View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A review by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Business
Conditions
September 1972

Contents
Directory of
international organizations
Th e F a rm C re d it S y ste m

2
10

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Directory of
international organizations

2

It is almost impossible to read a major
newspaper thoroughly nowadays without
coming across names of organizations in­
volved in international economic affairs.
But even as this form of repetition increases
public consciousness of these organizations,
it is often difficult to retain a clear under­
standing of the functions of the many and
diverse groups involved.
What has given rise to the proliferation
of international organization since World
War I has been an increasing awareness by
national governments that the well-being
of their economies are interdependent in
matters of currency and trade. In the mod­
ern era of instant communications and jetage “shoulder rubbing,” more and more
governments have come to recognize the
need for formal rules to regulate multina­
tional economic relationships. To date, it
would seem, international organizations
have proved the most effective mediums for
accomplishing the objectives.
The purpose of this directory is to identify
major international organizations now in
operation, and to describe briefly their pur­
poses and functions. It is hoped that such a
listing will provide the interested reader
with a concise “Who’s Who” in the world
of international organizations.
The directory divides the organizations
into three categories based on their primary
area of involvement. Although the stated
objective and functions of any particular
organization might indicate an overlap into




more than one category, the three-part
breakdown remains useful for an overview.
The categories are:
• Organizations whose primary interest
relates to monetary policy and financial
matters.
• Organizations whose primary interest
relates to development financing and
economic and technical assistance.
• Organizations whose primary interest
relates to international trade and re­
gional development.

Monetary organizations
Bank for International Settlements (BIS).
Most currently viable international organi­
zations are of post-World War II vintage.
The BIS, however, originated in 1930, grow­
ing out of the need for an organization to
promote international cooperation among
European central banks—a need stemming
from difficulties experienced in the interna­
tional administration of Germany’s World
War I reparations payments.
The bank, located in Basle, Switzerland,
survived World War II, the reconstruction,
and recurring international financial crises,
and today continues as a highly-regarded
institution for the coordination of certain
multinational monetary arrangements, and
serves as a pipeline for the exchange of in­
formation among major central banks.

Business Conditions, September 1972

Committee of Twenty (C-20). (See Interna­
tional Monetary Fund.) After the currency
realignments in December 1971, the United
States proposed that the International
Monetary Fund develop a research and
policy group more broadly based than the
Group of Ten, one that would include rep­
resentation from the less developed coun­
tries. A proposal to this effect was approved
by the International Monetary Fund mem­
bership, and the Committee on Reform of
the International Monetary System and Re­
lated Issues (C-20) met for the first time
in September 1972 at the annual meetings
of the International Monetary Fund in
Washington, D.C. Membership in the 20nation group is made up of the Executive
Board of the International Monetary Fund
—currently appointees of France, Germany,
India, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the
United States—and 14 representatives elect­
ed by the remaining 118 members.
Group of Ten (G-10). (See International
Monetary Fund.) In 1962, ten major indus­
trial countries—Belgium, Canada, France,
Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands,
Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the
United States—agreed to support the In­
ternational Monetary Fund’s General Ar­
rangements to Borrow by lending their own
currencies should that become necessary. Be­
cause of the group’s dominant economic
stature, it evolved into an important poli­
cy-making body within the International
Monetary Fund. For example, the mone­
tary realignments of December 1971 were
basically a product of G-10 negotiations.
International Monetary Fund (IMF).
First envisaged in July 1944 at the United
Nations Monetary and Financial Confer­




ence1 at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire,
and implemented in December 1945, the
International Monetary Fund today is the
world’s foremost organization dealing with
international money matters. IMF policies
formed the foundation for the postwar re­
covery of the international monetary sys­
tem by fostering two goals simultaneously.
One was to provide for the convertibility of
national currencies in an environment of
international stability. The other was to in­
sure that individual nations could pursue
independent monetary and fiscal policies.
The IMF accomplished these goals through
rules of conduct designed to promote the
orderly operation of world money markets.
Among the most important of these were
procedures for borrowing reserves from the
IMF, permissible exchange rate adjust­
ments, the establishment of currency values
in terms of gold or the U. S. dollar, and the
elimination of exchange controls.
Over time, the IMF has been instrumen­
tal in developing policies conducive to the
smooth functioning of the international
monetary system and growth of world trade.
It acts as a forum for cooperation among
nations in monetary matters, and through
its large staff of experts, as an advisory
body particularly to small, developing na­
tions. Since 1970, the IMF has acted as the
administrator of the special drawing rights
(SDRs)—a scheme launched to provide
member nations with additional interna­
tional reserves.
In 1972, the Fund, with a membership of
124 nations as of September 22, 1972, is un­
dergoing profound change, as is the inter­
national monetary system itself. The sus­
pension of convertibility of the dollar into
1The United Nations did not come into being
until June 26, 1945—the reference to “United Na­
tions” refers to a coalition of anti-Axis nations.

3

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

gold in August 1971, the temporary floating
of most major currencies, and the renewed
imposition of currency and exchange con­
trols have struck at the heart of the IMF as
it was originally constituted. But not only
does the Fund continue to function, it has
become the rallying point for governments
looking for a new and reliable way to re­
vitalize the international monetary system.
The Fund’s day-to-day operations are
supervised by the 20-member IMF Execu­
tive Board, which is made up of six ap­
pointees of major members and 14 elected
representatives of the remaining members.
IMF headquarters are in Washington, D.C.
The United States has dominated the op­
eration of the Fund since its inception. But
this influence may have wained somewhat
over the past year due to the spreading
power base represented by the Committee of
Twenty, and the increasing economic power
centered in Western Europe and Japan.

