story. A manager with private information that his
firm is low risk would always choose

4 Q1 2006 Business Review

the shortest possible maturity. However, even firms with low default risk
may temporarily suffer low profits and
find themselves trying to refinance
their debt at an inopportune time.
This might simply lead to higher interest costs for a time, or it might force
the firm to cut back business or forgo
profitable investments. This is called
liquidity risk. Liquidity risk limits even
a low-risk firm’s appetite for shortening

The Firm’s Optimal Debt
Maturity Depends on Observable
Measures of Credit Risk. Consider
two firms, one of which creditors view
as riskier than the other based on
observable indicators of credit risk.
Although in the real world the information available to creditors is a lot
broader than the credit rating alone,
I’ll use the shorthand term credit rating
to summarize these observables. In

Even firms with low default risk may
temporarily suffer low profits and find
themselves trying to refinance their debt at an
inopportune time.
the maturity of its debt. While low-risk
firms will take account of liquidity risk,
high-risk firms will take it even more
seriously because they have a higher
likelihood of reporting low profits and
facing higher borrowing costs.
There is empirical evidence that
liquidity risk is a real concern for firms
and that it affects their choice of debt
maturity. CFOs responding to John
Graham and Campbell Harvey’s extensive survey of 392 financial executives
cite the “cost of refinancing in bad
times” as the second most important
factor affecting their debt maturity
choice.

High-risk firms would prefer to make their borrowing costs less sensitive to public information
by locking in today’s rate. But in Diamond’s
model, they are forced to mimic the low-risk
firms and borrow short-term funds or else be
revealed as high-risk firms. Economists call this
type of equilibrium a pooling equilibrium. Mark
Flannery’s paper also highlights private information and low-risk firms’ desire to make funding
costs more sensitive to public information as it
arrives. In his paper, the countervailing cost
of short-term debt is that underwriters must be
paid each time firms sell a new debt issue. He
presents a separating equilibrium in which managers with private information that their firm is
high risk do not mimic the managers of low-risk
firms; low-risk firms issue short-term debt and
high-risk firms issue long-term debt.
1

Diamond’s model, firms with a higher
credit rating are more likely to report
strong earnings in the future than
those with a lower credit rating. That
is, at higher credit ratings it is more
likely that the manager of a firm has
private information that the firm is
low risk. This means that firms with
higher credit ratings face less liquidity
risk, and thus, Diamond predicts firms
with higher credit ratings will use more
short-term debt than firms with lower
credit ratings.
Actually, there is a twist. For
some very risky firms, lenders are
simply unwilling to lend long term
because lenders will lose money too
often if they are unable to raise their
rate or will refuse to provide further
funding based on the most current
information. As a result, lenders will
provide only very short-term financing
for such firms to keep them on a short
leash.2 So Diamond predicts that both
very low-risk and very high-risk firms
will use short-term debt.

Lenders use a number of other contractual
devices for such borrowers, especially collateral
and detailed loan covenants.
2

www.philadelphiafed.org

The Empirical Evidence for the
Signaling/Liquidity Risk Tradeoff.
Studies of large firms with access to
public securities markets uniformly
support Diamond’s predictions.3 Researchers have found that a firm’s debt
maturity increases as its credit rating
falls, at least until its credit rating
becomes speculative (BB or lower).4
They also find that firms without
a credit rating typically use more
short-term debt. There are two ways
to think about the absence of a credit
rating. No credit rating usually means
that there is little public information
about a firm — which investors view
as a source of risk in itself — or it may
mean that a firm is smaller and riskier
than the typical firm with public ratings.
Studies of small firms, which
have more limited access to financial
markets than large firms, provide
less consistent support for Diamond’s
model. These firms typically borrow
from banks or from finance companies
rather than by selling bonds to the
public. There are difficulties testing
Diamond’s predictions for firms without credit ratings because researchers
often can’t observe what information is
actually available to lenders.
Allen Berger, Marco EspinosaVega, W. Scott Frame, and Nathan
Miller take the interesting approach
of using the internal risk ratings that
banks assign their loan customers as
a summary measure of the information available to a firm’s lender and
find that debt maturity is longer for
riskier loans, as Diamond predicts for

firms with low and moderate credit
risk. However, there is no switch in the
relationship for the riskiest borrowers.
One possible explanation for this finding is that bank loan contracts to the
riskiest borrowers are likely to include
very close monitoring by the lender;
thus, the relationship between credit
risk and maturity may be more complicated than in Diamond’s model.5 This
monitoring includes the extensive use

Researchers have
found that a firm’s
debt maturity
increases as its credit
rating falls, at least
until its credit rating
becomes speculative
(BB or lower).
of covenants that require the borrower
to prove its financial health to avoid
default; longer-term debt with extensive covenants may be viewed as a
relatively close substitute for short-term
debt. In itself, the availability of such a
substitute may confound the relationship between credit risk and maturity
in the Diamond framework.
STOCKHOLDER/BONDHOLDER
CONFLICTS MAY AFFECT DEBT
MATURITY
When Firms Have Too Much
Long-Term Debt, Managers May
Forgo Profitable Investments. Another classic article by Stewart Myers
Berger and co-authors also find evidence that
supports the empirical significance of private
information for the debt maturity of bank loans.
Specifically, they show that the relationship
between the bank’s rating and the firm’s maturity is weaker for loans in which the bank used
credit scoring as part of the loan underwriting
process. The authors argue (plausibly) that
information asymmetries are less significant for
such loans.
5

Articles that provide empirical support for
Diamond’s model for larger firms include the
ones by Michael Barclay and Clifford Smith;
Mark Stohs and David Mauer; Shane Johnson;
and Michael Faulkender and Mitchell Petersen.
3

Bonds are rated according to their default
risk by ratings agencies, the most prominent of
which are Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s.
4

www.philadelphiafed.org

begins by making the crucial distinction between investments already in
place and growth opportunities, options
to make an investment sometime in
the future. The key to Myers’s theory is
that the way in which the investments
in place have been financed — in
particular, whether with debt or with
equity, and if debt, whether with shortor long-term debt — affects the profits
stockholders make from exercising
growth options.
To see the issues, begin with the
simple case where the growth opportunity is profitable on a stand-alone
basis — that is, the project has positive
net present value — and the firm has
no existing debt. In this case, existing stockholders would evaluate the
growth opportunity separately from
the investment in place and would support exercising the growth opportunity
because it is profitable.6 But if the firm
has debt outstanding, stockholders will
have to share future profits with the
bondholders who provided the funds
to finance the investment in place.
When the outstanding debt is large
enough to affect a firm’s investment
decisions, it is often referred to as the
debt overhang. If the debt overhang is
large, the bondholders will capture a
relatively large share of the projected
revenues from the new profits, and the
firm might forgo the profitable growth
opportunity. This is known as the
underinvestment problem.
To see how this can happen, consider a firm that owns a fleet of carts
that sell roasted chestnuts in Central
Park. The firm is considering whether
to purchase a second fleet of ice cream
stands. The chestnut carts are profitable only in cold weather, while the ice

Myers assumes that managers faithfully carry
out the interests of the firm’s existing stockholders. Other prominent models in finance emphasize the conflict between managers’ interests
and those of the firm’s stockholders.
6

Business Review Q1 2006 5

cream stands are profitable only when
the sun is shining. Forecasters are
predicting an early spring and a long
summer, which means that the chestnut carts are likely to be unprofitable,
and the firm may even have to default
on its debt if it doesn’t diversify into ice
cream sales.
How will the firm’s managers
reason? According to Myers, they
may argue: “Most of the profits from
the new ice cream stands are going
to go to pay off the old debt used to
finance the chestnut carts, rather than
to the firm’s stockholders. The profits
received by current stockholders are
much lower than the profits that would
be generated by the ice cream stands
alone. Since we are concerned about
our existing stockholders, we shouldn’t
make the investment, even though it
would be profitable.”7
While stockholders might support
this decision in the short run, in the
long run, they would actually prefer
that the firm find a way to avoid
underinvestment. To see this, think
about a firm that systematically says no
to profitable new investments; such a
firm would suffer from an endemically
low stock price because its profits will
be low. So stockholders—especially the
stockholders of firms with significant
growth opportunities—would support
policies to induce managers not to pass
up profitable investments.
Firms with large growth opportunities can reduce the underinvestment
problem in two ways. First, they can
borrow less to begin with. The less
debt a firm has, the lower the possibility that creditors’ and stockholders’
interests will conflict in a material way.
(Microsoft is an example of a firm with
The discerning reader may ask why stockholders and bondholders can’t strike some kind of
deal to ensure that the profitable investment
is made. Myers’s model assumes that there are
impediments to renegotiating the terms of the
debt.
7

 Q1 2006 Business Review

no debt outstanding.) Second, for any
given amount of debt, the firm can use
primarily short-term debt, specifically
debt that matures before its existing
investments. For example, a firm that
uses three-month bank loans or commercial paper that matures in three
months can’t shift risks to its creditors
because the creditors can insist on a
new interest rate in line with current
risks every three months.
The Evidence for a Relationship Between Underinvestment and
Debt Maturity. One of the predictions
of Myers’s model mirrors a standard
practitioner’s rule of thumb: A firm
should try to match the maturity of
its assets and liabilities. Indeed, for
Graham and Harvey’s CFOs, matching assets and liabilities is the most
commonly cited factor determining
debt maturity. In all empirical studies
of firms’ choices of debt maturity, firms
with longer-lived assets have longerterm debt. While there is significant
empirical evidence for maturity matching, Myers underinvestment story is
not the only theoretical rationale for
this practice. (See Enforcement Concerns May Affect Debt Maturity.)
Myers’s model also predicts that
firms with larger growth opportunities should use more short-term debt.
Think of a fast-growing firm or one
with substantial investments in R&D
as examples of firms with significant
growth opportunities.8 Although the
literature is not unanimous, most
studies support this prediction. Shane

Most studies use the ratio of a firm’s market
value to its book value as a measure of growth
opportunities. The market value includes the
firm’s outstanding stock measured at market
prices and the value of its debt, while the book
value is the original sale price of the stock plus
the value of its debt. The idea behind using this
ratio as a measure of growth opportunities is
that the firm’s stock price will include investors’
valuation of future investments. Many studies
also use the firm’s investment in R&D as an
indicator of growth opportunities.

Johnson’s article is probably the most
thorough empirical study so far. First,
he finds that firms with larger growth
opportunities take on less debt.
Second, he finds that firms that use
primarily short-term debt have higher
debt loads than firms that use primarily long-term debt. These findings are
consistent with the idea that firms
try to avoid underinvestment both by
reducing their reliance on debt and by
shortening the maturity of the debt
they use.9
MARKET TIMING MAY AFFECT
DEBT MATURITY
Managers Seem to Believe That
They Can Time the Market. The
empirical literature has consistently
found evidence suggesting that managers time their borrowings in the belief
they can use their forecast of interest
rate movements to lower their cost of
funds. This is the third most common
reason given by CFOs in Graham and
Harvey’s survey. Specifically, CFOs
say that they issue short-term debt
when “short-tem rates are low compared to long-term rates,” or when “we
are waiting for long-term rates to come
down.” This is particularly important
for large firms, which have relatively
easy access to financial markets. Other
studies have consistently found that
short-term borrowings are higher
when the term spread—the difference
between the 10-year and the one-year
interest rate on Treasury securities—is
high, that is, when long-term rates are
relatively high compared to short-term
rates.10 Graham and Harvey’s response

8

Johnson’s paper takes explicit account of both
the firm’s choice of leverage and of the maturity
of its debt as a means of resolving underinvestment. This resolves some contradictory findings
in the earlier contributions.
9

These studies include those by Barclay and
Smith; Jose Guedes and Tim Opler; and Faulkender and Petersen.
10

www.philadelphiafed.org

ENFORCEMENT CONCERNS MAY AFFECT DEBT MATURITY

O

liver Hart and John Moore present a
model of debt maturity in which the
borrower can’t fully commit to a stream
of future debt payments. In particular,
an entrepreneur can always threaten to
walk away from her debts. Although she can be compelled
to turn over the physical assets of the firm in the event
of default, her accumulated skills and knowledge (her
human capital) can’t be touched by her creditors. Thus,
each debt payment potentially gives rise to bargaining
between the lender and the borrower, in which the lender
threatens to take the firm’s assets and the borrower
answers that assets are worth less in the hands of another
manager (so that the lender would be shooting himself in
the foot by carrying out the threat).
While this scenario may seem a little melodramatic
as a description of a routine debt transaction, Hart and
Moore argue that, ultimately, the borrower’s threat
to walk away and the lender’s threat to seize assets
determine the feasibility of a particular stream of debt
payments. If the debt maturity is too long term, i.e.,
if debt payments are postponed until too late in the
productive life of the assets they finance, the borrower’s
threat to walk away becomes a serious problem. In this
case, the contract would be calling upon the borrower
to make large repayments precisely when the lender’s
threat to liquidate is weakest. When the remaining life
of the assets is very short: (1) the borrower’s lost profits
from losing control of the assets are small, so the costs of
walking away are small;a (2) the value of the assets to the
lender is small (because the assets have depreciated), so

a

the gains to the lender from seizing assets are small.
At the same time, the firm’s debt can be too short
term. Investments yield profits over time, and the firm’s
accumulated cash flow from a project may be too small to
cover large debt payments early on. One possibility is to
use short-term debt that might be renegotiated if current
cash flows are too small to cover promised payments. But
efficient renegotiation may be impossible. The problem is
that even if future revenues are high enough to shift some
payments into the future under a renegotiated agreement,
the borrower has only limited ability to make credible
commitments to make debt payments out of future
revenues. So renegotiations would only lead to promises
that would never be kept.b
Hart and Moore’s theoretical analysis includes two
interesting empirical predictions. The first is that firms
will match the maturity of their assets and their debts;
thus, Hart and Moore provide another explanation of
this businessman’s maxim (borne out by Graham and
Harvey’s survey findings). As assets become longer lived,
they provide the creditor with the security to wait longer
before being repaid; the lender’s threat to seize assets
is more credible when assets are longer lived. A second
prediction is that more fungible assets — those that can
be more readily used by another firm — can more readily
support long-term debt. Again, the firm’s ability to commit to making debt payments out of future revenues is
enhanced by the strength of the lender’s threat to seize
assets. This prediction has recently found empirical support in a historical study of the U.S. railroads by Efraim
Benmelech.