Financial assistance organizations
Asian Development Bank (ADB). The
ADB headquarters were established in the
Philippines in 1966 primarily to provide
technical assistance and loans for capital
and infrastructure development within non­
communist Asian nations. Thirty-six coun­
tries are members of the bank—14 of them
are non-Asian, primarily North American
and European. A major part of the financial
backing for the bank comes from Japan and
the United States.

4

European Investment Bank (EIB). When
the Treaty of Rome of 1957 created the
European Economic Community, it also
established the European Investment Bank,




commonly called the European Bank.
Originally, the EIB was thought of as a
regional development bank that would re­
strict its lending activity to the six members
of the Economic Community. It has since
expanded its activities to associate members,
Greece and Turkey, and other Communityassociated nations—mainly former colonies
of Common Market members.
The bank provides funds for development
projects in less developed regions of the
Community, for modernization or develop­
mental projects of interest to all Common
Market members, and for the furtherance
of progress within the Community itself.
Located in Luxembourg and directed by of­
ficials appointed by members of the Euro­
pean Economic Community, the European
Bank functions as an autonomous public
institution within the Community.
Inter-Am erican Developm ent Bank
(IDB). Focusing on Latin America, this re­

gional development bank grew out of pres­
sures within Latin America for the estab­
lishment of a development bank specific to
the region. It began in 1959, with head­
quarters in Washington. About 40 percent
of the capital subscription comes from the
United States. Development loans may be
for social or economic purposes.
International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development (IBRD). This is another

world organization that grew out of the
Bretton Woods Conference. Formed as a
companion institution to the International
Monetary Fund—and, like it, headquartered
in Washington—the International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development—often
called the World Bank—was established to
provide IBRD-member governments with a

Business Conditions, September 1972

source of long-term capital for the purpose
of economic development. The bank ob­
tains funds through subscriptions by mem­
ber countries, bond offerings on various
world capital markets, the resale of loans,
and from earnings of active loans. From
its inception through mid-1971, the World
Bank had made loans of more than $16
billion in 89 countries.
International Development Association
(IDA). An adjunct to the World Bank, the

International Development Association, lo­
cated in Washington, and administratively
a part of the World Bank, was established
in 1960 to provide long-term economic de­
velopment loans specifically to the less de­
veloped countries. A major distinction be­
tween IBRD and IDA loans is that IDA
loans are restricted to less developed coun­
tries, and repayment and interest terms are
less rigorous than is the case for IBRD
conventional loans. Developed countries
supply most of IDA’s capital subscription.
International Finance Corporation (IFC).
The International Finance Corporation, an­
other Washington-based and -administered
adjunct of the World Bank, was established
in 1956 to provide private firms in less de­
veloped countries with either loans or equity
capital. Capital funds of the IFC come
primarily from subscriptions of developed
countries.
World Bank. See International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development.

Trade organizations
The organizations in this category have
their roots in trade agreements. They are



mainly regional in orientation, having been
formed as special trading blocs. Some have
long since gone far beyond strictly matters
of trade, and today function on principles
of multinational economic cooperation and
have as a goal full economic integration.
The Andean Group Common Market.
In 1966, after it became clear that the fiveyear-old Latin American Free Trade Asso­
ciation was not progressing as rapidly as
had been anticipated, the Andean group
of nations took a small-scale approach to
trade problems through a declaration of
common objectives. In 1969, the common
market concept was established formally
with a 15- to 20-year plan to reduce internal
trade barriers, to set common external tar­
iffs, and to develop a common approach to
regulating investment, trade, and banking
within the area. Observers of the Latin
American area are more optimistic about
the potential success of the Andean Group
Common Market than they are about other
Latin American integration schemes. Its
membership so far is limited to countries
bordering the Andes—Bolivia, Chile, Co­
lombia, Ecuador, and Peru. (Venezuela is
associated with the group but is not a
member.)
Central Am erican Common Market
(CACM). During the mid-1950s, the United

Nations Economic Commission for Latin
America proposed the idea of economic
integration in Central America. In 1960,
the work of nearly a decade was brought
together in the Managua Treaty that estab­
lished the Central American Common Mar­
ket. Membership includes Costa Rica, El
Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, and Nica­
ragua. While the countries of the CACM
are similar in terms of their cultural, social,

5

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

and religious heritage—unlike the more di­
verse situation in Europe—moves toward
integration in the area have been much
more modest in scope than those of the
European Common Market.
One of the major early criticisms directed
toward the CACM, and toward other at­
tempts at economic integration among less
developed countries (LDCs), was that gen­
erally LDCs are producers of primary
goods—raw materials and foods—and as
such have little need to trade with each
other. Reducing trade barriers through an
LDC common market arrangement, it was
claimed, would offer few advantages.
Nonetheless, a Brookings Institution
study reported that intra-CACM trade in­
creased about eight times between 1960 and
1968, and that a pronounced increase oc­
curred in the share of trade among market
members.2 It seems beyond question that a
substantial portion of these gains were
achieved because the market agreed to
eliminate internal tariffs on goods produced
within the region, and to establish common
tariffs against nonmembers. Another suc­
cessful undertaking within CACM was the
Central American Clearing House to handle
currency clearings of members.
In recent years, progress in CACM de­
velopment has faltered. During 1969, an
armed conflict between two members—El
Salvador and Honduras—halted progress
within CACM. And in September of this
year, Guatemala, El Salvador, and Nicara­
gua refused to admit goods from Costa
Rica. With political tensions continuing
in the area, the future of the CACM is
tenuous.

6

2Grunwald, Joseph; Wionczek, Miquel S.; and
Camoy, Martin, Latin America Economic Integra­
tion and U.S. Policy, Brookings Institution, Washjngton, D.C., 1972, p. 45.




Council for M utual Econom ic Aid
(CEMA or COMECON). The Council for

Mutual Economic Aid, commonly known
as COMECON in the United States, is a
Soviet-bloc organization with a common
market orientation. Roughly equivalent to
the European Economic Community, the
CEMA places special emphasis on integra­
tion and coordination of economic planning
and scientific research. Begun in 1949, the
CEMA is currently in the early stages of a
15- to 20-year plan for attaining economic
integration of member economies by the
mid- or late 1980s. The CEMA, long dom­
inated by the U.S.S.R. and with headquar­
ters in Moscow, is made up of eight mem­
bers—Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, East Ger­
many, Hungary, Mongolia, Poland, Ru­
mania, and Russia.
European Common Market. See Euro­
pean Economic Community.
European Economic Community (EEC)
or European Community (EC). During the

postwar reconstruction of Europe, there was
a broad-based desire for increased economic
cooperation among nations. In 1951, six
nations established a “common market” by
pooling their coal and steel resources to
form a free trade area. This first step at
economic integration was called the Euro­
pean Coal and Steel Community (ECSC).
For powerful forces within Europe, calling
for broader-scale economic integration, es­
tablishment of a free trade area in two basic
commodities was only a beginning.
The ECSC evolved into the European
Economic Community, the official name of
what is popularly known as the European
Common Market. This successful economic
integration plan began in 1958, with mem­
bership identical to that of the Euro-

Business Conditions, September 1972

pean Coal and Steel Community. Belgium,
France, West Germany, Italy, Luxembourg,
and the Netherlands were the founders
and shapers of the EEC. There has been
no alteration in membership from 1958
through 1972. However, if the governments
of applicant countries ratify pending agree­
ments, membership in the EEC will expand
to include Denmark, Ireland, Norway, and
the United Kingdom on January 1, 1973.3
The most obvious accomplishments of the
EEC in moving toward economic integra­
tion have been the removal of tariff bar­
riers to trade among members, and the set­
ting of uniform community tariffs on non­
member imports. Other accomplishments
of the Community include the development
of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP),
a uniform stance on agricultural policy (see
Business Conditions, February 1970), freer
labor force mobility among members and
associate members, and increased com­
monality in tax systems (see Business Con­
ditions, February 1971). The most recent,
and if successful the most far-reaching,
movement within the EEC concerns plans
to establish a “common currency” and an
implied common monetary-fiscal policy.
What was evolved in the EEC is far more
than a free trade area. Today, the Common
Market is a community of nations with a
degree of integration that makes it an eco­
nomic and political unit to be reckoned
with on its own terms, quite apart from the
nations of which it is composed. Headquar­
ters of the EEC are in Brussels, Belgium.
3In a national referendum late in September, the
Norwegian electorate voted to reject EEC mem­
bership. The final decision will be made by a vote
in Parliament which is expected to follow the lead
set by the referendum. Denmark will hold a bind­
ing national referendum on EEC membership early
in October.




E u rop ean F ree T rade A sso c ia tio n
(EFTA). When the European Common

Market was in the formative stage, several
important European nations chose not to
participate in the Community. Nonetheless,
these governments were fully aware that the
common external tariffs of the EEC would
place individual nonmember states at a dis­
advantage in the European Community.
Spurred by mutual concern, Austria, Den­
mark, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, Switzer­
land, and the United Kingdom established
the European Free Trade Association in
1960, with headquarters in Geneva, Switzer­
land. In 1961, Finland joined, and in 1970
Iceland became a member.
Like the Common Market, EFTA sought
a greater degree of international coopera­
tion among its members, but, overall, its
aims were much more modest than those of
the Common Market group. EFTA’s main
objective was to eliminate tariffs and quota
restrictions on industrial goods traded
among its members. Unlike the long-range
goals of the Common Market, EFTA’s ob­
jectives stopped short of the integration of
members’ economies, and members retained
full control over their own trade restrictions
in relations with third countries.
The future status of EFTA is uncertain.
Britain will terminate EFTA membership
when it joins the EEC next January. In 1970,
Britain accounted for 56 percent of EFTAgenerated gross national product, and 43
percent of its world trade. Denmark and
Norway have also negotiated a membership
agreement, however, lack of public support
within these countries may preclude them
entering the EEC. (See footnote 3.) In that
case, they will remain in EFTA.
The six EFTA countries that chose not to
apply for Common Market membership en­
gaged in negotiations with the EEC earlier

7

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

this year in an effort to obtain trade conces­
sions to mitigate the economic impact of the
association’s reduced size. Denmark and
Norway, if they do not become EEC mem­
bers, may be expected to engage in efforts
to obtain trade concessions from the EEC
similar to those granted other EFT A coun­
tries. As EFT A develops a greater identifi­
cation with the Common Market through
special trading arrangements (some of which
have been negotiated), thereby accomplish­
ing adequate reductions in trade barriers,
it may result in the eventual termination of
EFTA as a formal organization.
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT). In the immediate postwar era, the

8

major trading nations of the world were
quick to recognize the need for new rules
to govern international trade relationships
and the need to establish a forum for study­
ing and discussing mutual trade problems.
This was long before many of these gov­
ernments began to view solutions to trade
problems in terms of the integration of in­
ternational trading patterns and even of na­
tional economies.
The United Nations sponsored the first
major attempt to write new “rules of the
game” for international trade following
World War II. The International Trade Or­
ganization, proposed by the UN, failed to
gain the necessary support and was dropped.
Its aims and objectives, however, were at­
tractive to 23 important trading nations. In­
dependent of the UN, these Western Euro­
pean and North American countries, with
the United States the driving force, worked
out the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade, and implemented the agreement on
January 1, 1948. Today, GATT, with head­
quarters in Geneva, Switzerland, has 80
members, 15 nonmembers that adhere to its