Of course, borrowers will also be concerned about their reputation and their access to future finance.

b

An implication of this line of reasoning is that the borrower’s inability to commit to forgo seeking to renegotiate the contract can lead to underinvestment (for reasons different from those emphasized by Myers). That is, some essentially profitable investments simply can’t be financed. This will
happen if the borrower has to borrow a large share of the initial investment, if the project yields cash flows too late in the life of the project, and if
the project’s liquidation value is too low.

www.philadelphiafed.org

Business Review Q1 2006 7

to their findings sums up researchers’ typically puzzled response: “[I]t is
not clear to us why firms pursue this
strategy” (p. 233).11
Michael Faulkender’s article
presents striking evidence that firms’
managers believe they can time their
borrowings to reduce their cost of
funds. He examines financing policies for firms in the chemical industry
between 1994 and 1999.12 In particular, Faulkender examines these firms’
use of interest rate swaps undertaken
jointly with their new borrowings. In
the simplest interest rate swap, one
party exchanges the interest payments on its own debt for the interest
payments on another party’s debt. So
a firm that pays a floating rate on its
own debt can exchange these variable
payments for another firm’s fixed interest rate payments.
When a firm increases its shortterm debt, it will end up paying
higher interest costs if interest rates
rise. Conversely, when it increases its
long-term debt, it will be paying higher
interest rates than those prevailing in
the market if interest rates fall. This
is called interest rate risk. When firms
undertake a new borrowing they may
take an accompanying swap position
to offset, or hedge, their interest rate
risk. For example, a firm that takes on
new floating rate debt will be hurt if
interest rates rise. The firm can hedge

One theory of debt maturity by Ivan Brick and
Abraham Ravid does predict that the term premium should affect firms’ optimal debt maturity
through tax effects. But their model has been
consistently rejected by the data, with the puzzling exception of Stohs and Mauer’s paper.
11

Focusing on firms in a single industry is attractive for two reasons. First, since firms in a
single industry face similar operating environments, it is less likely that empirical findings are
driven by unobserved differences between firms.
Second, it is easier to find comparable measures
for factors that researchers expect will affect
firms’ borrowing policies, for example, factors
affecting industry risk.
12

8 Q1 2006 Business Review

this risk by exchanging the interest
rate payments on its floating rate debt
for fixed interest rate payments in
the swap market.13 However, a CFO
who firmly believes that he or she can
forecast interest rates might not hedge
against the risk of interest rates rising
but might purchase a swap that amplifies the firm’s exposure to rising rates.
This behavior is called speculation.

affecting the relationship between
short-term and long-term interest rates
is investor expectations about future
interest rates. For example, according to the expectations theory of the
yield curve, the 10-year Treasury rate
is simply the average of investors’
expected one-year T-bill rates over the
next 10 years. While it is plausible that
corporate CFOs might have private

The belief that CFOs can time the market
is equivalent to the belief that sophisticated
lenders are systematically taken to the
cleaners by corporate CFOs.
Faulkender finds that the swaps
undertaken in conjunction with new
borrowings are not taken for hedging
purposes. That is, a firm that takes on
new floating rate debt is not typically
swapping floating interest payments for
fixed interest payments. In itself, this
is surprising. Most academic observers have simply assumed that these
swaps were undertaken to hedge the
new debt. Further, the likelihood that
a firm takes a speculative position
depends on the term premium. So a
firm is not only more likely to borrow
using floating rate debt when the term
premium is high; it is also more likely
to swap fixed interest payments for
floating interest payments at the same
time as the debt offering when the
term premium is high.
Most Economists Believe That
CFOs Can’t Time the Market. To
a first approximation, the main factor

The reader may wonder why a firm would ever
want to borrow short term using floating rate
debt if it preferred a fixed interest rate (or vice
versa). A number of explanations are possible.
One is that the firm chooses its debt maturity
to avoid underinvestment. While short-term
debt might be attractive for this reason, a firm
may not want to bear the additional interest
rate risk.
13

information about their firms’ financial
condition — as in Diamond’s model
— they are very unlikely to have superior information about future interest
rate movements, and thus, they are
not likely to produce systematically
better interest rate forecasts than other
market participants.14 If CFOs don’t
have superior forecasts, economic
theory says that borrowing short term
and refinancing should lead to the
same (risk-adjusted) borrowing costs as
borrowing long term.15
One way to see this is to imagine that CFOs could systematically
reduce borrowing costs by borrowing
short term when short-term rates are

I am simplifying here. Factors other than
expectations affect the precise shape of the yield
curve and the theory of the yield curve is a venerable and continuing controversy in economics. Nonetheless, the main point still holds.
There is little reason to imagine that corporate
treasurers have systematically better information than other market participants about other
factors affecting the supply and demand for
funds at different maturities.
14

Just to be clear, in this discussion I am not
taking account of the issues considered by
Diamond. Think about a world in which all
information about a firm’s creditworthiness is
public information.
15

www.philadelphiafed.org

unusually low and switching to longterm rates when long-term rates are
unusually low. This would mean that
borrowers are systematically profiting
at lenders’ expense. It should be kept
in mind that these lenders are large
banks, insurance companies, money
market funds, and so forth. Thus, the
belief that CFOs can time the market
is equivalent to the belief that sophisticated lenders — whose business is
to make money by borrowing and lending — are systematically taken to the
cleaners by corporate CFOs.
Why do CFOs believe they can
time the market? One possibility is
that CFOs are simply wrong and that
their firms’ cost of funds is not lowered
by market timing. Indeed, Graham
and Campbell’s survey uncovers a
number of capital budgeting and
financing policies that are very common, yet don’t appear rational from the
standpoint of a financial economist.
Another possibility is that CFOs are
actually able to lower their cost of
funds, but for reasons other than their
ability to forecast interest rate movements. Perhaps managers have hit
upon a rule of thumb that has actually
worked, but not because CFOs have
better models of the yield curve.
In their article, Malcolm Baker,
Robin Greenwood, and Jeffrey Wurgler, using U.S. data between 1953 and
2000, present empirical evidence that
large firms do indeed borrow short
term when long-term borrowing would
have been more expensive (and vice
versa). The authors suggest that managers may actually be able to exploit
inefficiencies in debt markets to lower
their borrowing costs, although they
do not identify a particular type of
market inefficiency that would explain
this possibility.
Alexander Butler, Gustavo Grullon, and James Westen have argued
that Baker and coauthors’ results are

www.philadelphiafed.org

flawed on econometric grounds.16
Apart from these concerns, most economists will remain unconvinced about
the profitability of market timing without a plausible economic mechanism
to explain corporate treasurers’ success. Ultimately, Baker and coauthors’
main argument for taking the possibility of profitable market timing seriously
is that corporate treasurers believe it
is profitable. But essentially irrational
practices can persist as long as the
available data do not provide strong
evidence that the practice is losing
money. The correlations unearthed
by Baker and coauthors suggest that
during the postwar period, corporate
treasurers could convince themselves
that they were not losing money for
their firms, even if their dreams of timing the market were delusory.
CONCLUSION
Financial economists have made
significant progress in understanding
firms’ debt maturity decisions. Substantial empirical evidence supports
the view that firms’ private information about their credit risk is an important determinant of debt maturity.
In particular, the evidence is broadly
consistent with a model in which firms
balance two opposing factors. Shortterm debt makes borrowing costs more
sensitive to public information but may
force a firm to borrow at an inopportune time. Substantial evidence
also supports the view that firms with
significant growth opportunities will
choose the maturity of their debt to

Butler, Grullon, and Westen’s article makes
a convincing argument that the empirical
patterns in Baker et al. are spuriously driven by
structural shifts during the 1980s. In particular,
they argue that both excess returns and firms’
debt maturity policies changed in response to
changes in monetary and fiscal policy in the
1980s, leading to a spurious correlation in Baker
et al.’s data.
16

avoid debt overhang, which can lead
the firm to forgo profitable investments.
While it is not the business of
economists to slavishly produce models
that reinforce businessmen’s prejudices,
both views find support in survey responses by CFOs, who state that they
choose debt maturity to match the maturity of their assets and liabilities and
that their borrowing choice reflects
their desire to avoid having to borrow
at an inopportune time. CFOs’ own
statements provide financial economists with some comfort that they are
not theorizing about debt maturity in
a vacuum.
While the theories seem to have
been successful in explaining the borrowing choices of large firms, financial
economists have made less headway in
understanding maturity decisions for
smaller firms.
However, CFOs also state that
their debt maturity choices are partly
driven by the desire to borrow short
term when short-term rates are unusually low or to lock in a long-term rate
when they believe long-term rates are
likely to rise. There is also substantial
empirical evidence that firms’ financing decisions do, in fact, reflect this
motive. Here, there is less comfort for
economists because economic models
do not support the idea that firms can
systematically reduce borrowing costs
this way.
While economists are often
puzzled and challenged to explain business practices — is the practice simply
irrational, or is there some logic to it?
— CFOs’ belief that they can reduce
borrowing costs by timing the maturity of their borrowings is even more
puzzling, because there is some recent
evidence that such timing may actually
work. Unsurprisingly, this evidence
has been forcefully challenged and
remains an open area for research. BR

Business Review Q1 2006 9

REFERENCES

Baker, Malcolm, Robin Greenwood,
and Jeffrey Wurgler. “The Maturity of
Debt Issues and Predictable Variation
in Bond Returns,” Journal of Financial
Economics (November 2003).

Butler, Alexander, Gustavo Grullon,
and James Westen. “Can Managers
Successfully Time the Maturity of
Their Debt Issues?” Working Paper,
Rice University (July 2004).

Barclay, Michael J., and Clifford W.
Smith Jr. “The Maturity Structure of
Corporate Debt,” Journal of Finance, 50
(June 1995), pp. 609-31.

Diamond, Douglas. “Debt Maturity
Structure and Liquidity Risk,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics (August
1991), pp. 709-37.

Barclay, Michael J., Leslie M. Marx,
and Clifford W. Smith Jr. “The Joint
Determination of Leverage and
Maturity,” Journal of Corporate Finance,
9 (2003), pp. 149-67.

Faulkender, Michael. “Hedging or
Market Timing? Selecting the Interest
Rate Exposure of Corporate Debt,”
Journal of Finance, 60 (April 2005), pp.
931-62.

Benmelech, Efraim. “Asset Salability
and Debt Maturity: Evidence from
the 19th Century American Railroads,”
Working Paper, Harvard University,
(2004).

Faulkender, Michael, and Mitchell A.
Petersen. “Does the Source of Capital
Affect Capital Structure?” Review of
Financial Studies, 19, 1 (Spring 2006),
pp. 45-79.

Berger, Allen N., Marco A. EspinosaVega, W. Scott Frame, and Nathan
H. Miller. “Debt Maturity, Risk, and
Asymmetric Information,” Journal of
Finance, 60, 6 (December 2005),
pp. 2895-2923.

Flannery, Mark J. “Asymmetric
Information and Risky Debt Maturity
Choice,” Journal of Finance, 41 (March
1986), pp. 19-37.

Brick, Ivan, and Abraham Ravid.
“Interest Rate Uncertainty and the
Optimal Debt Maturity Structure,”
Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, 26 (March 1991), pp. 63-81.

www.philadelphiafed.org
10 Q1 2006 Business Review

Guedes, Jose, and Tim Opler. “The
Determinants of the Maturity of Corporate Debt Issues,” Journal of Finance,
51 (December 1996), pp. 1809-33.
Hart, Oliver, and John Moore.
“A Theory of Debt Based on the
Inalienability of Human Capital,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109
(1994), pp. 841-79.
Johnson, Shane A. “Debt Maturity and
the Effects of Growth Opportunities
and Liquidity Risk,” Review of Financial
Studies, 16 (Spring 2003), pp. 209-36.
Myers, Stewart C. “Determinants
of Corporate Borrowing,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 5 (1977), pp.
147-75.
Stohs, Mark H., and David C. Mauer.
“The Determinants of Corporate Debt
Maturity,” Journal of Business, 69 (July
1996), pp. 279-312.

Graham, John R., and Campbell R.
Harvey. “The Theory and Practice of
Corporate Finance: Evidence from the
Field,” Journal of Financial Economics,
60 (2001), pp. 187-243.

www.philadelphiafed.org
Business Review Q1 2006 10

What a New Set of Indexes Tells Us About
State and National Business Cycles
by theodore m. crone

M

any people are interested in comparing the
pattern of economic growth in their state
with growth in other states or in the nation.
Although the National Bureau of Economic
Research sets dates for peaks and troughs of national
business cycles, we lack official dates for turning points
in state economies. Some states have suffered recessions
when the nation did not, and some avoided recessions
during some national downturns. In this article, Ted
Crone presents information on a recently constructed
set of coincident indexes for the 50 states. These
indexes can be used to define business cycles at the state
level and can tell us how business cycles and the overall
patterns of growth have differed among the states.

Workers, business owners, and
policymakers are typically interested in
how the pattern of economic growth
in their state compares with growth
in other states or in the nation. Often
their job prospects, their profits, or
their tax revenues are sensitive to the
local business cycle. They may want to
know if recessions are more frequent

Ted Crone is a
vice president
in the Research
Department of the
Philadelphia Fed.
He is also head of
the department’s
regional economics
section.
www.philadelphiafed.org

in their state than in other states or if
their recessions are more severe or last
longer. They may also be interested in
how well the information they have
about the local economy reflects national conditions.
At the national level, we have
a commonly accepted definition of
business cycles. A committee of the
National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) sets dates for peaks at
the end of expansions and troughs at
the end of recessions.1 The economies
of the individual states, however, do

An explanation of the committee’s procedure
for determining the dates of business-cycle turning points can be found at www.nber.org/cycles.
html.
1

not march in lock-step with the national economy, and there are no official dates for turning points in state
economies. A casual glimpse at state
economic data reveals that some states
have suffered recessions when the
nation did not and some states have
avoided recessions when the nation
was in a downturn. Using a recently
constructed set of coincident indexes
for the 50 states, we can more clearly
define business cycles at the state
level.2 We can also learn about the
course of the national economy from
what is happening in the states. For
example, by following the states whose
indexes are declining we can trace the
spread of national recessions across
the country. Finally, by calculating an
index based on the number of states in
decline versus the number expanding
we can get an early signal of national
recessions.
WHAT IS A BUSINESS CYCLE
ANYWAY?
The popular notion of a business
cycle and the one used by the NBER
dating committee goes back to the
work of Arthur Burns and Wesley
Mitchell. They identified four phases

See the article I wrote with Alan ClaytonMatthews. The historical series for these
indexes can be found at www.philadelphiafed.
org/econ/stateindexes. This article is based on
the indexes from 1979 to 2004. A complete
set of state indexes is available only from 1979
because some data series needed to construct
the indexes are not available before then. For
consistency, each state’s index is constructed
from the same set of variables. Using a different
set of variables for different states could affect
the timing and magnitude of changes in the
index so comparisons across the states would
not be valid.
2

Business Review Q1 2006 11

of the business cycle: an expansion
followed by recession and contraction
and then a revival of economic activity
leading to the next expansion phase.
These four phases are commonly collapsed into two periods: a period of
growth (revival and expansion) and a
period of widespread and significant
decline in economic activity (recession
and contraction).
The NBER dating committee
looks at a number of indicators, such
as personal income, employment,
wholesale and retail sales, and industrial production, when it sets the dates
for peaks in the expansion and troughs
in the recession. These data are not all
available at the state level. But the new
state indexes combine several monthly
and quarterly data series that are
available for all 50 states — nonfarm
employment, average hours worked
in manufacturing, the unemployment
rate, and wages and salaries adjusted
for inflation. The indexes represent a
composite measure of the underlying
“state of the economy” in each of the
50 states, and we use changes in the
indexes to define state business cycles.
To compare business cycles at
the state level with national business
cycles, we need a common measure of
the underlying “state of the economy.”
For this purpose we have constructed
a national index of economic activity
based on the same economic series
as the state indexes. (See A National
Index of Economic Activity, pages 2223.) Over the past 25 years, all of the
monthly declines in the national index
have occurred in unbroken time intervals that we can identify as national
recessions. The four periods of decline
in this index correspond closely to
the four official recessions defined by
the NBER. When we refer to national
recessions in the remainder of this article, we will be referring to these periods of decline in the national index of
economic activity.

12 Q1 2006 Business Review

BUSINESS CYCLES DIFFER
WIDELY AMONG THE STATES
The state indexes do not trace out
recessions and expansions as clearly
as the national index. During state
expansions, the indexes sometimes
register a month or two of decline
that is neither sharp enough nor long
enough to indicate a separate state
recession. During state recessions, the
indexes sometimes register a month or
two of increases that do not indicate
the beginning of a recovery. The data
at the state level are more volatile than
the national data, and single events,

have been in recession every time the
nation has, and 28 states have not had
a recession independently of a national
recession. Fifteen states belong to
both groups. They have had recessions
that correspond to all four national
downturns since 1979 and have had
no other recessions (Table 1, Column
1).5 Missouri and Pennsylvania are
good examples of states whose business cycles follow the national pattern
(Figure 1). Recessions in both states
have occurred at the same time as in
the nation. But the state recessions
in Missouri and Pennsylvania have

The state indexes do not trace out recessions
and expansions as clearly as the national
index.
such as hurricanes, plant shutdowns,
or temporary spikes or declines in demand for a particular product, can affect the state economies more strongly
than the national economy.
We use the following criteria to
define recessions at the state level.
The cumulative decline in the state’s
coincident index must be at least 0.5
percent, which is the smallest decline
in the national index for any recession
in the last quarter century. The period from the state index’s peak to its
trough must be at least three months.3
Based on these criteria, at least 36
states and as many as 44 states have
been in recession during each of the
four national recessions since 1979.4
The Number and Timing of
Recessions Varies Among the 50
States. Only about half the states (24)
These criteria were chosen to meet Burns
and Mitchell’s conditions for a recession: The
decline in the economy must be diffuse, last
a sufficient length of time, and be sufficiently
large.
3

Thirty-six states were in recession during the
brief national recession in 1980, and 44 states
were in recession at some point in the long
national recession in 1981-82.
4

been deeper and lasted longer than the
national recessions. In part because of
the longer and deeper recessions, the
average monthly growth in the indexes
for these two states has only been
about three-quarters as great as the average for the nation (Table 2). Among
the 50 states, the average monthly
increases in the state indexes have
ranged from 1.8 times the U.S. average
(Nevada) to slightly more than onethird the U.S. average (Louisiana). Not
surprisingly, the states with the highest
average economic growth as measured
by the change in their indexes also
had some of the greatest increases in
population (Nevada, Arizona, Georgia,
Florida, and Utah), and states with the
weakest economic growth had some
of the slowest population growth over
the past 26 years (Louisiana, West Virginia, Michigan, North Dakota, Ohio,
and Iowa).