rules, and one provisional member.
GATT’s primary purpose is to provide a
framework of rules for international trade
as free of governmental intervention and
restriction as possible. To maintain this in­
termediary position. GATT calls for adher­
ence to the most-favored-nation principle
in trade and to the use of the GATT as the
forum for settling disputes and for negotiat­
ing reductions in tariff and nontariff barriers
to trade. Testimony to GATT’s effectiveness
is seen in two “rounds” of trade negotiations,
one in 1960, the other in 1964, that resulted
in significant and broad-scale tariff reduc­
tions. A third round of trade talks dealing
with problems of nontariff barriers to trade
is scheduled for 1973. (See Business Condi­
tions, February 1972.)
GATT is unique among trade organiza­
tions. It has proved itself better able than
any other organization to establish rules
for international trade, and to provide re­
course to injured member countries by
sanctioning penalties that injured countries
might apply to member countries that break
GATT regulations. But GATT’s toughest
proving grounds may well lie in the future.
As less developed countries (LDCs) have
joined GATT, increasing pressure has de­
veloped for greater recognition of their
trade problems. The domination of GATT
by the major trading nations continues to
frustrate many LDC efforts to obtain more
favorable trade regulations vis-a-vis the de­
veloped nations. These trade problems are
so troublesome in certain areas that the UN
entered the picture directly through the
United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development. (See below.)
Latin American Free Trade Association
(LAFTA). This Latin American version of

the European Free Trade Association was

Business Conditions, September 1972

established in 1961. It encompasses Mexico
and ten South American countries. Designed
as an instrument of trade liberalization
among member countries, its progress in this
respect has been slow and its other accom­
plishments minimal. Originally, the free
trade area was to be in operation by 1973,
but that target date has been reset to
1980. Initial long-range plans to move all of
LAFTA toward a common market have
been all but sidetracked as emphasis within
Latin America has shifted toward the devel­
opment of more economically homogeneous
groups of countries within smaller, more
manageable geographic areas. (See the An­
dean Group).
Organization for Economic Development
and Cooperation (OECD). In 1948, the

Organization for European Economic Co­
operation (OEEC) was established as a co­
ordinating body for planning and adminis­
tering Marshall Plan aid in the economic
recovery of Western Europe. When recov­
ery became a fact, the older body was re­
placed by the Organization for Economic
Development and Cooperation. Today,
OECD is a 23-member worldwide organiza­
tion concerned primarily with analyzing a
broad range of economic issues. Consulting
and advisory functions are implemented
through the efforts of working committees,
such as the Trade Committee, the Economic
Policy Committee, and the Development
Advisory Committee. The potential for dup­
lication between OECD committees and
various other international organizations—
for example the OECD’s Trade Committee
and GATT—is more apparent than real.
Seldom does the Paris-based OECD go past
defining, examining, and analyzing prob­
lem areas, and making recommendations
for actions. Typically, these functions are



undertaken as complementary to work be­
ing done by other organizations.
United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development (UNCTAD). Frustration and

dissatisfaction by the less developed coun­
tries with their treatment under the rules
of GATT led to the development of the
UN Conference on Trade and Development
in 1964. UNCTAD, currently with 141 mem­
bers, was conceived as an organization
which could apply itself to the unique trade
needs of the developing countries. It has,
however, been restrained by the developed
countries from duplicating the operational
roles of other international organizations,
especially GATT. With the possible excep­
tion of control over some international com­
modity agreements, UNCTAD functions
largely as a forum at which the LDCs make
their needs known, and where these needs
can be studied and analyzed. Resolutions
adopted by the heavily-weighted LDC mem­
bership of UNCTAD may or may not be
adhered to by members, at their individual
discretion, with no sanctions involved for
nonadherence. Regarding effective action
on trade matters of concern to the LDCs,
GATT remains the important agency.
UN Economic Commissions. The United
Nations has served as a springboard for a
number of regional economic organizations.
These organizations may be characterized
as being oriented toward providing a forum
for communications among members, and
for promoting economic development with­
in the region. These are: UN Economic
Commission for Africa (ECA), UN Eco­
nomic Commission for Asia and the Far East
(ECAFE), UN Economic Commission for
Europe (ECE), and UN Economic Commis­
sion for Latin America (ECLA).

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The Farm Credit System
The Farm Credit System of the United
States has provided more than $150 billion
in financing to farmers and their coopera­
tives since its inception in 1916. This tra­
ditional lending role of the System, how­
ever, was augmented recently when the
Farm Credit Act of 1971 authorized the
System to make certain types of nonfarm
loans. This new dimension, along with
liberalization of its farm lending, suggests
that the Farm Credit System will continue
to grow rapidly, despite indications that the
growth in farm debt may slow in the years
ahead.
Structure an d functions

10

The Farm Credit System encompasses a
nationwide network of 37 cooperativelyowned banks and more than 1,000 local
associations. Responsibility for the overall
direction of the System rests with the
13-member Federal Farm Credit Board.
Twelve of the Board’s members are selected
by the President of the United States, the
other by the Secretary of Agriculture. The
Farm Credit Administration—an independ­
ent agency of the U. S. Government—op­
erates under the policies established by the
Board and provides supervision, examina­
tion, and coordination for the System’s
banks and associations.




The banks and associations are spread
over 12 districts. A Federal Land Bank, a
Federal Intermediate Credit Bank, and a
Bank for Cooperatives are located in a
central city within each district. The addi­
tional bank, the Central Bank for Coopera­
tives, is located in Denver, Colorado.
Throughout each district are numerous
Federal Land Bank Associations and Pro­
duction Credit Associations. These local
associations link the System to individual
borrowers.
The Farm Credit System provides three
types of credit. The Federal Land Banks
and the Federal Land Bank Associations
provide long-term real estate loans. The
actual loans are made by the Federal Land
Banks. The Federal Land Bank Associa­
tions, whose membership is made up of the
individual borrowers, process real estate
loan applications and service the loans
made by the land banks.
The Federal Intermediate Credit Banks
and the Production Credit Associations join
together to provide short- and intermediateterm production credit. The actual loans
are made by the Production Credit Associa­
tions, whose membership consists of the in­
dividual borrowers. The funds for such
loans are obtained by borrowings from,
or discounts to, the Federal Intermediate

Business Conditions, September 1972

The 12 Farm Credit Districts

north

Dakota

SOOTH DAKOTA

MICHIGAN

NEBRASKA
fColorado

"ILLINOIS1
INDIANA

Omaha

IBerkeley'
MISSOURI

Denver

Washington.