Two states in recession during all four national
recessions (Delaware and Illinois) had no
recovery between the two national recessions in
the early 1980s. Seven states were in recession
during three of the four national recessions and
had no other recessions (Table 1, Column 2).
5

www.philadelphiafed.org

FIGURE 1
Three-Month Change in State Index
Percent
3

Missouri

2

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

Pennsylvania

Percent
3

Jan JanJan JanJanJan JanJan JanJanJan Jan Jan Jan Jan JanJan Jan Jan JanJanJanJan JanJan Jan
79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04

National Recessions

-3

Jan JanJan JanJanJan JanJan JanJanJan Jan Jan Jan Jan JanJan Jan Jan JanJanJanJan JanJan Jan
79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04

3-Month Change in State Index

Shaded areas represent periods of decline in the national index described in A National Index of Economic Activity.

TABLE 1
States in Recession During Most National
Recessions Since 1979 and Experiencing No
Other State Recessions
States in Recession During
All Four National Recessions
Since 1979

States in Recession During
Three of the Four National
Recessions Since 1979

Alabama
Georgia
California
Iowa
Delaware*
Maine
Illinois*
Maryland
Indiana	Rhode Island
Kansas
Utah
Kentucky
Virginia
Massachusetts
Minnesota
Missouri
	Nevada
Pennsylvania
South Carolina
	Tennessee
Wisconsin
*These states had no recovery between the 1980 and 1981-82 recessions.

www.philadelphiafed.org

While state recessions generally
occur around the same time as national recessions, 22 states have had
at least one recession that did not correspond to a national recession. Texas
is a good example. Figure 2 shows the
three-month change in the coincident
index for Texas, with periods of decline
in the national index shaded in gray.
Texas has had three recessions since
1979, but only two of them occurred
during national downturns. The third
recession in Texas occurred in the
mid-1980s when all the major energyproducing states suffered an economic
downturn. This was a period of general
decline in oil prices.6 At some time
between 1984 and 1986, 13 states were
in recession, including all nine states
with the highest proportion of output
(gross state product) in mining and
natural resources. These nine states
are Wyoming, Alaska, Louisiana, New
Mexico, West Virginia, Oklahoma,
Texas, North Dakota, and Montana.7
There was a 50 percent decline in the refiners’
acquisition costs of crude oil between the fourth
quarter of 1985 and the fourth quarter of 1986.
6

The four other states that suffered a recession in the mid-1980s were Colorado, Idaho,
Nebraska, and South Dakota.
7

Business Review Q1 2006 13

Industrial Structure Explains
Some of the Differences in the Pattern of Growth Among the States.
In general, changes in the indexes
for states with a relatively high dependence on natural resources are
not highly correlated with changes
in the U. S. index, and changes in
these states tend to lag changes in the
national economy. That is, over the
business cycle, the U.S. economy tends
to accelerate or decelerate before the
economy in these states. To illustrate
this point, we calculated the correlations of the change in the national index with the change in the state index
for the same month and for each of the
six months preceding and following
the change in the national index.8
Table 3 shows the highest correlation for each state in this 13-month
span and the month in which the highest correlation occurs.9 For the states
in the column marked “t,” the highest
correlation was between changes for
the state and the nation in the same
month. Almost half the states (23) had
their highest correlation with the contemporaneous change in the national
index. The columns to the left of “t”
show states with the highest correlations between the national changes
and previous months’ changes in the
states. Thus, for Arkansas the highest correlation (0.73) was between the
The correlation of the change in the indexes
measures the degree of co-movement between
changes in the state index and the national
index. The correlations will not be affected by
differences in trend growth.
8

The correlations at neighboring leads and lags
are often very similar, but the correlations continually decline as one moves farther away from
the lead or lag with the highest correlation. The
correlations for Alaska were negative for all the
leads and lags in the 13-month span we considered. For Alaska, we report the correlation
closest to zero during that time span. Alaska’s
business cycles have not been in sync with the
national cycles; in terms of timing the closest
positive correlation is between the change in
the national index and the change in the state
index 26 months prior.
9

14 Q1 2006 Business Review

change in the national index and the
change in the state index two months
earlier. In other words, Arkansas’
growth leads that of the nation. The
columns to the right of “t” show states
with the highest correlations between
the changes at the national level and
future months’ changes for the states.
For example, the highest correlation
with the change in the Illinois state
index (0.84) was one month after the

change in the national index.
We used the proportion of state
output, or gross state product, for nine
different sectors to estimate the effect
of industrial structure on the timing
of changes in each state’s economy.
Other things equal, economic growth
in states with higher percentages of
output in agriculture and construction
tends to lead growth in the nation.
The opposite is true for states with

TABLE 2
Average Monthly Increase in State Indexes
1979 to 2004
(Average Increases in U.S. Index = 0.24)

State
Nevada
New Hampshire
Arizona
Georgia
Florida
Idaho
Oregon
Utah
North Carolina
Colorado
California
Massachussetts
New Mexico
Washington
Delaware
South Carolina
Vermont
Virginia
Texas
New Jersey
Minnesota
Tennessee
Connecticut
Maryland
Rhode Island

Average Monthly
Growth in State
Index
0.44
0.40
0.40
0.35
0.34
0.34
0.32
0.32
0.31
0.30
0.30
0.30
0.29
0.29
0.29
0.29
0.29
0.28
0.28
0.28
0.27
0.27
0.27
0.25
0.24

State
Maine
South Dakota
Arkansas
Wisconsin
Kentucky
Nebraska
Alabama
Indiana
Mississippi
New York
Missouri
Pennsylvania
Kansas
Illinois
Hawaii
Iowa
Wyoming
Ohio
North Dakota
Michigan
Oklahoma
Montana
West Virginia
Alaska
Louisiana

Average Monthly
Growth in State
Index
0.23
0.23
0.23
0.23
0.21
0.21
0.21
0.20
0.20
0.19
0.19
0.18
0.18
0.18
0.17
0.17
0.17
0.17
0.14
0.14
0.14
0.13
0.12
0.11
0.09

www.philadelphiafed.org

FIGURE 2
Three-Month Change in Texas State Index
Percent
3

2
1

0
-1
-2
-3
Jan
1979

Jan
1981

Jan
1983

Jan
1985

Jan
1987

Jan
1989

Jan
1991

Jan
1993

Jan
1995

Jan
1997

Jan
1999

Jan
2001

Jan
2003

Shaded areas represent periods of decline in the national index described in A National Index of
Economic Activity.

higher percentages of output in mining
and natural resources and in wholesale
trade.10 Thus, differences in industrial
structure help explain differences in
the timing of growth among the states.
INFORMATION FROM THE
STATES ADDS TO OUR
UNDERSTANDING OF THE
NATIONAL ECONOMY
The 50 state indexes in this
article were designed to track economic conditions at the state level,
We used a statistical technique known as an
ordered probit to estimate the extent to which
the industrial structure of the states influenced
the timing of changes in their economic activity
relative to the nation. States were given values
between -2 and +6 based on the timing of
the highest correlation of the change in their
indexes with the change at the national level reported in Table 3. The other sectors included in
the ordered probit analysis were manufacturing,
transportation and utilities, financial services,
other services, and retail trade. None of these
had a significant effect on the timing of changes
in the states’ economies. The government sector
was omitted.
10

www.philadelphiafed.org

and we use them to define state business cycles. But they are also useful
in describing the geographic scope of
national expansions and contractions,
and they provide information about
the near-term outlook for the national
economy.
Changes in the State Indexes
Track the Geographic Progression of
National Recessions and Recoveries.
The maps in Figure 3 show the progression of the most recent recession
and recovery. The shading indicates
which states experienced an increase,
a decrease, or no change in their economic activity indexes at three-month
intervals between March 2001 and
June 2002—a period that spans the
recession and early recovery. In March
2001 declines were concentrated in a
limited number of states, mostly in the
Midwest and South. By September, the
recession had spread to almost every
state in the nation, and most remained
in recession through the end of 2001.

By March 2002, however, most of the
states in the West, Rocky Mountains,
and Southeast were in recovery. By
June 2002 almost all the states were in
recovery.11
The other three national recessions since 1979 developed in a similar
manner. Declines began in a relatively
small group of states, most of them
in one or two geographic areas. The
initial group of states has not always
been the same, but 12 states have consistently gone into recession before the
nation, even if they have not been in
the initial group.12 Eventually, the economic decline spreads to almost all of
the states and practically every section
of the country.13 Once the national recession is over, the number of states in
decline drops quickly to just a few, and
most states enter their recovery phase.
A Diffusion Index Summarizes
the Pattern of Growth and Decline
Among the States. The geographic
Researchers at the St. Louis Fed have also
used the 50 state indexes with a slightly different definition of state recessions to illustrate
the geographic spread of the four national
recessions since 1979. See the article by Michael
Owyang, Jeremy Piger, and Howard Wall.
The authors use the state indexes in what is
known as a regime-switching model to estimate
whether a state is in the recession or expansion
phase of the business cycle in every quarter
from 1979 to 2002. In my 2005 article I used
similarities among the cyclical components of
these state indexes to redefine economic regions
in the U.S.
11

The 12 states are California, Indiana,
Massachusetts, Michigan, Missouri, North
Carolina, Ohio, Oregon, Pennsylvania, South
Carolina, Tennessee, and Washington. The
lead times have varied, however, for each
state and each recession. This pattern is not
likely to be the result of mere chance. If, for
every national recession, each state had a 50
percent chance of going into recession before
the nation, the probability of a state going into
recession early all four times since 1979 would
be 0.0625 = (0.5)4. This would imply that only
about three states, not 12, would have entered
every recession since 1979 before the nation as
a whole.
12

13
The 1990-91 recession was somewhat different. Even though most states went into
recession, many in the Southwest and Rocky
Mountain regions did not.

Business Review Q1 2006 15

TABLE 3
Highest Correlation of Change in the State Index
With Change in the National Index*
Period Relative
to U.S. (= t)
Number of
States

t-2

t-1

t

t+1

t+2

t+3

t+4

t+5

t+6

7

13

23

2

1

1

1

1

1

LA (0.31)

OK (0.31)

WY (0.23)

AR (0.73) GA (0.83) AL (0.73) IL (0.84) WV (0.63) TX (0.55)
DE (0.72) IN (0.74) AZ (0.81) UT (0.71)
ID (0.54) MD (0.77) CA (0.65)
MT (0.34) ME (0.71) CO (0.56)
OR (0.68) MI (0.72) CT (0.75)
SD (0.52) MO (0.83) FL (0.77)
WA (0.74) MS (0.77) HI (0.21)
NE (0.67) IA (0.72)
NH (0.71) KS (0.71)
NV (0.69) KY (0.78)
OH (0.77) MA (0.70)
RI (0.67) MN (0.79)
SC (0.84) NC (0.84)
ND (0.35)
NJ (0.76)
NM (0.64)
NY (0.80)
PA (0.82)
TN (0.84)
VA (0.80)
VT (0.72)
WI (0.78)
AK (-0.15)

* The correlation indicates the degree to which the change in the state’s index moves with the change in the national index. For example, if the highest correlation occurs at t-1, this means that economic growth or decline in the state precedes growth or decline at the national level.

16 Q1 2006 Business Review

www.philadelphiafed.org

FIGURE 3
March 2001

June 2001

Decreased
No Change
Increased

September 2001

Decreased
No Change
Increased

December 2001

Decreased
No Change
Increased

March 2002

June 2002

Decreased
No Change
Increased

www.philadelphiafed.org

Decreased
No Change
Increased

Decreased
No Change
Increased

Business Review Q1 2006 17

dispersion of national recessions and
expansions like that shown in Figure 3
can be summarized by a diffusion index of the 50 states. This index is simply the percentage of states in which
the economy is expanding minus the
percentage in which it is declining.14
Diffusion indexes can be calculated using changes over any interval of time,
although one-, three-, and six-month
changes in the indexes are the most
common.
Figure 4 presents the one-month
and three-month diffusion indexes for
the 50 states from 1979 to 2004. The
one-month diffusion index represents
the percentage of states whose indexes
have increased in the last month minus the percentage whose indexes have
declined. The three-month diffusion
index represents the percentage of
states whose indexes have increased
over the most recent three-month
period minus the percentage of states
whose indexes have declined over that
period. These indexes do not measure
the magnitude of the change but only
the scope of change across the states.
The degree of increase or decrease in a
state’s index does not affect the diffusion index.
Diffusion indexes are commonly
used to measure the breadth of a
downturn or of an expansion in the
overall economy or in a particular sector.15 For example, the Bureau of Labor
Statistics (BLS) produces a diffusion
index for payroll employment, and the
Federal Reserve Board produces one
for industrial production by subtractReported percentage changes in these indexes,
like changes in most statistical series, are
rounded to the first decimal place. Thus, any
change less than 0.05 percent in either direction
is recorded as no change.
14

Diffusion indexes are also a standard way to
summarize the responses to qualitative surveys
in which respondents are asked whether some
aspect of their business has increased, decreased, or remained unchanged. See the article
by Michael Trebing and the OECD handbook.
15

18 Q1 2006 Business Review

ing the percentage of subsectors that is
declining from the percentage that is
increasing.16
These types of indexes received
considerable attention in the 1950s
when Geoffrey Moore argued that they
could be used as leading indicators
because they tend to decline before the
aggregate series in economic downturns and rise before the aggregate
series in recoveries.17 But this is not
The diffusion index of the 50 state economies
differs in a significant way from these two.
The state indexes are not components of the
national index. The national index is estimated
separately; it is not the sum or a weighted average of the 50 states, as in the case of employment and industrial production.
16

See the two articles by Moore. The suggestion
that diffusion indexes decline before the peak in
the aggregate series and rise before the trough
is only a historical observation, not a statement
about the mathematical properties of diffusion
indexes. See the article by Stefan Valavanis.

true for all diffusion indexes. Patricia
Getz and Mark Ulmer compared turning points or peaks and troughs in
the diffusion indexes for total private
employment and for manufacturing
employment to turning points in the
two overall series from 1977 to 1989.
They found some evidence that turning points in the diffusion index for
manufacturing employment signaled
turning points in overall manufacturing employment, but they found no
such evidence for total employment.18
James Kennedy at the Federal Reserve
Board examined break-even or reference points in the diffusion index for
industrial production, that is, points at

17

The authors examined the relationship
between the diffusion indexes and the levels of
employment. But the logical comparison is with
growth rates. See the article by Arthur Broida
and the one by H.O. Stekler.
18

FIGURE 4
One-Month and Three-Month
Diffusion Indexes for the 50 States
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
-80
Aug
1979

Aug
1981

Aug
1983

Aug
1985

Aug
1987

Recessions

Aug
1989

Aug Aug
1991 1993

Three-Month

Aug
1995

Aug
1997

Aug
1999

Aug
2001

Aug
2003

One-Month

Shaded areas represent periods of decline in the national index described in A National Index of
Economic Activity.

www.philadelphiafed.org

which the number of components that
were increasing equaled the number
decreasing. These break-even points
rarely preceded turning points in industrial production, and more often
than not, they lagged the turning
points in the overall index.
Our Diffusion Indexes of Economic Activity in the 50 States Do
Better as Predictors of National
Recessions. The one-month diffusion
index has turned negative before the
decline in the national index in all
four recessions since 1979, with lead
times of one to four months (Figure 4).
The three-month diffusion index has
not provided as much lead time as the
one-month index. In three of the four
recessions it turned negative between
one and three months before the national index. In the other recession, it
turned negative in the same month as
the decline in the national index.19
The ability of a diffusion index
to predict a coming recession can be
formalized with a statistical model
that uses the index to predict the
probability of being in recession in the
near future. It is obvious from Figure
4 that recessions are preceded by low
readings of the diffusion index and by
sharp declines in the index. We used
the three-month diffusion index and
the three-month change in that index
to predict the probability of being in
a national downturn three months
in the future (Figure 5).20 We would

expect that when the probability
climbs above 50 percent, the nation
would be in a recession sometime in
the near future. Indeed, the probability
climbs above 50 percent before every
national recession, with a lead time of
one to four months. Moreover, there
has been no occasion since 1979 when
the probability climbed above 50
percent and the nation did not go into
recession. At the end of recessions, the
model’s record of predicting recoveries
is good but not perfect. Before the
end of every recession except the one
in 1980, the probability of being in
recession in the near future drops
below 50 percent. After the 1980
recession, the probability dropped
below 50 percent in the first month of
the recovery.
Diffusion Indexes Also Contain
Information on the Course of the
National Economy Beyond Turning
Points. In his study of industrial

production, James Kennedy found that
the diffusion index provided valuable
information for forecasting near-term
growth in industrial production. We
repeated Kennedy’s exercise with the
one-month and three-month diffusion
indexes for the states and the monthly
change in the national index. We
got results similar to Kennedy’s. (See
Information in the Diffusion Indexes
about Changes in the National Index,
page 24.) Past changes in the national
economic activity index provide
information about the current month’s
change. If we add past values of the
diffusion index for the 50 states, we
get a better estimate of the current
month’s change in the national
index. Thus, the diffusion index of
the 50 states not only confirms the
information in the national index,
but it also provides independent
information about the future course of
the national economy.

FIGURE 5
Probability of Being in a National Recession
in Three Months Based on the Three-Month
Diffusion Index for the 50 States*
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5

Both the one-month and the three-month
diffusion indexes had a one-month negative
reading in early 2003 that was not followed by a
recession. This negative reading may have been
associated with the uncertainty surrounding the
buildup to and the beginning of the war in Iraq.
19

We estimated the probability with a standard
probit model. See the article by Andrew Filardo
for the use of probit and other types of models
to predict recessions. The one-month diffusion
index and its three-month change send signals
of recession using the probit model, but the
signals are somewhat weaker. The one-month
change also produces a false signal in February
2003 when the recession probability was slightly
above 50 percent.
20

www.philadelphiafed.org

0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
Jan
1979

Jan
Jan
1981 1983

Jan
Jan
Jan
Jan
1985 1987 1989 1991

Jan
Jan
Jan
1993 1995 1997

Jan
1999

Jan
Jan
2001 2003

Shaded areas represent periods of decline in the national index described in A National Index of
Economic Activity.
* The probability is based on the three-month diffusion index for the 50 states and the three-month
change in that index.
Business Review Q1 2006 19

THE VIEW FROM THE STATES:
A FULLER PICTURE OF
REGIONAL AND NATIONAL
BUSINESS CYCLES
The new indexes for the 50 states
were developed as summary measures
of state economic conditions. They
provide valuable information not only
about the economies of the individual
states but also about the national
economy. The indexes help us identify
state business cycles. We can compare
the state cycles with national cycles in
terms of their timing and severity, and
we can compare business cycles across
states.
The state indexes also allow us
to track the geographic development
of national recessions and recoveries.

20 Q1 2006 Business Review

Furthermore, diffusion indexes for the
50 states can signal the near-term onset of a national recession. This ability
to forecast recessions is formalized in a
model that predicts recession probabilities rather accurately. Furthermore,
the diffusion indexes contain information about the course of the national
economy beyond these turning points;
they provide independent information
about the next month’s increase in the
national index.
More than a half century ago,
Arthur Burns and Wesley Mitchell
argued that we should look at a large
number of indicators when judging
the condition of the U. S. economy.
The NBER dating committee looks at
a number of national series to set the

dates for recessions and expansions,
but they do not determine these dates
until recessions or expansions are well
underway. The new state indexes add
another set of indicators for researchers
and economic forecasters to look at.
The individual state indexes and the
diffusion indexes for the 50 states are
available within a month of the time
the data are collected. The indexes
can confirm the information in the
national data that are available at the
time; they can illustrate the breadth
of expansions and recessions; and
they can provide valuable information
about the near-term course of the national economy. BR

www.philadelphiafed.org

REFERENCES
Broida, Arthur L. “Diffusion Indexes,”
American Statistician, 9, 3 (June 1955),
pp. 7-16.
Burns, Arthur F., and Wesley C.
Mitchell. Measuring Business Cycles.
N.Y.: NBER, 1946.
Crone, Theodore M. “The Long and
the Short of It: Recent Trends and
Cycles in the Third District States,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review (Third Quarter 2003),
pp. 29-37.
Crone, Theodore M. “An Alternative
Definition of Economic Regions in the
United States Based on Similarities in
State Business Cycles,” Review of Economics and Statistics (November 2005),
pp. 617-626.
Crone, Theodore M., and Alan Clayton-Matthews. “Consistent Economic
Indexes for the 50 States,” Review of
Economics and Statistics (November
2005), pp. 593-603.
Filardo, Andrew J. “How Reliable Are
Recession Prediction Models?” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City (Second Quarter 1999),
pp. 35-55.

www.philadelphiafed.org

Getz, Patricia M., and Mark G. Ulmer.
“Diffusion Indexes: A Barometer of
the Economy,” Monthly Labor Review
(April 1990), pp. 13-21.

Rudebusch, Glenn D. “Has a Recession Already Started?,” Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter
2001-29 (October 19, 2001).

Kennedy, James E. “Empirical Relationships between the Total Industrial
Production Index and Its Diffusion
Indexes,” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series No. 163, Federal
Reserve Board, Washington, D.C., July
1991.

Stekler, H.O. “Diffusion Index and
First Differencing,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 43 (1961), pp. 201-208.

Moore, Geoffrey H. “Analyzing Business Cycles,” American Statistician, 8, 2
(April-May 1954), pp. 13-19.
Moore, Geoffrey H. “Diffusion Indexes: A Comment,” American Statistician,
9, 4 (October 1955), pp. 13-17, 30.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Business
Tendency Surveys: A Handbook. Paris:
OECD, 2003.
Owyang, Michael T., Jeremy Piger,
and Howard J. Wall. “Business Cycle
Phases in U.S. States,” Review of Economics and Statistics (November 2005),
pp. 604-30.

Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson.
“New Indexes of Coincident and Leading Economic Indicators,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1989, pp. 351-94.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson.
“Business Cycle Fluctuations in US
Macroeconomic Time Series,” Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol I. NY:
Elsevier, 1999, pp. 3-64.
Trebing, Michael E. “What’s
Happening in Manufacturing:
‘Survey Says . . .’,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Business Review
(September/October 1998), pp. 15-29.
Valavanis, Stefan. “Must the Diffusion
Index Lead?” American Statistician, 11,
4 (October 1957), pp. 12-16.

Business Review Q1 2006 21

A National Index of Economic Activity

I

hours worked, the change in the unemployment rate, and
the change in real wages and salaries. ∆ct is the change
in the log of the unobserved state of the economy or the
coincident index that is to be estimated. The trend in the
index is set to equal the trend in total gross state product
for the 50 states.
The figure below shows the monthly percentage
change in the national coincident index estimated from
this model. There have been four periods since 1979 when
changes in the national index were negative for several
consecutive months; these four periods correspond closely
to the four official recessions since 1979. Except for these
four periods there has never been a monthly decline in
the index. Thus, we can use the index to designate a
set of business-cycle peaks and troughs for the national
economy. The cumulative declines in the index from peak
and trough have ranged from 0.5 percent (1990-91) to 1.8
percent (1981-82).

n the late 1980s James Stock and Mark
Watson developed a coincident index for
the U.S. economy by identifying a common unobserved factor underlying the
observed measures of economic activity
for the nation.a The U.S. index in this
paper is estimated by a Stock/Watson type model using
national data that are also available at the state level.b
Thus, the model produces a national index comparable to
the state indexes. The Stock/Watson type model is commonly referred to as a single dynamic factor model and is
based on the following set of equations.
For each of the observed variables:
∆xt = a + b ∆ct + ut
For the unobserved state of the economy:
∆ct = d + f ∆ct-1 + g ∆ct-2 + et
In the model developed for this article, ∆xt is the change
in the log of employment, the change in the log of average

Figure
One-Month Change in National Index
(Shaded Areas Represent Recessions Based on NBER Dates)
Percent change
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
-0.2
-0.4
Jan
1979

Jan
1981

Jan
1983

Jan
1985

Jan
1987

Jan
1989

Jan
1991

Jan
1993

Jan
1995

Jan
1997

Jan
1999

Jan
2001

Jan
2003

1- month

See the article by Stock and Watson. The Stock and Watson coincident index was developed as an alternative to the coincident index currently
published by the Conference Board. The NBER no longer publishes the alternative Stock and Watson index; it was discontinued at the end of 2003.

a

b

This is the same model referred to in my 2003 Business Review article.

22 Q1 2006 Business Review

www.philadelphiafed.org

A National Index of Economic Activity (continued)
The table below compares the peaks and troughs
based on this national index to the peaks and troughs
designated by the NBER dating committee. The peaks
in the business cycle based on the index are one to two
months later than the official dates set by the NBER dating committee. The troughs of the recession are either
simultaneous with the NBER dates or two months later.
This difference in timing between the index and the
NBER dates may be due to the fact that the timing of the
index is primarily based on the timing of nonfarm employment, which slightly lags the overall economy.c

Despite the differences in timing, the index contains
valuable information about national recessions and expansions. The NBER typically announces the end of an
expansion or recession five months or more after the
end has occurred because it wants to make sure that a
new phase of the business cycle has begun and that the
original data do not simply represent the normal variation
in the series. Therefore, any information before the announcement can be helpful in evaluating the state of the
national economy.d

TABLE
Business-Cycle Peaks and Troughs
1979-2004
		
		

Coincident Index of
U.S. Economic Activity

NBER Business
Cycle Dates

NBER
Announcement Dates

Peak
March 1980
January 1980
June 1980
Trough
July 1980
July 1980
July 1981
						
% change in the index
-0.7%
Peak
Trough
% change in the index
Peak
Trough
% change in the index
Peak
Trough
% change in the index

August 1981
July 1981
November 1982	November 1982

January 1982
July 1983

-1.8%
September 1990
May 1991

July 1990
March 1991

April 1991
December 1992

-0.5%
May 2001
March 2001	November 2001
January 2002	November 2001
July 2003
-0.6%

c
See Stock and Watson’s article. Each of the other variables besides employment contributes significantly to the estimation of the coincident index
for the nation. This is also true for most of the state indexes.
d

See the article by Glenn Rudebusch for an illustration of the difficulty of timing recessions.

www.philadelphiafed.org

Business Review Q1 2006 23

Information in the Diffusion Indexes about Changes in the National Index

I

n his examination of the diffusion indexes for industrial production, James
Kennedy tested whether the diffusion
indexes provide any independent information about future changes in overall
industrial production. He estimated a
regression of the one-month change in industrial production on 12 lags of changes in industrial production and 12
lags of various diffusion indexes for industrial production.
He found that the lags of the diffusion indexes provided
information beyond that found in past changes in industrial production itself.
We repeated Kennedy’s experiment with the national economic index and the one-month and three-

month diffusion indexes of the 50 states. The results of
our regressions are found in the table below. A standard
statistical test (an F-test) confirms that the 12 lags of the
diffusion indexes add information to past changes in the
national index that helps predict the current change in
the national index. The statistics reported in the table are
based on equations of the following form:
12

12

i=1

i=1

∆ln(US)t = α + ∑ ßi ∆ln(US)t-i + ∑ γi DIFFt-i
where (US)t is the national index of economic activity
described in this article and DIFF is either the one-month
or three-month diffusion index for the 50 states.

table
Results of Regression of One-Month Change in the National
Index on 12 Lags in the Change in the National Index and
12 Lags in the Diffusion Indexes for the 50 States*
Adjusted R-squared
(R2)

Probability that all the coefficients
on the lags of the diffusion index
equal zero (based on an F-test)

12 lags of changes in the
national index

0.89

—

12 lags of changes in the
national index and 12 lags
of the one-month diffusion index

0.91

< 0.001

12 lags of changes in the
national index and 12 lags of the
three-month diffusion index

0.92

< 0.001

Dependent variables
in the equation

* The adjusted R2 is a measure of the goodness of fit of the regression. A higher R2 for the estimated equations with the diffusion indexes
indicates a better fit with the inclusion of these variables. The probability measure from the F-test indicates that the improvement in the
R2 is statistically significant.

24 Q1 2006 Business Review

www.philadelphiafed.org

Your House Just Doubled in Value?
Don’t Uncork the Champagne Just Yet!
by wenli li and rui yao

M

ore and more the United States is becoming
a nation of homeowners. Along with this
rise in ownership, an increasing share of
households’ wealth is invested in housing.
However, house prices fluctuate over time. Some studies
offer evidence that changes in house prices have had a
large effect on total output and total consumption. In
this article, Wenli Li and Rui Yao present their recent
research, which tries to quantify the effects of houseprice changes on both consumption and the well-being of
American households. Their study looks at the economy
as a whole, as well as different demographic groups.

The United States is increasingly
becoming a country of homeowners.
As reported recently by the Census
Bureau, close to 70 percent of households now own their primary residence. Homeownership is no longer
just an American dream; watering
lawns, sweeping sidewalks and cleaning drain gutters is no longer the sole
privilege of middle-income and affluent households. With the rise in the
homeownership rate, an increasing
share of household wealth is tied to

Wenli Li is
an economic
advisor and
economist in
the Research
Department of
the Philadelphia
Fed.
www.philadelphiafed.org

housing.1 According to the Federal Reserve Board’s Flow of Funds account,
residential property accounts for over
30 percent of total household assets,
and home equity accounts for over 20
percent of total household net worth.
House prices, however, fluctuate
over time (Figure 1). As can be seen in
the figure, since 1975 the country has
had two episodes of prolonged negative returns (adjusted for inflation) on
housing: one from the late 1970s to
early 1980s and the other in the early
1990s. Since 1996, however, the return
on housing has been moving up steadily, exceeding 15 percent in real terms
in the second quarter of 2004.

The rise of housing wealth’s share in total
household net worth started in 2000 after the
stock bubble burst.
1

There has been some speculation
and some evidence that house-price
movements have had a large impact
on total output and total consumption. For instance, Global Economic
Research wrote in its recent publication that “the U.S. housing market
has been a significant driver of U.S.
economic growth in recent years and
has contributed more to GDP than
many analysts expected. We estimate
that housing accounted for 10 percent
to 15 percent of the growth in real
GDP in 2004, more than double its
normal share in the economy.”2 Some
academic researchers have found that
house-price appreciation also has a
sizable effect on consumption. Economists Karl Case, John Quigley, and
Robert Shiller find that an additional
dollar of housing wealth increases total
household consumption by 3 to 15
cents. Similarly, John Benjamin, Peter
Chinloy, and Donald Jud find that
housing wealth increases household
consumption by 8 cents.
In their recent working paper,
Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan and
Federal Reserve Board staff economist
James Kennedy estimate that cashouts
through mortgage refinancing and net
extensions of home equity loans less

2

See the article by Joseph Carson.

Rui Yao is an assistant professor
of economics and finance, Zicklin
School of Business, Baruch College,
New York City.