St. Louis!
ILouisviU
KENTUCKY

Wichita

ALABAMA

Houston

******
StOROIA

. CAROLINA

lNew Orleans

■ FARM C R E D IT BA N KS
Federal Land Bank
Federal Intermediate Credit Bank
Bank for Cooperatives

A C E N T R A L BA N K FO R C O O P ER A T IV ES
•

Credit Banks. The Federal Intermediate
Credit Banks also make loans to, and dis­
counts for, other financing institutions
serving agriculture.
Banks for Cooperatives lend directly to
farmer-owned cooperatives engaged in pro­
cessing or marketing farm products, pur­
chasing or distributing farm supplies, or
providing farm services. The Central Bank



FARM C R E D IT A D M IN ISTR A TIO N

for Cooperatives lends to large farm coop­
eratives whose borrowing needs exceed the
lending capacity of the district Bank for
Cooperatives.
The majority of the funds used for lend­
ing by the banks within the Farm Credit
System are obtained through the sale of
bonds and debentures in national money
and capital markets. Other funds are ob-

11

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

tained from earnings, and from the sale of
investment bonds to individual borrowers
and employees.
Evolution of th e Farm C red it System

The availability of credit in rural areas
was inadequate to meet borrowing needs in
the early years of this century. Many rural
banks were small and undercapitalized. And
prior to the establishment of the Federal
Reserve System in 1913, rural banks did
not have a reliable access to funds from

12




sources outside their communities. The sea­
sonality of rural borrowing needs and the
lack of funds flowing between surplus and
deficit areas often resulted in comparatively
high interest rates on agricultural loans.
Maturities on agricultural loans in the
early 1900s were short, and repayments
were not geared to income flows or the pro­
duction period of the enterprise being fi­
nanced. Three- to five-year real estate loans
were common and, indeed, prior to the
Federal Reserve Act in 1913, national banks

Business Conditions, September 1972

were precluded from making real estate
loans for longer than five years. With such
short maturities, foreclosures on delinquent
loans rose sharply when agricultural in­
come declined for any extended period.
And because farm loans for operating pur­
poses were often collateralized by real
estate, even temporary declines in farm
prices could jeopardize a farmer’s entire
land holdings.
Such problems led Congress to enact the
Federal Farm Loan Act in 1916. This act
marked the first systematic participation of
the federal government in any type of cash
lending activity, and became the cornerstone
for today’s Farm Credit System.
The lan d b an ks

The Federal Farm Loan Act of 1916
established the 12 Federal Land Banks
(FLBs). The act authorized the land banks
to make fully amortized farm mortgage
loans with maturities of up to 40 years at
interest rates not to exceed 6 percent. The
National Farm Loan Associations (now
known as Federal Land Bank Associations),
also established by the act, were set up to
process loan applications and service loans
made by the land banks.
All 12 of the Federal Land Banks were
organized and in operation by 1917. The
initial capital structure of each bank totaled
$750,000 ($9 million in total), with practi­
cally all of the funds coming from the
federal government. In 1932, the federal
government subscribed to an additional
$125 million in FLB stock to help offset a
depressed market for FLB bonds—the pri­
mary source of funds used for lending. The
following year, in conjunction with emer­
gency measures to reduce the large volume
of foreclosures during the Depression, Con­
gress appropriated still another $189 mil­



lion to the FLBs’ paid-in-surplus account.
The FLBs drew upon this latter appropria­
tion for several years, and in 1939 outstand­
ing government capital in the land banks
reached a peak of $314 million.
Retirement of the government capital
was effected by a plan which required land
bank borrowers to purchase stock in their
local associations equivalent to 5 percent
of the loan they received from a FLB. The
local association, in turn, used the funds
from the sale of its own stock to purchase
an equivalent amount of the land bank’s
stock. By 1947, all government indebtedness
was retired, and the land banks, for all
practical purposes, have been completely
owned by farmer-borrowers ever since.
In addition to providing capital, the fed­
eral government found it necessary to pro­
vide the land banks with other sources of
funds during their early history. These addi­
tional funds came from Treasury deposits
in the land banks, and through Treasury
purchases of land bank bonds. Still other
funds came from the purchase of land bank
bonds by such government agencies as the
Federal Farm Mortgage Corporation and
the Production Credit Corporations. At
times, the funds provided by these sources
were substantial. For example, the $212
million of land bank bonds held by the U. S.
Treasury in 1920 represented nearly twothirds of total land bank bonds outstanding.
Production cre d it

The production credit arm of the Farm
Credit System developed in several stages.
The 12 Federal Intermediate Credit Banks
(FICBs) were established by the Agricul­
tural Credits Act of 1923. This act directed
the Secretary of the Treasury to subscribe
to the capital stock of these banks in an
amount not to exceed $5 million per bank