Business Review Q1 2006 25

unscheduled repayments amounted
to about $300 billion between 2003
and 2004, or roughly 13 percent of
the increase in the household real
estate assets during that same period
as reported in the U.S. flow of funds
account.
Our recent research tries to quantify the effects of changes in house
price on both consumption and the
well-being of American households,
both in the economy as a whole and
across different demographic groups.3
We find that the effects are small for
the economy as a whole, but they vary
substantially across households of different ages, homeownership status, and
amount of assets.
WHAT’S SPECIAL ABOUT
HOUSING AND HOUSING
WEALTH GAINS?
As discussed in a previous Business Review article, residential housing
3

See our working paper.

is unique because it combines a flow of
services with an investment good.4 The
homeowner gets to live in the house in
lieu of renting and receives a potential
return on the equity in the house.
As of yet, there is no financial
product that permits a complete
separation of these two functions of
residential houses—consumption
and investment—for homeowners. To
put it simply, when households live
in their own house, they necessarily
bear the risk that the value of their
house will fluctuate over time. In that
sense, owner-occupied housing is also
an investment. In principle, renting
would accomplish this separation.
More precisely, households can live
in a rented house and then invest in
other properties. But there are good
reasons why most renters wish to become homeowners. First, rents may
rise. As economists Todd Sinai and
Nicholas Souleles have argued, owning
4

See Wenli Li’s Business Review article.

FIGURE 1
Real Rate of Return of House Prices
Percent
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10

19

7
19 52
7
19 62
7
19 72
7
19 82
7
19 92
8
19 02
8
19 12
8
19 22
8
19 32
8
19 42
8
19 52
8
19 62
8
19 72
8
19 82
8
19 92
9
19 02
9
19 12
9
19 22
9
19 32
9
19 42
9
19 52
9
19 62
9
19 72
9
19 82
9
20 92
0
20 02
0
20 12
0
20 22
0
20 32
04
2

-15

one’s home provides insurance against
the risk that rents will rise by purchasing future housing services at today’s
price. Second, housing services are, in
general, cheaper for homeowners, since
renters have few incentives to maintain
the rental unit and landlords charge a
higher price to cover for possible damages. Finally, homeowners also get tax
breaks. They can deduct their interest
payment on mortgage loans on first
and second homes from their income
tax, as long as these loans total less
than $1.1 million, and they do not pay
tax on the implicit income they receive
from being their own landlords.
Housing wealth is less liquid than
many other types of financial wealth.
The conventional fee for selling one’s
house is 6 percent of the house value.
And the time and effort involved far
exceeds a trip to the ATM or a call
to your mutual fund company or broker. In addition, saving in the form of
housing exposes households to idiosyncratic (household-specific) risks,
unlike the well-diversified portfolio of
financial assets in most models of lifetime savings and consumption used by
economists. For example, if employers
relocate, households may need to move
at a time when they are unwilling or
unable to sell their houses.5
These differences suggest that
economists may need to modify their
models of savings and consumption in
a world populated by homeowners. The
reason is three-fold. First, in traditional
models, there is a sharp distinction
between consumption and savings,
but housing is both a consumption
good and a savings vehicle. Second,
in traditional models, consumers save

time
annualized real house price return, quarter over quarter

In the short run, as demand for housing goes
up, rents may come down. But eventually, rents
will go up as property value goes up. Since we
all need to live somewhere, Sinai and Souleles
argue that the actual idiosyncratic risk of owning a house is somewhat lower because ownership hedges against the risk of rents rising.
5

Note: The rates of return are calculated using the house price index, a weighted repeated sales
index constructed by the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight, deflated by the core
consumer price index (which excludes the often volatile food and energy prices) from the Bureau
of Labor Statistics. The core CPI compares prices for a fixed list of goods and services to a base
period. Currently, the base, which equals 100, is average prices in the period 1982-84. Returns
adjusted for inflation are called real returns.
26 Q1 2006 Business Review

www.philadelphiafed.org

to insure against a rainy day, so-called
precautionary savings. These models
do not take into account the transaction cost of using past savings to
finance current consumption needs,
as is the case with accessing home
equity. Third, in traditional models,
savings decisions are not affected by
constraints on a household’s wealth.
Current institutional arrangements,
however, often constrain homeowners from borrowing a mortgage that
exceeds 80 percent of the house value
unless private mortgage insurance is
purchased.6
The new set of models that economists have developed in recent years
to deal with housing issues explicitly
model households that plan over their
life cycle and make housing decisions
along two dimensions: renting versus
owning, and the size of the house
for those who choose to own. These
households also make mortgage decisions and other financial investment
decisions, such as buying stocks and
bonds. Notably, these households face
borrowing constraints that preclude
them from borrowing today against
their future income. Researchers
have used variations of such models
to study, among many other things,
households’ optimal mortgage choice,
portfolio decisions in the presence
of housing, and the cost of subsidizing mortgage interest payments.7 Our
paper is the first to study directly the
consumption and welfare consequences of changes in house prices using a

Financial innovations have relaxed, but not
abolished, the down payment requirement for
buying a house.
6

See, respectively, the articles by John Campbell
and Joao Cocco; the article by Joao Cocco and
the one by Rui Yao and Harold Zhang; and the
article by Martin Gervais. Patrick Bajari, C.
Lanier Benkard, and John Krainer also study
the welfare implications of house-price changes
but in a complete market setting with perfect
information.
7

www.philadelphiafed.org

model in which households explicitly
maximize their lifetime welfare.8
HOUSE PRICES AND
CONSUMPTION
Middle-Aged Homeowners’
Consumption Is Not Sensitive to
Changes in House Price. Contrary
to many accounts in the popular and
business press, some economists, most
prominently Ed Glaeser, have argued
that changes in housing price should
have little impact on the consumption
and welfare of an average homeowner,
even if housing is a large share of the
average individual’s wealth. The rea-

who has lived for some years in Manhattan. He has probably reaped an
enormous capital gain from his house,
but he would also find it very expensive to buy another house in Manhattan if he decides to sell his current
house to capture the capital gains.
However, this logic holds only if
today’s house is much like tomorrow’s
house, i.e., the homeowner lives in
the same house, as is the case with
an average household: a middle-aged
homeowner who has accumulated adequate savings to buy his desired house
and who has yet to retire to Palm
Beach, Florida. For these households,

Contrary to many accounts in the popular
and business press, some economists have
argued that changes in housing price should
have little impact on the consumption and
welfare of an average homeowner.
son is that when house prices increase,
the assets of the household that owns
a home obviously increase. At the
same time, however, the price of housing services—the price the household
would have to pay in order to rent the
same house—has also increased, thus
offsetting that gain. The household is
not richer, since housing expenses appear on both sides of the household’s
balance sheet. Imagine a homeowner

Economists refer to this class of models—which have become standard in modern
macroeconomics—as dynamic stochastic
equilibrium models. Every modeling exercise
requires simplifying assumptions to keep
things manageable. To single out the impact of
house-price changes, we assume that household
income does not change with house prices. In
reality, however, house prices and household
income are positively correlated—that is, they
tend to rise or fall together—especially in a
local market. Our argument remains true in this
new environment, with the added effect that
the changes in income will reinforce the impact
of changes in house price, in both an economic
upturn and a downturn.
8

the increase in housing wealth cancels
out the increase in the price of their
housing services. The net cancellation,
however, does not accurately reflect
the decisions faced by homeowners
who are either young or old, nor those
faced by renters.
Young Homeowners’ Consumption Is More Sensitive to Changes in
House Price. Young households’ main
wealth lies in their future earnings,
which are not easy to borrow against.
To a significant extent, young households’ housing choices are limited by
the down payment they can afford.
Economists say that such homeowners
are borrowing constrained. House-price
appreciation effectively increases their
assets and relaxes their borrowing
constraint. Since they now have more
home equity, young homeowners typically respond to the increase in house
price by cashing out some of the home
equity through mortgage refinancing
so that they can spend the money on
Business Review Q1 2006 27

other consumption goods.
Imagine a young couple who owns
a $150,000 home with 20 percent equity ($30,000). The household does not
have any other financial wealth, and
it lives on a budget. Suppose that the
price of the house increased 10 percent. The household now has $15,000
more in home equity. The couple may
decide to cash out $900—through refinancing, home equity loans, or second
mortgages—and buy that big TV they
wanted but couldn’t afford. In other
words, the 10 percent appreciation in
house price increased their nonhousing
spending by $900.
It is worth pointing out that the
consumption consequences of houseprice appreciation depend on the extent of house-price increases and their
persistence. For example, the initial
house-price appreciation eases young
homeowners’ borrowing constraint
and thus increases their consumption.
Once these young homeowners overcome the liquidity problems, future
house-price appreciation will not help
them much in that regard. Furthermore, young households will respond
more to more persistent house-price
changes, given the transaction cost.
Old Homeowners’ Consumption
Is Also More Sensitive to Changes in
House Price. Since old homeowners
face a relatively short remaining life
span, they are less concerned about
long-term consumption. The risk of
fluctuating rents in the future is not as
important to them as it is to middleaged and young homeowners. In other
words, the increase in the price of the
house they own increases their wealth
more than it does the cost of housing
consumption over their remaining
lives. Therefore, they are more likely
to sell their houses or downsize when
house prices increase in order to capture the wealth gains. As a result, their
nonhousing consumption, for example,
travel, increases correspondingly.

28 Q1 2006 Business Review

Consider an 80-year-old couple
who, according to the National Center
for Health Statistics, have a life expectancy of another five to six years.
Suppose the couple owns a $100,000
house with 100 percent equity. Suppose the price of their house rises 10
percent. The couple may decide to sell
the house and get $110,000—$10,000
more than they would have gotten
otherwise—and then rent a similar
house at an annual cost of 6 percent
of the house value. If house prices and

The consumption
consequences
of house-price
appreciation depend
on the extent of
house-price increases
and their persistence.
rents stay unchanged for the next five
years and assuming a zero discount
rate, the couple gains $110,000 by
selling the house, pays $33,000 for
renting a similar house for five years
(=$110,000*0.06*5), and still winds up
with $77,000 in cash.9 With the additional cash in hand, the couple can go
on a cruise to celebrate their anniversary, a choice that may have been too
expensive for them before, instead of
waiting till the end of the fifth year to
cash out the $110,000 from the house.
Having said this, the couple does have
to sell the house to get the cash right
now. Therefore, their balance sheet
may look worse than before, a price
they pay to obtain the liquidity.
Of course, this effect on old
homeowners may be weakened to
the extent that old people may prefer

Obviously, the longer the couple needs to rent,
the smaller will be the financial benefits of selling their house now to capture the capital gains.
9

leaving a house to their heirs rather
than leaving money, since a house
has more sentimental value for family
members than for strangers who buy
the house.
Renters Reduce Consumption
When House Price Increases. Since
rental housing and owner-occupied
housing are substitutes, their prices
typically move in the same direction.10
Thus, if house prices increase, rents
are also likely to increase. As a result,
renters may reduce their consumption
in order to pay the higher rent and
increase their savings for a down payment on a house.
Consider a renter who rents a
$100,000 house and pays $6,000 a year
for rent. Suppose the house appreciates 10 percent, to $110,000, and the
landlord adjusts the rent accordingly.
The renter ends up paying $600 more
a year for renting the same house. This
extra money will have to come from
someplace; the renter will have to cut
his current consumption or dip into
his (existing) savings. If the renter still
plans to buy a house, he will have to
cut current consumption in order to
continue living in the same house and
still save for the down payment on a
future house, which has also gotten
more expensive.
When house prices rise sufficiently, renters may decide that they
may never have enough wealth to buy
a house. As a result, renters may stop
saving for a down payment. Nevertheless, they still need to cut current consumption to pay for the higher rents if
they choose to stay in the same house.
Summarizing the Demographic
Effects. In our working paper, we

Substitutes are goods purchased in place of
another good when its price rises. For example,
if the price of houses goes up, the demand for
rental units may rise and so rents would rise. If
the price of houses falls, the demand for rental
units may decline, so rents fall.
10

www.philadelphiafed.org

find that an additional dollar of housing wealth raises the consumption
of young homeowners (those in their
twenties and early to mid-thirties) by
5 to 6 cents, middle-aged homeowners
(those in their late thirties to mid-sixties) by 4 cents, and old homeowners
(those in their mid-sixties and above)
by 8 cents (Figure 2). These are called
the marginal propensities to consume
out of housing wealth.
These numbers are largely in line
with those found in recent empirical
studies. Using data on UK households,
John Campbell and Joao Cocco estimate the largest effect of house prices
on consumption—11 cents on the dollar—for old homeowners, and almost
no effect for young renters.11 Using
data on U.S. households, Andreas
Lehnert also finds that the percentage
increase in consumption for a given
change in wealth depends crucially on
a household’s age, ranging from 0 percent for middle-aged homeowners to 4
percent for young homeowners and 8
percent for relatively old homeowners.
As a comparison, the marginal
propensities to consume out of housing
wealth found in our paper and those
cited above are slightly larger than the
marginal propensities to consume out
of stock market wealth. Econometric
specifications of total consumption
such as those included in the Federal
Reserve Board’s model, as outlined in
the article by Flint Brayton and Peter
Tinsley, generally show that an additional dollar of stock market wealth
raises the level of consumer spending
by 3 to 5 cents.

housing wealth rises, these increases
in consumption do not necessarily
make all homeowners better off. But
how do economists measure well-being? One way is to ask a household
a hypothetical question: How much
would your lifetime consumption have
to increase to make you indifferent
between the current situation where
house prices remain unchanged and a
permanent increase in house prices of
a certain percentage (10 percent as in
the case of our working paper)?12 Since
households of different homeownership
status (rent versus own), ages, or assets
have different needs for housing services, the answers will clearly be very
different for different households.
Young Homeowners Are Worse
Off. Young households’ income is
likely to rise steeply over most of their
lifetime, and the size of their families

Economists call this the change in compensated demand.
12

is likely to expand over time. Therefore, their desired house size–one that
matches their future income and family size–exceeds what they can afford
with their current income and wealth.
Thus, they will upgrade over time.
The typical housing ladder for young
households is an apartment, a starter
house, and then a larger house. Even if
all houses increase in value at the same
rate, a big house typically appreciates more in dollars than does a small
house.13 As a result, the wealth gains
young homeowners receive from their
current houses are not enough to offset
the cost of acquiring future housing
services that are likely to exceed their
current services.
Consider a young homeowner in

Joseph Gyourko and Joseph Tracy find that
between the mid-1980s and the late 1990s,
high-end houses tended to have a higher real
rate of appreciation than low-end houses. However, they argue that some of it is because the
quality of high-end houses has improved more
than that of lower-end houses.
13

FIGURE 2
Consumption Changes as a Percentage of
Housing Wealth Changes
Percent
9
8
7
6
5
4

WHEN CONSUMPTION RISES
BECAUSE OF RISING HOUSE
PRICES, HOUSEHOLDS AREN’T
ALWAYS BETTER OFF
Although homeowners will increase their consumption when their
11

See Campbell and Cocco’s 2004 article.

www.philadelphiafed.org

3
2
1
0

Renter

Young Homeowner

Middle-aged

Homeowner

Old Homeowner

Note: Renters do not participate in housing wealth gains since they do not own houses. As a result,
their consumption out of housing wealth gains is not defined.
Business Review Q1 2006 29

his late twenties who owns a condo
worth $100,000 and plans to move to
a house worth $200,000 after marriage. Assume that house price appreciates 10 percent, and the condo is
now worth $110,000 and the house,
$220,000. Before the house-price increase, the young homeowner needed
only $100,000 in addition to his gains
from selling his own house to buy the
new house; now he needs $110,000,
or $10,000 more. The young homeowner will have to either postpone the
purchase of the new house or buy a
smaller one.
Middle-Aged and Old Homeowners Benefit from House-Price
Appreciation as Wealth Effects
Dominate Their Consumption
Needs. For middle-aged homeowners,
income has peaked and family size has
stabilized. Their house size matches
their income and wealth profiles as
well as their families’ needs. Therefore,
they will not change their house size
for the foreseeable future. House-price
appreciation thus increases their assets
without changing their cost of acquiring future housing services.
For example, consider a middleaged couple who have two children,
both in primary school, and who own
a house worth $350,000. The couple
most likely will not experience dramatic changes in its income, since both
members have been working at their
careers for a number of years and their
children will remain at home for the
next five to 10 years. Since this family does not have any plans to move,
a 10 percent house-price appreciation
increases its assets by $35,000 without
increasing its cost of acquiring housing services. The household can then
spend the additional wealth on other
consumption goods over its remaining
life span.
Old homeowners, who are generally looking to downsize, also benefit from house-price appreciation.
House-price appreciation allows them
to capture additional housing wealth
30 Q1 2006 Business Review

gains and reduce their housing costs.
For example, imagine a 65-year-old
couple who own a $300,000 house
and who intend to move to a $100,000
condo. After the 10 percent house-

more for the same housing services.
To make it worse, suppose the renter
plans to buy the apartment, which
is being turned into a condo by his
landlord. Before he needed to pay

The effects of house-price changes on total
consumption and consumer welfare obviously
depend on the demographics of the economy.
price appreciation, the couple sell
the house for $330,000 and buy the
condo for $110,000. Their wealth gain
is $220,000, $20,000 more than the
wealth gain they would have received
before the house-price appreciation.
This additional wealth will help boost
their other consumption as well as
their bequest.
Renters Are Strictly Worse Off
When Housing Price Increases.
Think of a renter who pays $6,000 a
year for an apartment worth $100,000.
If we assume rent is 6 percent of the
house value, after house-price appreciation, he pays $6,600 a year, $600

only $100,000; now he needs to pay
$110,000, or $10,000 more. As with
the young homeowner, the renter will
have to either cut current consumption
to continue to live in the apartment or
buy a smaller condo.
As we show in our working paper,
house-price appreciation of 10 percent
yields a loss of 4.5 percent in welfare
for renters and a 2 percent loss in welfare for young homeowners. At around
age 50, the welfare gains reach breakeven. Only households beyond the age
of 65 receive a welfare gain exceeding
2 percent.

FIGURE 3
Change in Welfare from a 10 Percent
House-Price Appreciation
Percent
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6

Renter

Young Homeowner

Middle-aged

Homeowner

Old Homeowner

Note: The welfare consequence is defined as changes in a household’s lifetime consumption so as
to make it indifferent between the current situation where house prices remain unchanged and a
permanent 10 percent house-price appreciation. For example, an old homeowner would need to be
given 5 percent more lifetime consumption to be as well off without an increase in house prices as
with a 10 percent increase in house prices. In contrast, a renter would be willing to pay 4.4 percent
in consumption to avoid the 10 percent increase in house prices.

www.philadelphiafed.org

An Example of the Effects of a Change in Housing Wealth

C

onsider an economy that consists of one
renter, one homeowner in his early 30s,
one homeowner in his mid-50s, and one
homeowner in his 80s. The renter rents
a $150,000 house, the young homeowner
lives in a $200,000 house, the middle-aged homeowner
owns a $350,000 house, and the old homeowner has a
$300,000 house (to keep things simple, let’s forget about
the landlord).
Now let’s assume that all houses appreciate 10 percent. As a result, the young homeowner gains $20,000,
the middle-aged homeowner gains $35,000, and the old
homeowner gains $30,000. The total housing wealth gains
for households in this economy is thus $85,000 (=$20,000
+ $35,000 + $30,000). Further assume that the marginal
propensity to consume that results from this increase in
housing wealth—that is, the increased consumption arising from a $1 increase in wealth—is 0.06 for homeowners
younger than 35, 0.04 for homeowners between 35 and
75, and 0.10 for homeowners above age 75. The total consumption gain for the homeowners is $5,600 (=20,000 *
0.06 + 35,000 * 0.04 + 30,000 * 0.1).

Assuming a rental cost of 6 percent of the house
value, the renter needs to pay $900 more in rent because of
the house-price appreciation (=0.1*150,000*0.06). He will
need to find this rent money. Suppose the money comes
from lower current consumption and the renter increases
savings by $100 for the furure purchase of a house. Then
the total consumption of the homeowners and the renter
has increased by $4,600 (=$5,600 -$900 - $100), implying
a marginal propensity to consume out of the $85,000 increase in housing wealth of 5.4 percent (=$4,600/$85,000).
Suppose house prices stay high, and households in the
economy grow older and move into the houses formerly
occupied by the next oldest household. In addition, the
old homeowner dies, and a new renter is born into the
economy. Compared to the economy before house prices
appreciated, the new renter pays $900 more in rent. The
new young homeowner pays $20,000 more for the new
house. The new middle-aged homeowner loses $15,000 (he
made $20,000 but pays $35,000 more for his new house).
The new old homeowner gains $5,000. The old homeowner’s heirs are better off by $30,000, the appreciation of his
house. We illustrate the points in Tables 1 and 2.

TABLE 1
Housing Wealth and Consumption
Renter
Rents/house value
before house-price
appreciation

House value: $150,000
Annual rent:
$9,000=$150,000*0.06

Rents/house value
$900
gains after house
=$150,000*0.1*0.06
price appreciates 10%
Marginal propensity
to consume out of
housing wealth
Consumption gains

Young homeowner

Old
homeowner

House value:
$200,000

House value:
$350,000

House value:
$300,000

$20,000
=$200,000*0.1

$35,000
=$350,000*0.1

$30,000
=$300,000*0.1

0.06

-$1000
=-$900-$100 assuming
the renter increases
savings by $100 for
future house purchase

Middle-aged
homeowner

$1200
=$20,000*0.06

0.04

$1400
=$35,000*0.4

0.1

$3000
=$30,000*0.1

continued on page 32

www.philadelphiafed.org

Business Review Q1 2006 31

An Example of the Effects ... (continued)
TABLE 2
Housing Wealth and Consumer Welfare
Renter
Rents/house value
before house-price
appreciation

Middle-aged
homeowner

Old
homeowner

House value:
$200,000

House value:
$350,000

House value:
$300,000

Rents/house value
$900
gains after house
=$150,000*0.1*0.06
price appreciates 10%

$20,000
=$200,000*0.1

$35,000
=$350,000*0.1

$30,000
=$300,000*0.1

Wealth gains/losses
-$20,000
after upgrading to the
next house

-$15,000
=$20,000-35,000

$5,000
=$35,000-30,000

$30,000

memo

House value: $150,000
Annual rent:
$9,000=$150,000*0.06

Young homeowner

New renter loses $900

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE
ECONOMY AS A WHOLE
The effects of house-price changes
on total consumption and consumer
welfare obviously depend on the demographics of the economy. One thing
that is certain is that although individual groups—notably the old, the
young, and renters—may experience
significant changes in their wealth,
the overall change in wealth may be
small, since the individual effects may,
to some degree, cancel each other in
aggregation. (See An Example of the
Effects of a Change in Housing Wealth.)
In our analysis, we find that a permanent house-price increase of 10 percent
leads to a slight decrease (0.9 percent)
in overall welfare.
So far in our analysis, we assumed
that house-price appreciation is the
same for all places. Obviously, housing

32 Q1 2006 Business Review

markets are local markets. If you live
in an area where house-price appreciation is strong and move into an area
with low appreciation, you can gain. In
the longer term, however, appreciation
across areas will likely equalize precisely because of this type of movements.
We do not consider these differential
regional markets here. (See What If
Housing Prices Fall? for a brief discussion of the situation in which housing
prices depreciate.)
CONCLUSIONS
Homeownership occupies a pedestal next to apple pie and motherhood as part of the American dream.
Spurred by demographic trends, a
strong economy, and preferential
government policy, the homeownership rate has increased significantly in
recent years. Today, close to 70 percent

of households own their houses, and
a substantial amount of households’
wealth is now tied to housing.
Do these statistics imply that
changes in housing prices will have
significant effects on households’ consumption and welfare? The answer is,
it depends on whom you’re asking.
Since a house is both an asset and
a necessary outlay (we all need to live
somewhere), house-price increases do
not make a typical household richer.
In other words, changes in house price
have limited effects for a typical household and for the overall economy. The
distributional effects, however, can be
large. In particular, increases in house
prices effectively transfer wealth from
renters to homeowners and from young
to old. By contrast, decreases in house
prices transfer wealth from homeowners to renters and from old to young.
BR

www.philadelphiafed.org

What If Housing Prices Fall?

S

o far, we have focused our attention on
the effects of house-price appreciation,
drawing on the recent experience of the
residential housing market. A natural
question is: What happens if house prices depreciate? This question is especially
important in light of recent concerns of a possible housing bubble in the U.S.
A housing bubble here means that house price is
significantly higher than its fundamental value. There
are several common ways of thinking about housing’s
fundamental value. One is to consider the ratio of housing prices to rents, an equivalent to the price-to-dividend
ratio for stocks. Since rent is a measure of the flow of
housing services, in the long run, there should be a stable
relationship between rents and housing prices. Another
way is to consider the ratio of housing prices to household income. Of course, regulatory and tax changes can
alter the long-run relationship between rents and housing
prices as well as income and housing prices. Interested
readers can read articles by Joshua Gallin (2003, 2004),
and Charles Himmelberg, Christopher Mayer, and Todd
Sinai (2005), among many others.
Our argument applies equally to the situation with
house-price depreciation. Middle-aged homeowners’ consumption will remain least responsive to the decline in
house price for the same reasons discussed earlier. Young
homeowners have to cut their consumption, since they
can no longer rely on home equity to help smooth con-

www.philadelphiafed.org

sumption. Note that these homeowners do not have much
liquid savings they can cut. Similarly, old homeowners,
who are already depleting their savings to support consumption, also need to cut their consumption now that
they are not as wealthy as they used to be. Renters, by
contrast, will increase their consumption, since they now
pay less in rent and do not need to save as much as they
used to in order to buy a house.
Despite the decline in consumption, young homeowners may still benefit from a depreciation in house prices if the decline in their future housing cost is significant
enough to offset the short-term drop in consumption due
to their worsened liquidity. Middle-aged and especially
old homeowners, on the other hand, are worse off because
the decline in housing costs for their remaining life may
not be enough to compensate them for the decline in
their wealth. Renters, by contrast, are strictly better off,
since they suffer no wealth loss, yet benefit from lower
future housing cost.
If the house-price depreciation becomes too severe,
however, many homeowners may choose to default on
their mortgage. Things would then become more complicated. Those who had more equity before the depreciation would obviously lose more financially. However, since
lenders may decide not to lend to these people in the
future, those households with longer expected life spans
(generally the young and middle-aged) will suffer more
from the reduced access to future credit.

Business Review Q1 2006 33

REFERENCES

Bajari, Patrick, C. Lanier Benkard,
and John Krainer. “House Prices and
Consumer Welfare,” Journal of Urban
Economics, forthcoming.
Benjamin, John, Peter Chinloy, and
Donald G. Jud. “Real Estate Versus
Financial Wealth in Consumption,”
Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29 3 (2004), pp. 342-54.
Brayton, Flint, and Peter Tinsley. “A
Guide to FRB/US,” Federal Reserve
Board Finance and Discussion Series
Working Paper 1996-42 (October).

Cocco, Joao F. “Portfolio Choice in the
Presence of Housing,” Review of Financial Studies (2005), pp. 535-67.
Gallin, Joshua. “The Long-Run Relationship between House Prices and
Rents,” Federal Reserve Board Finance
and Economics Discussion Series
2004-50.
Gallin, Joshua. “The Long-Run Relationship between House Prices and
Income: Evidence from Local Housing Markets,” Federal Reserve Board
Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2003-17.

Himmelberg, Charles, Christopher
Mayer, and Todd Sinai. “Assessing
High House Prices: Bubbles, Fundamentals and Misperceptions,” Columbia University Working Paper (September 2005).
Lehnert, Andreas. “Housing, Consumption, and Credit Constraints,”
Federal Reserve Board Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2004-63.
Li, Wenli. “Moving Up: Trends
in Homeownership and Mortgage
Indebtedness,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia Business Review (First
Quarter 2005), pp. 26-34.

Campbell, John, and Joao F. Cocco.
“Household Risk Management and
Optimal Mortgage Choice,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 118 (2004), pp.
1149-94.

Gervais, Martin. “Housing Taxation
and Capital Accumulation,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 49, 7 (2002), pp.
1461-89.

Campbell, John, and Joao F. Cocco.
“How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence from Micro Data,”
Harvard University and London Business School Working Paper.

Glaeser, Edward. “Comments and Discussion on Karl E. Case’s Real Estate
and the Macroeconomy,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 2 (2000),
pp. 146-50.

Sinai, Todd, and Nicholas S. Souleles.
“Owner-Occupied Housing as a Hedge
Against Rent Risk,” Quarterly Journal
of Economics, forthcoming.

Carson, Joseph G. “Home Appraisal:
Housing Cycle Should Continue
to Fuel Consumer Spending,”
Global Economic Research, www.
alliancebernstein.com.

Greenspan, Alan, and James Kennedy. “Estimates of Home Mortgage
Originations, Repayments, and Debt
on One-to-Four Family Residences,”
Federal Reserve Board Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2005-41.

Yao, Rui, and Harold H. Zhang.
“Optimal Consumption and Portfolio
Choices with Risky Housing and Borrowing Constraints,” Review of Financial Studies, 18 (Spring 2005),
pp. 197-239.

Case, Karl E., John M. Quigley, and
Robert T. Shiller. “Comparing Wealth
Effects: The Stock Market versus the
Housing Market,” University of California Working Paper.

34
34 Q1
Q1 2006
2006 Business
Business Review
Review

Li, Wenli, and Rui Yao. “The LifeCycle Effects of House Price Changes,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Working Paper 05-7 (2005).

Gyourko, Joseph, and Joseph Tracy.
“A Look at Real Housing Prices and
Incomes: Some Implications for Housing Affordability and Quality,” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York Economic
Policy Review, 5 (1999), pp. 63-77.

www.philadelphiafed.org
www.philadelphiafed.org

Recent Developments in Consumer Credit
and Payments

O

conference summary

n September 29 and 30, 2005, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s Research
Department and Payment Cards Center
organized the fourth in a series of conferences
exploring new academic research on the topic of
consumer credit and payments. Nearly 100 participants
attended the conference, which included seven research
papers on topics such as the design of consumer
bankruptcy law, predatory lending, consumers’ choice of
borrowing terms and indebtedness, the function of credit
reporting agencies, and pricing in credit card and ATM
networks.

Keynote speaker Gary H. Stern,
president of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis and current chairman of the Federal Reserve System’s
Financial Services Policy Committee,
opened the conference.
Stern began his remarks by pointing to the increasing quantity and
quality of research on consumer credit

This summary was prepared by Ronel
Elul, Joanna Ender, Bob Hunt, and
James McGrath. Elul and Hunt are senior
economists in the Research Department of
the Philadelphia Fed. Ender is a research
analyst in Research. McGrath is an
industry specialist in the Bank’s Payment
Cards Center. The conference agenda,
papers, and presentations can be found
at www.philadelphiafed.org/econ/conf/
consumercreditandpayments/index.html.

www.philadelphiafed.org

and payments. While the Federal Reserve System is a significant producer
of research in this area, it is also an
important consumer because it acts as
a provider and, in some instances, a
regulator of payment services. As with
monetary economics, good research
informs good policy decisions, and
this can be especially important when
research challenges the conventional
wisdom.
Next Stern described some of the
differences between the objectives of
private providers of payment services
(profit maximization) and the Fed,
which is to maximize social welfare.
In particular, the Fed’s mission is to
encourage the efficiency, accessibility,
and integrity of the payment system.
Its ability to make improvements along

these dimensions depends on the nature of competition in these markets,
the significant network features of
most payment systems, and any publicgood aspects that arise in facilitating
payments. Thus, one rationale for the
Fed’s involvement in a payment market
might be the existence of significant
market failure—too little competition
or too little investment in security
or reliability, for example—that cannot be more easily addressed by other
means (such as regulation).1 When
such conditions no longer exist, however, perhaps the Fed should gradually
exit the market.
Does economic reasoning inform
the Fed’s choice of which payment
services to provide and on what scale?
Stern argued yes, pointing to the Fed’s
recent decision to reduce its check-processing operations, which accounts for
the majority of the System’s staffing.
The national check-processing market
is declining about 10 percent each
year. If the Fed does not downsize, it
will account for an ever-growing share
of the business. But the Fed has determined that there is no market failure
in this market that would justify its
becoming an increasingly important
provider. Nor are there significant
economies of scope between its checkprocessing operations and its other
payment businesses.
In response, the Fed has decided
to reduce its check-processing capacity

Stern pointed out an additional rationale
would be the existence of significant economies
of scope between the Fed’s retail and wholesale
payment business (Fedwire), but such economies
must be rigorously demonstrated.
1

Business Review Q1 2006 35

while adjusting its prices to ensure that
it recovers the full cost of providing
these services. The Fed also supported
the recently enacted Check 21 law,
which will facilitate the electronic
presentment of checks, thereby reducing the need to process and ship paper
checks.
The market for automated clearinghouse (ACH) transactions has also
experienced significant change, and
the Fed is adapting. On the one hand,
demand has grown dramatically, a situation that requires significant ongoing
investment. On the other hand, private-sector providers have consolidated
and are now increasingly competitive.
While the Fed remains a dominant
provider, its market share has fallen
over time. Improvements in information-processing technology, combined
with significant economies of scale,
have reduced the cost of ACH transactions, leading the Fed to reduce prices
66 percent over the past decade.
In each of these cases, economic
research has aided the Fed’s decisionmaking. Stern offered some examples
of how economic research could influence the Fed’s policy decisions in the
payments arena in the future. First,
what is the efficacy of alternatives
to the Fed’s provision of retail payment services when there are market
failures? For example, should the Fed
play a more significant role in standard
setting, even where it is not an active
service provider? Second, how will
the electronification of checks affect
the market structure and competitive
conditions of the check processing
business? Third, are the existing theoretical models of payment networks
adequate for making policy decisions
about whether and how to regulate
interchange and other fees that arise
in credit and debit card transactions?
More economic research in each of
these areas would help to inform policymakers and improve social welfare.