13

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

14

($60 million in total). Additional capital
provided in later years pushed the govern­
ment’s peak outstanding capital in the
FICBs to $126 million.
The intended function of the Federal In­
termediate Credit Banks was to improve the
ability of private lending institutions to pro­
vide intermediate-term financing to farmers
at reasonable rates. This was to be accom­
plished by discounting eligible paper sub­
mitted by commercial banks, agricultural
credit corporations, livestock loan com­
panies, and other specified institutions en­
gaged in lending to farmers. Eligible paper
included notes, drafts, bills of exchange,
debentures, or other such obligations which
were direct evidence of funds advanced by
the institution for agricultural purposes. To
finance the discounting operations, FICBs
were empowered to sell debentures in na­
tional money markets.
Although it was expected that commer­
cial banks would be one of the major users
of the FICB discounting privilege, bankers
were reluctant to do so. In part, their re­
luctance reflected the upper limit on interest
rates banks could charge on loans to their
customers and still meet eligibility require­
ments for FICB discounting. According to
the 1923 act, the margin between the in­
terest rate specified on paper discounted
by a Federal Intermediate Credit Bank and
the FICB discount rate could not exceed
1.5 percentage points. (In turn, the FICB
discount rate could not exceed the rate on
the last issue of FICB debentures sold by
more than 1 percentage point.) Since this
margin was not wide enough to include
prevailing lending rates, bankers limited
their use of the FICB discounting privilege.
Another factor limiting the attractiveness
of FICB discounting was the generally more
favorable terms Federal Reserve System




member banks could obtain by discounting
agricultural paper through their regional
Reserve bank. Federal Reserve banks did
not impose a maximum limit on the margin
between their discount rate and the interest
rate on discounted paper. Moreover, the
Federal Reserve discount rate tended to be
lower than that for the Federal Intermedi­
ate Credit Banks, and the Federal Reserve’s
definition of eligible paper tended to be
broader than the FICB definition.
Several attempts were made during the
late Twenties and early Thirties to offset
the limited use of FICBs by commercial
banks. The margin between the interest rate
on eligible loans and the discount rate was
raised to 3 percentage points, and FICBs
were granted the authority to make direct
loans to institutions otherwise eligible for
discounting privileges. In addition, other
institutions were granted the privilege of ob­
taining funds from the FICBs. But despite
these measures, the volume of discounting
and lending by FICBs continued to lag
original expectations. Finally, Congress
passed the Farm Credit Act of 1933, which
significantly expanded the role of the Fed­
eral Intermediate Credit Banks.
The 1933 act authorized the establish­
ment of 12 Production Credit Corporations,
one for each farm credit district. The Pro­
duction Credit Corporations were empow­
ered to charter local Production Credit As­
sociations (PCAs) and act in a supervisory
capacity over them. The local PCAs were
charged with the responsibility of making
short- and intermediate-term farm loans. To
obtain funds for lending, PCAs were grant­
ed the privilege of discounting their loans
with the FICBs.
Government-subscribed capital to the
Production Credit Corporations totaled
$120 million. The majority of this was to be

Business Conditions, September 1972

used to purchase the stock of the local
PCAs in each district. Additional equity in
each local association was to be provided
by borrower purchases of PCA stock—a
requirement instituted to pattern retirement
of government capital in Production Credit
Corporations after the plan used for the
land banks.
Further changes came with the Farm
Credit Act of 1956. This act merged the
Production Credit Corporations with the
Federal Intermediate Credit Banks and pro­
vided a plan for repayment of the consoli­
dated government capital so that the FICBs
ultimately would be owned by the local
PCAs. At the time of the 1956 act, most
of the PCAs were already borrower-owned,
and by the end of 1968 the remainder
of the government capital in the FICBs was
retired. Since then, the entire production
credit arm of the System has been owned by
farmer-borrowers.
B an ks fo r C o o p e ra tiv e s

Although Banks for Cooperatives formal­
ly emerged in 1933, their functions within
the Farm Credit System started in 1923,
when FICBs were established and author­
ized to discount eligible paper from agri­
cultural credit and marketing cooperative
associations. Because these discountings
proved small, Congress included the authori­
zation for Banks for Cooperatives (BCs) in
the Farm Credit Act of 1933. The act
called for the establishment of 12 district
Banks for Cooperatives and a Central Bank
for Cooperatives located in Washington,
D. C. (recently moved to Denver, Colorado).
The district BCs were authorized to lend
directly to the farmer-owned cooperatives
in their district. The Central Bank for Co­
operatives was designed to lend to large
farm cooperatives whose operations cov­



ered more than one district, and to partici­
pate in large loans made by district BCs.
Funds for BC lending were to be obtained
by borrowing from, or discounting with,
FICBs and commercial banks, and through
the sale of consolidated collateral trust de­
bentures to investors in national money and
capital markets.
The original capital for the Banks for
Cooperatives came from the governmentprovided Agricultural Marketing Revolving
Fund—a fund established in 1929 and later
transferred in part to the BCs. At the peak,
outstanding government capital in the
Banks for Cooperatives totaled $178 mil­
lion. Additional equity capital was to be
provided by borrowing cooperatives with
the ultimate objective that this source of
equity could eventually be used to retire
government capital. This was completed in
1968.
The 1933 act established broad lending
authorities for the Banks for Cooperatives.
Eligible loans to farm cooperatives included
(1) long-term loans for the construction or
purchasing of buildings and other capital
assets, (2) operating loans for inventories,
supplies, etc., and (3) loans to facilitate the
marketing of commodities or the purchasing
of farm supplies. Interest rates and maturi­
ties varied by the type of loans, as did the
stock purchase requirement placed on the
borrowing cooperatives.
G ro w th of th e System

The Farm Credit System has recorded re­
markable growth, especially since the early
Fifties. Total loans or discounts outstand­
ing nearly tripled in both the Fifties and
Sixties, and by mid-1972 amounted to near­
ly $18 billion. Of this, over $15 billion—or
nearly one-fourth of total farm debt out­
standing—represented direct loans to farm-