36 Q1 2006 Business Review

Do Consumers Choose the
Right Credit Contracts?
In the first paper presented,
Nicholas Souleles, of the University of
Pennsylvania, reported the results of a
study (with Sumit Agarwal, Souphala
Chomsisengphet, and Chunlin Liu)
that examined consumers’ choice between two credit card contracts and
their subsequent borrowing decisions
in the period 1997 to 1999.2 A large

more than consumers who chose the
card without the annual fee. Almost
half of these borrowers (44 percent)
paid interest on an average balance
of $500 or more during the period
studied. More than half of consumers
choosing the no fee contract did not
carry a balance at any time during the
two-year period. On average at least,
consumers would appear to be making
rational choices about loan contracts.

Improvements in information-processing
technology have reduced the cost of ACH
transactions, leading the Fed to reduce prices
66 percent over the past decade.
U.S. bank offered consumers a choice
between two credit cards: one with an
annual fee (about $20) but a lower interest rate and another with no annual
fee but a higher interest rate (about
three percentage points higher). Consumers were free to switch from one
contract to the other at any time.
To minimize their total borrowing
costs, consumers expecting to borrow
a large amount should choose the contract with the annual fee and a lower
rate. Conversely, consumers who do
not expect to borrow very much should
choose the card without an annual
fee. Did consumers choose rationally?
When consumers chose a contract that
turned out to be more expensive for
them, how likely were they to switch
contracts?
Souleles and his co-authors found
that, on average, consumers who chose
the card with an annual fee (and lower
interest rate) subsequently borrowed

“Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit
Contracts?,” mimeo, University of Pennsylvania
(2005). This paper was previously circulated
under the title “How Well Do Consumers
Forecast Their Future Borrowing?”
2

After the fact, however, some
consumers would have done better had
they chosen the other contract. For
example, 24 percent of consumers who
paid the annual fee never borrowed at
all. Among consumers who did not pay
the annual fee, 12 percent paid interest on an average balance of $1,200
a month or more. In total, about 40
percent of consumers chose a contract
that turned out to be more expensive
(56 percent paying the annual fee
and 21 percent who didn’t). Are these
mistakes? Or is it that consumers’ borrowing was not what they anticipated
it would be?
To explore the possibility that
consumers are making mistakes, Souleles and his co-authors examined a
subset of consumers who also had substantial deposits at the bank. The idea
is that these customers have ample
liquid funds to help them manage an
expense shock, so we would not expect
them to borrow much on their cards or
to pay the annual fee. Not surprisingly,
only 22 percent of these consumers do
pay the annual fee (compared to 55
percent for the entire sample). What is
surprising, however, is that 10 percent

www.philadelphiafed.org

of these liquid customers who did not
pay the annual fee also paid interest
on an average balance of $1,200 a
month or more. These customers chose
a contract that turned out to be more
expensive because they borrowed a
significant amount, and yet it seems
unlikely this was due to unanticipated
shocks. The authors concluded that
unanticipated borrowing does not explain all of the patterns in the data
Next, the authors explored
whether consumers are likely to choose
the more affordable contract when the
cost of mistakes is higher. In particular,
they calculated the interest consumers
would have saved if they had paid the
annual fee to benefit from the lower
interest rate on their card. When the
interest savings (net of the annual fee)
was less than $26, about 37 percent of
consumers chose the wrong contract.
But when the interest savings exceeded
$300, only 7 percent of consumers
chose the wrong contract. Examining the small share of consumers who
changed their contracts, the authors
found that the majority of those initially chose a contract that turned out
to be more costly than the alternative.
They also found that the probability
that a consumer changes his or her
contract is significantly affected by the
net savings that result after the switch.
The discussant, John Leahy, of
New York University, suggested that
Souleles and his co-authors present a
formal model of consumers’ contract
choices to help interpret the pattern of
mistakes they report. Leahy suggested
that borrowers might choose the more
costly contract to discourage themselves from borrowing in the future.
This is an example of a commitment
problem explored by other researchers in the literature. Leahy also noted
that only 5 percent of borrowers’ errors cost them more than $25 a year;
only 1 percent made errors that cost
them more than $100 a year; and even

www.philadelphiafed.org

less, 0.1 percent, made errors that cost
more than $300 a year. Such low costs
suggest that many errors may simply
be due to consumers’ inattention. It
is even possible that some consumers
forgot they had the option to switch.
For those who did pay the annual fee,
such costs are sunk until the fee comes
due a year later.
Explaining the Rise in
Consumer Bankruptcies
in the U.S.
Igor Livshits, of the University
of Western Ontario, presented the
results of his research (co-written with
James MacGee and Michèle Tertilt),
which tested a variety of explanations
for the dramatic rise in bankruptcy
filings in the U.S. over the last quarter
century.3 The basic facts are as follows:
(1) the number of filings increased
from 1.4 per thousand adults in 1970
to 8.5 per thousand in 2002; (2) filers’
ratio of unsecured debt-to-income has
increased; and (3) the average real interest rate on unsecured credit hardly
changed.
The authors constructed a lifecycle model of consumers who borrow
and sometimes default and calibrated
it to match the behavior of borrowers
in the U.S. economy during the late
1990s. They used the model to explore
the effects of many proposed explanations for the rise in the bankruptcy filing rate that occurred after 1980. They
considered a variety of possible explanations for the rise in the bankruptcy
filing rate and concluded that while no
single explanation is fully consistent
with the evidence, a combination of
factors, including a decline in stigma
associated with filing for bankruptcy,
comes reasonably close.

“Accounting for the Rise in Consumer
Bankruptcies,” mimeo, University of Western
Ontario (2005).

3

Livshits and his colleagues first
considered whether an increase in “uncertainty” can explain the patterns in
the data. They found that increases in
the magnitude or likelihood of expense
shocks (such as out-of-pocket medical
expenses) or income shocks (such as
unemployment spells) would increase
the bankruptcy filing rate, but it would
also reduce the ratio of unsecured
debt-to-income, which did not happen.
The authors also considered shocks to
family structure (such as divorce or an
unplanned pregnancy) but found that
these did not rise after the early 1980s.
They did find that the decline in the
share of the adult population that is
married would explain a small part of
the rise in the filing rate. They found
no effect from changes in age structure
of the population.
Livshits and his co-authors then
turned to changes in the credit market
environment. They rejected the potential effect of the changes in U.S. bankruptcy law introduced in 1978, arguing
that Canada also experienced a rise in
bankruptcy filings in the absence of a
change in its laws. They found the relaxation of binding usury ceilings after
1978 can explain a significant rise in
bankruptcy filings and an increase in
the debt-to-income ratio, but it would
also imply an increase in the real cost
of unsecured credit that is not observed in the data.4 They are also skeptical that in practice the usury ceilings
are sufficiently restrictive to generate
such effects.
They did find two factors that
seem to be important in explaining the

In Marquette National Bank v. First Omaha
Service Corp, 439 U.S. 299 (1978), the Supreme
Court determined that lenders could charge interest rates permitted under the laws of the state
where they were located, rather than where
their customers were located. Thereafter, states
competed to attract lenders to their jurisdiction
by raising their usury ceilings.
4

Business Review Q1 2006 37

rise in bankruptcy filings but which
cannot individually explain the patterns in the data. First, a decline in the
cost of underwriting unsecured credit
(perhaps due to rapid improvements
in information technology) would increase borrowing but would have little
effect on bankruptcy filing rates and is
associated with a significant decline in
average real interest rates. On the other hand, a decline in the stigma associated with filing for bankruptcy would
indeed explain a significant share of
the increase in filings but would also
increase real interest rates and reduce
the ratio of debt-to-income.5
In short, no single explanation
seems to fit the trends observed in
the U.S. economy over the last two
decades. Livshits and his colleagues
then asked what combination of
factors would explain the observed
trends. They argue that increases in
both expense and income uncertainty,
combined with a decline in underwriting costs and stigma, fit the data fairly
well. In their simulation, increases in
uncertainty play a relatively small role,
while a decline in stigma is the primary driver of the rise in bankruptcy
filings. At the same time, a decline in
underwriting costs offsets the effect of
stigma on interest rates and the ratio
of debt-to-income. The authors concluded that a decline in stigma plays
a very important role in the story and
suggested that it should be the focus of
future research.
The discussant, Satyajit Chatterjee, of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, argued that the paper is
an important advance but its results
should be interpreted cautiously. For

example, when the model is calibrated
to the data, the implied recovery rate
for debt in bankruptcy is about 28
percent, which seems rather high for
a model that seeks to explain filings
under Chapter 7 (discharges) rather
than Chapter 13 (workouts). In the
paper, this is explicitly modeled as

In their calibrations, the level of stigma required to explain the filing rate of the early
1980s is equivalent to the welfare lost from a
28 percent decline in consumption.

6

5

38 Q1 2006 Business Review

Predatory lending is
less likely to occur as
the lending market
becomes more
competitive.
a wage garnishment, but Chatterjee
suggested that its high value probably
reflects other costs omitted from the
model, such as the nonexempt assets
subject to liquidation by the court. He
also wondered how the results would
change if the assumption of a perfectly
competitive loan market was relaxed.
Predatory Lending
The next speaker, Bilge Yilmaz,
of the University of Pennsylvania, presented the results of his research (with
Philip Bond and David Musto) on the
topic of predatory lending. They begin
by offering a definition of the practice
and investigating the conditions under
which it can occur.6
The authors define predatory
lending as a loan the lender knows
will, on average, make the borrower
worse off. But why would a borrower
choose a loan that was likely to make
him or her worse off? In their model
of a rational loan market, it must be

Philip Bond, David Musto, and Bilge Yilmaz,
“Predatory Lending in a Rational World,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working
Paper 06-2 (2006).

the case that lenders know more about
a borrower’s future income prospects
than does the borrower. Predatory
lending has two obvious policy implications. First, if borrowers are choosing
loans that are likely to make them
worse off, credit is being misallocated
in a way that may be socially wasteful. Second, predatory lending may
increase the inequality in the distribution of wealth.
Yilmaz and his co-authors develop
a model in which a borrower applies for
a loan using his or her home as collateral. The lender has some information
about whether the borrower is more
likely a “good” or “bad” risk. Borrowers who are good risks are more likely
to earn sufficient income in the future
to repay the loan than are borrowers who are bad risks. Based on that
knowledge, the lender makes a loan
offer, which the borrower either accepts or declines. If the loan cannot be
repaid, the lender recoups at least some
of the proceeds by foreclosing on the
borrower’s home.
Their first insight, according to
Yilmaz, is that in order for predatory
lending to occur, it must be the case
that good and bad risks receive the
same loan terms. In other words, the
equilibrium must be a pooling equilibrium. If that were not the case, the
lender’s superior information would
be revealed by his offer: The bad risks
would realize they faced a higher risk
of defaulting on the loan than they
originally thought. In that case, the
bad risks would not take out the loan.
When is predatory lending likely
to occur? Yilmaz and his co-authors
show that several conditions are
required. First, predatory lending requires that lenders be better informed
than borrowers about the riskiness
of the loan. Second, collateral values
must be sufficiently high, so that lenders do not lose too much if they lend
to bad borrowers who subsequently

www.philadelphiafed.org

default.7 Third, predatory lending is
less likely to occur as the lending market becomes more competitive because
rival lenders tend to cherry-pick the
best borrowers, unraveling the pooling
equilibrium.8
The authors examine three policies that may affect predatory lending.
They argue that interest-rate ceilings
(usury laws) can sometimes help reduce predatory lending. If the ceiling is
set sufficiently low, lenders cannot recoup the cost of their inefficient loans
to the bad risks. Of course, such a benefit must be weighed against the other
distortions usury ceilings can cause.
Next, they consider the Community
Reinvestment Act, which requires
banks to lend in underserved and underprivileged areas. The authors suggest that this can also help break down
predatory lending if it increases competition in the lending market in such
areas. Note this might imply less actual
lending in these areas, rather than
more, because the bad risks choose not
to borrow. Finally, they consider the
Equal Credit Opportunity Act, which
specifies that certain factors (for example, age, race, or gender) may not be
considered in underwriting or pricing
loans. If such restrictions do facilitate a
pooling equilibrium, predatory lending
may become more likely.
Discussant Andrew Winton, of
the University of Minnesota, pointed
to some alternative explanations
of why a borrower might accept a
predatory loan. For example, borrowers might not understand the “fine

They point out that loans that increase the
value of collateral, such as home-improvement
loans, may therefore increase the prospects for
predatory lending.
7

Still, as long as loans are fully collateralized,
the authors show that predatory lending remains a possibility even under highly competitive conditions.

print” of loan contracts, or lenders may
misrepresent loan terms. Borrowers
may exhibit excessive optimism or too
heavily discount the costs of a loan
contract that occur in the future. Each
is an example of predatory lending in
a less than rational world. Winton also
suggested that, in addition to foreclosures, the authors should examine
other costs of predatory loans, including excessive loan payments.
Credit Bureaus,
Relationship Banking,
and Loan Repayment
Martin Brown, of the Swiss National Bank, discussed his work with
Christian Zehnder on the function and
effects of credit reporting agencies.9 In
particular, they studied the extent to
which credit registries improve repayment behavior, an idea that is widely
accepted but has not been rigorously
tested in empirical work. They also
examined another mechanism for
disciplining borrowers—relationship
lending, which involves repeated interactions between a specific borrower
and lender. One question they sought
to answer was the degree to which
these two mechanisms are substitutes
or complements.
Brown and Zehnder developed
an experiment in which multiple borrowers and lenders interact with each
other in a computerized lending game.
There are more lenders than borrowers, so the loan market is relatively
competitive. The authors examined
the performance of their experimental
loan market along two dimensions:
whether or not a credit bureau exists
and whether or not borrowers and
lenders can recognize each other. Note
that if borrowers and lenders cannot

8

www.philadelphiafed.org

“Credit Registries, Relationship Banking, and
Loan Repayment,” IEW Working Paper 240,
University of Zurich (2005).
9

recognize each other, they cannot engage in relationship lending.
Suppose that borrowers and lenders cannot recognize each other. This
is consistent with a lending market in
which borrowers are highly mobile.
If there is no credit bureau, borrowers are essentially anonymous. In that
case, the experimental results show
the market performs extremely poorly
– borrowers frequently default so few
lenders offer any funds. Next, Brown
and Zehnder introduce a credit bureau.
This consists of a list lenders receive
in every period that documents each
borrower’s previous loans and repayment behavior (no other information
is provided). With the bureau in place,
the market functions dramatically better, for most rounds of the game. Repayment rates and lending volume are
significantly higher.
Brown and Zehnder attribute
this improvement in results to the
disciplining effect of credit registries;
borrowers are willing to repay in order
to maintain reputations and hence retain access to future credit. As further
evidence, they point to the following
detail from their experimental results.
In the final periods of the game, the
market breaks down even in the presence of a credit bureau. Borrowers recognize that they have no further need
to maintain their reputation and lenders, recognizing this, decline to lend.
Next, Brown and Zehnder considered the case where borrowers and
lenders can recognize each other,
which makes ongoing lending relationships possible between specific borrowers and lenders. They found that
even in the absence of a credit bureau,
the loan market functions very well.
Thus lending relationships also appear to act as an effective mechanism
for disciplining borrowers. When a
credit bureau is introduced in this
environment, there is a slight increase
in performance, but the difference is