15

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

ers. The remainder represented outstand­
principle repayments for a period of five
ings at Banks for Cooperatives and FICB
years, (4) make loans to liquidate the indebt­
edness of farmers with mortgaged land, and
loans and discounts to non-PCA institutions.
(5) raise the maximum loan to any one bor­
The land banks are the largest part of
rower from $25,000 to $50,000. These pro­
the Farm Credit System and the leading
visions caused a surge in the demand for
institutional supplier of farm real estate fi­
FLB loans which, combined with the great­
nancing. As of mid-1972, loans outstanding
er availability of funds, allowed the FLBs
among the 12 FLBs totaled over $8 billion.
to extend $730 million in loans during 1934
This accounted for approximately 25 per­
—a record that held until 1963.
cent of total farm real estate debt and near­
Following the mid-Thirties, new money
ly 44 percent of all institutionally-supplied
loaned annually by the FLBs dropped sharp­
farm real estate debt.
ly to a rather stable average of around $60
Lending activity of the land banks
showed erratic patterns during the first
million until 1945. But since then, new
money loaned annually has trended steadily
three decades of their existence. Temporary
declines in the market demand
for FLB bonds resulted in sharp
reductions in the amount of new
The Farm Credit System has
money loaned by the land banks
in the early Twenties, and again
grown rapidly since the
in the late Twenties and early
late Forties
Thirties. Congressional action,
billion dollars
however, provided rapid recov­
8 T
total loans and
discounts outstanding
ery—especially in the Thirties.
BCs
The latter recovery reflected sev­
PCAs
eral factors. Funds available for
lending rose sharply, reflecting
FIC Bs to non-PCAs
large government appropriations
FLBs
billion dollars
to FLB capital, bond purchases
3
by other government agencies,
and a decision to make FLB
bonds the consolidated liability
of all FLBs (thus improving in­
vestor demand). At the same
time, congressional concern over
the sharp rise in farm fore­
closures during the Depression
led to authorizations permitting
FLBs to (1) lower maximum in­
terest charges in both outstand­
ing loans and new loans to 3.5
1920
1930
1940
1950
I9 6 0
1970
percent, (2) eliminate late-payment penalty charges, (3) suspend

B

16




Business Conditions, September 1972

upward, reaching a total of $1.7 billion in
fiscal 1972.
Despite fluctuations in lending behavior,
outstanding farm real estate loans at FLBs
rose steadily until interrupted by shortages
of lendable funds in the late Twenties and
early Thirties. But in conjunction with the
emergency measures during the Depression,
outstandings at FLBs rose sharply to over
$2.1 billion by the end of 1936. This level,
which represented over 30 percent of total
farm real estate debt, was not surpassed
until 1959. Following the mid-Thirties peak,
FLB outstandings declined until the late
Forties—reflecting repayments on the large
volume of loans made during the Depres­
sion and the retirement of government capi­
tal—and then nearly tripled in the Fifties
and the Sixties.
Outstanding loans and discounts at Pro­
duction Credit Associations totaled nearly
$7 billion as of mid-1972. This represented
approximately 18 percent of total non-real
estate farm debt and 31 percent of institu­



tionally-supplied non-real estate farm debt.
In addition to the PCA outstandings, FICBs
held $300 million in loans to, or discounts
for, non-PCA institutions at midyear.
Unlike the land banks, growth in PCA
lending has trended consistently upward.
Outstandings at PCAs increased 2.5 times
during both the latter half of the Thirties
and the decade of the Forties. Thereafter,
the rate of gain in outstandings picked up
sharply, rising to a near 3.5-fold gain in
both the Fifties and Sixties. These growth
rates outpaced both the gains in total nonreal estate farm debt and the gains in such
debt provided by commercial banks—the
leading institutional supplier of non-real
estate farm debt. As a result, PCAs have
continuously absorbed a larger portion of
the non-real estate farm debt market.
Banks for Cooperatives, like PCAs, have
shown strong and consistent growth in their
lending. Between mid-1934 and mid-1939,
loans outstanding at BCs increased nearly
threefold, followed by a nearly fourfold

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

increase during the Forties. The rate of ex­
pansion slowed during the Fifties, but again
accelerated during the Sixties. As of mid1972, outstanding loans at Banks for Co­
operatives totaled $2 billion.
N ew act p o rten d s fu rth e r g ro w th

Prior to 1971, the legal framework sup­
porting the Farm Credit System was en­
tangled in a host of separate acts and
amendments. The Farm Credit Act of 1971,
however, completely rewrote the statutes
governing the System. But more important­
ly, the 1971 act defined new lending provi­
sions which will provide a broader base for
future growth of the Farm Credit System.
The most noteworthy changes in the 1971
act are those that expand the definition of
“eligible borrowers.” The act authorized
both FLBs and PCAs to make loans to
rural nonfarm residents, and loans to farmrelated businesses. Loans to rural nonfarm
residents are restricted to financing the pur­
chase, construction, or remodeling of mod­
erately-priced, single-family dwellings that
are permanently occupied by the borrow­
ing owner. The total amount of such loans
outstanding at any FLB or PCA may not
exceed 15 percent of its total loans out­
standing. Loans to farm-related businesses
are restricted to the financing of those as­
sets or activities used by the business to per­
form custom-type, farm-related services on
the farm.
The act further liberalized the definition
of “eligible borrowers” by authorizing PCAs
to participate in eligible loans made by com­
mercial banks and other lenders, and au­
thorizing Banks for Cooperatives to lend to
farm cooperatives whose membership is
composed of at least 80 percent farmers,
compared to the previously more restrictive
18 90 percent requirement. Another liberaliz­



ing feature of the 1971 act grants FLBs the
authority to lend up to 85 percent of the
“appraised market value” of the real estate
securing the loan. Prior to this change, land
banks were restricted to 65 percent of the
“normal agricultural value” of the mort­
gaged real estate. Both the higher percent­
age and the revised basis for evaluating real
estate will tend to boost FLB lending.
Projected System gro w th to 1980

Projections of future developments are
rarely accurate. Differing analytical tech­
niques and underlying assumptions often
yield widely varying results. Nevertheless,
projections can provide signposts that point
up the general outline of particular devel­
opments at some juncture in the future.
Such is the case in any projection of the
future growth in farm debt and the amount
of financing by the Farm Credit System.
Total farm debt outstanding currently is
estimated at about $65 billion and divided
about equally between non-real estate loans
and loans secured by farmland. While the
magnitude of change In farm debt is un­
certain, it is clear that the upward trend
has not run its course. One recent study
projected that total farm debt would reach
$107 billion by 1980. i This implies a some­
what smaller annual rate of growth in total
farm debt than that experienced during the
past two decades mainly because of an ex­
pected slowing in real estate financing. A
separate study currently in progress suggests
that real estate debt will account for 41
percent of the total farm debt by 1980 and
non-real estate debt will account for the
remaining 59 percent. Assuming the pro-1
1Emanuel Melichar, “Aggregate Farm Capital
and Credit Flows since 1950 and Projections to
1980,” Agricultural Finance Review, vol. 33, July
1972.

Business Conditions, September 1972

jected $107 billion in total farm debt is
realized, farm real estate debt would total
$44 billion and non-real estate debt would
reach $63 billion by 1980.
Federal Land Banks currently account
for 25 percent of total farm real estate debt
outstanding—up from around 19 percent in
1960. PC As, on the other hand, account for
over 18 percent of total non-real estate farm
debt outstanding, compared to less than 12
percent in 1960. If FLBs and PC As con­
tinue to enlarge their share of the farm
credit market at the same rates as they have
since 1960, the land banks’ proportion
would rise to around 29 percent by 1980,
while PCAs would increase to nearly 23
percent. The combined projections of $107
billion total debt and of the proportional
breakdown between real estate and nonreal estate debt would imply that FLB loans
outstanding to farmers would reach ap­




proximately $13 billion by 1980. Similarly,
outstanding PCA loans to farmers might
exceed $14 billion.
The change in the 1971 act, permitting
FLBs to lend up to 85 percent of “market
value,” may cause FLB loans to farmers
to grow at an even faster pace than indi­
cated. In 1945, FLBs were authorized to
raise their loan-to-value ratio from 50 to
65 percent of the normal agricultural value.
This was followed by a sharp uptrend in
new money loaned annually. Whether or
not that experience will be repeated follow­
ing the most recent change is difficult to
foresee. However, the large portion of FLB
loans made at the maximum ratio in recent
years suggest that FLBs will have an in­
centive to utilize the more lenient rules.
The new provision permitting PCAs to
participate in loans made by commercial

19

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

banks and other lenders should also tend
to boost PCA loans to farmers. Although
there is evidence suggesting that banks may
be reluctant to use such arrangements, it is
possible that much of this reluctance will
dissipate by 1980. Moreover, since a signifi­
cant number of rural banks currently use
loan participation arrangements with cor­
respondent banks, it seems reasonable that
PCAs likely will attract at least a portion
of the farm loans carried by banks under
such arrangements.
The new provisions in the 1971 act au­
thorizing PCAs and FLBs to make rural
nonfarm housing loans and farm-related
business loans may well contribute signifi­
cantly to the amount of credit extended by
these lenders over the next several years.
While the volume of rural housing loans le­
gally could reach an upper limit of 15 percent
of total outstandings, an apparent reluctance
on the part of some PCAs and FLBs likely
will hold such lending to a smaller amount.
And while the amount of farm-related busi­
ness financing is not subject to an upper
limit, the restricted scope that the law pro­
vides for this lending makes it doubtful
that such activity will represent a large part
of total lending by FLBs and PCAs. Op­
portunities for such financing will exist and

BU SIN ESS C O N D IT IO N S is p u b lish ed m o n th ly

undoubtedly increase over the next few
years. However, it will take time for the
FLBs and PCAs to develop the expertise
needed to evaluate such loans.
While little basis exists to accurately pro­
ject the overall impact of the new provi­
sions on PCA and FLB outstandings, it is
certain that the new lending authority will
add to the expanding amount of credit ex­
tended. Thus, it is quite likely that the total
credit (including that extended under the
new provisions) outstanding at PCAs and
FLBs at the end of the decade will ap­
proach, and could well exceed, the $30 bil­
lion mark. BC outstandings and FICB loans
and discounts to non-PCA institutions could
add an additional $5 billion to this total.
Overall, the Farm Credit System is sure
to achieve substantial growth during the
current decade. Despite a projected decline
in the rate of growth in total farm debt,
which would slow the growth in loans to
farmers provided by the System, such loans
undoubtedly will continue to represent a
larger portion of total farm debt. More­
over, the new authority to extend certain
nonfarm loans could easily hold the Sys­
tem’s growth rate in total outstandings close
to the rate of expansion which has prevailed
since the Fifties.

b y the F e d e ra l

R eserve

B a n k o f C h ic a g o .

Ja c k L. H e rv e y w a s p r im a rily re sp o n sib le fo r the a rtic le "D ire c to ry o f in te rn a tio n a l o rg a n i­
z a tio n s " an d G a r y L. B e n ja m in fo r "T h e Fa rm C re d it S y s te m ."
Su b scrip tio n s to Business Conditions a re a v a ila b le to the p u b lic w ith o u t c h a rg e . For in fo rm a ­
tion co ncern ing b u lk m a ilin g s , a d d re ss in q u irie s to the F e d e ra l R ese rve B a n k o f C h ic a g o ,
B ox 8 3 4 , C h ic a g o , Illin o is 6 0 6 9 0 .
20

A rtic le s m a y be re p rin te d p ro v id e d source is cred ite d .