Business Review Q1 2006 39

not statistically significant. Brown and
Zehnder conclude that credit bureaus
and relationship lending are largely
substitutes.
Discussant Paul S. Calem (LoanPerformance) argued that the paper
raises several potential policy implications. It clearly provides evidence of
the contributions that credit bureaus
can make—they make it possible for
consumers to invest in their reputations as good borrowers. This, in turn,
increases the availability and pricing
of credit.
But Calem pointed out that the
experiment is highly stylized so it is
important to place the results in the
context of actual credit markets. For
example, in the U.S. at least, there
are markets in which credit bureaus
dominate (consumer credit) and other
markets where relationship lending is
more important (small-business lending). In addition, he pointed out that
while relationship lending may serve as
another mechanism for enforcing repayment, it does have some drawbacks.
For example, it may suffer from “lockin” where the cost of changing lending
relationships results in less competitive pricing. Returning to Brown and
Zehnder’s experiment, Calem noted it
would be interesting to know whether
the presence of a credit bureau has
a significant effect on the pricing of
loans or whether the incremental contribution of credit bureaus depends on
competitive conditions.
Finally, while the paper is silent
on these questions, Calem pointed
out that the actual content of credit
bureau files may be important factors.
Brown and Zehnder’s credit bureaus
include both positive and negative
credit information, but many bureaus
around the world include only negative
information. In addition, the optimal
length of credit histories included in
bureau files is open to debate. If records are kept too long, marginal bor-

40 Q1 2006 Business Review

rowers may feel that their record can
never be rehabilitated, and this would
weaken the discipline that credit bureaus are supposed to enable.
The Effects of Incomplete
Information on Consumer
Credit
Jonathan Zinman (Dartmouth
College) presented the results of his
work with Dean Karlan. They have
designed an empirical study that seeks
to identify adverse selection and moral
hazard in loan markets.10 In other
words, do higher interest rate loans
attract riskier clients? (This is known
as adverse selection.) Do higher inter-

among the clients who respond to the
offer, approximately 40 percent were
randomly given a low contract rate
instead (the remainder received the
original offer rate). Finally, half of the
applicants were randomly given a dynamic repayment incentive—assuming
the borrower repaid the current loan,
he or she would receive a favorable interest rate on subsequent loans over the
next year.
To test for adverse selection, Karlan and Zinman compared the repayment performance of two groups: borrowers who responded to the low offer
rate and borrowers who responded to
the high offer rate but subsequently

Credit bureaus make it possible for
consumers to invest in their reputations as
good borrowers. This, in turn, increases the
availability and pricing of credit.
est rate loans induce borrowers to take
more risks (i.e., moral hazard)? How
can the two be separately measured?
Despite an abundance of theoretical
work, there is remarkably little empirical research on these questions.
Karlan and Zinman implemented
their experiment through a South African lender specializing in providing
unsecured credit to the working poor.
Their typical loans are small ($150)
and the term is rather short (four
months). Their experiment consisted
of three stages. In the initial stage an
interest rate (the offer rate) was randomly assigned to a pool of potential
borrowers with similar observable
characteristics. This rate could be
either high or low. In the next stage,

“Observing Unobservables: Identifying Information Asymmetries with a Consumer Credit
Field Experiment,” Working Paper (2005).
10

received the lower contract rate. This
is the test for adverse selection. Since
both groups actually received the low
interest rate in this experiment, there
should be no effect of moral hazard.
The question remains: Do higher interest rates attract riskier borrowers
who care less about high rates because
they are less likely to repay the loan?
Next, the authors constructed
two tests for moral hazard. Recall that
moral hazard exists when the terms
of credit affect an individual’s incentives to repay his or her loan. Karlan
and Zinman begin by focusing only on
those borrowers who responded to the
high offer rate. This should remove
the effects of adverse selection, because these borrowers should initially
have the same expectations about
their prospects for repaying the loan.
In the first test, Karlan and Zinman
compared the repayment performance
of borrowers who actually received a
www.philadelphiafed.org

lower contract rate with those who
paid at the original offer rate. Moral
hazard would then show up if the second group—that with the higher interest rate—is more likely to default.
Karlan and Zinman also considered a second, potentially cleaner test
for the effects of moral hazard. Under
the first test the fact that one group is
paying a higher interest rate than the
other implies there is a higher repayment burden, which in itself may lead
to differences in subsequent repayment
behavior, even in the absence of moral
hazard. In their second test, Karlan
and Zinman compared the repayment
behavior of borrowers who were offered
the favorable rate on future loans with
those who were not.11 If those offered
this dynamic repayment incentive
perform better, this would also provide
evidence of moral hazard (since it reflects the effect of incentives on repayment behavior).
Karlan and Zinman found the
problem of asymmetric information
to be relevant in these loan markets.
They estimate that about 20 percent
of the overall default rate can be attributed to a combination of adverse
selection and moral hazard. Moreover,
the strongest evidence of moral hazard
is identified when examining the effect
of the dynamic repayment incentive—
a one-percentage-point decrease in the
cost of future loans reduces the default
rate on the current loan by about 4
percentage points. Interestingly, they
found that the particular type of information problem depended on the gender of the borrower. Lending to female
borrowers appeared to suffer from the
adverse selection problem, while lending to male borrowers appeared to suf-

Since both groups are currently paying the
same interest rate, there is no difference in repayment burden that may cloud the interpretation of the results.

fer from the moral hazard problem.
The discussant, Pierre-Andre
Chiappori (Columbia University),
stated this was extremely important
research. Distinguishing between
adverse selection and moral hazard is
important because each has distinct
welfare implications and policy prescriptions. He suggested the analysis
might benefit from a structural model.
In particular, he wondered about how
the competitive structure of the loan
markets might influence the results

Do higher interest rate
loans attract riskier
borrowers? Do higher
interest rate loans
induce borrowers to
take more risks?
and even the form of loan contracts.
Some people might not respond to
high rate offers because they receive
better offers elsewhere. What alternatives are available to potential borrows? Do these depend on gender? Can
that explain the differences in results
for men and women?
Pricing in Consumer
Payment Networks
Alexander Tieman (International Monetary Fund) presented a paper
co-authored with Wilko Bolt that
examines pricing behavior in two-sided
markets.12 A two-sided market is one
in which there are two distinct types
of end users that derive benefits from
interacting with each other, which is

For an accessible review of the literature,
see Bob Hunt’s 2003 Business Review article
at http://www.philadelphiafed.org/files/br/
brq203bh.pdf.
13

11

www.philadelphiafed.org

typically facilitated by a network or
platform. They focus on the concrete
example of a consumer payment network, such as Visa or MasterCard,
which facilitates transactions between
merchants and consumers.
Two-sided markets often exhibit
positive externalities. In the case of
payment networks, the value of holding a card for consumers is increasing
in the number of merchants willing to
accept the card. Conversely, the value
to merchants of agreeing to accept a
payment card is increasing the number
of consumers that are willing to use it.
Thus participants on each side of the
market would benefit from subsidies
that increase demand among participants on the other side. One role of
payment networks, then, is to coordinate the incentives offered to consumers and merchants.
Bolt and Tieman point out that
in such markets there is both a price
and a price structure. In this case, price
refers to the total cost of transactions
paid by the merchant and the consumer, while price structure refers to
the share of the total price that is paid
by each party. Both are set directly, or
indirectly, by the network. The distinction is important because it is possible
that one party, perhaps the consumer,
may not pay anything for the transaction or may even receive a subsidy for
using a payment card. This appears
to be the case for debit cards in the
Netherlands, for example. Such skewed
pricing structures are receiving a good
deal of scrutiny by antitrust authorities
around the world and are the focus of
a number of lawsuits in the U.S.
The economic literature on twosided networks is relatively new and
underdeveloped.13 Tieman points out

“Skewed Pricing in Two-Sided Markets: An
IO Approach,” DNB Working Paper 2004/13,
De Nederlandsche Bank, Amsterdam (2004).

12

Business Review Q1 2006 41

that in many theoretical models of
these markets, the equilibrium price
structure does not look like what we
often observe in consumer payment
networks. Instead of skewed pricing,
where one side of the market pays all
(or more) of the cost of a transaction,
these models tend to generate interior
pricing, where each side of the market
contributes to the cost of a transaction. In addition the share of total
transaction costs paid by one side of
the market is inversely related to the
relative price elasticity of demand.14
Put more simply, the side of the market whose demand is most sensitive to
changes in price bears the larger share
of the total cost of the transaction.
This is exactly opposite the intuition
learned from the microeconomic analysis of a traditional market.
In their paper, Bolt and Tieman
report that such results follow from
a particular assumption about the
properties of the demand curves (log
concavity). If a more traditional assumption about demand curves (constant elasticity of substitution) is used
instead, the results are very different.
In that case, the side of the market
that is least sensitive to price changes
will bear the larger share of total transaction costs. And if one side of the
market (e.g., consumers) is sufficiently
more sensitive to changes in prices
than the other (e.g., merchants), it will
bear none of the transactions costs.
Indeed, a profit-maximizing network
would choose to subsidize consumers,
financing the subsidy at least in part by
raising the price paid by merchants. In
short, their model derives a price structure that looks like what is observed in
many consumer payment networks.

By price elasticity, we mean the decline in
transaction volume, expressed in percentage
terms, induced by an increase in transaction
price, also expressed in percentage terms.
14

42 Q1 2006 Business Review

Next, Bolt and Tieman turned to
policy questions. How does the pricing
strategy of a profit-maximizing network
compare to that of a benevolent social
planner? They found that a social
planner would also choose a highly
skewed price structure, but a lower
total price than would a profit-maximizing network. Thus, a monopoly
payment network would result in too
few, rather than too many, transactions. In contrast, a social planner
would run the network at a loss, which
would require ongoing subsidies from

One role of
payment networks
is to coordinate the
incentives offered
to consumers and
merchants.
some other part of the economy. If the
network was required to break even,
it is likely that all the costs would be
recovered from prices charged on only
one side of the network.
Bolt and Tieman concluded that
the existence of skewed pricing in
itself does not justify intervention by
antitrust authorities, but a concern
for the overall price charged might.
This stands in contrast to the public
debate, which focuses primarily on
skewed pricing rather than on the total
prices charged by consumer payment
networks.
The discussant, Rafael Rob (University of Pennsylvania), distinguished
between the two types of equilibria
explored in models of this sort. Most
papers in the literature focus on an
interior equilibrium where not all
consumers and merchants adopt the
payment technology. Bolt and Tieman,
on the other hand, focus on the cor-

ner solutions where there is universal
adoption by one or both sides of the
market. Rob pointed out that models
in the existing literature can also generate corner solutions if the disparities
in price elasticities are sufficiently
great, but they may not have the same
properties as the ones explored by Bolt
and Tieman. Rob also pointed out that
this is a model of a monopoly provider
of payment services. While this is a
good approximation of the Dutch debit
card market, the U.S. credit and debit
card networks are a duopoly. It would
be interesting to explore whether the
results are sensitive to this distinction.
ATM Surcharges and
Consumer Welfare
Gautam Gowrisankaran (Washington University, St. Louis) presented
his paper with John Krainer that explores the potential gains and losses associated with the introduction of ATM
surcharges in the 1990s.15 Surcharges
are fees charged to consumers by owners of an ATM. Prior to 1996, ATM
surcharges were extremely rare, but
thereafter they became very common.
This change had two effects. On
the one hand, ATMs became more
profitable, which stimulated the deployment of ATMs and reduced the
distance consumers must travel in
order to access their deposit accounts.
On the other hand, consumers were
now required to pay for the privilege of
using at least some ATMs. In addition,
the increase in ATMs exceeded the
increase in transaction volume so that
the average number of transactions per
machine fell. Since most of the cost of
operating an ATM is fixed, the decline
in transaction volume implies that the

15
“The Welfare Consequences of ATM
Surcharges: Evidence from a Structural Entry
Model,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Working Paper 2005-01 (2005).

www.philadelphiafed.org

average cost of each transaction rose
significantly.
Gowrisankaran and Krainer asked
whether, on balance, consumers and
society were made better or worse off
by the introduction of ATM surcharges. In practice, this simple question
is very difficult to answer. To do so,
Gowrisankaran and Krainer painstakingly gathered a data set of ATM locations, potential ATM locations (grocery stores and banks), and population
in 32 counties along the border of two
states, Minnesota and Iowa. They
chose this area because, unlike Minnesota, Iowa enforced a no-surcharge
law throughout the 1990s. In principle,
differences in the deployment and use
of ATMs in these border counties can
be used to estimate the effects of a
surcharge ban. But to do so, Gowrisankaran and Krainer also had to develop
a structural model of the ATM market
and some novel approaches to estimating the parameters of the model.
To estimate their model
efficiently, the authors needed to avoid
calculating equilibrium outcomes
for every possible combination of
parameter values. While this has
been done for other models of entry,
Gowrisankaran and Krainer were at
a disadvantage—they did not know
what the prices (surcharges) were
in Minnesota. Their insight was to
estimate the entry model using data
from Iowa counties (where prices = 0)
and, using those coefficients, estimate
the effects of nonzero prices using data
from Minnesota counties.
Assuming that the fixed cost of
deploying ATMs and consumer preferences are similar in counties on either
side of the Minnesota-Iowa border,
the difference in the relative number

www.philadelphiafed.org

and geographic dispersion of ATMs
between the two states can be used to
infer something about the price elasticity of demand. All else equal, the
greater these differences, the less elastic is the demand curve for ATMs. In
the actual estimation, they found that
the probability a consumer will use a
given ATM falls equally as much if the

total surplus is 14 percent higher.
The discussant, James McAndrews (Federal Reserve Bank of New
York), pointed to one of the simplifying assumptions of the paper—that the
market for ATM transactions is independent of the market for other bank
services. If that assumption is relaxed,
differences in the market structure of

Since most of the cost of operating an ATM is
fixed, the decline in transaction volume implies
that the average cost of each transaction rose
significantly.
ATM is moved 1 kilometer away or she
is required to pay 8 to 10 cents more to
use it. They conclude that consumer
demand for transactions at ATMs is
price elastic.
Using estimates from their model,
Gowrisankaran and Krainer calculated
measures of consumer and producer
surplus that result under a no surcharge regime and one that permits
surcharging. They reported little
difference in the total surplus generated but significant differences in its
distribution. While fewer ATMs are
deployed in a no surcharge regime, the
estimated consumer surplus is about 10
percent higher (and producer surplus
10 percent lower) than in a regime
that permits surcharging. Transaction
volume is also about 16 percent higher
in the no surcharge regime. They also
derived the first best outcome, where
consumers are charged only the marginal cost of a transaction and fixed
costs are recovered via lump sum taxes. Compared to the surcharge regime,
there are 50 percent more ATMs and
38 percent more transactions, and the

banking between the two states might
influence ATM deployment and pricing decisions. It is then possible that at
least some of the effects attributed to a
surcharge ban might actually be driven
by differences in banking structure.
McAndrews presented evidence
that banking markets in the Minnesota border counties are indeed different from those in the Iowa border
counties. He conjectured that Minnesota’s single-office banks were likely
to charge lower foreign fees.16 On the
other hand, he conjectured that since
the banking market in Iowa was more
concentrated, surcharges may be lower
because competition for deposits is less
intense.17 The net effect, McAndrews
argued, is that the benefits of surcharging may be exaggerated. BR

16
Foreign fees are fees a bank charges its own
customers when they use an ATM the bank
does not own.

One reason banks may surcharge consumers
that are not their own customers is to encourage
them to become customers.
17

Business Review Q1 2006 43